Nursing Care v. Casualty ( 1993 )


Menu:
  • February 25, 1993
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    For The First Circuit
    No. 92-1856
    SANDY RIVER NURSING CARE, ET AL.,
    Plaintiffs, Appellants,
    v.
    AETNA CASUALTY, ET AL.,
    Defendants, Appellees.
    APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF MAINE
    [Hon. Morton A. Brody, U.S. District Judge]
    Before
    Selya, Circuit Judge,
    Coffin, Senior Circuit Judge,
    and Stahl, Circuit Judge.
    K.  Craig  Wildfang  with  whom  Wood  R.  Foster,  Jr.,  Anne  K.
    Weinhardt,  Sidney St. F. Thaxter, John D. Gleason, Vance K. Opperman,
    Robert J. Schmit, Patrick N.  McTeague, and Barnet D. Skolnik were  on
    brief for appellants.
    Richard G.  Parker with  whom Paul  W. Chaiken,  James E.  Kaplan,
    Mark F. Horning,  Paul Macri,  Fredric W. Yerman,  Lewis V.  Vafiades,
    Michael L. McCluggage, Harold  J. Friedman, Carl F. Rella,  Stanley B.
    Block,  Robert  S. Frank,  Robert  F. Hanson,  William  A. Montgomery,
    Michael A. Nelson, James van R. Springer, George Z.  Singal, Joseph E.
    Coughlin, Paul H. Friedman, Randall B. Weill, Alfred C. Frawley, Peter
    J.  Rubin, Lewis V. Vafiades, and Lewis  A. Noonberg were on brief for
    appellees.
    Stephen L. Wessler, Deputy Attorney General, Francis E.  Ackerman,
    Assistant  Attorney General,  and  Thomas D.  Warren, Deputy  Attorney
    General, on brief for the State of Maine, amicus curiae.
    February 25, 1993
    COFFIN,  Senior Circuit  Judge.  Plaintiffs  are a  group of
    Maine employers who claim  that the defendant insurance companies
    illegally  conspired to  fix prices  and conduct  a boycott  in a
    successful effort to coerce the state legislature into permitting
    higher rates for workers'  compensation insurance.1  The district
    court  granted  summary  judgment  for defendants  based  on  the
    doctrines established in  Parker v. Brown,  
    317 U.S. 341
      (1943),
    and Eastern  R.R. Presidents  Conference v. Noerr  Motor Freight,
    
    365 U.S. 127
      (1961).2   The  court  concluded that  plaintiffs'
    claimed damage -- the  additional cost of their insurance  -- was
    attributable  to  the  legislation  rather than  to  the  alleged
    conspiracy,  and  that,   consequently,  federal  antitrust  laws
    provide no relief.
    On appeal, plaintiffs contend that  the court erred both  in
    construing their  claims and in immunizing  defendants' actions.
    After carefully  reviewing the  record and pertinent  caselaw, we
    conclude  that  the  district  court   properly  granted  summary
    judgment for  defendants.  Although  we depart somewhat  from the
    court's  analysis   --  finding  that   the  alleged   conspiracy
    constituted a  per se violation of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.   1
    1  Plaintiffs  sued  fifteen  insurance  companies  and  the
    National  Council on  Compensation Insurance (NCCI),  a voluntary
    association  of  insurers   that  is   a  state-licensed   rating
    organization.
    2 In briefest summary, these doctrines exempt from antitrust
    liability  anticompetitive  actions  attributable  to  the state,
    Parker, 
    317 U.S. at 350-52
    , and political activity by individuals
    seeking to influence  the passage or enforcement  of laws, Noerr,
    
    365 U.S. at 136-40
    .
    --  we affirm the court's  holding that the  Parker doctrine bars
    plaintiffs' requested relief.3
    I.4
    Workers'  compensation insurance has  long been an extremely
    sensitive issue in Maine.   Regulation is strict.   All employers
    who do not self-insure  are required to purchase such  insurance.
    Insurers  are "required by Maine  Law to charge  only those rates
    for workers'  compensation insurance which have  been filed with,
    and  approved  by,  the  Maine  Superintendent  of  Insurance  in
    conformance with Maine Law."  Complt.    32.  The businesses  and
    the insurers both have been dissatisfied with the system.
    At  least  since  1981,  NCCI  and  its  members have  taken
    affirmative steps  to challenge  the allowable rates  as unfairly
    low.    They  have  sought review  of  the  Superintendent's rate
    decisions in  court, see, e.g., National  Council on Compensation
    Ins.  v.  Superintendent  of  Ins.,  
    481 A.2d 775
      (Me.  1984)
    (affirming  Superintendent's   disapproval  of  a  requested rate
    increase  of 27.5%;  NCCI had  claimed that  statistical evidence
    showed that a 110% increase was warranted), and consistently have
    lobbied for legislation that  would reduce statutory benefits and
    permit insurers to charge higher rates.  Neither their litigation
    3  The complaint  sought  injunctive relief  in addition  to
    damages, but neither the district  court nor the parties  devoted
    attention to  this request.  We  note only that, in  light of our
    analysis,  we see no basis  upon which plaintiffs  may be awarded
    injunctive relief.
