Nursing Care v. Casualty ( 1993 )


Menu:
  • USCA1 Opinion









    February 25, 1993
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    For The First Circuit
    ____________________

    No. 92-1856

    SANDY RIVER NURSING CARE, ET AL.,

    Plaintiffs, Appellants,

    v.

    AETNA CASUALTY, ET AL.,

    Defendants, Appellees.

    ____________________

    APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT

    FOR THE DISTRICT OF MAINE

    [Hon. Morton A. Brody, U.S. District Judge]
    ___________________

    ____________________

    Before

    Selya, Circuit Judge,
    _____________
    Coffin, Senior Circuit Judge,
    ____________________
    and Stahl, Circuit Judge.
    _____________

    ____________________

    K. Craig Wildfang with whom Wood R. Foster, Jr., Anne K.
    ___________________ ______________________ ________
    Weinhardt, Sidney St. F. Thaxter, John D. Gleason, Vance K. Opperman,
    _________ _____________________ _______________ _________________
    Robert J. Schmit, Patrick N. McTeague, and Barnet D. Skolnik were on
    ________________ ____________________ _________________
    brief for appellants.
    Richard G. Parker with whom Paul W. Chaiken, James E. Kaplan,
    __________________ ________________ ________________
    Mark F. Horning, Paul Macri, Fredric W. Yerman, Lewis V. Vafiades,
    _______________ __________ _________________ __________________
    Michael L. McCluggage, Harold J. Friedman, Carl F. Rella, Stanley B.
    _____________________ ___________________ _____________ __________
    Block, Robert S. Frank, Robert F. Hanson, William A. Montgomery,
    _____ ________________ _________________ ______________________
    Michael A. Nelson, James van R. Springer, George Z. Singal, Joseph E.
    _________________ _____________________ _________________ _________
    Coughlin, Paul H. Friedman, Randall B. Weill, Alfred C. Frawley, Peter
    ________ ________________ ________________ _________________ _____
    J. Rubin, Lewis V. Vafiades, and Lewis A. Noonberg were on brief for
    _________ _________________ __________________
    appellees.
    Stephen L. Wessler, Deputy Attorney General, Francis E. Ackerman,
    __________________ ____________________
    Assistant Attorney General, and Thomas D. Warren, Deputy Attorney
    _________________
    General, on brief for the State of Maine, amicus curiae.
    ____________________

    February 25, 1993
    ____________________














    COFFIN, Senior Circuit Judge. Plaintiffs are a group of
    _____________________

    Maine employers who claim that the defendant insurance companies

    illegally conspired to fix prices and conduct a boycott in a

    successful effort to coerce the state legislature into permitting

    higher rates for workers' compensation insurance.1 The district

    court granted summary judgment for defendants based on the

    doctrines established in Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. 341 (1943),
    ______ _____

    and Eastern R.R. Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight,
    ____________________________________ ____________________

    365 U.S. 127 (1961).2 The court concluded that plaintiffs'

    claimed damage -- the additional cost of their insurance -- was

    attributable to the legislation rather than to the alleged

    conspiracy, and that, consequently, federal antitrust laws

    provide no relief.

    On appeal, plaintiffs contend that the court erred both in

    construing their claims and in immunizing defendants' actions.

    After carefully reviewing the record and pertinent caselaw, we

    conclude that the district court properly granted summary

    judgment for defendants. Although we depart somewhat from the

    court's analysis -- finding that the alleged conspiracy

    constituted a per se violation of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 1
    ___ __




    ____________________

    1 Plaintiffs sued fifteen insurance companies and the
    National Council on Compensation Insurance (NCCI), a voluntary
    association of insurers that is a state-licensed rating
    organization.

    2 In briefest summary, these doctrines exempt from antitrust
    liability anticompetitive actions attributable to the state,
    Parker, 317 U.S. at 350-52, and political activity by individuals
    ______
    seeking to influence the passage or enforcement of laws, Noerr,
    _____
    365 U.S. at 136-40.














    -- we affirm the court's holding that the Parker doctrine bars
    ______

    plaintiffs' requested relief.3

    I.4

    Workers' compensation insurance has long been an extremely

    sensitive issue in Maine. Regulation is strict. All employers

    who do not self-insure are required to purchase such insurance.

    Insurers are "required by Maine Law to charge only those rates

    for workers' compensation insurance which have been filed with,

    and approved by, the Maine Superintendent of Insurance in

    conformance with Maine Law." Complt. 32. The businesses and

    the insurers both have been dissatisfied with the system.

