Caribe v. Bayerische ( 1994 )


Menu:
  • UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE FIRST CIRCUIT
    No. 93-1653
    CARIBE BMW, INC.,
    Plaintiff, Appellant,
    v.
    BAYERISCHE MOTOREN WERKE AKTIENGESELLSCHAFT, ET AL.,
    Defendants, Appellees.
    APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF PUERTO RICO
    [Hon. Raymond L. Acosta, U.S. District Judge]
    Before
    Breyer, Chief Judge,
    Coffin, Senior Circuit Judge,
    and Boudin, Circuit Judge.
    Anne  M.  Rodgers  with  whom  William  R.  Pakalka,  Fulbright  &
    Jaworski, L.L.P., Enrique J. Mendoza Mendez, Law Offices of Enrique J.
    Mendoza Mendez,  Randall A. Hopkins,  Randall A.  Hopkins, P.C.,  Dahr
    Jamail,  Jamail &  Kolius,  Thomas R.  McDade,  and McDade  &  Fogler,
    L.L.P., were on brief and reply brief for appellant.
    Irving Scher  and Manuel  A. Guzman  with whom  Bruce A.  Colbath,
    Weil,  Gotshal &  Manges  and  McConnell  Valdes  were  on  brief  for
    appellees.
    March 25, 1994
    BREYER, Chief  Judge.    This  appeal  raises  two
    issues  of antitrust law.   First, do a  firm's wholly owned
    subsidiary and the  firm itself amount to  a "single seller"
    under the Robinson-Patman Act?  15 U.S.C.   13.  Second, can
    a retailer's lost profit, brought  about by a maximum resale
    price  fixing  agreement  between  that  retailer   and  its
    supplier, amount  to an "antitrust  injury," thereby  giving
    that retailer "standing" to obtain treble damages?  Atlantic
    Richfield Co.  v. USA Petroleum  Co. ("ARCO"), 
    495 U.S. 328
    (1990); Albrecht v.  Herald Co.,  
    390 U.S. 145
      (1968).   We
    answer both these questions in the affirmative.  Because the
    district  court's  dismissal  of the  plaintiff's  complaint
    rested upon  negative answers to the same  questions, we set
    its dismissal aside.
    I
    Background
    From  1981   through   1990,  Caribe   BMW,   Inc.
    ("Caribe"),  through     contracts   with  the   German  BMW
    manufacturer,  Bayerische  Motoren Werke  Aktiengesellschaft
    ("BMW AG"), bought  BMW automobiles from BMW AG  in Germany,
    imported them into Puerto Rico, and sold them at retail.  In
    February  1991,  Caribe (the  appellant  here) brought  this
    lawsuit  against (the  appellees)  BMW AG  and BMW's  wholly
    -2-
    2
    owned North American subsidiary,  BMW of North America, Inc.
    ("BMW  NA").    Caribe's  complaint  (actually,  its  second
    amended complaint), with commendable simplicity, listed four
    counts.
    Count I charged a violation of the Robinson-Patman
    Act.  15 U.S.C.   13.  It said that BMW AG sold cars  to BMW
    NA, which resold  those cars to other retailers who competed
    with  Caribe,  at  prices  lower  than,  or  on  terms  more
    favorable than, those at  which BMW AG sold similar  cars to
    Caribe.  Count II charged a violation of   1  of the Sherman
    Act.  15  U.S.C.   1.   It said that BMW AG  had set maximum
    resale  prices  for  the cars  that  it  sold  to Caribe  by
    "threaten[ing]  to  terminate  Caribe's   contracts"  unless
    Caribe  would  agree,  in  effect, to  maintain  low  resale
    prices.   Count III charged "breach of contract."  It listed
    various  ways in which BMW AG had allegedly broken its word.
    Count  IV charged  that,  in terminating  its contract  with
    Caribe, BMW AG had violated Puerto Rico's Dealers' Contracts
    Act, more familiarly known  as Act 75.  P.R.  Laws Ann. tit.
    10,   278 et seq.
    The district court dismissed the complaint for two
    related reasons.   First, it found that  the complaint's two
    antitrust  counts  "fail[ed] to  state  a  claim upon  which
    -3-
    3
    relief can be granted."  Fed.  R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6).  Second,
    it  noted that  a forum  selection  clause in  the contracts
    between   Caribe  and   BMW  AG   provided  for   "exclusive
    jurisdiction" in  "Germany" to resolve "disputes"  about the
    "termination of" or  "rights and duties arising  out of" the
    agreement.  It found this clause applicable to the remaining
    (non-antitrust) claims,  and it dismissed  those claims "for
    improper venue" or, in the alternative, "on grounds of forum
    non  conveniens."   Caribe BMW,  Inc. v.  Bayerische Motoren
    Werke Aktiengesellschaft  , 
    821 F. Supp. 802
     (D.P.R. 1993).
    Caribe appeals.
    When  reviewing  the  dismissal of  the  antitrust
    claims  we  take  the  facts  basically  as  stated  in  the
    complaint and make reasonable  inferences that will help the
    plaintiff.   Garita  Hotel  Ltd. Partnership  v. Ponce  Fed.
    Bank,  F.S.B., 
    958 F.2d 15
    , 17  (1st  Cir. 1992).    After
    examining those  facts,  in light  of the  relevant law,  we
    conclude that  the district court should  not have dismissed
    the  antitrust claims.   And,  that conclusion  requires the