    4  We draw  heavily  from the  district court's  well-stated
    description  of   the  recent  history  of   the  Maine  workers'
    compensation system.
    -3-
    nor lobbying proved successful during the period relevant to this
    litigation.
    Indeed,  to  the contrary,  the  Maine  legislature in  1985
    enacted the "Workers' Compensation Competitive Rating Act," which
    directed  that workers'  compensation  insurance rates  be rolled
    back at least 8% and  frozen at that level until 1987.   Me. Rev.
    Stat.  Ann. tit. 24-A,    2331-2357 (1985) (repealed).  Under the
    Act,  insurers were  prohibited  from  requesting rate  increases
    exceeding  10% in  1987, 1988  and  1989.   Id.  at    2355.   In
    addition, the 1985 Act declared that it was intended, inter alia:
    1.  . . . To prohibit price fixing agreements and other
    anticompetitive behavior by insurers.
    . . .
    3.  . . . To promote price competition among insurers .
    . . .
    Id. at   2332.
    The insurers challenged the 1985 act in court.  Although the
    Maine Superior Court  determined that the  rate ceilings were  so
    low that they were confiscatory, the court held that the ceilings
    were not unconstitutional because  insurers were free to withdraw
    from  the market  for workers'  compensation insurance  in Maine.
    National Council on Compensation  Ins. v. Superintendent of Ins.,
    CV-85-459  (Sup.  Ct.  May  14,  1987)  (Alexander,  J.),  appeal
    dismissed, 
    538 A.2d 759
      (Me. 1988)  (dismissed as moot  because
    1987 legislation repealed 1985 Act).
    In this lawsuit,  plaintiffs assert that defendants,  unable
    to  achieve  their goals  legally,  resorted  to improper  means.
    Plaintiffs  contend that  defendants  allegedly conspired  to fix
    -4-
    prices at a higher-than-lawful  rate and to conduct a  boycott of
    the  Maine workers'  compensation  market  to induce  legislation
    authorizing rate increases.  As early as 1986,  plaintiffs claim,
    defendants   jointly   began   refusing   to   insure   employers
    voluntarily,  requiring  them  to  obtain  workers'  compensation
    coverage through  the "residual" or "involuntary"  system.  Every
    insurer  authorized to  write workers'  compensation  policies in
    Maine is required by state law to participate in the "involuntary
    market" and,  thus, to share the  underwriting responsibility for
    employers   otherwise   unable   to   obtain  coverage.5      The
    conspirators  allegedly  increased  the  pressure  on  the  Maine
    legislature to  act when, between  late summer and  October 1987,
    virtually all workers' compensation insurers in Maine prepared to
    withdraw from the state.
    To  avert the  crisis  that  would  occur  if  all  workers'
    compensation  insurers left,  Governor John  McKernan convened  a
    special  session  of  the  legislature   devoted  exclusively  to
    reviewing and reforming Maine's workers' compensation system.  In
    short order, the legislature approved the "Workers'  Compensation
    Rating Act" (deleting the word "competitive" that had been in the
    title of the 1985 Act), Me. Rev. St. Ann. tit. 24-A,    2361-2374
    (West 1990 and 1992 Supp.).  The 1987 Act removed the limitations
    on rate increases contained in the 1985 Act.  It authorized  NCCI
    to  act as agent for its member insurance companies by submitting
    5 Plaintiffs  seem to suggest  that the  shift of  employers
    from  the voluntary  to the  involuntary market  was in  some way
    detrimental to them, but they do not explain how.
    -5-
    joint  rate proposals  on their behalf  to the  Superintendent of
    Insurance,  who  is  the  ultimate  decisionmaker  on  the  rates
    insurers may charge.  Insurers are permitted, however, to deviate
    below the rate approved by the Superintendent.
    In 1988,  1989 and  1990, the insurers  collectively applied
    for rates beyond the limits allowed  in the 1985 Act.  Each year,
    the  Superintendent rejected  the requested  rate  increases, but
    authorized lower increases  that still exceeded the 10%  caps set
    by the 1985 legislation.  Plaintiffs contend that, as part of the
    insurers'   continuing    price-fixing   conspiracy,   defendants
    unlawfully agreed to charge only the maximum rates allowed by the
    Superintendent.
