Lee v. LINA ( 1994 )


Menu:
  • May 25, 1994      UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE FIRST CIRCUIT
    No. 93-1988
    TONY LEE, ET AL.,
    Plaintiffs, Appellants,
    v.
    THE LIFE INSURANCE COMPANY OF NORTH AMERICA,
    Defendants, Appellees.
    ERRATA SHEET
    The opinion of this Court issued on May 4, 1994, is  amended
    as follows:
    Cover sheet:
    Jay S. Goodman for The University of Rhode Island, et al.
    William P.  Devereaux and  McGovern, Noel  & Benik,  Inc. on
    brief for The Life Insurance Company of North America.
    Phillip A. Proger, with whom Gregory A. Castanias and Jones,
    Day, Reavis &  Pogue were  on brief for  The Life  Insurance
    Company of North America, and for all appellees on antitrust
    issues.
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE FIRST CIRCUIT
    No. 93-1988
    TONY LEE, ET AL.,
    Plaintiffs, Appellants,
    v.
    THE LIFE INSURANCE COMPANY OF NORTH AMERICA, ET AL.,
    Defendants, Appellees.
    APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF RHODE ISLAND
    [Hon. Raymond J. Pettine, Senior U.S. District Judge]
    Before
    Torruella, Circuit Judge,
    Aldrich, Senior Circuit Judge,
    and Cyr, Circuit Judge.
    Jay S. Goodman for The University of Rhode Island, et al.
    William P.  Devereaux and  McGovern, Noel  & Benik, Inc.  on
    brief for The Life Insurance Company of North America.
    Phillip A. Proger, with whom Gregory A. Castanias and Jones,
    Day, Reavis &  Pogue were  on brief for  The Life  Insurance
    Company of North America, and for all appellees on antitrust
    issues.
    May 4, 1994
    CYR, Circuit  Judge.  Three University  of Rhode Island
    CYR, Circuit  Judge.
    ("URI") students  appeal from  a district court  order dismissing
    their federal antitrust, equal protection, and due process claims
    against  URI, its Board  of Governors,  three URI  officials, and
    URI's student-health  insurer, Life  Insurance  Company of  North
    America ("LINA").  Finding no error, we affirm the district court
    judgment.
    I
    BACKGROUND
    As a  precondition to reregistering each  semester, URI
    requires  all full-time undergraduate students to pay a fixed fee
    for the  right to  use URI's  on-campus, walk-in  medical clinic,
    University Health Services  ("UHS").1  All  students who pay  the
    UHS  clinic fee  must  also carry  supplemental health  insurance
    coverage for certain medical services, such as x-rays,  lab tests
    and gynecological  tests, that  are available  through UHS.   Two
    supplemental insurance options are available.  First, the student
    may obtain supplemental insurance  through LINA, a private health
    care  underwriter which  URI sponsors  as its  "default" insurer.
    LINA  purportedly "dovetails" its  supplemental coverage  so that
    the insured student pays an  annual premium that minimizes dupli-
    cative  coverage;  that is,  it lessens  the  risk that  the LINA
    premium and  the UHS clinic  fee will reflect  redundant coverage
    1Graduate students are  not required to  pay the UHS  clinic
    fee,  provided they  have  health insurance  coverage that  meets
    URI's requirements.
    for the same medical  procedures.2  As a second  option, students
    may  secure "comparable  [supplemental]  coverage"  from an  off-
    campus  health care insurer of their choice, except that URI does
    not consider either Rhode Island Blue Cross or Rhode Island-based
    HMOs "comparable coverage."   Students who do not opt  out of the
    LINA "default" coverage by a specified deadline are automatically
    billed for the annual LINA premium, and cannot reregister for the
    following semester until  the LINA  premium has been  paid.   The
    automatic "default" scheme notwithstanding, only about 40% of the
    students who pay the UHS clinic fee insure through LINA.
    Appellants  initiated  this  class  action  in  federal
    district court against URI and LINA in January 1992.  The amended
    complaint alleges  that the  practice  of conditioning  continued
    matriculation at URI on payment of the UHS  clinic fee and/or the
    LINA supplemental  insurance premium  violates the  Sherman Anti-
    trust Act, 15 U.S.C.   1 (1993),  as well as the equal protection
    and due process guarantees  under the United States Constitution.
