Bowe v. Polymedica Corp. , 432 F.3d 1 ( 2005 )


Menu:
  •           United States Court of Appeals
    For the First Circuit
    No. 05-1220
    In re POLYMEDICA CORP. SECURITIES LITIGATION
    RICHARD BOWE, SEP-IRA, on behalf of himself and all others
    similarly situated; JOHN T. MUHA; THOMAS THUMA; LAWRENCE STOREY;
    JIANWEI XU; HOWARD HOFFMAN,
    Plaintiffs-Appellees,
    v.
    POLYMEDICA CORP.; LIBERTY MEDICAL SUPPLY, INC.;
    ERIC G. WALTERS; WARREN K. TROWBRIDGE; STEVEN J. LEE,
    Defendants-Appellants.
    APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS
    [Hon. Robert E. Keeton, Senior U.S. District Judge]
    Before
    Torruella, Cyr, and Lipez, Circuit Judges.
    Jeffrey B. Rudman, with whom James W. Prendergast,
    Michael G. Bongiorno, J. Andrew Kent, and Wilmer Cutler Pickering
    Hale and Dorr LLP were on brief, for appellants PolyMedica Corp.
    and Liberty Medical Supply, Inc.
    Michael DeMarco, with whom Daniel E. Rosenfeld and
    Kirkpatrick & Lockhart LLP were on brief, for appellant Eric G.
    Walters.
    Allan J. Sullivan, with whom Baker & McKenzie LLP was on
    brief, for appellant Warren K. Trowbridge.
    Anthony M. Feeherry, with whom Gus P. Coldebella, Stuart
    M. Glass, and Goodwin Procter LLP were on brief, for appellant
    Steven J. Lee.
    Thomas G. Shapiro, with whom Theodore M. Hess-Mahan,
    Shapiro Haber & Urmy LLP, Andrew M. Schatz, Jeffrey S. Nobel,
    Justin S. Kudler, and Schatz & Nobel, P.C. were on brief, for
    appellee Thomas Thuma.
    December 13, 2005
    LIPEZ, Circuit Judge.     In this appeal pursuant to Rule
    23(f) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure from an order
    certifying a class in a securities fraud case, we must decide an
    issue of first impression in this Circuit:            the standard for
    determining whether a market was "efficient" when applying the
    fraud-on-the-market presumption of investor reliance.            We also
    address the level of inquiry that a district court may pursue at
    the    class-certification   stage   when   making    that     efficiency
    determination.     Defendants-Appellants     PolyMedica      Corporation,
    Liberty Medical Supply, Inc. ("Liberty"), and various officers of
    both   companies   (collectively,    "PolyMedica"1)   argue    that   the
    district court erred in finding that common questions predominated
    under Rule 23(b)(3) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, by
    determining that the market was efficient for eight months of the
    class period, from January 2001 through August 2001 (the "Contested
    Time Period"), and deeming PolyMedica's expert evidence irrelevant
    to that determination.   For the reasons set forth below, we vacate
    the district court's order certifying the class for the Contested
    Time Period, and remand for further proceedings.
    1
    For the sake of simplicity, we refer to both Defendants-
    Appellants who bring this appeal, together with the company whose
    stock is at issue in this case, PolyMedica Corporation, as
    "PolyMedica."
    -3-
    I.
    Thomas Thuma ("Plaintiff") is a purchaser of PolyMedica
    stock,   who   seeks    to   represent    a   class    of    all    purchasers   of
    PolyMedica     stock    from    October       1998    through       August    2001.2
    PolyMedica is the parent company of Liberty, a seller of diabetic
    testing supplies.        According to Plaintiff, PolyMedica reported
    record   revenues      and   earnings    during      the    class    period   based
    primarily on the growth of Liberty's diabetic supplies business,
    which accounted for up to 80% of PolyMedica's revenues.                        As a
    result of these increases in revenue and earnings, the price of
    PolyMedica's stock, which traded on the NASDAQ3 and the American
    Stock Exchange during the class period, increased substantially.
    2
    This is a consolidated action. On November 27, 2000, Richard
    Bowe, SEP-IRA, filed a federal securities class action against
    PolyMedica Corporation and its Chief Executive Officer, Steven J.
    Lee. A like action was subsequently filed by Trust Advisors Equity
    Plus LLC on December 19, 2000. The district court consolidated the
    two cases on July 30, 2001, and allowed a motion appointing Bowe,
    John T. Muha, and Thomas Thuma as lead plaintiffs and approving
    their selection of lead counsel. On October 9, 2001, the three
    lead plaintiffs, together with three other plaintiffs, Lawrence
    Storey, Jianwei Xu, and Howard Hoffman, filed a consolidated
    complaint. The district court subsequently allowed Bowe and Muha
    to withdraw, leaving Thomas Thuma as lead plaintiff. For the sake
    of simplicity, we treat all the plaintiffs' filings as being made
    by Thuma.
    3
    "NASDAQ" stands for the National Association of Securities
    Dealers Automated Quotation, "the largest electronic, screen-based
    market in the world. . . . [whose] services enable securities firms
    to execute transactions in The Nasdaq Stock Market from their own
    locations, relying on real-time trade reporting and automated
    market surveillance."    Nasdaq Stock Market, Inc. v. Archipelago
    Holdings, LLC, 
    336 F. Supp. 2d 294
    , 297 (S.D.N.Y. 2004).
    -4-
    In the consolidated complaint, filed on October 9, 2001, Plaintiff
    alleges that PolyMedica artificially inflated the market price of
    its   stock     by    misrepresenting    sales,    revenues,   and    accounts
    receivable, and by issuing false press releases, causing Plaintiff
    and other members of the class to purchase stock at artificially
    inflated prices.        Plaintiff further alleges that when the truth of
    this fraud became known, PolyMedica's stock lost more than 80% of
    its value.         Plaintiff seeks damages under Section 10(b) of the
    Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. § 78j(b) (the "Exchange
    Act") and Rule 10b-5 promulgated thereunder, 
    17 C.F.R. § 240
    .10b-5,
    and Section 20(a) of the Exchange Act, 15 U.S.C. § 78t(a).
    On     January   28,   2004,    following   several    years   of
    litigation, Plaintiff moved for class certification pursuant to
    Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(a)4 and (b)(3)5, asserting that common questions
    of law and fact predominated, based on the "fraud-on-the-market"
    theory.   As we explain in greater detail below, under the Supreme
    4
    PolyMedica does not dispute that the requirements of Rule 23(a)
    – numerosity, typicality, commonality, and adequacy – have been
    met. Therefore, we do not address them here.
    5
    Rule 23(b)(3) provides, in relevant part, that "[a]n action may
    be maintained as a class action if . . . the court finds that the
    questions of law or fact common to the members of the class
    predominate over any questions affecting only individual members."
    This requirement, "although reminiscent of the commonality
    requirement of Rule 23(a), is 'far more demanding' because it
    'tests whether proposed classes are sufficiently cohesive to
    warrant adjudication by representation.'" Unger v. Amedisys Inc.,
    