    Through this lawsuit, plaintiffs seek recovery of damages in
    the amount of  the increased  premiums they have  paid since  the
    1987 Act was passed  and defendants began charging higher  rates.
    The district court concluded that this  relief was barred because
    the alleged harm  was directly traceable to the  1987 legislation
    and the approval of rate increases by the Maine Superintendent of
    Insurance.    The court  relied  on  the well-established  Parker
    principle,  see  
    317 U.S. at 350-52
    ,  that  injury  caused  by
    anticompetitive  state   action  is  not  compensable  under  the
    antitrust  laws.   The  court further  believed that  defendants'
    actions were protected  by the  Noerr doctrine, see  
    365 U.S. at 136-40
    ,  which  exempts from  antitrust liability  the collective
    efforts of private actors to promote anticompetitive legislation.
    -6-
    Plaintiffs  argue on  appeal that  the district  court erred
    because it  mistakenly attributed their asserted  injury to state
    action.     They  contend  that  they  were  harmed  not  by  the
    legislation  itself  but  by  defendants'  ongoing conspiracy  to
    obtain  and  charge  higher  rates.    Parker,  they  insist,  is
    therefore inapplicable.  They  further assert that Noerr provides
    no  immunity   for  defendants  because  the  alleged  conspiracy
    involved classic  anticompetitive economic  conduct --  a boycott
    and  price-fixing  --  rather  than political  activity  such  as
    lobbying or petitioning.
    Defendants  respond that,  regardless of  the nature  of the
    conspiracy,  which  they  admitted  solely for  purposes  of  the
    summary judgment  proceedings, they  cannot  be assessed  damages
    based  on the premium increases authorized by state law.  Because
    that  is the  only  injury  for  which  plaintiffs  seek  relief,
    defendants  maintain that  the district  court correctly  granted
    summary judgment.
    II.
    The issues  we face on this  appeal are matters of  law, and
    our standard of review is therefore de novo.  Liberty Mutual Ins.
    Co. v.  Commercial Union  Ins. Co., 
    978 F.2d 750
    , 757  (1st Cir.
    1992).  Although plaintiffs repeated at oral argument a complaint
    earlier made to the  district court that they had  had inadequate
    time to develop the  facts through discovery, we  do not see  how
    additional investigation could have affected the summary judgment
    decision.    Defendants  have  admitted, for  purposes  of  their
    -7-
    motion, that  they conspired to withdraw from  the Maine workers'
    compensation  market.    Plaintiffs identify  no  other  possibly
    discoverable  fact that  would  be material  to the  legal issues
    before  us.  We note,  moreover, that they  have not appealed the
    district court's denial of  their motion for additional discovery
    time.
    Plaintiffs  make a  related  claim that  the district  court
    erred  in repeatedly failing  to construe their  complaint in the
    light  most favorable  to  them, arguing  that  this standard  of
    scrutiny -- normally applicable to motions to dismiss --  applies
    here because defendants conceded the material factual allegations
    of  the  complaint.    This  claim  also  is  irrelevant  to  our
    disposition.   As  our analysis  in the  following  sections will
    demonstrate,  plaintiffs' appeal  fails no  matter  how liberally
    their allegations concerning defendants' conspiracy are construed
    because the  specific relief they seek  is barred as a  matter of
    law.
    III.
    We begin  our analysis with an  aspect of the case  that has
    engendered  some confusion,  but apparently no  real disagreement
    among the parties.   In the concluding paragraph of  its opinion,
    the district  court stated that "[t]he  defendants' conspiracy to
    press for legislation permitting them  to charge higher rates  --
    which  in and of itself caused Plaintiffs  no injury -- is immune
    under Noerr."  Opinion at 22.  The State of  Maine construed this
    statement  and similar  references  elsewhere in  the opinion  as
    -8-
    holding  that  private actors  lawfully  may  employ a  concerted
    economic  boycott  to  influence  a   legislative  determination.
    Disturbed  by this  specific  holding, the  State sought  and was
    granted permission to file an amicus brief limited to urging that
    we reverse the ruling.
    We have  some doubt  that the  district  court intended  the
    broad  statement attributed to it  by the State.   Regardless, at
    this  point, the State's  position meets with  no opposition from
    any  party.   Plaintiffs and  defendants all  agree that  private
    actors who conduct  an economic boycott  violate the Sherman  Act
    and may be held responsible  for direct marketplace injury caused
    by  the  boycott, even  if the  boycotters'  ultimate goal  is to
    obtain  favorable  state action.    This view,  we  find, clearly
    reflects Supreme Court precedent.
    In  Noerr,  the  Supreme   Court  held  that  the  defendant
    railroads could associate for  the purpose of waging  a publicity
    campaign  designed to  secure legislative  action harmful  to the
    truckers with whom they competed, without implicating the Sherman
    Act prohibition against combinations in restraint of trade.   
    365 U.S. at 136-37
    .   The  Court observed that,  in a  representative
    democracy, individuals  must have  the ability to  "freely inform
    the  government  of  their wishes,"  
    id. at 137
    ,  and they  are
    permitted   to  do  so   even  if  their   motives  are  entirely
    anticompetitive,  
    id. at 139-40
    .   Any  other conclusion  "would
    impute to the  Sherman Act  a purpose to  regulate, not  business
    activity, but political  activity, a purpose which would  have no
    -9-
    basis whatever in the  legislative history of  the Act."  