    district court to reexamine dismissal of the other claims as
    well.
    II
    The Robinson-Patman Act Claim
    -4-
    4
    The Robinson-Patman Act forbids "any person"
    to   discriminate   in   price   between
    different  purchasers of  commodities of
    like grade  and quality . .  . where the
    effect of such discrimination may be . .
    .  to injure . . .  competition with any
    person who . . . grants  . . . the . . .
    discrimination,  or with  [that granting
    person's] customers . . . .
    15 U.S.C.   13(a).   Caribe's complaint alleges most  of the
    essentials  of a  violation.   It says  that a  "person" has
    "discriminate[d]  in  price  between  different  purchasers"
    (namely, Caribe  and  other retailers  in  competition  with
    Caribe)  of cars,  with the  effect that  "competition with"
    that  person's "customer"  (namely, Caribe)  is "injure[d]."
    See FTC v. Morton Salt Co., 
    334 U.S. 37
    , 45 (1948).  But, it
    embodies an ambiguity in respect to the "person" who did the
    discriminating.  It says  that BMW AG sold cars  directly to
    Caribe, which resold them at retail.  It then  says that BMW
    NA sold cars to other retailers, who compete with Caribe, at
    lower  prices than BMW AG sold its  cars to Caribe.  At this
    point,  there appear  to be  two "persons"  selling BMWs  to
    retailers,  namely, BMW AG (selling them  to Caribe) and BMW
    NA (selling  them to  Caribe's competitors).   The complaint
    adds, however, that BMW NA is the wholly owned subsidiary of
    BMW AG.  Thus, we must face the legal question of whether or
    not  this last mentioned fact  is sufficient to  make of the
    -5-
    5
    two  separately incorporated companies a single "person" for
    Robinson-Patman Act purposes.  If so, the complaint properly
    alleges that a single "person" has sold similar goods at two
    different  prices (allegedly  with  the  required  statutory
    effect).    If  not,  there  may  be  no  "person"  who  has
    "discriminate[d]."   See  
    id.
     ("discrimination"  requires at
    least  two sales by a  single person at  different prices to
    different customers  in competition  with  each other);  see
    also  Phillip Areeda  & Louis  Kaplow, Antitrust  Analysis
    601(c) (4th ed. 1988); 3 Earl W. Kintner &  Joseph P. Bauer,
    Federal Antitrust Law   21.11, at 192-93 (1983).
    So far,  when courts  have faced this  question --
    whether or not a firm and its subsidiary amount to  a single
    "person"  (or a "single seller") -- they have answered it by
    examining  the extent of common ownership  and the degree of
    control over pricing and  distribution policies that the one
    exercises over the other.   See Acme Refrigeration of  Baton
    Rouge,  Inc. v.  Whirlpool Corp.,  
    785 F.2d 1240
    ,  1243 (5th
    Cir.) (100% ownership, without control, not enough to create
    a  "single  seller"), cert.  denied,  
    479 U.S. 848
      (1986);
    Island Tobacco  Co. v.  R.J. Reynolds  Indus., Inc.,  
    513 F. Supp. 726
    , 734 (D. Haw. 1981) (same); Baim & Blank, Inc., v.
    Philco  Corp.,  
    148 F. Supp. 541
    ,  543-44 (E.D.N.Y.  1957)
    -6-
    6
    (same); Massachusetts Brewers Ass'n  v. P. Ballantine & Sons
    Co., 
    129 F. Supp. 736
    , 739 (D. Mass. 1955) (same);  see also
    Kintner & Bauer,  supra,   21.16 at 212.   In this case, the
    extent  of ownership  is  100%;  Caribe's complaint  alleges
    nothing about  actual control.   Thus,  we must  ask whether
    100%   ownership,  by  itself,   amounts  to   a  sufficient
    allegation  that the  "firm  plus subsidiary"  are a  single
    Robinson-Patman Act "person."  We conclude, for reasons that
    we shall now explain, that it does.
    For  purposes of  clarity, we  shall refer  in our
    explanation to  hypothetical entities whom we  shall call 1)
    the Manufacturer  (M), 2) its wholly  owned Distributor (D),
    3)  the Retailer  (R1) who buys  from D,  and 4)  the Direct
    Buying  Retailer (DBR),  who buys  directly from  M and  who
    resells  in   competition  with   R1.     The   distribution
    arrangement looks like the following:
    M
    D
    R1                    DBR
    -7-
    7
    In our case,  BMW AG holds  the position of  M; BMW NA,  the
    position of  D; Caribe,  the position of  DBR; and  Caribe's
    unspecified  retail competitors,  the position  of R1.   The
    legal question, put in  terms of the diagram, is  whether or
    not  M's 100%  ownership of  D  makes M  and D,  together, a
    "single  seller,"  say  "MD."    If  so,  a single  "person"
    (allegedly) "discriminates" in price.
    We now  return to the reasons  for our affirmative
    answer, which are three.  First,  in 1984, after many of the
    above-cited "single seller" cases  were decided, the Supreme
    Court decided  Copperweld Corp. v. Independence  Tube Corp.,
    