    401 F.3d 316
    , 320 (5th Cir. 2005) (quoting Amchem Prods., Inc. v.
    Windsor, 
    521 U.S. 591
    , 623-24 (1997)).
    -5-
    Court's plurality decision in Basic, Inc. v. Levinson, 
    485 U.S. 224
    (1988),6   this   theory    obviates   the    need   for    a   plaintiff   to
    demonstrate individualized reliance on a defendant's misstatement
    by permitting a class-wide rebuttable presumption of reliance,
    thereby enabling a securities fraud class action to meet Rule
    23(b)(3)'s commonality requirement. PolyMedica opposed the motion,
    arguing that the fraud-on-the-market presumption of reliance was
    inapplicable for the Contested Time Period7 because the market for
    PolyMedica   stock    was    not   "efficient"       (a    prerequisite     for
    application of the presumption).             Both sides submitted expert
    testimony in support of their respective positions.
    Plaintiff's expert, Alan R. Miller, relying upon each of
    the five widely-accepted market-efficiency factors set forth in
    Cammer v. Bloom, 
    711 F. Supp. 1264
     (D.N.J. 1989), concluded that
    the market for PolyMedica stock was efficient.                  PolyMedica's
    expert, Dr. Denise Neumann Martin, in turn, concluded that the
    Polymedica market was not efficient, based on three factors not
    enumerated in Cammer.       A hearing on Plaintiff's motion for class
    6
    Justice Blackmun delivered the opinion of the Court in Basic,
    joined by Justices Brennan, Marshall, and Stevens. Justice White,
    joined by Justice O'Connor, dissented from the portion of the
    Court's holding applying the fraud-on-the-market presumption of
    reliance. Justices Rehnquist, Scalia, and Kennedy took no part in
    the consideration or decision of the case.
    7
    PolyMedica does not dispute that the fraud-on-the-market
    presumption of reliance applies to the first two years of the class
    period, October 1998 through December 2000.
    -6-
    certification was held on July 16, 2004.    On September 7, 2004, the
    district court granted Plaintiff's motion to certify the class for
    the entire proposed class period, rejecting Dr. Martin's evidence
    as not relevant to the definition of "market efficiency," which the
    court derived from Basic.   The court also excluded from the class
    those investors who participated in short-sale transactions (i.e.,
    transactions involving the sale of a borrowed security, as further
    discussed below), leaving it to "able counsel [to] develop an
    efficient solution" for identifying short-sellers.
    PolyMedica   filed   an    interlocutory   appeal   from   the
    district court's order certifying the class pursuant to Rule 23(f),
    which we permitted on February 15, 2005.8      On appeal, PolyMedica
    argues that the district court erred in determining that the market
    for PolyMedica stock was "efficient" during the Contested Time
    Period, and in concluding that the fraud-on-the-market presumption
    of reliance was therefore applicable for these months.        PolyMedica
    further argues that the district court erred in certifying the
    class without a plan for identifying and excluding short-sellers
    from the class.
    8
    Rule 23(f) provides, in relevant part, that "a court of appeals
    may in its discretion permit an appeal from an order of a district
    court granting or denying class action certification under this
    rule if application is made to it within ten days after entry of
    the order." Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(f).
    -7-
    II.
    A.            Standard of Review
    We generally review decisions granting or denying class
    certification under the highly deferential "abuse of discretion"
    standard.     Smilow v. Southwestern Bell Mobile Sys., Inc., 
    323 F.3d 32
    , 37 (1st Cir. 2003).               Since Rule 23 contains express legal
    standards      for     class     certification,    "an   appeal     of   a     class
    certification can pose pure issues of law which are reviewed de
    novo," that is, without deference to the district court.                     Tardiff
    v. Knox County, 
    365 F.3d 1
    , 4 (1st Cir. 2004).                  "An error of law
    is, of course, always an abuse of discretion."                 Charlesbank Equity
    Fund II v. Blinds To Go, Inc., 
    370 F.3d 151
    , 158 (1st Cir. 2004).
    Mixed questions of law and fact fall along a degree-of-deference
    continuum,      ranging        from   non-deferential    plenary     review      for
    law-dominated questions, to deferential clear-error review for
    fact-dominated questions.             Johnson v. Watts Regulator Co., 
    63 F.3d 1129
    , 1132 (1st Cir. 1995).
    The formulation of the proper standard for efficiency is
    a    purely    legal    question       reviewed   de   novo.      Reviewing      the
    application of that standard to the facts of a case involves the
    review of a mixed question of law and fact.                See Cammer, 
    711 F. Supp. at 1277
     (stating that "[t]he question of whether the fraud-
    on-the-market theory can substitute for direct reliance in any
    given case is both a legal and a factual one:                   is the market in
    -8-
    which a particular company's stock trades efficient").9              Given the
    various factors relevant to an efficiency determination, and the
    abundant evidence that can be developed with respect to each
    factor, the determination of whether a market is efficient is a
    fact-dominated inquiry.     Therefore, deferential clear-error review
    applies to that determination.          The ultimate decision to certify a
    class is, of course, a discretionary one.
    B.          Level of Inquiry by the District Court
    In determining whether to certify the class, the district
    court   went   well   beyond     the    four   corners   of   the   pleadings,
    considering both parties' expert reports and literally hundreds of
    pages of exhibits focused on market efficiency.                Before we can
    decide whether the district court correctly certified Plaintiff's
    class based on a finding of market efficiency, we must determine
    whether this detailed level of inquiry was appropriate at the
    class-certification     stage.         Plaintiff,   relying   on    the   Second
    Circuit's   decision   in   In    re    Visa   Check/MasterMoney     Antitrust
    9
    We recognize that several courts, including the district court in
    this case, have characterized the determination of whether a
    particular market is efficient as a question of fact. See, e.g.,
    In re PolyMedica Corp. Sec. Litig., 
    224 F.R.D. 27
    , 42 (D. Mass.
    2004) (citing In re Laser Arms Corp. Sec. Litig., 
    794 F. Supp. 475
    ,
    490 (S.D.N.Y. 1989) (stating that "[w]hether in fact [defendant
    company] traded in an efficient market is a question of fact")).
    Because this determination involves the application of the
    definition of efficiency to a particular market, however, we think
    it is more accurate to characterize this determination as a mixed
    question of law and fact.
    -9-
    Litigation, 
    280 F.3d 124
     (2d Cir. 2001), argues that a district
    court should not engage in a weighing of competing evidence at the
    class-certification stage, and should instead confine its review to
    the allegations raised in the plaintiff's complaint.               At that
    stage, according to the Second Circuit, "a district court may not
    weigh    conflicting   expert   evidence   or   engage   in   'statistical
    dueling' of experts."     
    Id. at 135
     (quoting Caridad v. Metro-North
    Commuter R.R., 
    191 F.3d 283
    , 292-93 (2d Cir. 1999)).          In support of
    its position, the Second Circuit looked to Eisen v. Carlisle &
    Jacquelin, 
    417 U.S. 156
     (1974), in which the Supreme Court held
    that Rule 23 did not authorize courts "to conduct a preliminary
    inquiry into the merits of a suit in order to determine whether it
    may be maintained as a class action."      
    Id. at 177
    ; see also J.B. ex
    rel. Hart v. Valdez, 
    186 F.3d 1280
    , 1290 n.7 (10th Cir. 1999)
    (recognizing that "when deciding a motion for class certification,
    the district court should accept the allegations contained in the
    complaint as true").
    PolyMedica, on the other hand, argues that we should
    follow the majority of courts of appeals that have addressed this
    issue.   According to these courts, a district court is not limited
    to the allegations raised in the complaint, and should instead make
    whatever legal and factual inquiries are necessary to an informed
    determination of the certification issues.        See Unger, 
    401 F.3d at 321
     (stating that while "[c]lass certification hearings should not
    -10-
    be mini-trials on the merits of the class or individual claims. .
    . . '[g]oing beyond the pleadings is necessary, as a court must
    understand the claims, defenses, relevant facts, and applicable
    substantive law in order to make a meaningful determination of the
    certification issues'") (quoting Castano v. Am. Tobacco Co., 
    84 F.3d 734
    , 744 (5th Cir. 1996)); accord Cooper v. Southern Co., 
    390 F.3d 695
    , 712 (11th Cir. 2004); Gariety v. Grant Thornton, LLP, 
    368 F.3d 356
    , 365 (4th Cir. 2004); West v. Prudential Sec., Inc., 
    282 F.3d 935
    ,    938    (7th    Cir.    2002)       ("Tough    questions     [at    class-
    certification        stage]   must    be    faced      and   squarely     decided,    if
    necessary by holding evidentiary hearings and choosing between
    competing perspectives."); Johnston v. HBO Film Mgmt., Inc., 
    265 F.3d 178
    , 189 (3rd Cir. 2001); see also Wagner v. Taylor, 
    836 F.2d 578
    , 587 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (noting that "a decision on class
    certification        cannot   be     made    in    a    vacuum,"    and    that   "some
    inspection     of    the   circumstances          of   the   case   is    essential   to
    determine whether the prerequisites of Federal Civil Rule 23 have
    been met").
    In support of this more demanding inquiry at the class-
    certification stage, many of these courts rely on General Telephone
    Co. of Southwest v. Falcon, 
    457 U.S. 147
     (1982), in which the
    Supreme Court noted that since "the class determination generally
    involves considerations that are enmeshed in the factual and legal
    issues comprising the plaintiff's cause of action. . . . sometimes
    -11-
    it may be necessary for the court to probe behind the pleadings
    before coming to rest on the certification question."           
    Id. at 160
    (internal quotation marks and citations omitted); see also Amchem,
    