    Id. at 137
    .
    Noerr does not  protect from  antitrust liability,  however,
    all actions designed to influence government.  The Court has made
    it clear  that certain  "combinations normally held  violative of
    the Sherman  Act," 
    id. at 136
    ,  including price-fixing agreements
    and  boycotts, are  not "outside the  coverage of  the .  . . Act
    simply because  [their] objective was the  enactment of favorable
    legislation," FTC v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass'n, 
    493 U.S. 411
    , 424 (1990).  See also Allied Tube & Conduit  Corp. v. Indian
    Head, Inc., 
    486 U.S. 492
    , 503-04 (1988);  Noerr, 
    365 U.S. at 136
    .
    In  other  words,  a  classic  economic  restraint  of  trade  is
    actionable even if its primary purpose is political.
    This limitation on the Noerr doctrine was  fully explored in
    Trial Lawyers, a  case closely  analogous to the  one before  us.
    Trial  Lawyers  involved a  boycott organized  by members  of the
    District  of Columbia criminal defense bar.  The attorneys agreed
    not  to  accept  any  court appointments  to  represent  indigent
    criminal defendants in order to force the District's City Council
    to  raise the  hourly rate  of pay  for court-appointed  criminal
    defense   work.    The  Supreme  Court   held  that  the  boycott
    constituted  a "plain violation of  the antitrust laws," 
    493 U.S. at 428
    , and that "[o]ur decision in Noerr in no way detracts from
    this  conclusion," 
    id. at 424
    .   Noerr,  the Court  emphasized,
    involved "mere  attempts to influence the  passage or enforcement
    of laws,"  
    id.
     (quoting Noerr,  
    365 U.S. at 135
    ), not an  actual
    -10-
    restraint on price  and output, id. at 423.   The Noerr exception
    to  antitrust liability  thus  was inapplicable  to the  lawyers'
    boycott.  Id. at 428.
    The district court here  sought to distinguish Trial Lawyers
    from   the  case  before  it,  at  least  in  part,  because  the
    anticompetitive  conspiracy there was directed at the government,
    the  District   of  Columbia   City  Council,  as   a  commercial
    participant.  Opinion  at 20-21.  The court appeared  to view the
    government's role  as a purchaser  as significant to  the Supreme
    Court's conclusion that Noerr immunity was unavailable:
    The  goal  of  the  trial lawyers'  conspiracy  was  to
    inflict economic pain on  the government, forcing it to
    pass  legislation.     In  this   case,  however,   the
    Defendants' alleged conspiracy was not intended to harm
    the government  as  a  commercial  participant  in  the
    marketplace, only to prompt it  to pass anticompetitive
    legislation.
    Opinion at 21.   Consequently, the district court seemed  to say,
    the conspiracy in this case was protected by Noerr.
    Trial  Lawyers does  not establish  a "government-as-market-
    participant" exception to Noerr.   What was significant about the
    concerted activity  there was  not  that the  government was  the
    purchaser, but  that the defendants  had sought to  influence the
    government through an economic boycott that directly affected the
    marketplace by,  inter alia,  constricting the supply  of lawyers
    available to  represent indigent criminal defendants.   The Court
    emphasized  that  Noerr   provides  immunity  when  the   alleged
    restraint of trade is  imposed by the government as  the intended
    consequence  of  the  defendants'  concerted  activity.    It  is
    -11-
    inapplicable when private actors  impose the challenged restraint
    of  trade  through  a  boycott or  other  traditionally  unlawful
    economic  measure, even  when  the boycott's  sole purpose  is to
    instigate favorable governmental action.
    Whether  the  boycotted purchaser  is  the  government or  a
    private individual  is  irrelevant;  the  significant  factor  is
    direct market effect.
    The restraint  of trade that was  implemented while the
    boycott  lasted  would  have  had  precisely  the  same
    anticompetitive consequences during that period even if
    no legislation had been enacted.  In Noerr, the desired
    legislation  would  have created  the restraint  on the
    truckers'  competition;  in  this  case  the  emergency
    legislative response to  the boycott put an  end to the
    restraint.
    Trial Lawyers, 
    493 U.S. at 425
    .
