Legality Under Anti-Lottery Laws of Amendments to Simultaneous Oil and Gas Leasing Procedures ( 1981 )


Menu:
  •       Legality Under Anti-Lottery Laws of Amendments to
    Simultaneous Oil and Gas Leasing Procedures
    The amendment of the Simultaneous Oil and Gas (SOG) Leasing Procedures to clarify
    the discretion of the Secretary o f the Interior to decline to award leases to applicants
    whose names are drawn under the SOG procedures, provides some additional support
    for the conclusion in the April 7, 1980, O LC memorandum that the SOG program is
    not a prohibited lottery within the scope of 
    18 U.S.C. §§ 1302
     and 1304.
    Serious legal difficulties would arise if the SOG regulations were amended to establish a
    multiple filing system which would give preference to those willing and able to pay the
    most for lease opportunities, because of the statutory requirement that oil and gas leases
    be awarded not to the highest bidder but to the first qualified person making applica­
    tion to hold a lease. Moreover, insofar as a multiple Tiling system would tax lease
    applicants by making their chances depend on the size o f their payments, and poten­
    tially enrich the government, it might be considered a violation of the anti-lottery laws.
    In the absence of a specific statutory limitation on the amount which may be charged
    each applicant for a lease, the Secretary is authorized to increase the present fee to a
    level that more accurately reflects the actual cost of administering the system.
    June 8, 1981
    MEMORANDUM OPINION FOR THE DEPUTY SOLICITOR,
    DEPARTM ENT OF THE INTERIOR
    You have requested the views of this Office on two legal questions
    that involve the Simultaneous Oil and Gas (SOG) Leasing Procedures.
    Both of these questions were prompted in part by a memorandum
    issued by this Office on April 7, 1980, Applicability o f Anti-Lottery Laws
    to Simultaneous O il and Gas Leasing Procedures, 
    4 Op. O.L.C. 557
    (1980). In that memorandum we expressed the view that the random
    lease allocation system established by these procedures is not a prohib­
    ited “lottery” within the meaning of 
    18 U.S.C. §§ 1302
     and 1304. Those
    statutes are discussed in detail in that memorandum.
    Your first question concerns a recent change in the SOG regulations.
    Although it has always been the law that the Secretary of the Interior
    has discretion to decline to award leases to applicants whose names are
    drawn under the SOG procedures, some portions of the old regulations
    did not expressly recognize that discretion. See, e.g., 
    43 C.F.R. § 3112.4-1
     (1979) (a lease “will be issued to the first drawee qualified to
    receive a lease”). The regulations have now been amended to establish
    an offer and acceptance procedure that is more clearly in harmony with
    153
    the Secretary’s discretionary power.1 You ask whether this change in
    the regulation alters our previous conclusion that the SOG program
    falls within the usual legal definition of a lottery 2 but is not a prohib­
    ited lottery within the meaning of §§ 1302 and 1304.
    In our previous memorandum we took note of the argument that the
    Secretary’s residual discretion distinguishes the SOG program from
    some kinds of lotteries. See 4 Op. O.L.C. at 561. We concluded, how­
    ever, that the existence of discretion in the Secretary does not in itself
    make a decisive legal difference in the interpretation of the criminal
    statutes. The purpose of the SOG procedures is to “manage the crowd”
    while implementing the Secretary’s responsibility to award leases to the
    first qualified persons making application. The system operates by allot­
    ting things of value (oil and gas leases) among multiple qualified appli­
    cants on the basis of chance. That is the effect of the procedures
    whenever the Secretary, in his discretion, awards a lease to a randomly
    selected applicant. Whenever that occurs, the SOG procedures so
    clearly resemble a “lottery” that there would be a substantial question
    concerning their legality if Congress had intended in the relevant crimi­
    nal statutes to suppress lotteries of every kind. As you know, we
    concluded in our previous memorandum that Congress did not intend
    to suppress certain “lotteries” employed by officers of the United States
    in the due administration of their statutory powers, if such lotteries are
    not designed to enrich the “promoters.”
    The change in the old regulation to reflect more clearly the scope of
    the Secretary’s discretion does not affect our previous analysis or the
    conclusion articulated in the April 7, 1980, opinion. If anything, the
    clarification of the regulation with respect to the Secretary’s discretion
    provides a small measure of additional support for our conclusion that
    the SOG program, in its present form, is a reasonable attempt by the
    Secretary to carry out a function assigned to him by statute and is not
    therefore a prohibited lottery within the scope of §§ 1302 and 1304.