    Following  minimal  discovery,  URI  and LINA  moved  to  dismiss
    pursuant to Fed.  R. Civ.  P. 12(b)(6),3 and  the district  court
    dismissed all claims.  Lee v. Life Ins. Co. of N.A., 829 F. Supp.
    2LINA coverage requires the student to present for treatment
    at UHS in  the first  instance, pending possible  referral to  an
    outside health care provider.
    3Appellants'  motion  for  class  certification  was  stayed
    pending disposition of appellees' motions to dismiss.
    4
    529 (D.R.I. 1993).4
    II
    DISCUSSION
    A.  The Antitrust "Tying" Claim
    Appellants  challenge the dismissal of their claim that
    the URI health care-insurance  scheme is an impermissible "tying"
    arrangement in violation of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.   1 (1993)
    ("Every contract . . . in restraint of trade or commerce . . . is
    hereby declared to be illegal.").  See Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image
    Technical  Servs., Inc.,  
    112 S.Ct. 2072
     (1992)  ("Kodak").   "A
    tying arrangement is 'an agreement by a party to sell one product
    but only on the condition that the buyer also purchases a differ-
    ent (or  tied)  product, or  at  least agrees  that he  will  not
    purchase that product  from any  other supplier.'"   
    Id. at 2079
    (quoting Northern Pac. Ry. Co. v.  United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5-6
    (1958)).  Generally speaking, an impermissible "tie-in" occurs if
    a seller  (viz., URI)  enjoys either  a monopoly  or "appreciable
    economic  power"  ("AEP") in  the  "tying"  product (or  service)
    market, and uses  its considerable market leverage  to "coerce" a
    buyer     already intent on purchasing the tying product from the
    seller    into  buying a  second, "tied" product  that the  buyer
    would not have bought based solely on the quality or price of the
    tied  product itself.  See Fortner Enters., Inc. v. United States
    4At  the same time, the district  court declined to exercise
    jurisdiction over several pendent state-law claims, see 28 U.S.C.
    1367(c)(3) (1993).  Cf. infra note 11.
    5
    Steel Corp., 
    394 U.S. 495
    , 503  (1969); see generally  Grappone,
    Inc. v. Subaru of  New England, Inc., 
    858 F.2d 792
    , 794-96  (1st
    Cir. 1988) (describing  procompetitive policy interests animating
    per  se  tying analysis).5   Since  many  product "ties"  may not
    prove anti-competitive, notwithstanding their somewhat misleading
    epithet, "per  se" tie-ins may require a "fairly subtle antitrust
    analysis" of  "market power,"  a fact-intensive inquiry  aimed at
    winnowing out  only  those ties  most  likely to  threaten  anti-
    competitive harm.  
    Id. at 795
    .
    Appellants claim three "product" tie-ins:   (1) between
    a  university  education  (URI)  and  health  insurance  coverage
    (LINA); (2) between health care services (UHS) and  health insur-
    ance  coverage (LINA);  and  (3) between  a university  education
    (URI) and health care services (UHS).6       We  agree  with  the
    5The tie-in  must also affect  a substantial volume  of com-
    merce in the tied market, see Kodak, 
    112 S. Ct. at 2079
    , a factor
    not at issue in this case.  Further, we assume, without deciding,
    that  URI is a participant  in the insurance  "market," for anti-
    trust  purposes,  simply  because  it  receives  a  one-time  $10
    processing fee for each LINA policy sold to a URI student.