    Here,  too,  the defendants  allegedly employed  an economic
    boycott that  beyond doubt  "`constituted a classic  restraint of
    trade within the  meaning of Section 1 of the Sherman Act,'" 
    id.,
    493 U.S. at  422
     (quoting  Court of  Appeals, 
    856 F.2d 226
    ,  234
    (1988)).  Had  these or other plaintiffs sought injunctive relief
    during  the boycott period, or  had they sought  damages based on
    the boycott's direct market effects (such as reduced availability
    of insurance or higher  prices resulting from reduced competition
    during  the  boycott  period),  they  would  have  had  a  viable
    antitrust  claim.   These  plaintiffs, however,  explicitly  have
    disclaimed any request for relief based on injury occurring while
    -12-
    the boycott was in place, before the Maine Legislature passed the
    1987 Act.6
    In all likelihood, it was the plaintiffs' decision to pursue
    only post-legislation damages that influenced the  district court
    to state broadly that defendants were immune from liability.  The
    court  correctly  recognized  that  a  conspiracy  to  press  for
    legislation  permitting  defendants  to charge  higher  rates was
    permissible unless it was implemented through an actual restraint
    on trade.   Because  plaintiffs sought  no direct  market damages
    from  the boycott, the court evidently treated the boycott not as
    a  prohibited  restraint  of  trade  but  as  a  lobbying  effort
    equivalent  to the  unethical  and deceptive  publicity  campaign
    waged by the defendants in Noerr.
    In so  doing,  the court  may  have overstated  its  holding
    unintentionally, permitting the inference drawn by the government
    that the boycott itself was being held immune under Noerr.  As we
    have  explained, such a holding would conflict with Supreme Court
    caselaw.    Defendants'  boycott  plainly constituted  a  per  se
    violation  of  the Sherman  Act  even though  plaintiffs  seek no
    marketplace damages resulting from it.
    IV.
    The  central  issue  before  us is  whether  plaintiffs  may
    recover  damages based  on the  higher rates  they have  paid for
    workers'  compensation  insurance  since  enactment of  the  1987
    6 We offer no view as to whether plaintiffs would  have been
    able to prove damages from a constriction of supply or absence of
    price competition resulting from the conspiracy.
    -13-
    legislation.   The district  court  ruled that  the state  action
    doctrine  of Parker v. Brown, 
    317 U.S. 341
    , precluded such relief
    because  the   rate  increases  were  authorized   by  the  Maine
    Legislature,   and  adopted  and   implemented  by   the  state's
    Superintendent of Insurance.
    In Parker, "[r]elying on  principles of federalism and state
    sovereignty, [the Supreme  Court] held that  the Sherman Act  did
    not apply to anticompetitive restraints imposed by the States `as
    an  act  of  government.'"   City  of  Columbia  v. Omni  Outdoor
    Advertising, Inc., 
    111 S. Ct. 1344
    , 1349 (1991) (quoting  Parker,
    
    317 U.S. at 352
    ).   The district court believed that  the actions
    of  the legislature  and  Superintendent of  Insurance superseded
    defendants' previous conduct, rendering the rate hikes "an act of
    government" immune  under Parker rather than  an injury inflicted
    by defendants' conspiracy.
    Plaintiffs offer  two reasons  why the Parker  doctrine does
    not bar the relief they seek.  First, in an argument more heavily
    utilized  in the  district  court, plaintiffs  maintain that  the
    defendants'  use of  unlawful  activity to  coerce the  favorable
    legislation makes the Parker  doctrine inapplicable.  Because the
    legislature unlawfully  was pressured  to act, they  contend, the
    statute   may   not  be   used   to   insulate  defendants   from
    responsibility.   Second, plaintiffs  argue that  it was  not the
    legislation simply  permitting rate  hikes that harmed  them, but
    the defendants'  longstanding  conspiracy to  charge the  maximum
    possible rates.
    -14-
    Neither  of  these  arguments  is  persuasive.    The  first
    contention,  that the defendants'  coercive conduct circumscribes
    the effect of the legislature's actions, is directly contradicted
    by  Supreme Court precedent.  In a  recent case, Omni, 
    111 S. Ct. at 1352
    , the Court reaffirmed its previously stated determination
    that  Parker  immunity  turns   on  who  imposed  the  challenged
    restraint, not why:
    "[W]here the action complained of . . . was that of the
    State  itself,  the  action  is  exempt  from antitrust
    liability regardless  of the State's motives  in taking
    the action."
    
    Id. at 1352-53
     (quoting Hoover  v. Ronwin, 
    466 U.S. 558
    , 579-80
    (1984)).
    Omni rejected a proposed  conspiracy exception to the Parker
    doctrine  that  would   have  denied  immunity  when   government
    employees were  involved as  conspirators with private  actors in
    the challenged restraint of trade.  The Court considered possible
    methods   for  defining  a  conspiracy  exception,  including  an
    approach  that  would  make   Parker  inapplicable  only  if,  in
    connection with  the governmental action in  question, bribery or
    some other  violation of state  or federal law  were established.
    Id.  at 1353.  It  ultimately concluded that  any such limitation
    would  be,  at   best,  an  imprecise  way  to   determine  which
    anticompetitive state  actions should be  exempted from antitrust
    liability.