    At least since 1981, NCCI and its members have taken

    affirmative steps to challenge the allowable rates as unfairly

    low. They have sought review of the Superintendent's rate

    decisions in court, see, e.g., National Council on Compensation
    ___ ____ _________________________________

    Ins. v. Superintendent of Ins., 481 A.2d 775 (Me. 1984)
    ____ ________________________

    (affirming Superintendent's disapproval of a requested rate

    increase of 27.5%; NCCI had claimed that statistical evidence

    showed that a 110% increase was warranted), and consistently have

    lobbied for legislation that would reduce statutory benefits and

    permit insurers to charge higher rates. Neither their litigation

    ____________________

    3 The complaint sought injunctive relief in addition to
    damages, but neither the district court nor the parties devoted
    attention to this request. We note only that, in light of our
    analysis, we see no basis upon which plaintiffs may be awarded
    injunctive relief.

    4 We draw heavily from the district court's well-stated
    description of the recent history of the Maine workers'
    compensation system.

    -3-














    nor lobbying proved successful during the period relevant to this

    litigation.

    Indeed, to the contrary, the Maine legislature in 1985

    enacted the "Workers' Compensation Competitive Rating Act," which

    directed that workers' compensation insurance rates be rolled

    back at least 8% and frozen at that level until 1987. Me. Rev.

    Stat. Ann. tit. 24-A, 2331-2357 (1985) (repealed). Under the

    Act, insurers were prohibited from requesting rate increases

    exceeding 10% in 1987, 1988 and 1989. Id. at 2355. In
    ___

    addition, the 1985 Act declared that it was intended, inter alia:
    _____ ____

    1. . . . To prohibit price fixing agreements and other
    anticompetitive behavior by insurers.
    . . .
    3. . . . To promote price competition among insurers .
    . . .

    Id. at 2332.
    ___

    The insurers challenged the 1985 act in court. Although the

    Maine Superior Court determined that the rate ceilings were so

    low that they were confiscatory, the court held that the ceilings

    were not unconstitutional because insurers were free to withdraw

    from the market for workers' compensation insurance in Maine.

    National Council on Compensation Ins. v. Superintendent of Ins.,
    ______________________________________ ______________________

    CV-85-459 (Sup. Ct. May 14, 1987) (Alexander, J.), appeal
    ______

    dismissed, 538 A.2d 759 (Me. 1988) (dismissed as moot because
    _________

    1987 legislation repealed 1985 Act).

    In this lawsuit, plaintiffs assert that defendants, unable

    to achieve their goals legally, resorted to improper means.

    Plaintiffs contend that defendants allegedly conspired to fix


    -4-














    prices at a higher-than-lawful rate and to conduct a boycott of

    the Maine workers' compensation market to induce legislation

    authorizing rate increases. As early as 1986, plaintiffs claim,

    defendants jointly began refusing to insure employers

    voluntarily, requiring them to obtain workers' compensation

    coverage through the "residual" or "involuntary" system. Every

    insurer authorized to write workers' compensation policies in

    Maine is required by state law to participate in the "involuntary

    market" and, thus, to share the underwriting responsibility for

    employers otherwise unable to obtain coverage.5 The

    conspirators allegedly increased the pressure on the Maine

    legislature to act when, between late summer and October 1987,

    virtually all workers' compensation insurers in Maine prepared to

    withdraw from the state.

    To avert the crisis that would occur if all workers'

    compensation insurers left, Governor John McKernan convened a

    special session of the legislature devoted exclusively to

    reviewing and reforming Maine's workers' compensation system. In

    short order, the legislature approved the "Workers' Compensation

    Rating Act" (deleting the word "competitive" that had been in the

    title of the 1985 Act), Me. Rev. St. Ann. tit. 24-A, 2361-2374

    (West 1990 and 1992 Supp.). The 1987 Act removed the limitations

    on rate increases contained in the 1985 Act. It authorized NCCI

    to act as agent for its member insurance companies by submitting

    ____________________

    5 Plaintiffs seem to suggest that the shift of employers
    from the voluntary to the involuntary market was in some way
    detrimental to them, but they do not explain how.

    -5-














    joint rate proposals on their behalf to the Superintendent of

    Insurance, who is the ultimate decisionmaker on the rates

    insurers may charge. Insurers are permitted, however, to deviate

    below the rate approved by the Superintendent.