    Your second question concerns a proposal that has been made for
    further modification of the SOG procedures. Under the present system,
    each lease applicant is permitted, for a nominal fee, to file a single
    application for a given lease; and all qualified applicants have an equal
    chance of being selected under the random selection process. It has
    been suggested that this system could be changed to permit applicants
    to make an unlimited number of applications. The application fee could
    remain the same ($10 for each application), or it could be raised. In
    either case, the amended system would permit each applicant to pur­
    chase as many chances for a lease as he desired, while requiring him to
    1T he new regulations are set o u t in 
    45 Fed. Reg. 35,164
     (M ay 1980). In general, they provide that
    an applicant whose name is draw n under the SO G procedures may execute and tender a lease
    agreem ent, together with a year’s rent, which the Secretary may then accept or reject in his
    discretion.
    2 See F C C v. American Broadcasting Co., 
    347 U.S. 284
     (1954).
    154
    pay proportionately for that privilege. Thus, if an applicant wished to
    purchase 1,000 chances, he would pay the Department $10,000, assum­
    ing the application fee remained $10; he would pay $10,000 for 500
    chances if the fee were increased to $20 per application.
    You note that in our previous memorandum we attributed some
    significance to the fact that the present SOG “lottery” does not enrich
    federal coffers and does not encourage “gambling” by permitting appli­
    cants to purchase more than one chance for a lease. In light of that
    position, you ask whether we would take a different view of the
    “lottery” issue if the SOG regulations were amended to permit multiple
    filings either at the present $10 fee or at an increased fee. You also ask
    whether our views would be altered if the present single filing system
    were retained but the application fee were increased to generate greater
    revenues for the government. We will address those questions in turn.
    1.   Multiple filing. We have carefully reviewed with appropriate offi­
    cials within your Department the policy reasons behind your consider­
    ation of a multiple filing system. We understand that the SOG program
    is not entirely satisfactory from a policy standpoint. As presently ad­
    ministered, it is inefficient economically, for it does not allocate leases
    to the applicants who are most qualified to explore for oil and gas. It
    has produced a private assignment market in which leases obtained by
    applicants who have no intention of exploring for oil or gas are sold to
    bona fide exploration companies for impressive profits. It encourages
    fraud by creating an economic incentive for violation of the single
    application rule. The suggestion has been made that these problems
    could be ameliorated, or perhaps even cured, if applicants were permit­
    ted to register the strength of their desires for a given lease by purchas­
    ing multiple chances at an aggregate price that would approximate the
    “true” value of the exploration opportunity represented by the lease.
    We do not question the merit of the policy argument, but we think
    that serious legal difficulties would arise if the SOG program were
    amended to establish a multiple filing system. We could not recommend
    that such a change be made without further statutory authorization.
    The primary problem is that the change would make it more difficult
    to argue that the SOG system is an otherwise lawful and reasonable
    means of carrying forward the underlying statutory mandate—the re­
    quirement that the Secretary award these leases, not to the highest
    bidders, but to the persons “first making application” who are “quali­
    fied to hold a lease.” See 
    30 U.S.C. § 226
    (c). The random selection
    process was sustained in Thor-Westcliffe Development, Inc. v. Udall, 
    314 F.2d 257
     (D.C. Cir. 1963), as a reasonable means of “managing the
    crowd” while complying with that mandate; but if the system were
    changed to authorize multiple filings at prices that would depend on
    the number of filings made by each applicant, the Secretary would be
    “managing the crowd” by giving an advantage to those applicants who
    155
    are willing and able to pay the most for lease opportunities. We think it
    would be difficult to reconcile that preference with the legislative
    intention that appears on the face of the leasing statute. Among other­
    wise qualified applicants,3 the willingness of one applicant to pay more
    than the others for a chance at a lease may be some indication of the
    relative strength of his desire to exploit the exploration opportunity; it
    may also be nothing more than an indication of his willingness to risk
    more money to obtain a lease that can be sold on the assignment
    market. In any case, there is no suggestion in the statute that an
    applicant’s willingness to pay more should entitle him to priority over
    the other qualified applicants, all o f whom seek a place in line.4 Con­
    gress has mandated that the lease should be awarded not to the person
    who is willing to pay the most, but to the person “first making applica­
    tion.” In complying with that mandate the Department has long taken
    the position that all applicants should be given an “equal chance” for a
    lease. The single application rule was adopted for that very reason.