    Such unlawful activity has no necessary relationship to
    whether  the  governmental  action  is  in  the  public
    interest.   A mayor is guilty of accepting a bribe even
    if  he  would and  should  have  taken,  in the  public
    interest, the same action for which the bribe was paid.
    -15-
    . . . To  use unlawful political influence as  the test
    of legality of  state regulation undoubtedly vindicates
    (in a rather blunt  way) principles of good government.
    But the statute  we are construing  is not directed  to
    that end.
    Id.
    The  holding in  Omni  fully embraces  plaintiffs'  tendered
    coercion  exception.   Allegations  of  coercion,  like those  of
    conspiracy,   implicate  only   the  off-limits   issue   of  the
    legislators' motivation.   Omni  reaffirms that the  state action
    protection provided by Parker is not vulnerable to such claims.
    Plaintiffs' second  theory bears  down more closely  on the
    1987  legislation.   Because the  statute does  not mandate  that
    insurers charge the maximum  rates allowed by the Superintendent,
    but  merely eliminated the caps imposed by the repealed 1985 Act,
    plaintiffs maintain  that  the higher  rates by  which they  were
    damaged  resulted  from  defendants'  conspiracy  to  charge  the
    maximum  rates  and not  from the  legislature's adoption  of the
    statute.  We detect two problems with this argument.
    First, the  manner in which plaintiffs  asserted this theory
    before the district court differed in a subtle, yet  significant,
    way  from  the  approach  adopted  on  appeal.    Throughout  the
    proceedings before the district court, plaintiffs emphasized that
    they alleged injury from a conspiracy initiated in the summer and
    fall of 1987 to violate the 1985 legislation, which promoted open
    competition    in   the    workers'    compensation   market.
    Plaintiffs  do  not claim  that  they  were injured  by
    actions  mandated by  the  1987  legislation.   Indeed,
    plaintiffs allege  not only that  the conspiracy  began
    before the 1987 legislation  was even enacted, but that
    -16-
    the  objective   of  the   conspiracy  was   that  very
    enactment.   Plaintiffs in  fact allege that  they were
    injured by  defendants' conspiracy to violate  the 1985
    legislation.    It is  therefore  the 1985  legislation
    against which state action claims must be tested.
    Plaintiffs' Memorandum in Opposition to Defendants'  Joint Motion
    for Summary Judgment, at 18 n.11 (emphasis in original).
    At oral argument on  the summary judgment motion, plaintiffs
    again  asserted that it had  been unlawful for  the defendants to
    conspire to increase prices  while the 1985 legislation governed.
    See  App.  at  720.    When  the  district  court  asked why  the
    defendants' actions were not protected in light of their  "acting
    within the framework set  up by the legislature in  the enactment
    of rates,"  plaintiffs' counsel responded  that "one needs  to be
    clear on the time frame."  Id. at 729.  He continued:
    At the time the  conspiracy was hatched and effectuated
    in summer and fall of 1987, the policy of the  State of
    Maine  was  open competition  in  workers'  comp.   The
    policy of the State of Maine was, "Go compete with each
    other."
    And these defendants  had a private agreement,  in
    effect, not to compete and to boycott consumers and the
    state.
    Id.
    Thus, the argument to the  district court focused on conduct
    leading  up to the 1987 act:  the defendants unlawfully conspired
    to  charge higher rates, and obtained permission to do so through
    unlawful  means,  making  the  new  rates  wholly   a  result  of
    defendants' unlawful conduct.   Moreover, the plaintiffs  argued,
    even though the specific  harm for which they sought  damages did
    not  occur until  after  the law  was  changed and  higher  rates
    -17-
    authorized, defendants  had to be held responsible  so that their
    past  illegal  conduct  would  not  be  immunized  retroactively.
    Failing to hold them liable, plaintiffs argued,
    would  lead to the  anomalous result  that unsuccessful
    boycotts  (i.e.  boycotts  which  do  not  successfully
    coerce   governmental   action)   would  be   antitrust
    violations, but that successful boycotts (i.e. boycotts
    to which government succumbs in order to avoid chaos or
    disaster) would be immunized.
    Plaintiffs'  Memorandum  in  Opposition,  at  35-36 (emphasis  in
    original) (footnote omitted).7
    The argument on appeal  unquestionably adds a new dimension.
    Plaintiffs  now contend  that,  after passage  of  the 1987  act,
    defendants again violated antitrust  laws by conspiring to refuse
    to  sell  below   the  new  maximum  rates  established   by  the
    Superintendent of Insurance.   That agreement is  not entitled to
    state action immunity, plaintiffs suggest, because  the provision
    in  the 1987  Act  allowing independent  ratesetting demonstrates
    that  state  policy  still  favors  competition.    Consequently,
    plaintiffs contend that  defendants should be held liable for the
    rate increases.8
    7  As we  made clear in  Section III,  the response  to this
    argument is that unlawful boycotts with direct marketplace impact
    will result  in accountability for the  market injury, regardless
    of their success in inducing governmental action.