    467 U.S. 752
     (1984).   The Court there considered  the scope
    of Sherman Act    1's word  "conspiracy."  It held  that the
    word  did not  cover  an agreement  between  a wholly  owned
    subsidiary and its parent, because a wholly owned subsidiary
    could not "conspire" with the parent.  That, the Court said,
    is because they have
    a  complete unity  of  interest.   Their
    objectives  are  common, not  disparate;
    their  general   corporate  actions  are
    guided or determined not by two separate
    corporate consciousnesses, but one.  . .
    .   [And] [t]hey share a  common purpose
    whether or not the parent keeps a  tight
    rein over the subsidiary . . . .
    
    Id. at 771
    .   The  Court  added  that  a "corporation  has
    complete  power to  maintain"  a portion  of the  enterprise
    -8-
    8
    either  in the form of an unincorporated division, or in the
    form of a separately incorporated subsidiary.  But, the
    economic, legal, or other considerations
    that lead corporate management to choose
    one  structure  over the  other  are not
    relevant  to  whether  the  enterprise's
    conduct seriously threatens competition.
    
    Id. at 772
    .  For these reasons, the Court held,
    the coordinated activity of a parent and
    its  wholly  owned  subsidiary  must  be
    viewed  as that  of a  single enterprise
    for purposes of   1 of the Sherman Act.
    