    6Notwithstanding  certain  misgivings,  we  further  assume,
    without deciding,  that the  amended complaint  adequately pleads
    two other  essential "tying"  claim elements.   These assumptions
    merely facilitate clearer focus on the  core deficiency in appel-
    lants' antitrust claim.   First, we presume that the  products at
    issue are distinct, i.e., that each is distinguishable by consum-
    ers  in the relevant market,  and that there  would be sufficient
    consumer demand  for each individual  product, and not  merely as
    part  of an integrated  product "package."   See Jefferson Parish
    Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    , 21-22 (1984).  But see 
    id. at 39
     (O'Connor, J., concurring) (noting obvious policy limits of
    "two product"  rule, since almost  every product could  be broken
    down into smaller constituent parts that  might be sold separate-
    ly); Lee, 829 F. Supp. at  537 ("I do not believe plaintiffs have
    adequately alleged  that this arrangement  involved two  separate
    products.").    Second,  we accept,  arguendo,  the  questionable
    6
    district  court however,  that  appellants failed  to allege  any
    "tie-in" claim upon which  relief could be granted.   In particu-
    lar,  appellants failed  to advance  a colorable  claim as  to an
    indispensable  element:  that URI  had AEP in  the relevant tying
    markets (university education and health care services).   AEP or
    "market  power" is the demonstrated ability of a seller "to force
    a purchaser to do something that he would not do in a competitive
    market."  Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    ,
    14  (1984); see  also Grappone,  
    858 F.2d at 794
    .   AEP may  be
    demonstrated,  for example, if the seller holds a monopoly in the
    tying product (e.g.,  a patented product), controls  a very large
    share of sales  in the tying product market, see  
    id. at 796
     (AEP
    "means significant market power" over an "'appreciable' number of
    buyers") (emphasis in original) (citation omitted), or produces a
    "unique"  tying  product,  and  therefore  faces  no  significant
    competition from  functionally similar products or  services, see
    Jefferson  Parish, 
    466 U.S. at
    37-38 n.7  (O'Connor, J., concur-
    ring) (market must be defined  to include "all reasonable substi-
    tutes  for the  product");  Grappone,  
    858 F.2d at 796
      (market
    encompasses all "readily available substitutes").
    Appellants can assert no colorable claim that URI holds
    AEP either in the "tying" market for a university education or in
    the  "tying" market for health  care services.   URI competes for
    new undergraduate and graduate students on a regional and nation-
    contention  that  URI  students are  "coerced"  financially  into
    buying LINA coverage because only LINA insurance "dovetails" with
    UHS clinic fee services.
    7
    al  level with  dozens of universities  and colleges.7   Although
    URI obviously  is a "unique"  institution in a  colloquial sense,
    appellants cannot claim that  other institutions of higher educa-
    tion do not or  cannot provide "functionally similar" educational
    offerings to potential  URI applicants.   Cf. 
    id. at 798
      (brand
    name alone does not  establish product "uniqueness" necessary for
    AEP).  And,  of course,  absent AEP  in the  university-education
    market  it is a  virtual given that  URI cannot enjoy  AEP in the
    student health care business.
    Appellants attempt to circumvent URI's  evident lack of
    AEP in the two  relevant tying markets by contriving  a so-called
    Kodak  "lock-in."    Kodak  involved distinct  products:    Kodak
    copiers (the "lock-in"  product), Kodak copier  replacement parts
    (the tying product), and Kodak  copier servicing and repair  (the
    tied  product).  In 1985,  Kodak began to  confine sales of Kodak
    copier  parts to Kodak copier owners who contracted to have their
    copiers  serviced  by Kodak,  rather  than  by Kodak's  servicing
    competitors ("ISOs").  Kodak, 
    112 S.Ct. at 2077-78
    .  Significant-
    ly, only  Kodak parts would fit Kodak copiers.  
    Id. at 2077
    .  The
    ISOs initiated an antitrust action  against Kodak under section 1
    of  the Sherman  Act.   After  truncated discovery,  the district
    court granted summary  judgment for  Kodak.   
    Id. at 2078
    .   The
    Ninth Circuit reversed, Kodak, 
    903 F.2d 612
    , 617 (9th Cir. 1990),
    and the Supreme Court affirmed, Kodak, 
    112 S. Ct. at 2092
    .
    7As of  1991, for example, Rhode  Island residents comprised
    only 56% of the URI student body.
    8
    By reason of Kodak's very small market share in  copier
    sales, the parties had  stipulated that Kodak had  no AEP in  the
    copier  market (assuming copier sales to  be the relevant "tying"
    market),  and hence, no unlawful  "tie" could exist between Kodak
    copiers  and Kodak  parts-servicing.   
    Id.
      at  2081 n.10.    The
    Supreme Court  accordingly focused on whether  an unlawful tie-in
    nonetheless existed between Kodak parts and Kodak servicing.  
    Id.
    Kodak  argued for  the view  that, either  presumptively or  as a
    matter of  law, vigorous competition  in the copier  market would
    prevent  Kodak  from raising  its  parts  and servicing  contract
    prices above competitive levels, because any such price increases
    in these "derivative aftermarkets"  would become known to copier-
    equipment consumers, and eventually cause Kodak to lose ground to
    its competitors in copier sales.  