    521 U.S. at 616
     (noting that Rule 23(b)(3) involves a "close look"
    at predominance and superiority criteria).
    We have already expressed our preference for the majority
    view.   In Waste Management Holdings, Inc. v. Mowbray, 
    208 F.3d 288
    (1st Cir. 2000), we upheld a district court's decision to certify
    a class, where the court "engaged in a case-specific analysis that
    went well beyond the pleadings."          
    Id. at 297
    .    In that case, we
    also squared the Supreme Court's holdings in Eisen and Falcon,
    noting that while Eisen prohibits a district court from inquiring
    into whether a plaintiff will prevail on the merits at class
    certification, it "does not foreclose consideration of the probable
    course of litigation," as contemplated by Falcon.              
    Id. at 298
    .
    "After all," we explained, "a district court must formulate some
    prediction as to how specific issues will play out in order to
    determine whether common or individual issues predominate in a
    given case."    
    Id.
    Three years later, in Smilow v. Southwestern Bell Mobile
    Systems, 
    323 F.3d 32
     (1st Cir. 2003), we noted that "[a] district
    court   must   conduct   a   rigorous   analysis   of   the   prerequisites
    established by Rule 23 before certifying a class."               
    Id.
     at 38
    (citing Falcon, 
    457 U.S. at 161
    ).         And last year, in Tardiff, we
    -12-
    noted the split between circuits, reasoning that while "[i]t is
    sometimes taken for granted that the complaint's allegations are
    necessarily controlling . . . in our view a court has the power to
    test disputed premises early on if and when the class action would
    be proper on one premise but not another."             
    365 F.3d at 4-5
    .
    Therefore, in light of our prior precedent, we conclude that the
    district court was entitled to look beyond the pleadings in its
    evaluation    of   the   applicability     of   the   fraud-on-the-market
    presumption   of   reliance,   and   its    resolution   of   the   class-
    certification question.
    III.
    A.        The Fraud-on-the-Market Theory
    The Supreme Court has described the "basic elements" of
    a securities fraud action under § 10(b) of the Exchange Act and
    Rule 10b-5 promulgated thereunder as including:          (1) "a material
    misrepresentation (or omission)"; (2) "scienter, i.e., a wrongful
    state of mind"; (3) "a connection with the purchase or sale of a
    security"; (4) "reliance"; (5) "economic loss"; and (6) "loss
    causation."    In re Stone & Webster, Inc., Sec. Litig., 
    414 F.3d 187
    , 193 (1st Cir. 2005) (quoting Dura Pharm., Inc. v. Broudo, 
    125 S. Ct. 1627
    , 1631 (2005)); see also Wortley v. Camplin, 
    333 F.3d 284
    , 294 (1st Cir. 2003). While reliance is typically demonstrated
    on an individual basis, the Supreme Court has noted that such a
    rule would effectively foreclose securities fraud class actions
    -13-
    because individual questions of reliance would inevitably overwhelm
    the common ones under Rule 23(b)(3).            Basic, 
    485 U.S. at 242
    .
    To avoid this result, the Supreme Court has recognized
    the fraud-on-the-market theory, which relieves the plaintiff of the
    burden    of     proving     individualized    reliance   on   a   defendant's
    misstatement, by permitting a rebuttable presumption that the
    plaintiff relied on the "integrity of the market price" which
    reflected that misstatement.10          As the Supreme Court recognized in
    Basic, "[t]he fraud on the market theory is based on the hypothesis
    that, in an open and developed securities market, the price of a
    company's stock is determined by the available material information
    regarding the company and its business," including any available
    material misstatements.         
    Id. at 241
     (internal quotation marks and
    citation omitted).          Since investors who purchase or sell stock do
    so in reliance on "the integrity of the market price," 
    id. at 247
    ,
    they indirectly rely on such misstatements because they purchase or
    sell     stock     at   a     price    which   necessarily     reflects   that
    misrepresentation.             Under    the    fraud-on-the-market    theory,
    "[m]isleading statements will therefore defraud purchasers of stock
    even if the purchasers do not directly rely on the misstatements."
    10
    Assuming the plaintiff gets the benefit of the rebuttable
    presumption at the class-certification stage, the defendant may
    still rebut this presumption at trial. According to the Court in
    Basic, "[a]ny showing that severs the link between the alleged
    misrepresentation and either the price received (or paid) by the
    plaintiff, or his decision to trade at a fair market price, will be
    sufficient to rebut the presumption of reliance." 
    485 U.S. at 248
    .
    -14-
    
    Id. at 242-43
     (quoting Peil v. Speiser, 
    806 F.2d 1154
    , 1160-61 (3d
    Cir. 1986)); see also Shaw v. Digital Equip. Corp., 
    82 F.3d 1194
    ,
    1218 (1st Cir. 1996) (noting that in cases involving fraud-on-the-
    market    theory,     "the    statements       identified    by       plaintiffs    as
    actionably misleading are alleged to have caused injury, if at all,
    not through the plaintiffs' direct reliance upon them, but by dint
    of the statements' inflating effect on the market price of the
    security purchased").
    Before an investor can be presumed to have relied upon
    the integrity of the market price, however, the market must be
    "efficient". See Basic, 
    485 U.S. at
    248 n.27 (recognizing elements
    cited    by   court    of    appeals    for     invoking    fraud-on-the-market
    presumption of reliance, including "that the shares were traded on
    an   efficient    market").11       Efficiency      refers       to    the   flow   of
    information      in   the    relevant    market    and     the    effect     of    that
    11
    In addition, the plaintiff must prove: "(1) that the defendant
    made public misrepresentations; (2) that the misrepresentations
    were material" (i.e., that there is a substantial likelihood that
    such misrepresentations "would have been viewed by the reasonable
    investor as having significantly altered the 'total mix' of
    information made available"), and "would induce a reasonable,
    relying investor to misjudge the value of the shares"; and (3)
    "that the plaintiff traded the shares between the time the
    misrepresentations were made and the time the truth was revealed."
    Basic, 
    485 U.S. at 231-32
    , 248 n.27 (citing Levinson v. Basic,
    Inc., 
    786 F.2d 741
    , 750 (6th Cir. 1986), vacated on other grounds,
    