    Id. at 771
    .
    Although the Court spoke of Sherman Act   1 and of
    "coordinated  activity,"  its reasoning  applies here.   See
    Areeda &  Kaplow, supra,   601(c), at  929.  In essence, the
    Court saw  an identity  of economic interest  between parent
    and wholly owned subsidiary that, considered in terms of the
    economically  oriented  antitrust  laws, warrants  regarding
    them as one.   See generally 7 Phillip E.  Areeda, Antitrust
    Law    1464   (1986).     Any  claimed  instance   of  truly
    "independent,"   owner-hostile,   subsidiary  decisionmaking
    would  meet  with  the  skeptical  question,  "But,  if  the
    subsidiary acts contrary to its parent's economic  interest,
    why   does   the  parent   not   replace  the   subsidiary's
    management?"   Given  the  strength of  that joint  economic
    -9-
    9
    interest,  we  do  not  see  how  a  case-specific  judicial
    examination of  "actual" parental control would help achieve
    any  significant antitrust  objective.   Those instances  in
    which a wholly owned subsidiary would intend to act contrary
    to  the economic interests of  its owner are  likely few and
    far between, and,  if they  ever exist, would  seem hard  to
    prove.  Cf. Areeda & Kaplow, supra,   215.
    Second,  there does  not  seem to  be any  special
    Robinson-Patman Act  purpose that a  case-specific "control"
    inquiry  would further.  To the contrary, one would not want
    a seller to be able to defeat the statute's clear objectives
    by transforming unlawful,  into lawful, price discrimination
    through the creation of a separately incorporated subsidiary
    "distributor"  that  sells  to  the   disfavored  customers,
    whether  or  not  the  parent retained  "control"  over  the
    pricing decisions of the  subsidiary.  Suppose, for example,
    that M violates the  Act by selling to one retailer (DBR) at
    $10  and another competing retailer  (R1) at $12.   M should
    not be  able to avoid  the law simply  by creating a  wholly
    owned, but "independent" D, to whom it sells at $10, knowing
    that  "independent"  D   will  (say,  for  profit-maximizing
    reasons) "independently" resell to R1 at the same $12 price.
    -10-
    10
    We are aware that  this area of the law  is filled
    with difficulty.   For  example, should Robinson-Patman  Act
    liability attach in  the example just given  if (contrary to
    our  assumption) the  wholly  owned  distributor, D,  really
    fulfills  an important  distribution function,  necessary to
    supply R1, but not needed in  the case of sales to DBR, such
    that  DBR "ought" to  receive a lower price?   Or, suppose M
    (perhaps  as here) sets a  higher price to  direct buyers in
    order to  discourage direct  sales and thereby  to encourage
    the creation of an  independent distribution network?  These
    problems arise, however, in part, because it is difficult to
    reconcile   the   Robinson-Patman   Act's  strictures   with
    traditional practices  of  corporations that  seem  to  make
    sense from a practical viewpoint.  See, e.g., Texaco Inc. v.
    Hasbrouck,  
    496 U.S. 543
    , 559-62  (1990); Kintner  & Bauer,
    supra,    22.14; James F. Rill,  Availability and Functional
    Discounts  Justifying  Discriminatory Pricing,  53 Antitrust
    L.J. 929  (1985).  And the complexity of Robinson-Patman Act
    law has increased as courts have tried to introduce a degree
    of  flexibility into the Act as applied.  See, e.g., Kintner
    &  Bauer,   supra,     25.7,  at   454-460  (discussing  the
    availability   defense);  Hasbrouck,   
    496 U.S. at
      561
    -11-
    11
    (discussing functional discounts);  15 U.S.C.   13(a)  (cost
    justification defense); see also Rill, supra.
    For present  purposes, however, we need  only note
    that these  same problems  exist,  in one  form or  another,
    regardless of our holding in  this case.  That is to  say, a
    contrary holding would nonetheless produce the same problems
    wherever  M  does  "control"  the pricing  policies  of  its
    wholly-owned  subsidiary D (i.e.,  in most cases).   And, in
    the  remaining   cases  (where  wholly-owned  D  is  somehow
    nonetheless   "independent"),    various   other,   related,
    Robinson-Patman  Act  problems  would  often  arise  if  DBR
    complained about differences in price between M's price to D
    and M's price to DBR.   See pp. 12-14, infra.  Thus, we find
    nothing  special in  the  Robinson-Patman Act  context  that
    militates against Copperweld's reasoning or result.
    Third,  applying  Copperweld  avoids  a  potential
    anomaly.   A  majority  of courts,  using a  Copperweld-type
    analysis, have  held that  a firm  M's sale of  a good  to a
    wholly  owned  subsidiary D  is not  a "sale"  for Robinson-
    Patman  Act purposes; rather,  it is simply  a transfer; and
    that is so whether D is, or D is  not, somehow "independent"
    in  reality.  See City  of Mt. Pleasant  v. Associated Elec.
    Coop., Inc., 
    838 F.2d 268
    , 278 (8th Cir. 1988);  Russ' Kwik
    -12-
    12
    Car  Wash, Inc. v. Marathon Petroleum Co., 
    772 F.2d 214
    , 221
    (6th Cir.  1985) (per curiam) (quoting  Copperweld, 
    467 U.S. at
    772 n.18);  O'Byrne v. Checker Oil Co., 
    727 F.2d 159
    , 164
    (7th  Cir. 1984); Security Tire & Rubber Co. v. Gates Rubber
    Co., 
    598 F.2d 962
    , 965-67 (5th Cir.), cert. denied, 
    444 U.S. 942
      (1979).  These holdings mean that D, the transferee, is
    not a "purchaser" from M,  and, for that reason, M does  not
    violate the Act even if  he sells the same good to  a direct
    buying  retailer (DBR), or even a direct competitor of D, at
    a  higher price than the  price at which  he "transfers" the
    good to  D.  Our holding  today means that  when the wholly-
    owned subsidiary D resells the good  to R1, it must do so at
    a "nondiscriminatory" price, i.e., at a price that would  be
    permissible under the Act had D's sale to R1 been made by M.
    Thus, if M sells to DBR at 14, D cannot sell  to R1 for less
    than 14 (assuming, of course, that all other Robinson-Patman
    Act  liability  conditions  are  met  and  no  defenses  are
    available).
    But,  suppose  we  were  to   hold  the  contrary.
    Suppose  that we were to hold that a wholly-owned subsidiary
    D and  its owner M  were not a  "single seller" where  D was
    somehow  nonetheless  "independent."    Then,  an  anomalous
    difficulty might  well prevent  DBR from bringing  an action
    -13-
    13
    where M "transfers" to D at 10, D resells to R1 at 12, but M
    insists  on  charging  DBR   14  (i.e.,  approximately   the
    allegations before us).   The doctrine just  mentioned -- in
    effect finding that M and D are a single entity for purposes
    of  the transfer  between  them --  would  prevent DBR  from
    complaining about  the effect of  the M-D  "transfer."   Cf.
    Hasbrouck,  
    496 U.S. at 569-71
    .   At  the same  time,  our
    (imagined) holding (the opposite of our actual holding) that
    M and D were not a single entity for purposes of D's sale to
    R1  would  likely prevent  DBR  from  complaining about  the
    effect  of  that sale  because of  its  inability to  find a
    single "person"  who discriminated (because M  does not sell
    to R1, while D does not sell to DBR, see pp.  12-13, supra).
    Perhaps  one could  somehow avoid this  anomaly in
    other ways, but  it seems undesirable to invent epicycles in
    an already  too complex area of  the law.  It  is simpler to
    hold  in  parallel  fashion  that ownership  alone  makes  a
    "single seller" of a firm and  its wholly owned distributor,
    just  as ownership  alone  eliminates the  possibility of  a
    Robinson-Patman Act "sale" between them.
    We   therefore  find   it  appropriate   to  apply
    Copperweld's reasoning outside Sherman Act    1.  See, e.g.,
    -14-
    14
    City of Mt. Pleasant, 
    838 F.2d at 278
    ; Russ' Kwik Car Wash,
    