    Id. at 2081-82, 2083
    .
    The Court rejected Kodak's  per se "cross-elasticity of
    demand" theory, identifying two different fact patterns which, if
    borne out by  the evidence, might support a  reasonable inference
    that  parts  and servicing  contract  price  increases would  not
    necessarily  cause Kodak to lose  copier sales.   Under the first
    scenario, the  evidence  might  demonstrate  that  a  substantial
    number  of consumers, at the  time of their  original copier pur-
    chases, would not enjoy  cost-efficient8 access to the difficult-
    to-acquire  pricing  information  needed to  evaluate  the  total
    8The Court noted that  even assuming readily available price
    information, consumers rationally might decide not to investigate
    life-cycle costs  if investigation  would prove more  costly than
    the potential savings.  
    Id. at 2086
    .
    9
    "life-cycle" cost of  the entire Kodak  "package"    namely,  the
    price  of  the copier,  likely  replacement  parts, and  product-
    lifetime  servicing.  
    Id. at 2085-87
    .  Under the second scenario,
    the  Court postulated that, in a market for complex durable goods
    like  copiers, current  Kodak-copier  owners might  tolerate even
    uncompetitive  price increases  in Kodak  parts and  servicing as
    long  as the  increases did  not exceed  the costs  of abandoning
    their  original investment in the Kodak copier and switching, for
    example, to  a Canon  or Xerox  copier.  
    Id. at 2087-88
    .   Since
    Kodak's servicing competitors had produced some evidence of "very
    high" switching costs  for Kodak copier owners,  the Court opined
    that such "lock-ins"     attendant  as they are  to the  original
    copier purchase    could conceivably enable the plaintiff ISOs to
    establish Kodak's  AEP in the derivative  "tying" aftermarket for
    Kodak parts.  The  Court accordingly concluded that the  undeter-
    mined  "information  costs"  and  "switching  costs"  represented
    material  issues of fact, and  if in genuine  dispute, would pre-
    clude  summary judgment,  even  though Kodak  lacked  AEP in  the
    "lock-in" product market for copiers.  
    Id. at 2086-87
    .
    Appellants  attempt to shoehorn  their allegations into
    this  Kodak  "derivative  aftermarket"  mold,  by  proposing  the
    following comparative model:  first-semester matriculation at URI
    serves  as the "lock-in" product, as did the Kodak copier; subse-
    quent  semesters at URI serve as the  tying product, as did Kodak
    replacement parts;  and health clinic services  and health insur-
    ance  coverage represent the tied products.  Of course, URI, like
    10
    Kodak, might contend, on  summary judgment or at trial,  that its
    lack  of AEP in the  locked-in product market  ("sales" of first-
    semester  university education)  creates  a "cross-elasticity  of
    demand," which would  prevent health clinic fees and LINA supple-
    mental insurance  premiums from being  increased to uncompetitive
    levels.  Nevertheless, because Kodak was a summary judgment case,
    rather  than a Rule 12(b)(6) case, appellants argue that they did
    enough  to withstand URI's  motion to dismiss  simply by alleging
    the existence of unspecified "information" and "switching" costs,
    which must be credited  for Rule 12(b)(6) purposes.   See Rumford
    Pharmacy, Inc. v. City of East Providence, 
    970 F.2d 996
    , 997 (1st
    Cir. 1992) (review of Rule 12(b)(6) dismissal is de novo, credit-
    ing  all allegations in the  complaint and drawing all reasonable
    inferences favorable to plaintiff).
    Appellants  challenge the  district  court ruling  that
    their "information cost" allegations  were insufficient to defeat
    the motion to dismiss.   First, appellants argue that  URI cannot
    posit  a  "cross-elasticity of  demand"  in  the present  context
    because the prices charged for health clinic services and  insur-
    ance premiums  are too insignificant  in relation to  tuition and
    other university-education  costs to  be considered a  meaningful
    factor in determining whether  potential applicants for admission
    will attend URI or some other university.   Alternatively, appel-
    lants argue that URI would bear the burden of proof on this issue
    at  trial, and that  on appeal it  has not  pointed to supportive
    evidence of consumer "sophistication."