    8 We note that some  portions of plaintiffs' appellate brief
    retain the focus on the 1985 legislation:
    Plaintiffs   do   not    challenge   the    Defendants'
    "participation  in  ratesetting  proceedings"  in  1988
    after  the 1987 legislation  was enacted  repealing the
    1985 Competitive Rating Act.  What Plaintiffs challenge
    is  Defendants' conspiracy begun in 1986 and 1987, at a
    time   when  Maine  law  specifically  prohibited  such
    -18-
    This link between plaintiffs'  conspiracy allegation and the
    1987  Act never  was offered  to the  district court;  indeed, as
    noted above, plaintiffs  expressly disclaimed  the new  statute's
    relevance to the  Parker issue.  The conspiracy achieved success,
    plaintiffs  asserted, when  the  State enacted  the law  allowing
    higher  premiums.    See  Memorandum  in  Opposition  to  Summary
    Judgment, at 2-3 (quoted in  District Court Opinion, at 3).   Led
    by these  arguments, the district court  never considered whether
    the defendants could be held responsible for the rate increases -
    - despite authorization  of those rates by  the state --  if they
    had conspired not to deviate below the maximum rate.
    Whether plaintiffs sufficiently preserved this argument need
    not unduly detain us, however, because the theory is in any event
    unavailing.   When the  legislature enacted the  1987 statute, it
    did not simply eliminate the ceiling on the permissible rates for
    workers' compensation insurance, but it also  moved away from the
    state's previous pro-competitive policy toward  ratesetting.  The
    1987 Act  provided for joint rate  filings9 and, in  our view, it
    conspiracies, to  constrict supply, to fix  prices, and
    to boycott consumers in order  to coerce the removal of
    the existing price ceiling.
    Plaintiffs' Brief at 31 (additional emphasis added).
    9 It did so  somewhat indirectly through repeal of  the 1985
    Act, which meant that the  joint ratemaking provisions that  then
    existed  for  all lines  of insurance  sold  in Maine  again were
    applicable  to workers'  compensation  insurance.   In 1989,  the
    legislature revised  the general  insurance ratemaking system  to
    encourage  competition, leaving  the joint  ratemaking provisions
    applicable only to the  workers' compensation providers.  Compare
    Me. Rev. Stat. Ann. tit.  24-A,   2309 (West 1990) with  Me. Rev.
    Stat. Ann. tit. 24-A,   2309 (West Supp. 1992).
    -19-
    must  be construed  as  implicitly condoning  an agreement  among
    insurers to  charge the  rates they  jointly propose,  subject to
    approval  by the  Superintendent.   When  insurers work  together
    within  a state regulatory system to advocate rates that they all
    presumably  believe  are  appropriate  for  workers' compensation
    insurance, we  fail to see  how it could be  illegal price fixing
    for them also subsequently  to agree to charge the  rates allowed
    by the state, particularly when the approved rates fall below the
    jointly proposed rates.
    At a  minimum, it  must be lawful  for insurers to  agree to
    charge  the approved  rate where,  as here,  the Superintendent's
    obligation is to establish rates that are "[j]ust and reasonable"
    and "[b]ased only  on a  just and reasonable  profit."  Me.  Rev.
    Stat.  Ann. tit. 24-A,    2363 (7)(A)(1),  (2).   Thus, while the
    statute  stipulates  that  these rates  set  the  upper  limit on
    permissible charges, id.  at   2362,  the expectation clearly  is
    that  the Superintendent's rates are the ones that generally will
    be appropriate  for, and  thus used  by, all insurers.   In  this
    context,  the legislature  evidently  viewed the  sort of  "price
    fixing" alleged by plaintiffs as  benign; notably absent from the
    1987 statute is a provision contained in the 1985 Act prohibiting
    insurers from agreeing  "to adhere  to or  use a  rate or  rating
    plan," id. at   2347 (2) (1985) (repealed).
    Plaintiffs  rely  on the  provision  allowing  downward rate
    deviation to  support their claim that  defendants' conspiracy to
    charge  a uniform  rate was  unauthorized and,  consequently, not
    -20-
    immunized  under Parker.  But  the fact that  insurers may charge
    less than the approved  rate is of little significance when it is
    juxtaposed with  the uniform approach  to ratemaking that  is the
    overriding characteristic of  the reformed system.   On its  own,
    the  permissive provision  certainly does  not establish  a state
    policy favoring  competitive  pricing.    Moreover,  the  Supreme
    Court,  in  Southern Motor  Carriers  Rate  Conference v.  United
    States,  
    471 U.S. 48
     (1985), explicitly held that Parker immunity
    is  available to private parties  acting pursuant to  a regime of
    collective ratemaking that  is authorized, though not  compelled,
    by the state.