    772 F.2d at 221
    ; cf.  United  States v.  Waste Management,
    Inc.,  
    743 F.2d 976
    ,   979  (2d  Cir.  1984)  (attributing
    subsidiary's activity to parent  for purposes of Clayton Act
    7).   We hold that BMW  AG's ownership of BMW  NA makes of
    those two  entities,  for Robinson-Patman  Act  purposes,  a
    single seller.
    We now  turn to  a second, independent  reason the
    district court  gave for  concluding that the  complaint did
    not adequately state a Robinson-Patman Act claim.  The court
    correctly  noted that if a seller makes its favorable prices
    and  terms  available to  an otherwise  disfavored customer,
    that  customer has no legal  right to complain.   See, e.g.,
    Bouldis v.  U.S. Suzuki  Motor Corp.,  
    711 F.2d 1319
    , 1326,
    1328-29 (6th Cir. 1983) (discussing availability defenses to
    2(a), 2(d), and 2(e)); Shreve Equip., Inc. v. Clay Equip.
    Corp.,  
    650 F.2d 101
    ,   105-06  (6th   Cir.)  (discussing
    availability  under    2(a)),  cert.  denied,  
    454 U.S. 897
    (1981); Edward J. Sweeny  & Sons, Inc. v. Texaco,  Inc., 
    637 F.2d 105
    , 120-21 (3d  Cir. 1980) (same),  cert. denied, 
    451 U.S. 911
     (1981); see also  Kintner & Bauer,  supra,   25.7.
    The district court then concluded that Caribe, in a  portion
    of  its complaint,  in  effect conceded  that  BMW made  its
    -15-
    15
    favorable  prices  and  terms  available to  Caribe.    That
    complaint portion says that in 1987
    despite Caribe's remarkable success, BMW
    attempted to convert  Caribe from  being
    an importer-retailer purchasing directly
    from  the factory to being a mere retail
    dealer purchasing from BMW N.A.
    We do not believe, however, that one can draw from
    this   statement  the  "availability"  concession  that  the
    district court found.  The complaint also says that
    [u]nbeknownst  to Caribe,  and beginning
    by at least 1987, BMW began lowering its
    prices   for   BMWs  sold   to  Caribe's
    competitors    and     offering    those
    competitors  other  economic  advantages
    while maintaining its  prices to  Caribe
    at a discriminatorily high level and not
    making  the  other  economic  advantages
    available  to Caribe  on proportionately
    equal terms.
    The emphasized language says  that Caribe did not  know that
    its competitors  were receiving favored treatment.   And, we
    do not  see how ordinarily one  could say that  a seller has
    made favored treatment "available" to a disfavored  customer
    if the disfavored  customer does not know  about the favored
    treatment.  See, e.g., Alterman Foods, Inc. v. FTC, 
    497 F.2d 993
    , 1001 (5th Cir. 1974); Mueller Co.  v. FTC, 
    323 F.2d 44
    ,
    46-47  (7th Cir. 1963),  cert. denied, 
    377 U.S. 923
     (1964);
    Century Hardware  Corp. v. Acme  United Corp., 
    467 F. Supp. 350
    , 355-56 (E.D. Wis. 1979).
    .
    -16-
    16
    Caribe  also argues that the favored treatment, as
    a  practical  matter, was  not  "available"  because BMW  AG
    insisted  that   it  give  up  various   advantages  of  its
    importer's contract in order  to obtain it.  We  cannot tell
    from the complaint, however, just what those advantages were
    and how they related to the practical "availability"  of the
    favorable treatment given other  retailers.  Thus, we cannot
    say, at  this time, whether  or not Caribe  will be able  to
    prove  that the  favorable price  and terms, as  a practical
    matter, were not available.  At  this stage, however, Caribe
    has sufficiently alleged that they were not.
    Our conclusion is that Caribe's complaint states a
    valid  Robinson-Patman  Act  claim,  in  respect   to  price
    discrimination  under Robinson-Patman  Act    2(a),  and for
    similar reasons, under the Robinson-Patman Act sections that
    deal with  payments for  services, furnishing services,  and
    brokerage payments.  15 U.S.C.    13(b), (d)-(e).   Although
    Caribe's pleadings regarding these other Robinson-Patman Act
    sections are rather sparse, they are  sufficient to give BMW
    AG and BMW NA notice of the substance of Caribe's complaint.
    Caribe  also claimed  that  BMW NA  violated    2(f),  which
    forbids  knowingly inducing or receiving a discrimination in
    price.  15 U.S.C.   13(f).  In light of our holding that BMW
    -17-
    17
    NA  is not a separate "person," however, that portion of the
    complaint must be dismissed.
    III
    The Sherman Act
    Count Two of the Complaint says that
    BMW  has for years  imposed as  a secret
    condition   of  Caribe's   contracts  an
    agreement  or understanding  that Caribe
    charge its customers  prices set by BMW.
    . . . More specifically,  BMW threatened
    to  terminate Caribe's  contracts unless
    Caribe agreed  not to raise  its margins
    (i.e., and thus its retail prices) above
    levels fixed and set  by BMW, and Caribe
    reluctantly agreed.
    This complaint sets forth a claim that BMW and Caribe agreed
    to  fix "maximum" resale prices.  The Supreme Court has held
    that  Sherman Act   1  forbids this kind  of agreement.  See
    Albrecht  v. Herald Co., 
    390 U.S. 145
     (1968).  The complaint
    also  alleges  that the  "agreement  caused  Caribe to  lose
    additional  profits."   And,  Clayton Act     4 permits  any
    "person"  whose  "business"  is  "injured"  by  "reason   of
    anything forbidden in the  antitrust laws" to recover treble
    damages.  15 U.S.C.   15.
    The  district  court  nonetheless   dismissed  the
    complaint in light of Clayton Act   4's requirement that the
    injury must  result from an  action that the  antitrust laws
    forbid.  The  courts have held  that this requirement  means
    -18-
    18
    the  injury itself  must  be a  special "antitrust  injury,"
    which is  to say that it  must amount to "the  type" of harm
    "the antitrust laws  were intended to prevent,"  and it must
    flow  "from   that  which   makes  [the]   defendants'  acts
    unlawful."  Brunswick Corp.  v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 489 (1977) (emphasis added).   The district court
    thought that Caribe's  lost profits were  not the "type"  of
    harm that the anti-maximum-resale-price-fixing rule seeks to
    prevent.  And, it rested that conclusion upon its reading of
    a  Supreme  Court  case,   Atlantic  Richfield  Co.  v.  USA
    Petroleum Co. ("ARCO"), 
    495 U.S. 328
     (1990).
    As  the district  court pointed  out, in  ARCO the
    Supreme Court considered  the anticompetitive  possibilities
    that  had earlier led the Court to find maximum resale price
    agreements unlawful.   The Supreme Court  referred to three.
    First,  the "maximum"  resale price  agreement might  be, in
    reality, a  disguised "minimum"  resale price  agreement, in
    which case  the agreement would  threaten the very  kinds of
    harm that led the Court, in Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D.
    Park & Sons Co., 
    220 U.S. 373
     (1911), to find minimum resale
    price  agreements unlawful per se.   ARCO, 
    495 U.S. at 336
    .
    Second,  a maximum  resale price  agreement might  prevent a
    dealer  from  providing  "services  and  conveniences"  that
    -19-
    19
    customers would want to  the point that the  customers would
    accept (if necessary) the  price increases needed to provide
    them.  
    Id. at 335-36
    .  If  so, a supplier's  judgment about
    the  proper resale  price  (imposed  through the  supplier's
    maximum resale price agreement) would prevent consumers from
    obtaining  what  they  want  (higher  quality product)  from
    retailers who  would  like to  supply  it.   
    Id.
       Third,  a
    "maximum   resale   price    agreement"   might    "'channel
    distribution through  a few large or specifically advantaged
    dealers,'"  the only  ones  able to  earn  a profit  at  the
    mandated, low resale  price.  
    Id. at 336
      (quoting Albrecht,
    