    11
    Appellants  exaggerate  the role  that summary-judgment
    burden  shifting played  in  the Kodak  analysis.   Kodak  simply
    pointed out that summary judgment was not yet in order on Kodak's
    "cross-elasticity of demand" theory (1) in light of the plaintiff
    ISOs' proffer  on "information costs"     i.e., readily inferable
    expenses  associated  with  accumulating   technical  information
    relating to the costs of equipment, parts, and servicing over the
    lifetime  of a  "complex  durable goods"  item,  and (2)  in  the
    absence of any conclusive evidence  from Kodak that a substantial
    number of purchasers  actually make accurate prepurchase  assess-
    ments of the  life-cycle "package" price of  their Kodak copiers.
    Thus, the Court neither discussed any reallocation of  burdens of
    proof  at trial, nor in any way  intimated a shift in the eviden-
    tiary burden  of  proof on  the  factual issues  of  "information
    costs" and "lock-in."   See, e.g., Jefferson Parish, 
    466 U.S. at 13-14
      (assuming burden of proof rests with plaintiff to show AEP
    in tying-product  market); Town  Sound and Custom  Tops, Inc.  v.
    Chrysler Motors Corp., 
    959 F.2d 468
    , 479 n.12 (3d  Cir.) (plain-
    tiff bears burden  of proof on  "tying market" definition),  cert
    denied, 
    113 S. Ct. 196
      (1992).   In order  to withstand  URI's
    motion to dismiss for failure to state a claim, therefore, it was
    appellants'  burden (absent any colorable  claim that URI had AEP
    in  the locked-in  product markets  for university  education and
    student  health  services) to  allege  "information  costs" which
    would prevent a substantial number of URI students from accurate-
    ly assessing the total costs of a URI education, including health
    12
    clinic  fees and  insurance premiums,  in determining  whether to
    matriculate at URI.
    Second,  appellants  argue  that  it is  impossible  to
    allege  "information  costs"  because  potential  URI  applicants
    cannot  know or predict their  future URI health  clinic fees and
    LINA insurance  premiums with any  precision, since URI  and LINA
    reserve  the  right to  increase these  charges  each year.   But
    appellants  mistake the focus  of the Court's  concerns about the
    "information costs" in Kodak.
    In  Kodak,  the information  required  by  the customer
    pertained to the life-cycle pricing  of a Kodak copier "package,"
    information so patently "difficult and costly" to come by that it
    spontaneously gave  rise to  a reasonable inference  that unsoph-
    isticated  consumers would  not  have the  information needed  to
    evaluate  their options at the  time they made  their decision to
    purchase a  Kodak copier.  Kodak, 
    112 S. Ct. at 2085
    .9   By con-
    9The Kodak Court elaborated on the complexity of the "infor-
    mation" needed to make an informed investment:
    In  order to  arrive at an  accurate price,  a consumer
    must  acquire  a substantial  amount  of  raw data  and
    undertake sophisticated analysis.  The necessary infor-
    mation would include data on price, quality, and avail-
    ability  of  products  needed to  operate,  upgrade, or
    enhance the  initial equipment, as well  as service and
    repair costs, including estimates of breakdown frequen-
    cy,  nature of  repairs,  price of  service and  parts,
    length of  "down-time" and  losses incurred  from down-
    time.
    Much of  this information is difficult     some of
    it is  impossible      to acquire  at the time  of pur-
    chase.  During  the life  of a  product, companies  may
    change the service and  parts prices, and develop prod-
    ucts with more advanced  features, a decreased need for
    repair, or  new warranties.  In  addition, the informa-
    13
    trast,  before signing up for  their first semester  at URI, stu-
    dents are informed  that their continued matriculation  at URI is
    conditioned,  inter alia,  on their  "purchase" of  health clinic
    services at a stated annual fee, subject to historically predict-
    able  annual increases,  and  on their  purchase of  supplemental
    insurance coverage.10   See  Philip E.  Areeda  & Herbert  Hoven-
    kamp,  Antitrust Law   1709.2,  at 1174 (Supp.  1993) (Kodak does
    not focus on  potential exploitation of the "irrational  or fool-
    ish" purchaser, but the purchaser who makes the rational decision
    that comparative-shopping costs would outweigh any savings from a
    fully  informed purchase;  "the [Kodak]  context was  confined to
    hard-to-obtain information")  (emphasis added); cf.  id. at  1174
    ("[R]elevant  information  need  not  be so  comprehensive  as  a
    binding future price schedule . . . .");  see also supra note  8.
    tion is likely to be customer specific; lifecycle costs
    will vary  from customer to  customer with the  type of
    equipment, degrees of equipment use, and costs of down-
    time.