    485 U.S. 224
     (1988)); see generally A&J Deutscher Family Fund v.
    Bullard, No. CV 85-1850 PAR(JRX), 
    1988 WL 152011
    , at *8-12 (C.D.
    Cal. Nov. 29, 1988) (applying Basic's multi-prong test for
    determining presumption of reliance). These factors are not in
    dispute in this interlocutory appeal; therefore, we need not
    address them.
    -15-
    information on the price of the stock.           See In re Laser Arms Corp.
    Sec. Litig., 
    794 F. Supp. at 490
     (stating that "[t]he underlying
    premise of the fraud on the market theory assumes that the market
    is a transmission belt which efficiently translates all information
    concerning a security," including misleading information, "into a
    price").          In      an     efficient     market,      the    defendant's
    misrepresentations are said to have been absorbed into, and are
    therefore reflected in, the stock price. Conversely, when a market
    lacks efficiency, there is no assurance that the market price was
    affected by the defendant's alleged misstatement at all.                Instead,
    the   price     may    reflect   information    wholly     unrelated    to   the
    misstatement.         See Freeman v. Laventhol & Horwath, 
    915 F.2d 193
    ,
    198 (6th Cir. 1990) (stating that "[a]n inefficient market, by
    definition, does not incorporate into its price all the available
    information about the value of a security.              Investors, therefore,
    cannot be presumed to rely reasonably on the integrity of the
    market price of a security that is traded in such a market").
    The fraud-on-the-market presumption of reliance and its
    relationship to market efficiency can thus be reduced to the
    following syllogism:           (a) an investor buys or sells stock in
    reliance   on    the    integrity   of   the   market    price;   (b)   publicly
    available information, including material misrepresentations, is
    reflected in the market price; and therefore, (c) the investor buys
    or sells stock in reliance on material misrepresentations.                   This
    -16-
    syllogism breaks down, of course, when a market lacks efficiency,
    and the market does not necessarily reflect the alleged material
    misrepresentation.   With this understanding as background, we must
    now decide the appropriate standard for determining whether a
    market is efficient.
    B.        The Meaning of "Market Efficiency"
    The efficient market hypothesis began as an academic
    attempt to answer the following question: Can an ordinary investor
    beat the stock market, that is, can such an investor make trading
    profits on the basis of new information?   In an efficient market,
    the answer is "no," because the information that would have given
    the investor a competitive edge and allowed the investor to "beat"
    the market is already reflected in the market price.     See Lynn A.
    Stout, The Mechanisms of Market Inefficiency:   An Introduction to
    the New Finance, 
    28 J. Corp. L. 635
    , 639 (2003) (stating that
    "[t]he common definition of market efficiency . . . is really a
    shorthand for the empirical claim that 'available information' does
    not   support   profitable   trading   strategies   or     arbitrage
    opportunities") (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).12
    12
    Commentators note that "[c]onventional finance recognizes this
    cannot be absolutely true, or no one would have incentive to trade
    on information in a way that leads to the incorporation of that
    information into prices." Stout, supra, at 640 n.24. As further
    discussed below, efficient markets are understood to possess enough
    profit opportunities to allow a small subset of professional
    investors, so-called arbitrageurs, to engage in competition with
    each other, thereby moving the price of stock to reflect such
    -17-
    There is, therefore, no "bargain" from which an investor can
    benefit.    Since the stock price fully reflects the information, an
    investor cannot take advantage of it by either purchasing the stock
    (if the information indicates the stock is underpriced) or selling
    the stock (if the information indicates the stock is overpriced).
    See Philip H. Dyvig & Stephen A. Ross, Arbitrage, in 1 The New
    Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance 48 (Peter Newman et al.
    eds., 1992) (stating that "[t]he intuition behind [the efficient
    market hypothesis] is that if the price does not fully reflect all
    available information, then there is a profit opportunity available
    from buying the asset if the asset is underpriced or from selling
    the asset if the asset is overpriced").
    One way information gets absorbed into the market and
    reflected in stock price is through arbitrageurs, who obtain and
    analyze    information   about   stocks    from   a   variety    of   sources,
    including from the issuer, market analysts, and the financial and
    trade press.    In re Verifone Sec. Litig., 
    784 F. Supp. 1471
    , 1479
    (N.D. Cal. 1992); see generally Ronald J. Gilson & Reinier H.
    Kraakman, The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency, 
    70 Va. L. Rev. 549
    ,
    566   (1983)   (discussing   variety      of   mechanisms   by    which   new
    information is incorporated into stock price).          These arbitrageurs
    immediately attempt to profit from such information (for instance,
    information.
    -18-
    through short sales13), thereby causing the stock to move to a price
    which reflects the latest public information concerning the stock,
    where it is no longer possible to generate profits.    See Eckstein
    v. Balcor Film Investors, 
    8 F.3d 1121
    , 1129 (7th Cir. 1993)
    (stating that "[c]ompetition among savvy investors leads to a price
    that impounds all available information"); see also Stout, supra,
    at 638 n.15 (noting that if arbitrageurs observe a difference
    between price and value, "they immediately eliminate it by their
    trading") (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).14
    The capacity of arbitrageurs to "seek out new information
    and evaluate its effects on the price of securities" distinguishes
    13
    In a short-sale transaction, the seller borrows shares that the
    seller believes to be overvalued from a broker, and pays the broker
    a so-called "loan fee" for the right to borrow the shares plus
    collateral (in cash) for the value of the shares (which is held in
    an interest-bearing margin account). The seller agrees to return
    shares of a similar type and amount to the broker at an unspecified
    date in the future.    The seller then sells the borrowed stock.
    Assuming the price of the stock later decreases, the seller's
    profit will be the positive difference between the price the seller
    pays to replace the borrowed shares (a process known as
    "covering"), and the price at which the seller sold the stock. If
    the price increases before the seller covers its position, the
    seller suffers a loss.
    14
    Plaintiff offers the following example of an arbitrage
    opportunity. Assume that the price of gold trading on the New York
    commodities market was $100.50 per ounce, while on the London
    market, which opened five hours earlier, the price was only $100
    per ounce.   The arbitrageur could first sell an ounce of gold
    "short" in New York, receiving $100.50 in return, and then purchase
    an ounce of gold in London for $100, retaining a profit of $0.50.
    In an efficient market, the New York market would have swiftly
    moved to match the London market price as arbitrageurs moved to
    exploit the imbalance in the two markets.
    -19-
    them from ordinary investors, who "lack the time, resources, or
    expertise to evaluate all the information concerning a security,"
    and     are   thus   "unable   to   act   in   time   to   take   advantage   of
    opportunities for arbitrage profits."           Robert G. Newkirk, Comment,
    Sufficient Efficiency:         Fraud on the Market in the Initial Public
    Offering Context, 
    58 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1393
    , 1409 (1991).                  In an
    efficient market, then, an ordinary investor "who becomes aware of
    publicly available information cannot make money by trading on it"
    because the information will have already been incorporated into
    the market by arbitrageurs.           Stout, supra, at 640.        "An example
    would be an investor who decides to sell a stock upon the public
    announcement of a decline in corporate earnings, who finds that by
    the time she calls her broker, the price has already dropped."
    Id.15
    According   to    the   prevailing      definition    of   market
    efficiency, an efficient market is one in which market price fully
    15
    The efficient market hypothesis is not without its critics, some
    of whom argue that since not all investors have the means to seek
    out information on stocks or the expertise to decipher it, "the
    price of any given stock is not the same as it would be if all
    participants were informed; instead it merely reflects 'the actions
    of a mix of informed and uninformed participants.'"       Brian E.
    Pastuszenski & Inez H. Friedman-Boyce, Back to Basic: Challenging
    the Application of the Efficient Market Hypothesis in Federal
    Securities Lawsuits, SK080 A.L.I.-A.B.A. 907, 919 (2005). Others
    challenge what they interpret to be the efficient market
    hypothesis' faulty assumptions about human behavior, that is, that
    "human beings are rational actors with stable preferences" who are
    "never mislead by emotion and who never make foolish mistakes."
    Stout, supra, at 660 (internal quotation marks omitted).
    -20-
    reflects all publicly available information.         Stout, supra, at 639
    (citing Eugene F. Fama, Efficient Capital Markets:             A Review of
    Theory   and   Empirical   Work,   25   J.   Fin.   383   (1970)).16   This
    definition has been adopted by many lower courts as a prerequisite
    for   applying   the   fraud-on-the-market    presumption     of   reliance.
    PolyMedica urges us to do likewise, arguing that an "efficient"
    market is an open and developed one, in which a stock price will
    move quickly to reflect all publicly available information.
    16
    Courts and commentators have noted that this prevailing
    definition of market efficiency is consistent with the "semi-
    strong" form of the efficient market hypothesis. See, e.g., In re
    Res. Am. Sec. Litig., 
    202 F.R.D. 177
    , 189 (E.D. Penn. 2001)
    (stating that "[t]he Basic court adopted the semi-strong form of
    market efficiency as a prerequisite for a fraud on the market
    presumption"); Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Good
    Finance, Bad Economics:    An Analysis of the Fraud-on-the-Market
    Theory, 
    42 Stan. L. Rev. 1059
    , 1077-78 (1990). There are three
    competing forms of this hypothesis – weak, semi-strong, and strong
    – each of which makes a progressively stronger claim about the kind
    of information that is reflected in stock price. Under the weak
    form, an efficient market is one in which historical price data is
    reflected in the current price of the stock, such that an ordinary
    investor cannot profit by trading stock based on the historical
    movements in stock price. Under the semi-strong form, an efficient
    market is one in which all publicly available information is
    reflected in the market price of the stock, such that an investor's
    efforts to acquire and analyze public information (about the
    company, the industry, or the economy, for instance) will not
    produce superior investment results.     Finally, under the strong
    form, an efficient market is one in which stock price reflects not
    just historical price data or all publicly available information,
    but all possible information – both public and private. Based on
    this form of an efficient market, not even an inside trader can
    outperform other investors because all such information is
    reflected in market price.     Macey & Miller, supra, at 1077-78.
    Commentators have noted that both strong-form and weak-form market
    efficiency are incompatible with the fraud-on-the-market theory.
    Id. at 1078-79.
    -21-
    The district court, on the other hand, expressly declined
    to adopt this prevailing definition of market efficiency.    Relying
    upon language gleaned from the Supreme Court's decision in Basic,
    the district court held that "the 'efficient' market required for
    [the] 'fraud on the market' presumption of reliance is simply one
    in which 'market professionals generally consider most publicly
    announced material statements about companies, thereby affecting
    stock market prices'"; it "is not one in which a stock price
    rapidly reflects all publicly available material information."   In
    re PolyMedica Corp. Sec. Litig., 224 F.R.D. at 41 (emphasis in
    original) (quoting Basic, 
    485 U.S. at
    246 n.24).   Plaintiff agrees
    with the district court's definition, which, he contends, is drawn
    directly from language used by the Supreme Court in Basic.
    PolyMedica argues that the district court's definition of
    market efficiency, while rooted in a footnote in Basic, defies the
    controlling language of Basic, the cases upon which Basic relied,
    and the subsequent cases interpreting Basic, all of which support
    the prevailing definition of market efficiency.      Specifically,
    PolyMedica argues that the definition adopted by the district court
    wrongly focuses on the thought processes of unidentified market
    professionals and whether stock prices are in some way affected by
    their consideration of most (but not necessarily all) material
    public information.   The prevailing definition, on the other hand,
    requires a more searching inquiry into whether stock prices fully
    -22-
    reflect all publicly available information.            We must assess these
    conflicting positions of the parties.
    C.         The Standard for Determining an Efficient Market
    1.      Basic v. Levinson
    While endorsing the fraud-on-the-market presumption of
    reliance in Basic, the Supreme Court did not explicitly address the
    meaning of an "efficient" market.          See Gariety, 368 F.3d at 368
    (stating that Basic "offers little guidance for determining whether
    a market is efficient").    PolyMedica points to various passages in
    Basic   purportedly   showing   a     preference       for   the    prevailing
    definition of an efficient market, noting the Supreme Court's
    statements that "[t]he market is acting as the unpaid agent of the
    investor, informing him that given all the information available to
    it, the value of the stock is worth the market price," and that
    "the market price of shares traded on well-developed markets
    reflects   all   publicly   available      information,      and   hence,   any
    material   misrepresentations."         Basic,   
    485 U.S. at 244, 246
    (emphasis added) (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).
    Elsewhere, however, the Basic decision suggests that
    something less than "all publicly available information" may be
    required, noting that an investor's reliance may be presumed
    "[b]ecause most publicly available information is reflected in
    market price," 
    id. at 247
     (emphasis added).        In separate footnotes
    -23-
    of the decision, the Court further appeared to resist PolyMedica's
    suggested definition of an efficient market. As pointed out by the
    district court, the Supreme Court, after listing several academic
    articles, noted that:
    [w]e need not determine by adjudication what economists
    and social scientists have debated through the use of
    sophisticated statistical analysis and the application of
    economic theory.      For purposes of accepting the
    presumption of reliance in this case, we need only
    believe that market professionals generally consider most
    publicly announced material statements about companies,
    thereby affecting stock market prices.
    