    390 U.S. at 153
    ).
    The Supreme Court  went on to  hold that the  ARCO
    plaintiffs  had not  suffered  "antitrust injury."   But  it
    noted, and we note, that, unlike Caribe, the ARCO plaintiffs
    were not dealers  who themselves had  entered into (or  been
    forced to enter into) such agreements; rather  they were the
    competitors  of those  dealers.   They had claimed  that the
    agreements had helped the ARCO dealers (who entered into the
    agreements) obtain  more  sales, thereby  leaving them,  the
    competitors  of  the  ARCO  dealers, with  fewer  sales  for
    themselves.   The  Supreme  Court held  that, whatever  else
    might be  wrong with the  plaintiffs' assertion, it  did not
    -20-
    20
    allege harm of  the type  that Albrecht  sought to  prevent.
    That kind of  harm would have  taken the form of  fewer ARCO
    dealers, or fewer sales for the dealers who had entered into
    the  agreements  (because  those  customers  wanting  higher
    prices and extra services could not get them), not more ARCO
    dealer  sales.    The  Supreme  Court  then  wrote that  the
    plaintiffs, being rival dealers, were
    benefited rather than harmed if [ARCO's]
    pricing  policies restricted  ARCO sales
    to  a  few  large dealers  or  prevented
    [ARCO's] dealers  from offering services
    desired by consumers such as credit card
    sales.
    Id. at 336-37.  The Court added that if an agreement
    lowers prices but  maintains them  above
    predatory levels, the  business lost  by
    rivals   cannot   be   viewed    as   an
    "anticompetitive"  consequence   of  the
    claimed violation.
    Id. at 337 (emphasis added).
    In this case,  Caribe is not in  the same position
    as the ARCO plaintiffs, for Caribe is the very firm that the
    alleged maximum resale price fixing agreement forced to keep
    its price below the level it  preferred to set.  At least in
    theory, if customers would have preferred a higher price and
    consequently better product quality  or greater service, the
    agreement forced Caribe to provide less of what they wanted;
    the  agreement  thereby  might  have  led  to  lower  Caribe
    -21-
    21
    profits.  And, at  least in theory, if the  agreement helped
    other, larger  BMW dealers,  Caribe is the  firm that  would
    have  suffered.    Thus,  Caribe's  complaint  here  alleges
    antitrust harm of the "type" that Clayton Act   4 authorizes
    it to assert.   ARCO  supports, it does  not deny,  Caribe's
    standing.
    We   recognize  that   Albrecht   has   proved   a
    controversial case.  That  is, in part, because it  seems to
    outlaw  not  only  anticompetitive  uses  of  maximum  price
    fixing, but also procompetitive uses as well, namely, use of
    a  maximum resale  price agreement  that protects  consumers
    from  the exercise  of a  retailer's monopoly  power.   See,
    e.g., 8 Phillip E. Areeda Antitrust Law   1636 (1989).   And
    insofar  as  Caribe's  claim  of "lost  profits"  refers  to
    "losses"  that  occurred  because  the  agreement  prevented
    Caribe from  raising prices above the  competitive level, it
    is at  least arguable  that no "antitrust  injury" occurred.
    See id.   1640;  Phillip E. Areeda, Antitrust Law    340.3b,
    at  509-510 (Supp.  1993).    But,  at  this  stage  of  the
    proceeding, we must view  Caribe's complaint in a favorable,
    not an unfavorable, light.   We therefore read the complaint
    as implying  that the agreement cost  Caribe profits because
    it  inhibited Caribe  from  selling to  those potential  BMW
    -22-
    22
    customers who would  have preferred higher  quality service,
    even if that meant somewhat higher Caribe prices.
    We recognize  that one  might also wonder,  as did
    the district court, how Caribe could have been injured  both
    by a Robinson-Patman  Act violation and by  a maximum resale
    price agreement.  How could it have suffered  lost customers
    attracted  by  the  lower  prices of  retailers  who  bought
    cheaply from  BMW  NA and  also have  suffered lost  profits
    because  it could not increase its prices?  One might answer
    this question, however, by inferring from the complaint that
    Caribe has two different  kinds of customers.  Some  want to
    pay the  lowest possible  prices; others  would pay  more to
    receive special services that Caribe would offer only if  it
    could  charge  higher  prices.     At  least  in  principle,
    possibilities  of this  sort  are not  outlandish.   And, it
    seems  to us that  Caribe is entitled  to have a  court draw
    these inferences at this  complaint stage of the proceeding.
    Hospital  Bldg. Co.  v. Trustees  of Rex Hospital,  
    425 U.S. 738
    ,  746  (1976);  Conley v.  Gibson,  
    355 U.S. 41
    ,  45-46
    (1957);  Tri-State Rubbish, Inc.  v. Waste Management, Inc.,
    