    In 1988, 1989 and 1990, the insurers collectively applied

    for rates beyond the limits allowed in the 1985 Act. Each year,

    the Superintendent rejected the requested rate increases, but

    authorized lower increases that still exceeded the 10% caps set

    by the 1985 legislation. Plaintiffs contend that, as part of the

    insurers' continuing price-fixing conspiracy, defendants

    unlawfully agreed to charge only the maximum rates allowed by the

    Superintendent.

    Through this lawsuit, plaintiffs seek recovery of damages in

    the amount of the increased premiums they have paid since the

    1987 Act was passed and defendants began charging higher rates.

    The district court concluded that this relief was barred because

    the alleged harm was directly traceable to the 1987 legislation

    and the approval of rate increases by the Maine Superintendent of

    Insurance. The court relied on the well-established Parker
    ______

    principle, see 317 U.S. at 350-52, that injury caused by
    ___

    anticompetitive state action is not compensable under the

    antitrust laws. The court further believed that defendants'

    actions were protected by the Noerr doctrine, see 365 U.S. at
    _____ ___

    136-40, which exempts from antitrust liability the collective

    efforts of private actors to promote anticompetitive legislation.




    -6-














    Plaintiffs argue on appeal that the district court erred

    because it mistakenly attributed their asserted injury to state

    action. They contend that they were harmed not by the

    legislation itself but by defendants' ongoing conspiracy to

    obtain and charge higher rates. Parker, they insist, is
    ______

    therefore inapplicable. They further assert that Noerr provides
    _____

    no immunity for defendants because the alleged conspiracy

    involved classic anticompetitive economic conduct -- a boycott

    and price-fixing -- rather than political activity such as

    lobbying or petitioning.

    Defendants respond that, regardless of the nature of the

    conspiracy, which they admitted solely for purposes of the

    summary judgment proceedings, they cannot be assessed damages

    based on the premium increases authorized by state law. Because

    that is the only injury for which plaintiffs seek relief,

    defendants maintain that the district court correctly granted

    summary judgment.

    II.

    The issues we face on this appeal are matters of law, and

    our standard of review is therefore de novo. Liberty Mutual Ins.
    ___________________

    Co. v. Commercial Union Ins. Co., 978 F.2d 750, 757 (1st Cir.
    ___ __________________________

    1992). Although plaintiffs repeated at oral argument a complaint

    earlier made to the district court that they had had inadequate

    time to develop the facts through discovery, we do not see how

    additional investigation could have affected the summary judgment

    decision. Defendants have admitted, for purposes of their


    -7-














    motion, that they conspired to withdraw from the Maine workers'

    compensation market. Plaintiffs identify no other possibly

    discoverable fact that would be material to the legal issues

    before us. We note, moreover, that they have not appealed the

    district court's denial of their motion for additional discovery

    time.

    Plaintiffs make a related claim that the district court

    erred in repeatedly failing to construe their complaint in the

    light most favorable to them, arguing that this standard of

    scrutiny -- normally applicable to motions to dismiss -- applies

    here because defendants conceded the material factual allegations

    of the complaint. This claim also is irrelevant to our

    disposition. As our analysis in the following sections will

    demonstrate, plaintiffs' appeal fails no matter how liberally

    their allegations concerning defendants' conspiracy are construed

    because the specific relief they seek is barred as a matter of

    law.

    III.

    We begin our analysis with an aspect of the case that has

    engendered some confusion, but apparently no real disagreement

    among the parties. In the concluding paragraph of its opinion,

    the district court stated that "[t]he defendants' conspiracy to

    press for legislation permitting them to charge higher rates --

    which in and of itself caused Plaintiffs no injury -- is immune

    under Noerr." Opinion at 22. The State of Maine construed this
    _____

    statement and similar references elsewhere in the opinion as


    -8-














    holding that private actors lawfully may employ a concerted

    economic boycott to influence a legislative determination.

    Disturbed by this specific holding, the State sought and was

    granted permission to file an amicus brief limited to urging that

    we reverse the ruling.

    We have some doubt that the district court intended the

    broad statement attributed to it by the State. Regardless, at

    this point, the State's position meets with no opposition from

    any party. Plaintiffs and defendants all agree that private

    actors who conduct an economic boycott violate the Sherman Act

    and may be held responsible for direct marketplace injury caused
    _________________________

    by the boycott, even if the boycotters' ultimate goal is to

    obtain favorable state action. This view, we find, clearly

    reflects Supreme Court precedent.