    That interpretation of the statute has been approved by the courts, see
    M cK ay v. Wahlenmaier, 
    226 F.2d 35
     (D.C. Cir. 1955); and it has been
    tacitly accepted by Congress, a fact noted in our previous memoran­
    dum.
    Without further legislation, the question of authorization is made
    more problematic by the statutory prohibition against “lotteries.” We
    must construe the Acts of Congress harmoniously where such a con­
    struction is possible. Implied amendments or repeals are disfavored, and
    that principle is relevant here. It is one thing to conclude, as the court
    concluded in Thor-Westcliffe Development, Inc. v. Udall, 
    supra,
     that
    Congress has impliedly authorized the Secretary to pick randomly
    among a crowd of applicants when he has no more effective means of
    determining who is “first” while maintaining order in the queue; but it
    is quite another to conclude that Congress has impliedly authorized a
    system to multiple filings that would bear not only a formal, but also a
    substantive resemblance to devices that Congress has condemned in
    other legislation. Through the criminal statutes Congress has sought to
    suppress lotteries designed to tax the public and to enrich the “promot­
    ers.” A multiple filing system would tax lease applicants by making
    their chances depend on the size of their payments; and it could enrich
    the government, depending on the actual cost of administrative system
    3T he statute suggests that virtually any citizen o f the United States is “qualified” to hold a lease,
    subject to certain statutory ceilings on aggregate lease holdings. See 
    30 U.S.C. §§ 181
     and 184. The
    relevant regulations reflect that interpretation of the statute. See 
    43 C.F.R. § 3102
     1 et seq.
    4T he legislative history of th e leasing statute is consistent with the view that the size of an
    applicant's payments should not entitle him to priority T he lease system replaced the old system of
    prospecting permits for land containing no known deposits o f oil and gas; yet in replacing the old
    system. Congress ultimately declined to subject the new prospecting leases to competitive bidding.
    Congress thereby preserved the central feature o f the prospecting system—the preference given to the
    “ first” claimant, whatever his financial resources. See Act o f August 21, 1935, ch. 599, 
    49 Stat. 674
    ; see
    also 79 Cong Rec. S12075 (July 30, 1935) (remarks of Senator Pittman); see also Act of August 8,
    1946, ch 916, § 3, 
    60 Stat. 951
    ; see also S. Rep. No. 1392, 79th Cong., 2d Sess. (1946).
    156
    and the number of chances purchased by the applicants in a particular
    case. Since, as we noted in our earlier memorandum, Congress was
    concerned with the moral issues presented by schemes in which persons
    are encouraged to risk their resources on the chance of a windfall, we
    are concerned that a multiple filing system would appear to do pre­
    cisely that and might therefore be considered a violation of the anti­
    lottery laws. In general, the more closely the leasing system resembles
    otherwise prohibited lotteries, the more difficult it becomes to sustain
    the system under the leasing statute, for the leasing statute cannot
    authorize an otherwise prohibited lottery without impliedly amending
    the criminal statutes pro tanto.
    2.    Single filing, increased fee. You have asked whether any legal
    difficulty would be presented by a simple increase in the $10 filing fee.
    We understand from conversations with officials in your Department
    that under the options now being considered, the increase would be
    justified by the increased cost of administering the SOG procedures.
    Congress has declared generally that any “privilege, authority, use,
    franchise, license, permit, certificate, registration or similar thing of
    value” issued by a federal agency shall be “self-sustaining to the full
    extent possible”; and to that end Congress has authorized the head of
    each federal agency to prescribe uniform fees to be charged in connec­
    tion with the issuance of “things of value.” See 131 U.S.C. § 483a. In
    fixing the amount of such a fee, the agency head is entitled to take into
    account a number of factors, including the direct and indirect cost to
    the government, the value of the thing to the recipient, and the public
    policy or interest to be served in charging the fee. Id.
    We are unaware of any specific statutory limitation that would super­
    sede this general authority in the case of fees charged for SOG applica­
    tions. In the absence of a specific statutory limitation, we believe the
    Secretary is authorized by 31 U.S.C. § 483a to increase the present $10
    fee to a level that more adequately reflects the actual cost of adminis­
    tering the SOG system, a system which, in its present form, is author­
    ized by the leasing statute. We do not believe that an increase would be
    held to violate the anti-lottery laws if it is rationally related to the
    administrative costs by the system and to the purpose of finding quali­
    fied applicants, and is not adopted for the purpose of enriching the
    federal government.
    T h e o d o r e B. O l s o n
    Assistant Attorney General
    Office o f Legal Counsel
    157