    998 F.2d 1073
    , 1081 (1st Cir. 1993).
    We conclude  that the  district  court should  not
    have dismissed count II of the complaint.
    -23-
    23
    IV
    Puerto Rico Antitrust Claims
    Caribe   asserted   claims  under   Puerto  Rico's
    antitrust law  that parallel  its federal  antitrust claims.
    As the parties seem to agree, courts interpret Puerto Rico's
    laws as essentially embodying the jurisprudence  relevant to
    the  parallel federal law.  For that reason we reinstate the
    Commonwealth  antitrust claims  to the  same extent  that we
    have reinstated the federal claims.  Cf. R.W. Int'l Corp. v.
    Welch Food, Inc., No.  93-1704, slip op. at 19-25  (1st Cir.
    Jan. 20,  1994); Mitsubishi Motors Corp.  v. Soler Chrysler-
    Plymouth, 
    723 F.2d 155
    ,  161 (1st Cir. 1983), aff'd  in part
    and rev'd in part, on other grounds, 
    473 U.S. 614
     (1985).
    V
    The Contract Claims and the Act 75 Claim
    Our antitrust count decisions require the district
    court to  reconsider its  remaining dismissals,  of Caribe's
    breach of contact claims and its Act 75 claim.  The district
    court dismissed  those counts  because of a  forum selection
    clause in the Caribe contracts, which says
    the exclusive  jurisdiction for disputes
    concerning the . . . termination of this
    agreement  as well as all and any rights
    and duties arising out of this agreement
    is . . . Germany.
    -24-
    24
    The  court  did not  decide,  however, whether  or  not this
    clause covers  antitrust counts (for it  had dismissed those
    counts for failure  to state a valid claim).  We cannot tell
    from the wording  of the  clause alone whether  it does,  or
    does  not, cover  antitrust  claims --  whether such  claims
    "concern"  the  "termination"  of,  or  "rights  and  duties
    arising out of," the "agreement."  And, it  seems to us that
    the  parties  should  have  an opportunity  to  pursue  that
    question further in the  district court.  Compare Mitsubishi
    Motors, 
    723 F.2d at 159-61
     (analyzing numerous provisions in
    contract to  determine intended  scope of a  forum selection
    clause) with Bense v. Interstate  Battery Sys. of Am., Inc.,
    