    In Noerr, the Supreme Court held that the defendant
    _____

    railroads could associate for the purpose of waging a publicity

    campaign designed to secure legislative action harmful to the

    truckers with whom they competed, without implicating the Sherman

    Act prohibition against combinations in restraint of trade. 365

    U.S. at 136-37. The Court observed that, in a representative

    democracy, individuals must have the ability to "freely inform

    the government of their wishes," id. at 137, and they are
    ___

    permitted to do so even if their motives are entirely

    anticompetitive, id. at 139-40. Any other conclusion "would
    ___

    impute to the Sherman Act a purpose to regulate, not business

    activity, but political activity, a purpose which would have no


    -9-














    basis whatever in the legislative history of the Act." Id. at
    ___

    137.

    Noerr does not protect from antitrust liability, however,
    _____

    all actions designed to influence government. The Court has made
    ___

    it clear that certain "combinations normally held violative of

    the Sherman Act," id. at 136, including price-fixing agreements
    ___

    and boycotts, are not "outside the coverage of the . . . Act

    simply because [their] objective was the enactment of favorable

    legislation," FTC v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass'n, 493 U.S.
    ___ __________________________________

    411, 424 (1990). See also Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian
    ___ ____ ____________________________ ______

    Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492, 503-04 (1988); Noerr, 365 U.S. at 136.
    __________ _____

    In other words, a classic economic restraint of trade is

    actionable even if its primary purpose is political.

    This limitation on the Noerr doctrine was fully explored in
    _____

    Trial Lawyers, a case closely analogous to the one before us.
    _____________

    Trial Lawyers involved a boycott organized by members of the
    ______________

    District of Columbia criminal defense bar. The attorneys agreed

    not to accept any court appointments to represent indigent

    criminal defendants in order to force the District's City Council

    to raise the hourly rate of pay for court-appointed criminal

    defense work. The Supreme Court held that the boycott

    constituted a "plain violation of the antitrust laws," 493 U.S.

    at 428, and that "[o]ur decision in Noerr in no way detracts from
    _____

    this conclusion," id. at 424. Noerr, the Court emphasized,
    ___ _____

    involved "mere attempts to influence the passage or enforcement

    of laws," id. (quoting Noerr, 365 U.S. at 135), not an actual
    ___ _____


    -10-














    restraint on price and output, id. at 423. The Noerr exception
    __ _____

    to antitrust liability thus was inapplicable to the lawyers'

    boycott. Id. at 428.
    ___

    The district court here sought to distinguish Trial Lawyers
    _____________

    from the case before it, at least in part, because the

    anticompetitive conspiracy there was directed at the government,

    the District of Columbia City Council, as a commercial

    participant. Opinion at 20-21. The court appeared to view the

    government's role as a purchaser as significant to the Supreme

    Court's conclusion that Noerr immunity was unavailable:
    _____

    The goal of the trial lawyers' conspiracy was to
    inflict economic pain on the government, forcing it to
    pass legislation. In this case, however, the
    Defendants' alleged conspiracy was not intended to harm
    the government as a commercial participant in the
    marketplace, only to prompt it to pass anticompetitive
    legislation.

    Opinion at 21. Consequently, the district court seemed to say,

    the conspiracy in this case was protected by Noerr.
    _____

    Trial Lawyers does not establish a "government-as-market-
    ______________

    participant" exception to Noerr. What was significant about the
    _____

    concerted activity there was not that the government was the

    purchaser, but that the defendants had sought to influence the

    government through an economic boycott that directly affected the

    marketplace by, inter alia, constricting the supply of lawyers
    _____ ____

    available to represent indigent criminal defendants. The Court

    emphasized that Noerr provides immunity when the alleged
    _____

    restraint of trade is imposed by the government as the intended
    _________________

    consequence of the defendants' concerted activity. It is
    ___________


    -11-














    inapplicable when private actors impose the challenged restraint

    of trade through a boycott or other traditionally unlawful

    economic measure, even when the boycott's sole purpose is to

    instigate favorable governmental action.

    Whether the boycotted purchaser is the government or a

    private individual is irrelevant; the significant factor is

    direct market effect.

    The restraint of trade that was implemented while the
    boycott lasted would have had precisely the same
    anticompetitive consequences during that period even if
    no legislation had been enacted. In Noerr, the desired
    _____
    legislation would have created the restraint on the
    truckers' competition; in this case the emergency
    legislative response to the boycott put an end to the
    restraint.