    Kodak, 
    112 S.Ct. at 2085-86
    .
    10Considering  the recent  hyperinflationary  trends in  the
    health care industry as  a whole, UHS clinic fees  have increased
    at  fairly  predictable increments  since  1987:  1987-88 ($179);
    1988-89  ($188);  1989-90   ($200.50);  1990-91  ($227);  1991-92
    ($248); 1992-93 ($312).   LINA premiums have increased comparably
    over the same  period, from $158 in  1987-88 to $369 in  1992-93.
    The record  contains no evidence that  prospective URI applicants
    would have  great difficulty  gaining access to  this information
    from  any  number  of  reliable sources  (e.g.,  URI  application
    materials,  URI admissions  officials, past  or current  URI stu-
    dents, college entrance source books).  Nor do appellants suggest
    that  URI had any  incentive to conceal  the scope  of past price
    increases.  On  the billing  invoices it mails  to students,  URI
    routinely  individualizes its charges  for registration, tuition,
    UHS fees, LINA premiums, and taxes.
    14
    Appellants  have made no allegations sufficient to give rise to a
    reasonable  inference  that  the  health-care  and insurance-cost
    information needed to make an informed decision whether to accept
    the  preconditions to  continued matriculation  at URI  is either
    difficult or expensive to obtain or correlate.
    The district court further ruled that appellants failed
    to state an actionable claim that they were "locked in"; that is,
    they  failed to plead actual costs associated with switching from
    URI after their  first semester.  Although  appellants now assert
    that  they can  amend their  complaint to  allege such  costs, we
    conclude that  further  amendment to  allege specific  "switching
    costs" would be  futile.  See University of  Rhode Island v. A.W.
    Chesterton Co., 
    2 F.3d 1200
    , 1219 n. 20 (1993).
    First, there  is an important distinction between Kodak
    and  the present case.  Kodak was a "derivative aftermarket" case
    involving "complex durable  goods."  Unlike  the copier parts  in
    Kodak, subsequent URI semesters are  not "derivative aftermarket"
    components  upon which the  buyer's initial investment absolutely
    depends.  As the  Supreme Court noted, Kodak copiers  are "expen-
    sive when new," incompatible with replacement parts used in other
    copiers,  and  retain  "little resale  value"  presumably because
    complex durable goods depreciate so rapidly.  Kodak, 
    112 S.Ct. at 2077
    .  The "lock-in" would occur provided it could be shown  that
    Kodak copier  owners must either purchase  replacement parts from
    Kodak or  abandon their initial, unamortized  investment in their
    Kodak copier.  In contrast, a completed first semester at univer-
    15
    sity is discretely priced    students do not pay for their entire
    four-year stint in advance      and the "college credit" value of
    the first semester is neither nontransferable nor without econom-
    ic  or educational value in  the future even  if the student does
    not  remain at URI.   Thus, appellants' attempt  to extend Kodak,
    beyond  the "derivative  aftermarket" context to  the educational
    context, is problematic at best.
    Second, the timing  of the "lock-in" at issue  in Kodak
    was  central to  the Supreme  Court's decision.   Unsophisticated
    Kodak copier  owners were destined for "lock-in"  from the moment
    they  purchased their Kodak copiers.   At the  time current Kodak
    copier owners bought their copiers, Kodak had not yet conditioned
    its sale of replacement parts on the purchase of Kodak servicing,
    and its later-announced policy to that effect was made applicable
    both  to  prospective  and existing  Kodak  copier  owners.   Had
    previous customers known,  at the  time they  bought their  Kodak
    copiers, that Kodak would implement its restrictive parts-servic-
    ing policy,  Kodak's "market power," i.e., its leverage to induce
    customers to purchase  Kodak servicing, could  only have been  as
    significant as its AEP in the copier market, which was stipulated
    to  be inconsequential or nonexistent.   See Kodak,  
    112 S.Ct. at 2095-96
      (Scalia, J.,  dissenting)  (noting that  even the  Kodak
    majority  probably would have  found no  "lock-in" had  Kodak an-
    nounced its parts-service "tie" at the time of its market entry);
    see  generally  Philip E.  Areeda,  supra,    1709.2,  at 1164-68
    (same).  In the instant case, however, students know before their
    16
    matriculation that they are buying a URI "package" that  includes
    at least two  "tied" products     a URI  education and  on-campus
    health  care services  and  insurance.   As appellants  failed to
    assert a colorable claim that URI had AEP in the primary (univer-
    sity  education)  market,  no  Kodak-type  "lock-in"  could  have
    occurred  in subsequent  semesters,  and even  the most  detailed
    allegations of "switching costs" would be wholly unavailing.