    Id.
     at 246 n.24.   In addition, the Court noted that by accepting a
    rebuttable   presumption     of   reliance,   it   "d[id]   not   intend
    conclusively to adopt any particular theory of how quickly and
    completely publicly available information is reflected in market
    price."   
    Id.
     at 249 n.28.
    While the Supreme Court's language in Basic provides
    support for both the district court's definition of an efficient
    market as well as the prevailing definition urged by PolyMedica,
    the cases relied upon by the Supreme Court in Basic favor the
    latter definition.   In Peil, cited extensively in Basic, the Third
    Circuit noted that "[t]he 'fraud on the market' theory rests on the
    assumption that there is a nearly perfect market in information,
    and that the market price of stock reacts to and reflects the
    available information." Peil, 
    806 F.2d at
    1161 n.10. Likewise, in
    In re LTV Sec. Litig., 
    88 F.R.D. 134
     (N.D. Tex. 1980), which the
    -24-
    Supreme Court also cited, the district court stated that "[t]he
    central assumption of the fraud on the market theory [is] that the
    market price reflects all representations concerning the stock. .
    . . [E]fficient capital markets exist when security [sic] prices
    reflect all available public information about the economy, about
    financial markets, and about the specific company involved."           
    Id. at 144
    .
    Other cases cited in Basic, including the decision of the
    Sixth   Circuit   under   review   in   Basic,   similarly   support   the
    prevailing definition. See Levinson, 
    786 F.2d at 750
     (stating that
    "[t]he fraud on the market theory is based on two assumptions:
    first, that in an efficient market the price of stock will reflect
    all information available to the public . . . and, second, that an
    individual relies on the integrity of the market price when dealing
    in that stock"); T.J. Raney, Inc. & Sons v. Fort Cobb Irrigation
    Fuel Auth., 
    717 F.2d 1330
    , 1332 (10th Cir. 1983) (stating that
    "[t]he [fraud-on-the-market] theory is grounded on the assumption
    that the market price reflects all known material information").
    Given the Supreme Court's disclaimer that it was not
    adopting any particular economic theory in applying the fraud-on-
    the-market presumption of reliance, on the one hand, and its
    embrace of the holdings of cases adopting the prevailing definition
    of market efficiency on the other hand, the most that can be said
    of Basic is that it did not directly address the meaning of an
    -25-
    efficient market, choosing instead to leave the development of that
    concept to the lower courts.            See Abell v. Potomac Ins. Co. of
    Ill., 
    858 F.2d 1104
    , 1120 (5th Cir. 1988) (stating that "Basic
    essentially allows each of the circuits room to develop its own
    fraud-on-the-market rules"), vacated on other grounds sub. nom.
    Fryar v. Abell, 
    492 U.S. 914
     (1989).              Basic is therefore not the
    benchmark for deriving a definition of market efficiency.                 We must
    turn to the decisions of the lower courts, post-Basic, for further
    guidance.
    2.       Lower   Courts'        Interpretation      of     "Market
    Efficiency"
    PolyMedica correctly notes that in the wake of Basic,
    many lower courts have accepted a definition of market efficiency
    which    requires       that   stock   price    fully   reflect   all    publicly
    available information.          The district court conceded as much:             "I
    also note that the definition I have derived from Basic differs
    from    much    of    the   existing   case    law.     Most   cases    define   an
    'efficient' market as a market in which prices incorporate rapidly
    or promptly all publicly available information."               In re PolyMedica
    Corp. Sec. Litig., 224 F.R.D. at 42.
    The district court's observation was apt. The precedents
    from other circuits overwhelmingly favor the definition advanced by
    PolyMedica.          See Gariety, 368 F.3d at 368 (stating that "in an
    efficient market, 'the market price has integrity[;] . . . it
    -26-
    adjusts rapidly to reflect all new information'") (quoting Macey &
    Miller, supra, at 1060); Greenberg v. Crossroads Sys., Inc., 
    364 F.3d 657
    , 662 n.6 (5th Cir. 2004) (stating that "where securities
    are traded in an efficient market, it is assumed that all public
    information        concerning       a    company     is   known   to   the    market   and
    reflected in the market price of the company's stock"); No. 84
    Employer-Teamster Joint Council Pension Trust Fund v. Am. West
    Holding Corp., 
    320 F.3d 920
    , 947 (9th Cir. 2003) (stating that "in
    a modern and efficient securities market, the market price of a
    stock     incorporates        all        available       public   information");       GFL
    Advantage Fund, Ltd. v. Colkitt, 
    272 F.3d 189
    , 208 (3d. Cir. 2001)
    (defining "efficient marketplace" as one "in which stock prices
    reflect      all    available   relevant         information      about      the   stock's
    economic value"); Joseph v. Wiles, 
    223 F.3d 1155
    , 1164 n.2 (10th
    Cir. 2000) (stating that in an efficient market "the investor must
    rely    on    the    market     to        perform    a     valuation    process      which
    incorporates        all   publicly            available     information,       including
    misinformation"); Kowal v. MCI Communications Corp., 
    16 F.3d 1271
    ,
    1276 n.1 (D.C. Cir. 1994) (stating that "in an efficient securities
    market all publicly available information regarding a company's
    prospects has been reflected in its shares' price"); Raab v. Gen.
    Physics Corp., 
    4 F.3d 286
    , 289 (4th Cir. 1993) (reasoning that
    fraud-on-the-market presumption of reliance assumes "the market
    price   has    internalized             all   publicly     available    information");
    -27-
    Freeman, 
    915 F.2d at 198
     (stating that "[t]he fraud on the market
    theory rests on the assumption that the price of an actively traded
    security in an open, well-developed, and efficient market reflects
    all the available information about the value of a company").
    The prevailing definition of an efficient market is also
    consistent with language in our pre-Basic decision in Roeder v.
    Alpha Industries, Inc., 
    814 F.2d 22
     (1st Cir. 1987).         There, we
    stated that under the fraud-on-the-market theory, "[t]he market
    price of stock is taken to be the basis for investment decisions;
    because the price reflected all available information, investors
    are presumed to have been misled by the nondisclosure."         
    Id. at 27
    .17
    3.         Other   Arguments   Supporting  the    Prevailing
    Definition of "Market Efficiency"
    PolyMedica points to statements made by the United States
    Securities     and   Exchange   Commission   ("SEC")   supporting   the
    prevailing definition of market efficiency.        See Brief for the
    Securities and Exchange Commission as Amicus Curiae, Basic v.
    17
    We did not, however, determine the standard for market efficiency
    in Roeder. That case required us to decide whether the fraud-on-
    the-market theory creates an affirmative duty to disclose material
    information to the public.    We concluded that it does not, and
    stated that once plaintiffs have demonstrated breach of a duty to
    disclose material information, the fraud-on-the-market theory
    merely obviates the need for a plaintiff to prove reliance on the
    nondisclosure. We noted in dicta that this presumption of reliance
    stems from a plaintiff's reliance on market price which necessarily
    reflects that nondisclosure.
    -28-
    Levinson, 
    485 U.S. 224
     (1988) (No. 86-279), available at 
    1987 WL 881068
    , at *22 (stating that fraud-on-the-market theory rests on
    proposition that "in an active secondary market, the price of
    company's stock is determined by all material information regarding
    the company and its business"); see also Arthur Levitt, Chairman,
    U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, Testimony before House
    Subcomm. on Telecomm. & Fin., 104th Cong. 13 (Feb. 10, 1995),
    available at http://www.sec.gov./news/testimony/testarchive/1995/
    spch025.txt.
    PolyMedica also argues with some force that the district
    court's definition is logically inconsistent. By requiring that an
    efficient market need only be affected by most but not all material
    information     in   order   to   be   efficient,   the   district   court's
    definition allows some information to be considered "material" and
    yet not affect market price.           Cf. In re Burlington Coat Factory
    Sec. Litig., 
    114 F.3d 1410
    , 1425 (3d Cir. 1997) (stating that "[i]n
    the context of an 'efficient' market, the concept of materiality
    translates into information that alters the price of the firm's
    stock").
    4.        "Market Efficiency" Defined
    On the basis of the authorities and considerations cited,
    we conclude that the definition of market efficiency adopted by the
    district court is inconsistent with the presumption of investor
    -29-
    reliance at the heart of the fraud-on-the-market theory.           By
    rejecting the prevailing definition of market efficiency advocated
    by PolyMedica, and focusing instead on the general consideration by
    market professionals of most publicly announced material statements
    about companies, the district court applied the wrong standard of
    efficiency.    For application of the fraud-on-the-market theory, we
    conclude that an efficient market is one in which the market price
    of the stock fully reflects all publicly available information.
    Anticipating    the   possibility   of   this   definition,
    Plaintiff complains that it forces him to prove that market price
    "correctly" reflects a stock's fundamental value18 before a market
    will be considered efficient.       This argument misconstrues the
    conclusion that market price must "fully reflect" all publicly
    available information. The words "fully reflect" have two distinct
    meanings, each of which points to a different concept of market
    efficiency.
    5.       "Informational" v. "Fundamental Value" Efficiency
    The first meaning of "fully reflect" focuses on the
    ability of the market to digest information, thereby preventing
    18
    As we discuss in further detail below, fundamental value is a
    technical concept which depends on the present value of expected
    future cash flows (e.g., dividends, interest or principal payments,
    liquidations values), "as estimated by well informed and capable
    analysts."    Jonathan R. Macey et al., Lessons from Financial
    Economics: Materiality, Reliance, and Extending the Reach of Basic
    v. Levinson, 
    77 Va. L. Rev. 1017
    , 1022 (1991).
    -30-
    trading profits:       market price "fully reflects" all publicly
    available information when "prices respond so quickly to new
    information that it is impossible for traders to make trading
    profits on the basis of that information."        Stout, supra, at 651.
    This is known as "informational efficiency," and is best understood
    "as a prediction or implication about the speed with which prices
    respond to information."       Id. at 640; see also Daniel R. Fischel,
    Efficient Capital Markets, the Crash, and the Fraud on the Market
    Theory, 
    74 Cornell L. Rev. 907
    , 913 (1989) (stating that "[u]nder
    this definition, a market is efficient if it is impossible to
    devise a trading rule that systematically outperforms the market .
    . . absent possession of inside information").
    "With many professional investors alert to news, markets
    are efficient in the sense that they rapidly adjust to all public
    information . . . ."         West, 
    282 F.3d at 938
    .     Where the market
    reacts   slowly   to   new    information,   it   is   less   likely   that
    misinformation was reflected in market price and therefore relied
    upon. See City of Monroe Employees Ret. Sys. v. Bridgestone Corp.,
    