    Southern Motor  Carriers involved  a challenge to  the joint
    activities of motor  common carrier rate  bureaus in four  states
    where carriers were permitted to  agree on rate proposals  before
    their  submission  to  state agencies.    In  the  course of  its
    decision, the Court reaffirmed the two-pronged  test set forth in
    California Retail Liquor Dealers  Ass'n v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc.,
    
    445 U.S. 97
    ,   105   (1980),  for   determining  whether   the
    anticompetitive  conduct  of  private  parties  within  a   state
    regulatory scheme is shielded from the antitrust laws:
    First, the challenged restraint  must be "`one  clearly
    articulated  and  affirmatively   expressed  as   state
    policy.'"   Second, the  State must  supervise actively
    any private anticompetitive conduct.
    
    471 U.S. at 57
     (citations omitted).
    The  justices  then  considered  whether the  actions  of  a
    private party  can be attributed  to a clearly  articulated state
    policy, within the meaning of the Midcal test's first prong, even
    -21-
    if  the  state does  not  compel  the challenged  anticompetitive
    activity.  
    Id. at 59-60
    .  The Court  observed that a  compulsion
    requirement would reduce the range of alternatives available to a
    state  that  wished to  regulate  a  given  industry  --  thereby
    negatively affecting  principles of federalism  -- while  perhaps
    also causing greater restraints on trade -- thereby impairing the
    goal of the antitrust  laws to ensure "unfettered  competition in
    the marketplace," 
    id. at 61
    .  Declining to "believe that Congress
    intended  to resolve  conflicts between  two competing  interests
    [federalism  and  competition]   by  impairing  both  more   than
    necesssary," 
    id.,
     the  Court concluded that "a  state policy that
    expressly permits,  but does not  compel, anticompetitive conduct
    may  be `clearly articulated' within  the meaning of Midcal," 
    id.
    (emphasis in original).
    In  this  case,  it  is manifestly  clear  that  defendants'
    ratemaking activities meet both  prongs of the Midcal test.   The
    new scheme was  adopted by the legislature, fulfilling  the state
    policy prong of the test, and the Superintendent's involvement in
    reviewing    and   modifying   the   insurers'   proposed   rates
    unquestionably  meets  prong two's  requirement  of active  state
    supervision.    Indeed,  plaintiffs  expressly  acknowledge  that
    Midcal is  satisfied with respect to  the ratemaking proceedings.
    See  Reply Brief,  at  19 n.15.    Plaintiffs instead  hammer  on
    defendants'   "converting   the   results  of   that   ratemaking
    proceeding,  i.e. a schedule of maximum or ceiling prices, into a
    private agreement to  uniformly charge the maximum price,  and to
    -22-
    refuse  to deal at  prices below that  level."  
    Id.
      (emphasis in
    original).
    This argument misfires because it fails to take into account
    the  changed landscape.  Even  if defendants violated the Sherman
    Act in  the late summer and  early fall of 1987  by conspiring to
    raise the maximum prices they could charge beyond those permitted
    by  the 1985  Act, it  does not  necessarily  follow that  it was
    unlawful  for  them to  agree  to  charge  the rate  subsequently
    approved  by the Superintendent pursuant  to the 1987  Act.  Once
    the legislature  acted in November 1987,  defendants' conduct had
    to be assessed in  light of the new state policy  and procedures.
    As  we   have  discussed,  the  1987   Act  endorsed  cooperative
    ratesetting and anticipated that most, if not all, insurers would
    charge  the newly  authorized  rates.   Accordingly, the  damages
    sought  by  plaintiffs  --  the differential  between  the  rates
    allowed  under  the  1985  Act  and  the  new  rates  charged  by
    defendants under the 1987 Act  -- must be viewed as a  product of
    state action.   The district court  therefore correctly concluded
    that, under Parker,  defendants may not  be held accountable  for
    this claimed injury.
    V.
    In summary,  we hold  that the  economic  boycott and  price
    fixing conspiracy allegedly conducted by defendants in the summer
    and  early fall  of 1987  constituted a per  se violation  of the
    -23-
    Sherman  Act,  and  did  not  fall  within  the  Noerr doctrine's
    protection for  concerted activity  designed to  elicit favorable
    legislation.   But plaintiffs have not  sought damages for direct
    marketplace injury inflicted by that conspiracy.
    The monetary damages alleged by plaintiffs --  the amount of
    increase in their workers' compensation insurance rates under the
    1987 statutory scheme allegedly coerced by  defendants -- are not
    recoverable  from the  insurers.   Because  the state  authorized
    collective  ratemaking  and  closely supervised  the  setting  of
    higher  rates,  any  agreement  among defendants  to  charge  the
    maximum  authorized  rates  is  permissible,  and defendants  are
    immune from liability for the increase under the Parker doctrine.
    Affirmed.
    -24-