Levine v. Central Florida Medical Affiliates, Inc. ( 1996 )


Menu:
  •                    United States Court of Appeals,
    Eleventh Circuit.
    No. 94-3145.
    Scott D. LEVINE, M.D., Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.
    CENTRAL FLORIDA MEDICAL AFFILIATES, INC.; Healthchoice, Inc.;
    Sand Lake Hospital; Orlando Regional Healthcare System, Inc. f/k/a
    Orlando Regional Medical Center, Defendants-Appellees.
    Jan. 23, 1996.
    Appeal from the United States District Court for the Middle
    District of Florida. (No. 93-153-CIV-ORL-22), Anne C. Conway,
    Judge.
    Before ANDERSON and CARNES, Circuit Judges, and OWENS*, Senior
    District Judge.
    CARNES, Circuit Judge:
    Dr. Scott Levine, the plaintiff, appeals from the district
    court's grant of summary judgment in favor of the defendants on his
    state and federal antitrust claims.               The four defendants are
    Healthchoice, Inc., a preferred provider organization ("PPO");
    Central Florida Medical Affiliates, Inc. ("CFMA"), a physicians
    advocacy group organized to supply physician providers to the
    Healthchoice PPO;        Sand Lake Hospital;            and Orlando Regional
    Healthcare     System,    Inc.     ("ORHS"),      the     hospital's   parent
    corporation.    The incidents giving rise to the lawsuit are Dr.
    Levine's   unsuccessful    attempt    to   gain    provider    membership   in
    Healthchoice and CFMA, and the temporary suspension of his staff
    privileges at Sand Lake Hospital.          Because we conclude that there
    is no genuine issue of material fact about Dr. Levine failing to
    *
    Honorable Wilbur D. Owens, Jr., Senior U.S. District Judge
    for the Middle District of Georgia, sitting by designation.
    establish any anticompetitive effect resulting from being denied
    membership    in     Healthchoice       and    CFMA   or     from    his     hospital
    suspension, and that the defendants are accordingly entitled to
    judgment as a matter of law, we affirm the district court's grant
    of summary judgment in their favor.
    I. BACKGROUND
    Because the case has come to us on appeal of summary judgment,
    we construe the facts in the light most favorable to the nonmovant,
    in this case Dr. Levine.           Forbus v. Sears Roebuck & Co., 
    30 F.3d 1402
    , 1403 n. 1 (11th Cir.1994), cert. denied, --- U.S. ----, 
    115 S. Ct. 906
    , 
    130 L. Ed. 2d 788
    (1995).             The following is a summary of
    the facts as viewed in the light most favorable to Dr. Levine.
    Dr. Scott D. Levine is an internist.                  In 1989, a year after
    completing    his    residency     in    California,       Dr.    Levine     moved    to
    Orlando, Florida to begin private practice.                  Although Dr. Levine
    explored opportunities to join established medical practices as a
    salaried    employee,1       he   ultimately    decided      to     become    a     sole
    practitioner.       He began his practice in the summer of 1989.
    When    Dr.    Levine    began     his   practice,     he    sought,     and    was
    granted, provisional staff privileges at the ORHS hospitals.2 ORHS
    is a nonprofit organization that owns and operates five Orlando
    area hospitals:      Orlando Regional Medical Center ("ORMC");                 Arnold
    Palmer Hospital for Children and Women;               Sand Lake Hospital;            St.
    1
    One physician offered Dr. Levine $60,000 a year plus
    benefits, and another offered him $100,000 a year plus benefits.
    Neither offer appealed to Dr. Levine.
    2
    ORHS was formerly known as the Orlando Regional Medical
    Center, a name the organization shared with one of its
    unincorporated hospital facilities.
    Cloud Hospital;     and South Seminole Hospital (ORHS owns only half
    of it).     Dr. Levine primarily exercised his staff privileges at
    Sand Lake Hospital because it is located across the street from his
    office.    Around October of 1990, after Dr. Levine had successfully
    exercised his provisional staff privileges for more than a year,
    ORHS granted him full active staff privileges.                 During 1990 and
    1991,   Dr.    Levine   also    applied    for,    and   was   granted,   staff
    privileges at several other Orlando area hospitals:                the Florida
    Hospital      system,   which   operates    five    hospitals;       Glenbeigh
    Hospital;     Charter of Orlando South Hospital;         and Health Central.