    399 F.3d 651
    , 676 (6th Cir. 2005) (stating that "in an open and
    efficient securities market[,] information important to reasonable
    investors (in effect, the market) is immediately incorporated into
    stock prices") (internal quotation marks and citation omitted);
    Freeman, 
    915 F.2d at 199
     (stating that "[a]n efficient market is
    one which rapidly reflects new information in price") (quoting
    -31-
    Cammer, 
    711 F. Supp. at
    1276 n.17); Fischel, supra, at 912 (stating
    that     "the    more   rapidly    prices     reflect      publicly-available
    information, the more sensible it is to apply the [fraud-on-the-
    market theory]").
    Determining       whether   a     market     is   informationally
    efficient, therefore, involves analysis of the structure of the
    market and the speed with which all publicly available information
    is impounded in price.          See Fischel, supra, at 912 (enumerating
    factors     relevant    to    determination    of      "trading-rule"   [i.e.,
    "informational"] efficiency, including whether a stock "is actively
    traded, and whether it is followed by analysts and other market
    professionals. . . . , [and] the speed of price adjustment to new
    information [which] can be tested directly by use of widely-
    accepted statistical techniques").
    The second, and much broader meaning of "fully reflect,"
    focuses on the price of the stock as a function of its fundamental
    value:      market price "fully reflects" all publicly available
    information when it responds to information not only quickly but
    accurately, such that "market prices mirror the best possible
    estimates, in light of all available information, of the actual
    economic values of securities in terms of their expected risks and
    returns."       Stout, supra, at 640.       This is known as "fundamental
    value efficiency."           See Fischel, supra, at 913 (stating that
    fundamental value efficiency "focuses on the extent to which
    -32-
    security prices reflect the present value of the net cash flows
    generated by a firm's assets").
    Determining         whether    a     market   is    fundamental   value
    efficient    is    a    much    more    technical    inquiry     than    determining
    informational efficiency.              Depending on the method of valuation
    used, a stock's fundamental value turns on an assessment of various
    factors,    including        "present     operations,     future    growth    rates,
    relative risk levels, and the future levels of interest rates."
    Newkirk, supra, at 1399; see, e.g., Stout, supra, at 641, 643-44
    (discussing valuation of stocks based on Capital Asset Pricing
    Model, which focuses on expected risks and returns); cf. Fischel,
    supra, at 914 (stating that the results of certain kinds of tests
    which measure "how closely prices reflect value," such as those
    which measure "whether the variability of prices is greater than
    the variability of dividends over time . . . . have been extremely
    controversial").
    Courts and commentators often use these two concepts of
    market efficiency interchangeably.                 See Newkirk, supra, at 1407
    (stating    that       "[t]he    manner    in    which    the   courts    apply   the
    [efficient market hypothesis] is problematic because courts often
    fail   to   distinguish         between   value    efficiency     and    information
    efficiency").19         In     fact,   informational      and   fundamental    value
    19
    The parties, themselves, appear to confuse these two concepts.
    In its briefs to this Court, PolyMedica does not mention accuracy
    -33-
    efficiency "often are [] made to go hand-in-hand, with fundamental
    value efficiency flowing naturally from informational efficiency."
    See Stout, supra, at 641.   Despite this blurring of concepts, one
    thing is clear: a market can be information efficient without also
    being fundamental value efficient.    Stout, supra, at 651 (stating
    that "informational efficiency and fundamental value efficiency are
    distinct concepts"); see also Fischel, supra, at 913-14.      While
    fundamental value efficiency may be the more comprehensive of the
    two concepts, encompassing both speed and accuracy, "'[e]fficiency'
    is not an all-or-nothing phenomenon."   Eckstein, 
    8 F.3d at 1130
    .
    of stock price as a condition of market efficiency, and explicitly
    states that an efficient market need not always set a
    "statistically 'correct price' at each instant."      However, the
    report of PolyMedica's expert, Dr. Neumann Martin, together with
    PolyMedica's surreply to the district court, contend that market
    efficiency requires proof that "the resulting stock price fully and
    correctly reflected the news." PolyMedica's surreply goes on to
    state that "the case law makes clear that the market for a
    particular stock must absorb all publicly available information to
    bring about the 'correct price' in order for a market to be
    efficient," and furthermore, that "in an efficient market, the
    price must accurately reflect the stock's value based on that
    information." Thus, while PolyMedica purports to argue that the
    PolyMedica market was not efficient in the informational sense,
    PolyMedica occasionally uses language that reflects the broader
    concept of fundamental value.    By the same token, in his reply
    brief to this Court, Plaintiff objects to PolyMedica's application
    of a "correct price" approach to market efficiency. However, in
    his response to PolyMedica's surreply to the district court,
    Plaintiff appears to embrace this approach by quoting Hurley v.
    FDIC, 
    719 F. Supp. 27
     (D. Mass. 1989), for the proposition that an
    efficient market is "one that obtains material information about a
    company and accurately reflects that information in the price of
    the stock." 
    Id. at 33
     (emphasis added).
    -34-
    Therefore, by requiring that stock price in an efficient
    market fully reflect all publicly available information in order to
    establish the fraud-on-the-market presumption, we do not suggest
    that stock price must accurately reflect the fundamental value of
    the stock.   This distinction is well-supported by the legal and
    economic commentary.    See Jill E. Fisch, Picking a Winner, 
    20 J. Corp. L. 451
    , 464 (1995) (book review) (stating that "[s]tock
    prices regularly and persistently depart substantially from present
    value models as well as from financial variables that would appear
    to supply most of the information relevant to a calculation of
    fundamental value"); Baruch Lev & Meiring de Villiers, Stock Prices
    and 10B-5 Damages:     A Legal, Economic, and Policy Analysis, 
    47 Stan. L. Rev. 7
    , 20 (1994) (stating that "overwhelming empirical
    evidence   suggests   that   capital   markets   are   not   fundamentally
    efficient"); Newkirk, supra, at 1399 (noting that a "major drawback
    to fundamental value theory is that it requires a great deal of
    specific, sometimes unobtainable, information").
    Our focus on whether a particular market has absorbed all
    available information (and misinformation) – such that an ordinary
    investor cannot beat the market by taking advantage of unexploited
    profit opportunities – is not a fundamental value inquiry.             See
    Stout, supra, at 651 (stating that "when finance economists define
    market efficiency in terms of the difficulty of making arbitrage
    profits, they have implicitly abandoned the more-powerful claim
    -35-
    that efficient markets price securities accurately").                          On the
    contrary, for purposes of establishing the fraud-on-the-market
    presumption of reliance, investors need only show that the market
    was informationally efficient. See In re Verifone Sec. Litig., 
    784 F. Supp. at
    1479 n.7 (stating that the fraud-on-the-market theory
    does not require "proof that the market correctly reflects some
    'fundamental value' of the security.               To apply the fraud-on-the-
    market theory, it is sufficient that the market for a security be
    'efficient' only in the sense that market prices reflect the
    available information about the security.").                      The fraud-on-the-
    market   theory    is    concerned      with     whether     a    market     processes
    information in such a way as to justify investor reliance, not
    whether the stock price paid or received by investors was "correct"
    in the fundamental value sense.
    Still,      as   a   matter    of    logic,    we     cannot     say   that
    fundamental value efficiency has no place in applying the fraud-on-
    the-market    presumption        of   reliance    at   the   class-certification
    stage.     Evidence bearing on a stock's fundamental value may be
    relevant     to   the    efficiency       determination          as,   for    example,
    circumstantial evidence that arbitrageurs are not trading in the
    market, with the result that securities prices do not fully reflect
    all publicly available information.               In other words, evidence of
    fundamental value may be relevant to the extent that it raises
    questions about informational efficiency.               But there are practical
    -36-
    limits on the evidence a court can or should consider during the
    class-certification proceedings.        Courts which choose to consider
    such fundamental value evidence at the class-certification stage
    run the risk of turning the class-certification proceeding into a
    mini-trial on the merits, which must not happen.              See Eisen, 
    417 U.S. at 178
     (stating that "[i]n determining the propriety of a
    class   action,   the   question   is   not   whether   the    plaintiff   or
    plaintiffs . . . will prevail on the merits, but rather whether the
    requirements of Rule 23 are met") (internal quotation marks and
    citation omitted).
    6.      Evidence    Necessary      to   Prove   Presumption     of
    Reliance
    It is important to remember that the application of the
    fraud-on-the-market presumption only establishes just that – a
    presumption of reliance.      That reliance can be rebutted at trial.
    See Cammer, 
    711 F. Supp. at 1290
     (stating that "if it were
    concluded after a hearing [that] the market appeared efficient, and
    [that] plaintiffs could proceed under the rebuttable presumption,
    [the defendant] would be entitled to prove to a jury that the
    market was inefficient, thereby rebutting the presumption"); see
    also Lehocky v. Tidel Techs., Inc., 
    220 F.R.D. 491
    , 505 n.16 (S.D.
    Tex. 2004) (stating that "[a]t [the class-certification] stage of
    the proceedings, the Court need only inquire whether the stock
    traded in an efficient market and not examine the merits of the
    -37-
    case. . . . Thus, the Court will not address whether Defendants'
    [sic] can rebut the presumption of reliance").
    As the notes of the Advisory Committee on Rule 301 of the
    Federal Rules of Evidence, cited in Basic, make clear, a party need
    only establish "basic facts" in order to invoke the presumption of
    reliance.     See Basic, 
    485 U.S. at
    245 (citing Rule 301 and Advisory
    Committee Notes in support of statement that "presumptions are . .
    .   useful    devices     for     allocating      the   burden       of    proof   between
    parties"); see also Cammer, 
    711 F. Supp. at
    1291 n.48 (stating that
    under   the    notes      of    the    Advisory    Committee        on    Rule   301,   the
    nonmoving party has the burden of establishing the nonexistence of
    the    presumed    fact        "once    the   party     invoking         the   presumption
    establishes the basic facts giving rise to it") (emphasis in
    original) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    The question of how much evidence of efficiency is
    necessary for a court to accept the fraud-on-the-market presumption
    of reliance at the class-certification stage is therefore one of
    degree.      District courts must draw these lines sensibly, mindful
    that    evidence     of    fundamental        value     may    be    relevant      to    the
    determination        of    informational          efficiency,        but       other    more
    accessible     and     manageable       evidence      may     be    sufficient     at   the
    certification stage to establish the basic facts that permit a
    court to apply the fraud-on-the-market presumption.
    -38-
    We have no illusions that this line-drawing is easy.
    Knowing the high stakes in the class-certification decision,20 the
    parties will try to move the court in different directions, with
    plaintiffs arguing for less evidence of efficiency and defendants
    for more, some of it highly technical.       Exercising its broad
    discretion, and understanding the correct definition of efficiency
    and the factors relevant to that determination, the district court
    must evaluate the plaintiff's evidence of efficiency critically
    without allowing the defendant to turn the class-certification
    proceeding into an unwieldy trial on the merits.    In this highly
    variable setting, these generalities are the best we can do.
    IV.
    Having concluded that the district court adopted the
    wrong definition of market efficiency, we must now decide whether
    the court's determination that the market for PolyMedica stock was
    efficient is nevertheless supportable.   As previously discussed,
    the question of whether a particular market is efficient is a mixed
    question of law and fact.   While the proper definition of market
    efficiency is a purely legal issue reviewed de novo, application of
    this definition to the facts of a case requires district courts to
    20
    Very few class actions go to trial. See Barbara J. Rothstein &
    Thomas E. Willging, Federal Judicial Center, Managing Class Action
    Litigation:   A Pocket Guide for Judges 6 (2005) (stating that
    according to 2005 study, certified class actions settled ninety
    percent of the time).
    -39-
    make judgments about the structure of the market for a particular
    stock. These judgments are reviewed for clear error. Many factors
    bearing on the structure of the market may be relevant to the
    efficiency analysis, and courts have wide latitude in deciding what
    factors to apply in a given case, and what weight should be given
    to those factors.
    The district court in this case based its analysis of
    market efficiency on three factors: "(1) the involvement of market
    professionals,   (2)   the   degree     to   and   fluidity   with   which
    information is disseminated, and (3) whether information affected
    stock market prices."     In re PolyMedica Corp. Sec. Litig., 224
    F.R.D. at 42-43.       Applying these factors, the district court
    determined that the market for PolyMedica stock met the court's
    definition of market efficiency, that is, "one in which market
    professionals generally considered most publicly announced material
    statements about PolyMedica, thereby affecting the stock market
    price."   Id. at 43.    The court explicitly rejected PolyMedica's
    proffered evidence,21 which focused on whether market price "fully
    21
    PolyMedica submitted the expert report of Dr. Denise Neumann
    Martin, who asserted that constraints on short sales, as evidenced
    by a high degree of shorting, a high cost of borrowing shares, and
    the inability to find shares to short, prevented would-be short
    sellers from trading on information, thereby preventing the market
    from incorporating such information. Dr. Neumann Martin posited
    that this breakdown in the ability of the market to incorporate
    such information resulted in unexploited profit opportunities, as
    evidenced by the results of two tests: the serial correlation test
    (assessing whether an investor can predict price changes based on
    historical price data) and the put-call parity test (assessing
    -40-
    and    rapidly   reflect[ed]    all   the     publicly      available    material
    information," ruling that it was "not relevant to the definition of
    market 'efficiency'" announced by the court.                Id.
    PolyMedica argues that by adopting the wrong definition
    of market efficiency, the district court erroneously refused to
    consider    PolyMedica's       evidence      and,   therefore,        erroneously
    concluded that the market for PolyMedica stock was efficient.
    Plaintiff argues that regardless of whether the court adopted the
    wrong definition of efficiency, the factors analyzed by the court
    were   nevertheless   sufficient      to     support   a    finding     of   market
    efficiency under the correct definition of market efficiency that
    we adopt today.     While we agree with Plaintiff that the factors
    considered by the district court were relevant to the issue of
    market efficiency, these factors are not exhaustive.                  See Unger,
    