    Trial Lawyers, 493 U.S. at 425.
    _____________

    Here, too, the defendants allegedly employed an economic

    boycott that beyond doubt "`constituted a classic restraint of

    trade within the meaning of Section 1 of the Sherman Act,'" id.,
    ___

    493 U.S. at 422 (quoting Court of Appeals, 856 F.2d 226, 234

    (1988)). Had these or other plaintiffs sought injunctive relief

    during the boycott period, or had they sought damages based on

    the boycott's direct market effects (such as reduced availability

    of insurance or higher prices resulting from reduced competition

    during the boycott period), they would have had a viable

    antitrust claim. These plaintiffs, however, explicitly have

    disclaimed any request for relief based on injury occurring while







    -12-














    the boycott was in place, before the Maine Legislature passed the

    1987 Act.6

    In all likelihood, it was the plaintiffs' decision to pursue

    only post-legislation damages that influenced the district court

    to state broadly that defendants were immune from liability. The

    court correctly recognized that a conspiracy to press for

    legislation permitting defendants to charge higher rates was

    permissible unless it was implemented through an actual restraint

    on trade. Because plaintiffs sought no direct market damages

    from the boycott, the court evidently treated the boycott not as

    a prohibited restraint of trade but as a lobbying effort

    equivalent to the unethical and deceptive publicity campaign

    waged by the defendants in Noerr.
    _____

    In so doing, the court may have overstated its holding

    unintentionally, permitting the inference drawn by the government

    that the boycott itself was being held immune under Noerr. As we
    _____

    have explained, such a holding would conflict with Supreme Court

    caselaw. Defendants' boycott plainly constituted a per se
    ___ __

    violation of the Sherman Act even though plaintiffs seek no

    marketplace damages resulting from it.

    IV.

    The central issue before us is whether plaintiffs may

    recover damages based on the higher rates they have paid for

    workers' compensation insurance since enactment of the 1987

    ____________________

    6 We offer no view as to whether plaintiffs would have been
    able to prove damages from a constriction of supply or absence of
    price competition resulting from the conspiracy.

    -13-














    legislation. The district court ruled that the state action

    doctrine of Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. 341, precluded such relief
    ______ _____

    because the rate increases were authorized by the Maine

    Legislature, and adopted and implemented by the state's

    Superintendent of Insurance.

    In Parker, "[r]elying on principles of federalism and state
    ______

    sovereignty, [the Supreme Court] held that the Sherman Act did

    not apply to anticompetitive restraints imposed by the States `as

    an act of government.'" City of Columbia v. Omni Outdoor
    __________________ _____________

    Advertising, Inc., 111 S. Ct. 1344, 1349 (1991) (quoting Parker,
    _________________ ______

    317 U.S. at 352). The district court believed that the actions

    of the legislature and Superintendent of Insurance superseded

    defendants' previous conduct, rendering the rate hikes "an act of

    government" immune under Parker rather than an injury inflicted
    ______

    by defendants' conspiracy.

    Plaintiffs offer two reasons why the Parker doctrine does
    ______

    not bar the relief they seek. First, in an argument more heavily

    utilized in the district court, plaintiffs maintain that the

    defendants' use of unlawful activity to coerce the favorable

    legislation makes the Parker doctrine inapplicable. Because the
    ______

    legislature unlawfully was pressured to act, they contend, the

    statute may not be used to insulate defendants from

    responsibility. Second, plaintiffs argue that it was not the

    legislation simply permitting rate hikes that harmed them, but

    the defendants' longstanding conspiracy to charge the maximum

    possible rates.


    -14-














    Neither of these arguments is persuasive. The first

    contention, that the defendants' coercive conduct circumscribes

    the effect of the legislature's actions, is directly contradicted

    by Supreme Court precedent. In a recent case, Omni, 111 S. Ct.
    ____

    at 1352, the Court reaffirmed its previously stated determination

    that Parker immunity turns on who imposed the challenged
    ______ ___

    restraint, not why:
    ___

    "[W]here the action complained of . . . was that of the
    State itself, the action is exempt from antitrust
    liability regardless of the State's motives in taking
    the action."

    Id. at 1352-53 (quoting Hoover v. Ronwin, 466 U.S. 558, 579-80
    ___ ______ ______

    (1984)).

    Omni rejected a proposed conspiracy exception to the Parker
    ____ ______

    doctrine that would have denied immunity when government

    employees were involved as conspirators with private actors in

    the challenged restraint of trade. The Court considered possible

    methods for defining a conspiracy exception, including an

    approach that would make Parker inapplicable only if, in
    ______

    connection with the governmental action in question, bribery or

    some other violation of state or federal law were established.

    Id. at 1353. It ultimately concluded that any such limitation
    ___

    would be, at best, an imprecise way to determine which

    anticompetitive state actions should be exempted from antitrust

    liability.