    When Dr. Levine acquired provisional staff privileges at Sand
    Lake Hospital, he agreed to have his name put on the emergency room
    ("ER") call list. Each day doctors of various specialties would be
    "on call" in the ER, which means that if a patient came to the ER
    and needed to see, for example, an internist, the hospital would
    contact the internist whose name appeared on the call list for that
    day.    Dr. Levine found that being on the ER call list provided an
    effective means of building his new practice, and so during his
    early years in Orlando, he asked to be placed on the list as often
    as possible.      Many of the patients Dr. Levine treated in the ER
    would continue to see him as their internist after leaving the
    hospital. In addition, these patients would often refer Dr. Levine
    new patients.      Dr. Levine's strategy proved lucrative;            in 1990,
    his first full year of private practice, Dr. Levine's pre-tax net
    earnings were $553,176—more than twice the average earnings of
    Florida internists in private practice that year, according to
    studies conducted by the American Medical Association.
    A. THE DENIAL OF HEALTHCHOICE PPO MEMBERSHIP TO DR. LEVINE
    In addition to being on the ER call list, another method of
    building his practice that Dr. Levine explored was the possibility
    of   becoming   a   physician   provider    of    Healthchoice3   and   CFMA.4
    Healthchoice is a PPO, which is a form of managed health care
    coverage in which physicians agree to accept no more than a maximum
    allowable fee for services rendered to plan enrollees in exchange
    for a potentially higher volume of patients. CFMA is a physicians'
    advocacy group that was organized to supply the Healthchoice PPO
    with a panel of physician providers.             Dr. Levine had heard that
    Healthchoice was one of the largest PPOs in the Orlando area, and
    he believed that Healthchoice patients accounted for approximately
    twenty percent of some member physicians' practices.              Dr. Levine
    had also heard that Healthchoice physicians were, in his words,
    "very pleased with what they're getting as reimbursement."
    Dr.   Levine    sought    physician    provider     membership     with
    Healthchoice several times between 1989 and 1990, but Healthchoice
    denied his request for membership each time, explaining that it did
    not need any more internists in his geographical area.             Believing
    (incorrectly) that in order to be a member of Healthchoice, one had
    to be a member of CFMA, Dr. Levine also inquired about membership
    in CFMA. However, Dr. Levine's telephone call to CFMA was answered
    by a Healthchoice employee, and Dr. Levine was again told that it
    did not need any more internists in his area.
    3
    Healthchoice is owned by Healthnet Services, Inc., which is
    a for-profit wholly owned subsidiary of ORHS.
    4
    For a detailed description of how Healthchoice and CFMA
    operate, see infra pp. ---- - ----.
    During his first few years of practice, Dr. Levine pursued
    provider   memberships   in   three   other   Orlando   area   PPOs—Health
    Advantage, Alta, and Aetna.      He joined the Health Advantage PPO
    because it was part of the group health coverage he had purchased
    for himself and his office staff.        When his own health coverage
    administrators switched to the Alta PPO, Dr. Levine then joined
    Alta as well.     Dr. Levine also applied to become a physician
    provider of Aetna at the request of a patient, but Aetna denied his
    application for the same reason that Healthchoice had—Aetna already
    had enough internists in Dr. Levine's area.         Although Dr. Levine
    received numerous solicitations from other area PPOs inviting him
    to become a physician provider, he turned down each of those
    offers.
    In January of 1991, Dr. Levine's practice was so busy that he
    placed an advertisement in a medical journal to hire a physician as
    a salaried employee. However, because of events that transpired at
    Sand Lake Hospital that same month, Dr. Levine decided not to hire
    another physician for his practice.
    B. THE SUSPENSION OF DR. LEVINE'S STAFF PRIVILEGES AT SAND LAKE
    HOSPITAL
    In January of 1991, Cathy Canniff-Gilliam, the Executive
    Director of Sand Lake Hospital, removed Dr. Levine from the ER call
    list.     A few days later, the executive committee of Sand Lake
    Hospital voted to suspend Dr. Levine's remaining staff privileges
    pending investigation of various patient care concerns.5               The
    5
    Dr. Levine's staff privileges at Sand Lake Hospital
    included the privilege of admitting patients to the hospital and
    treating them during their stay, and the privilege of being on ER
    call and treating patients through the ER.
    executive committee reported these concerns to the ORHS credentials
    committee, which then assembled an investigative committee to
    review   the   incidents     giving    rise   to   those     concerns.   After
    interviewing Dr. Levine and reviewing his patients' charts, the
    investigative committee reported its findings to the credentials
    committee.      The credentials committee reviewed the report and
    recommended to the Sand Lake Hospital executive committee that it
    place Dr. Levine on probation for six months and that it proctor
    his performance of certain procedures several times each.                  The
    executive committee decided to increase the probationary period to
    one   year,    but   other   than     that,   it   adopted    the   credentials
    committee's recommendations.           Dr. Levine appealed the executive
    committee's decision, and in June of 1991, ORHS appointed a hearing
    panel to review the executive committee's decision.                  The panel
    affirmed the executive committee's decision to impose probationary
    conditions upon Dr. Levine.