    17
    B.   The "Due Process" and "Equal Protection" Claims
    Appellants attempt  to  raise two  vaguely  articulated
    constitutional  challenges to  the URI  health services-insurance
    scheme.   First, they argue  that URI's conditioning of continued
    matriculation on  the  payment of  a health  clinic fee  violates
    their constitutional right to  procedural due process, by depriv-
    ing  them of  a  property interest  (fees  and premiums),  and  a
    liberty-privacy interest (the alleged right to retain a physician
    of  one's  choice).    Unsurprisingly, appellants  cite  no  case
    authority  for  either  contention,  nor  have  we  found  any.11
    Appellants purchased  a  "product"-"service" from  URI with  full
    knowledge from the outset that health care fees  and supplemental
    11The  district court  interpreted appellants'  complaint as
    alleging claims based on substantive due process and the right to
    contract.   Appellants concede  that their  "cumbersome briefing"
    contributed to  this understanding, yet  did not move  for recon-
    sideration.  See Vanhaaren v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 
    989 F.2d 1
    , 4-5 (1st Cir. 1993)  (issues raised for the first time on
    appeal  are deemed  waived).   Unfortunately, the  procedural due
    process claim asserted on appeal is no less unwieldy.
    Inexplicably, appellants continue to urge that  Rhode Island
    law disempowered URI from entering the "business"  of health care
    and insurance, and that the LINA  policies were merely a fraud or
    sham  affording  students no  actual  coverage.   Although  these
    allegations might  be material  to appellants' ultra  vires claim
    under  state  law, which  the  district  court dismissed  without
    prejudice, cf. Boston Envtl.  Sanitation Inspectors Ass'n v. City
    of Boston,  
    794 F.2d 12
    ,  13 (1st  Cir. 1986) (noting  that state
    actor's "[m]ere  violation of  state statutory  requirements does
    not offend  federal constitutional due  process"), or conceivably
    may have served  as a basis for some  sort of consumer protection
    claim,  appellants do  not  explain  how  URI's mere  refusal  to
    continue  selling  them   a  service   (i.e.,  education)   would
    constitute an actionable "deprivation" of their "property rights"
    for  federal  due process  purposes.   Cf.  
    id.
     (noting  that "an
    alleged breach of contract [by a state actor] does not  amount to
    a  deprivation  of property  without  due  process"); Jimenez  v.
    Almodovar, 
    650 F.2d 363
    , 370 (1st Cir. 1981) (same).
    18
    insurance premiums were  a required  component of the  cost.   We
    perceive no procedural infirmity.
    Second,  appellants  argue that  the URI  "package" in-
    fringes  their constitutional  right to  equal protection  of the
    laws because male and female  students matriculating at URI  must
    pay the same health care fees, even though male students will not
    utilize the UHS gynecological services.  The district court aptly
    found  that appellants  failed to  allege  that URI  imposed this
    unitary  scheme  with any  discriminatory  animus  aimed at  male
    students.  See Nieves v. University  of Puerto Rico, 
    7 F.3d 270
    ,
    276 (1993) (plaintiff contesting  classification-neutral statutes
    on equal  protection grounds must  proffer not  only evidence  of
    disparate effect, but  evidence that enactment  resulted "because
    of," rather than "in spite of," classification) (citing Personnel
    Adm'r of Massachusetts v.  Feeney, 
    442 U.S. 256
    , 278-80  (1979));
    Lipsett v. University of Puerto Rico, 
    864 F.2d 881
    , 896 (1st Cir.
    1988).  Appellants advance  no curative allegations for relieving
    this infirmity.
    Affirmed.
    19