    401 F.3d at 323
    .    If the district court had used the definition of
    market efficiency that we adopt today, other factors cited by
    PolyMedica may have also been relevant to the efficiency analysis
    and may have supported a contrary finding.                 The district court’s
    error, therefore, was not in analyzing the factors that it did, but
    whether an investor can guarantee a profit by engaging in a series
    of transactions involving a company's stock and its options). We
    make no judgment on the relevance of this evidence to the efficient
    market determination, or the appropriateness of the court's
    consideration   of   this   evidence   during  class-certification
    proceedings. As we have just indicated, those questions are for
    the district court to decide in the first instance, applying the
    proper definition of efficiency.
    -41-
    in applying an erroneous definition of market efficiency that
    prevented it from analyzing other arguably relevant evidence.          We
    must therefore vacate its decision and remand for application of
    the proper standard.22
    V.
    We summarize the essential points of our analysis.        The
    district court was entitled to look beyond the pleadings and
    consider evidence in its evaluation of the applicability of the
    fraud-on-the-market presumption of reliance, and in its resolution
    of the class-certification question.       However, the district court
    adopted a standard of market efficiency at odds with the prevailing
    standard,    holding   that   market    efficiency   means   that   market
    professionals generally consider most publicly announced material
    statements about companies, thereby affecting stock market prices.
    This was error.
    For purposes of establishing the fraud-on-the-market
    presumption of reliance, we adopt the prevailing definition of
    market efficiency, which provides that an efficient market is one
    22
    In its order granting class certification, the district court
    specifically excluded all short-sellers from the class, noting that
    short-sellers do not rely on the integrity of the market price
    (rather, they believe the market price is too high), and therefore
    are not entitled to a fraud-on-the-market presumption of reliance.
    PolyMedica argues that, even if the market for PolyMedica was
    efficient during the Contested Time Period, class certification
    still should not have been granted because the class is not
    "ascertainable."   Because we vacate the district court's order
    certifying the class, we need not decide this issue.
    -42-
    in which the market price of the stock fully reflects all publicly
    available information.          By "fully reflect," we mean that market
    price   responds     so    quickly    to   new    information       that    ordinary
    investors    cannot    make     trading    profits      on   the    basis    of   such
    information.       This is known as "informational efficiency."                    We
    reject a second and much broader meaning of "fully reflect," known
    as "fundamental value efficiency," which requires that a market
    respond to information not only quickly but accurately, such that
    the market price of a stock reflects its fundamental value.
    While evidence of a stock's fundamental value may be
    relevant to the extent that it raises questions about informational
    efficiency, courts which choose to consider such fundamental value
    evidence at the class-certification stage run the risk of turning
    the class-certification proceeding into a mini-trial on the merits,
    which must not happen.         The fraud-on-the-market presumption, after
    all, only establishes a presumption of reliance which can be
    rebutted at trial.        At the class-certification stage, a party need
    only establish "basic facts" in order to invoke the presumption of
    reliance.     The question of how much evidence of efficiency is
    necessary    to    establish    the    fraud-on-the-market          presumption    of
    reliance is one of degree.              While district courts have broad
    discretion    to    draw    these     lines,     they   must   do    so     sensibly,
    understanding the correct definition of efficiency and the factors
    relevant to that determination.
    -43-
    Having    concluded   this   analysis,   we   must   vacate   the
    district   court's    order   certifying   the   class   for    the   period
    beginning January 2001 and ending August 2001, and remand for
    further proceedings consistent with this opinion. Each party shall
    bear its own costs of appeal.
    So ordered.
    -44-
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 04-8019