    Such unlawful activity has no necessary relationship to
    whether the governmental action is in the public
    interest. A mayor is guilty of accepting a bribe even
    if he would and should have taken, in the public
    interest, the same action for which the bribe was paid.

    -15-














    . . . To use unlawful political influence as the test
    of legality of state regulation undoubtedly vindicates
    (in a rather blunt way) principles of good government.
    But the statute we are construing is not directed to
    that end.

    Id.
    ___

    The holding in Omni fully embraces plaintiffs' tendered
    ____

    coercion exception. Allegations of coercion, like those of

    conspiracy, implicate only the off-limits issue of the

    legislators' motivation. Omni reaffirms that the state action
    ____

    protection provided by Parker is not vulnerable to such claims.
    ______

    Plaintiffs' second theory bears down more closely on the

    1987 legislation. Because the statute does not mandate that
    _______

    insurers charge the maximum rates allowed by the Superintendent,

    but merely eliminated the caps imposed by the repealed 1985 Act,

    plaintiffs maintain that the higher rates by which they were

    damaged resulted from defendants' conspiracy to charge the

    maximum rates and not from the legislature's adoption of the

    statute. We detect two problems with this argument.

    First, the manner in which plaintiffs asserted this theory

    before the district court differed in a subtle, yet significant,

    way from the approach adopted on appeal. Throughout the

    proceedings before the district court, plaintiffs emphasized that

    they alleged injury from a conspiracy initiated in the summer and

    fall of 1987 to violate the 1985 legislation, which promoted open
    ____

    competition in the workers' compensation market.

    Plaintiffs do not claim that they were injured by
    actions mandated by the 1987 legislation. Indeed,
    plaintiffs allege not only that the conspiracy began
    before the 1987 legislation was even enacted, but that

    -16-














    the objective of the conspiracy was that very
    _________
    enactment. Plaintiffs in fact allege that they were
    injured by defendants' conspiracy to violate the 1985
    ____
    legislation. It is therefore the 1985 legislation
    against which state action claims must be tested.

    Plaintiffs' Memorandum in Opposition to Defendants' Joint Motion

    for Summary Judgment, at 18 n.11 (emphasis in original).

    At oral argument on the summary judgment motion, plaintiffs

    again asserted that it had been unlawful for the defendants to

    conspire to increase prices while the 1985 legislation governed.

    See App. at 720. When the district court asked why the
    ___

    defendants' actions were not protected in light of their "acting

    within the framework set up by the legislature in the enactment

    of rates," plaintiffs' counsel responded that "one needs to be

    clear on the time frame." Id. at 729. He continued:
    ___

    At the time the conspiracy was hatched and effectuated
    in summer and fall of 1987, the policy of the State of
    Maine was open competition in workers' comp. The
    policy of the State of Maine was, "Go compete with each
    other."

    And these defendants had a private agreement, in
    effect, not to compete and to boycott consumers and the
    state.

    Id.
    ___

    Thus, the argument to the district court focused on conduct

    leading up to the 1987 act: the defendants unlawfully conspired

    to charge higher rates, and obtained permission to do so through

    unlawful means, making the new rates wholly a result of

    defendants' unlawful conduct. Moreover, the plaintiffs argued,

    even though the specific harm for which they sought damages did

    not occur until after the law was changed and higher rates


    -17-














    authorized, defendants had to be held responsible so that their

    past illegal conduct would not be immunized retroactively.

    Failing to hold them liable, plaintiffs argued,

    would lead to the anomalous result that unsuccessful
    ____________
    boycotts (i.e. boycotts which do not successfully
    ____
    coerce governmental action) would be antitrust
    violations, but that successful boycotts (i.e. boycotts
    __________ ____
    to which government succumbs in order to avoid chaos or
    disaster) would be immunized.

    Plaintiffs' Memorandum in Opposition, at 35-36 (emphasis in

    original) (footnote omitted).7

    The argument on appeal unquestionably adds a new dimension.

    Plaintiffs now contend that, after passage of the 1987 act,

    defendants again violated antitrust laws by conspiring to refuse

    to sell below the new maximum rates established by the

    Superintendent of Insurance. That agreement is not entitled to

    state action immunity, plaintiffs suggest, because the provision

    in the 1987 Act allowing independent ratesetting demonstrates

    that state policy still favors competition. Consequently,

    plaintiffs contend that defendants should be held liable for the

    rate increases.8

    ____________________

    7 As we made clear in Section III, the response to this
    argument is that unlawful boycotts with direct marketplace impact
    will result in accountability for the market injury, regardless
    ______
    of their success in inducing governmental action.