    683 F.2d 718
    , 720  (2d  Cir. 1982)  (broadly  worded forum
    selection clause includes antitrust claims).
    The answer to  this question, depending  upon what
    it  is,  might  add  strength  to  (or  weaken)  plaintiff's
    argument that the forum selection clause cannot apply to the
    Act 75 claim.  It also could affect  the arguments about the
    comparative "convenience" of Puerto Rico for  a trial on the
    contract  and Act  75  claims.   Were it  to  turn out,  for
    example, that an antitrust trial had to take place anyway in
    Puerto Rico, the  comparative balance of  conveniences might
    well change.
    -25-
    25
    We do not  mean to express  any view, however,  on
    the   merits  of   these   or  other   arguments  (such   as
    jurisdictional arguments)  that the parties may  make as the
    case  proceeds further.   We simply  hold that  the district
    court should not have dismissed  the antitrust claims in the
    complaint.   And, that holding, in  turn, requires the court
    to reconsider its other dismissals.
    The judgment of the  district court is vacated and
    the case is remanded for further proceedings.
    So ordered.
    -26-
    26
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 93-1653

Filed Date: 3/25/1994

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 12/21/2014

Authorities (19)

Century Hardware Corp. v. Acme United Corp. , 467 F. Supp. 350 ( 1979 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Morton Salt Co. , 68 S. Ct. 822 ( 1948 )

united-states-of-america-plaintiff-appellee-cross-appellant-v-waste , 743 F.2d 976 ( 1984 )

James C. O'Byrne v. Cheker Oil Company and Marathon Oil ... , 727 F.2d 159 ( 1984 )

Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc. , 97 S. Ct. 690 ( 1977 )

Mitsubishi Motors Corp. v. Soler Chrysler-Plymouth, Inc. , 105 S. Ct. 3346 ( 1985 )

Alterman Foods, Inc. v. Federal Trade Commission , 497 F.2d 993 ( 1974 )

Massachusetts Brewers Ass'n v. P. Ballantine & Sons Co. , 129 F. Supp. 736 ( 1955 )

Garita Hotel Limited Partnership, Etc. v. Ponce Federal ... , 958 F.2d 15 ( 1992 )

Pete Bouldis v. U.S. Suzuki Motor Corp. , 711 F.2d 1319 ( 1983 )

Tri-State Rubbish, Inc. v. Waste Management, Inc. , 998 F.2d 1073 ( 1993 )

Mitsubishi Motors Corporation v. Soler Chrysler-Plymouth, ... , 723 F.2d 155 ( 1983 )

Caribe BMW, Inc. v. Bayerische Motoren Werke ... , 821 F. Supp. 802 ( 1993 )

Island Tobacco Co. v. R. J. Reynolds Industries, Inc. , 513 F. Supp. 726 ( 1981 )

Conley v. Gibson , 78 S. Ct. 99 ( 1957 )

city-of-mt-pleasant-iowa-v-associated-electric-cooperative-inc-central , 838 F.2d 268 ( 1988 )

Baim & Blank, Inc. v. Philco Corporation , 148 F. Supp. 541 ( 1957 )

Hospital Building Co. v. Trustees of Rex Hospital , 96 S. Ct. 1848 ( 1976 )

Robert L. Bense v. Interstate Battery System of America, ... , 683 F.2d 718 ( 1982 )

View All Authorities »