Citation Numbers: 432 F.3d 1, 2005 U.S. App. LEXIS 27173

Judges: Torruella, Cyr, Lipez

Filed Date: 12/13/2005

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024

Authorities (35)

Nasdaq Stock Market, Inc. v. Archipelago Holdings, LLC , 336 F. Supp. 2d 294 ( 2004 )

Cammer v. Bloom , 711 F. Supp. 1264 ( 1989 )

Hurley v. Federal Deposit Ins. Corp. , 719 F. Supp. 27 ( 1989 )

Basic Inc. v. Levinson , 108 S. Ct. 978 ( 1988 )

no-84-employer-teamster-joint-council-pension-trust-fund-on-behalf-of , 320 F.3d 920 ( 2003 )

Pens. Plan Guide P 23912p James Johnson v. Watts Regulator ... , 63 F.3d 1129 ( 1995 )

max-l-levinson-karl-zuckerman-ronald-m-newman-84-3730-84-377576 , 786 F.2d 741 ( 1986 )

raymond-k-peil-on-behalf-of-himself-and-all-others-similarly-situated-v , 806 F.2d 1154 ( 1986 )

Shaw v. Digital Equipment Corp. , 82 F.3d 1194 ( 1996 )

Charles Kowal v. MCI Communications Corporation , 16 F.3d 1271 ( 1994 )

Dura Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v. Broudo , 125 S. Ct. 1627 ( 2005 )

Wortley v. Camplin , 333 F.3d 284 ( 2003 )

city-of-monroe-employees-retirement-system-on-behalf-of-itself-and-all , 399 F.3d 651 ( 2005 )

Gilbert Roeder, Etc. v. Alpha Industries, Inc. , 814 F.2d 22 ( 1987 )

dean-west-and-lyndell-eickholz-individually-and-on-behalf-of-a-class-of , 282 F.3d 935 ( 2002 )

Cornelius Cooper v. Southern Company , 390 F.3d 695 ( 2004 )

No. 99-1258 , 223 F.3d 1155 ( 2000 )

edward-c-abell-jr-and-carey-walton-cross-v-potomac-insurance-company , 858 F.2d 1104 ( 1988 )

Robert Eckstein v. Balcor Film Investors , 8 F.3d 1121 ( 1993 )

J.B. Ex Rel. Hart v. Valdez , 186 F.3d 1280 ( 1999 )

View All Authorities »