    8 We note that some portions of plaintiffs' appellate brief
    retain the focus on the 1985 legislation:

    Plaintiffs do not challenge the Defendants'
    "participation in ratesetting proceedings" in 1988
    after the 1987 legislation was enacted repealing the
    1985 Competitive Rating Act. What Plaintiffs challenge
    is Defendants' conspiracy begun in 1986 and 1987, at a
    __________
    time when Maine law specifically prohibited such

    -18-














    This link between plaintiffs' conspiracy allegation and the

    1987 Act never was offered to the district court; indeed, as

    noted above, plaintiffs expressly disclaimed the new statute's

    relevance to the Parker issue. The conspiracy achieved success,
    ______

    plaintiffs asserted, when the State enacted the law allowing

    higher premiums. See Memorandum in Opposition to Summary
    ___

    Judgment, at 2-3 (quoted in District Court Opinion, at 3). Led

    by these arguments, the district court never considered whether

    the defendants could be held responsible for the rate increases -

    - despite authorization of those rates by the state -- if they

    had conspired not to deviate below the maximum rate.

    Whether plaintiffs sufficiently preserved this argument need

    not unduly detain us, however, because the theory is in any event

    unavailing. When the legislature enacted the 1987 statute, it

    did not simply eliminate the ceiling on the permissible rates for

    workers' compensation insurance, but it also moved away from the

    state's previous pro-competitive policy toward ratesetting. The

    1987 Act provided for joint rate filings9 and, in our view, it

    ____________________

    conspiracies, to constrict supply, to fix prices, and
    to boycott consumers in order to coerce the removal of
    __________________________________
    the existing price ceiling.
    __________________________

    Plaintiffs' Brief at 31 (additional emphasis added).

    9 It did so somewhat indirectly through repeal of the 1985
    Act, which meant that the joint ratemaking provisions that then
    existed for all lines of insurance sold in Maine again were
    applicable to workers' compensation insurance. In 1989, the
    legislature revised the general insurance ratemaking system to
    encourage competition, leaving the joint ratemaking provisions
    applicable only to the workers' compensation providers. Compare
    ____ _______
    Me. Rev. Stat. Ann. tit. 24-A, 2309 (West 1990) with Me. Rev.
    ____
    Stat. Ann. tit. 24-A, 2309 (West Supp. 1992).

    -19-














    must be construed as implicitly condoning an agreement among

    insurers to charge the rates they jointly propose, subject to

    approval by the Superintendent. When insurers work together

    within a state regulatory system to advocate rates that they all

    presumably believe are appropriate for workers' compensation

    insurance, we fail to see how it could be illegal price fixing

    for them also subsequently to agree to charge the rates allowed

    by the state, particularly when the approved rates fall below the

    jointly proposed rates.

    At a minimum, it must be lawful for insurers to agree to

    charge the approved rate where, as here, the Superintendent's

    obligation is to establish rates that are "[j]ust and reasonable"

    and "[b]ased only on a just and reasonable profit." Me. Rev.

    Stat. Ann. tit. 24-A, 2363 (7)(A)(1), (2). Thus, while the

    statute stipulates that these rates set the upper limit on

    permissible charges, id. at 2362, the expectation clearly is
    ___

    that the Superintendent's rates are the ones that generally will

    be appropriate for, and thus used by, all insurers. In this

    context, the legislature evidently viewed the sort of "price

    fixing" alleged by plaintiffs as benign; notably absent from the

    1987 statute is a provision contained in the 1985 Act prohibiting

    insurers from agreeing "to adhere to or use a rate or rating

    plan," id. at 2347 (2) (1985) (repealed).
    ___

    Plaintiffs rely on the provision allowing downward rate

    deviation to support their claim that defendants' conspiracy to

    charge a uniform rate was unauthorized and, consequently, not


    -20-














    immunized under Parker. But the fact that insurers may charge
    ______ ___

    less than the approved rate is of little significance when it is

    juxtaposed with the uniform approach to ratemaking that is the

    overriding characteristic of the reformed system. On its own,

    the permissive provision certainly does not establish a state

    policy favoring competitive pricing. Moreover, the Supreme

    Court, in Southern Motor Carriers Rate Conference v. United
    __________________________________________ ______

    States, 471 U.S. 48 (1985), explicitly held that Parker immunity
    ______ ______

    is available to private parties acting pursuant to a regime of

    collective ratemaking that is authorized, though not compelled,

    by the state.

    Southern Motor Carriers involved a challenge to the joint
    ________________________

    activities of motor common carrier rate bureaus in four states

    where carriers were permitted to agree on rate proposals before

    their submission to state agencies. In the course of its

    decision, the Court reaffirmed the two-pronged test set forth in

    California Retail Liquor Dealers Ass'n v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc.,
    _______________________________________ _____________________

    445 U.S. 97, 105 (1980), for determining whether the

    anticompetitive conduct of private parties within a state

    regulatory scheme is shielded from the antitrust laws:

    First, the challenged restraint must be "`one clearly
    articulated and affirmatively expressed as state
    policy.'" Second, the State must supervise actively
    any private anticompetitive conduct.

    471 U.S. at 57 (citations omitted).

    The justices then considered whether the actions of a

    private party can be attributed to a clearly articulated state

    policy, within the meaning of the Midcal test's first prong, even
    ______

    -21-














    if the state does not compel the challenged anticompetitive

    activity. Id. at 59-60. The Court observed that a compulsion
    ___

    requirement would reduce the range of alternatives available to a

    state that wished to regulate a given industry -- thereby

    negatively affecting principles of federalism -- while perhaps

    also causing greater restraints on trade -- thereby impairing the
    _______

    goal of the antitrust laws to ensure "unfettered competition in

    the marketplace," id. at 61. Declining to "believe that Congress
    ___

    intended to resolve conflicts between two competing interests

    [federalism and competition] by impairing both more than

    necesssary," id., the Court concluded that "a state policy that
    ___

    expressly permits, but does not compel, anticompetitive conduct
    _______

    may be `clearly articulated' within the meaning of Midcal," id.
    ______ ___

    (emphasis in original).

    In this case, it is manifestly clear that defendants'

    ratemaking activities meet both prongs of the Midcal test. The
    ______

    new scheme was adopted by the legislature, fulfilling the state

    policy prong of the test, and the Superintendent's involvement in

    reviewing and modifying the insurers' proposed rates

    unquestionably meets prong two's requirement of active state

    supervision. Indeed, plaintiffs expressly acknowledge that

    Midcal is satisfied with respect to the ratemaking proceedings.
    ______

    See Reply Brief, at 19 n.15. Plaintiffs instead hammer on
    ___

    defendants' "converting the results of that ratemaking

    proceeding, i.e. a schedule of maximum or ceiling prices, into a
    ____ _______

    private agreement to uniformly charge the maximum price, and to
    _______


    -22-














    refuse to deal at prices below that level." Id. (emphasis in
    ___

    original).

    This argument misfires because it fails to take into account

    the changed landscape. Even if defendants violated the Sherman

    Act in the late summer and early fall of 1987 by conspiring to

    raise the maximum prices they could charge beyond those permitted

    by the 1985 Act, it does not necessarily follow that it was

    unlawful for them to agree to charge the rate subsequently

    approved by the Superintendent pursuant to the 1987 Act. Once

    the legislature acted in November 1987, defendants' conduct had

    to be assessed in light of the new state policy and procedures.

    As we have discussed, the 1987 Act endorsed cooperative

    ratesetting and anticipated that most, if not all, insurers would

    charge the newly authorized rates. Accordingly, the damages

    sought by plaintiffs -- the differential between the rates

    allowed under the 1985 Act and the new rates charged by

    defendants under the 1987 Act -- must be viewed as a product of

    state action. The district court therefore correctly concluded

    that, under Parker, defendants may not be held accountable for
    ______

    this claimed injury.





    V.

    In summary, we hold that the economic boycott and price

    fixing conspiracy allegedly conducted by defendants in the summer

    and early fall of 1987 constituted a per se violation of the
    ___ __


    -23-














    Sherman Act, and did not fall within the Noerr doctrine's
    _____

    protection for concerted activity designed to elicit favorable

    legislation. But plaintiffs have not sought damages for direct

    marketplace injury inflicted by that conspiracy.

    The monetary damages alleged by plaintiffs -- the amount of

    increase in their workers' compensation insurance rates under the

    1987 statutory scheme allegedly coerced by defendants -- are not

    recoverable from the insurers. Because the state authorized

    collective ratemaking and closely supervised the setting of

    higher rates, any agreement among defendants to charge the

    maximum authorized rates is permissible, and defendants are

    immune from liability for the increase under the Parker doctrine.
    ______

    Affirmed.
    ________




























    -24-