    Subject to his new probationary status, Dr. Levine regained
    admitting privileges in May of 1991, and ER call privileges in the
    fall of 1991, although he chose to wait until mid-December to
    resume being on ER call.              Dr. Levine still has not met the
    procedure proctoring requirements necessary to regain full staff
    privileges, because he has chosen to admit his patients to Florida
    Hospital, which is the largest hospital system in Orlando, and as
    a result he has not performed the procedures that were to be
    proctored at Sand Lake Hospital.
    During the time that his staff privileges were suspended at
    Sand Lake Hospital,6 Dr. Levine maintained staff privileges at
    Glenbeigh Hospital, Charter Hospital, Health Central Hospital, and
    Florida Hospital (which includes five campuses).            However, he has
    chosen not to exercise his staff privileges at Glenbeigh and
    Charter, purportedly due to the time he has spent pursuing this
    lawsuit.
    The suspension of Dr. Levine's staff privileges began in the
    third week of January in 1991.        Notwithstanding his suspension, in
    1991 Dr. Levine earned $724,722, which is $171,546 (or thirty-one
    percent) more than he had earned the previous year when his Sand
    Lake Hospital staff privileges were not suspended.
    II. PROCEDURAL HISTORY
    In March of 1993 Dr. Levine filed a complaint in the United
    States District Court for the Middle District of Florida against
    CFMA,       Healthchoice,   Sand   Lake   Hospital,   and   ORHS,   alleging
    violations of sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1
    & 2 (1988), and violations of various state laws.7           In Count 1 of
    his complaint, Dr. Levine claimed that CFMA and Healthchoice
    violated section 1 of the Sherman Act by maintaining a closed panel
    of physicians and by denying him physician provider membership.
    Dr. Levine claimed in Count 2 that all of the defendants conspired
    6
    Dr. Levine alleges that his staff privileges were suspended
    at ORMC as well as Sand Lake Hospital; however, we have found no
    evidence in the record to support that allegation.
    7
    In addition to the federal antitrust claims, Dr. Levine's
    complaint included the following: claims under Florida's
    antitrust statutes; a claim for tortious interference with
    business relations; a claim under Florida's general tort
    statute; and a claim for breach of contract. Dr. Levine filed a
    parallel suit in state court which has been held in abeyance
    pending resolution of this case in federal court.
    to, and did, monopolize the market for patients "whose employers
    have contracted with Healthchoice," in violation of section 2 of
    the Sherman Act.       In Count 3 Dr. Levine claimed that ORHS and Sand
    Lake Hospital engaged in a concerted refusal to deal in violation
    of    section    1    of   the   Sherman   Act   by   suspending   his    staff
    privileges.8         Dr. Levine sought monetary damages in excess of
    $100,000 and injunctive relief pursuant to sections 4 and 16 of the
    Clayton Act.9
    In June of 1994, after extensive discovery, each defendant
    filed a motion for summary judgment as to the state and federal
    antitrust claims.          The district court granted the defendants'
    motions, and, declining to exercise its supplemental jurisdiction,
    the   court     dismissed    the   remaining     state   law   claims    without
    prejudice.      Dr. Levine now appeals the district court's grant of
    summary judgment.
    III. DISCUSSION
    In granting the defendants' motions for summary judgment, the
    district court held that Dr. Levine lacked standing to prosecute
    his antitrust claims, and in the alternative that his claims lacked
    8
    Counts 1 through 3 also included Dr. Levine's state
    antitrust law claims.
    9
    Section 4 of the Clayton Act authorizes a private action
    for treble damages and provides, in pertinent part: "[A]ny
    person who shall be injured in his business or property by reason
    of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue therefor...."
    15 U.S.C.A. § 15(a) (West 1995). Section 16 authorizes a private
    action for injunctive relief, and provides, in pertinent part:
    "Any person, firm, corporation, or association shall be entitled
    to sue for and have injunctive relief, in any court of the United
    States having jurisdiction over the parties, against threatened
    loss or damage by a violation of the antitrust laws...." 15
    U.S.C.A. § 26 (West 1973).
    merit.         As   to   Dr.   Levine's    section    1    and   2   claims   against
    Healthchoice and CFMA for denying him membership, and his section
    2 claim against ORHS and Sand Lake Hospital for their part in the
    alleged conspiracy to monopolize, the district court held he lacked
    standing because he was not an efficient enforcer of the antitrust
    laws, and in the alternative, that those claims were without merit
    because he had failed to prove the defendants' market power.                        As to
    Dr. Levine's section 1 claim against ORHS and Sand Lake Hospital
    for suspending his staff privileges, the district court held that
    he lacked standing because he had failed to establish that his
    suspension          resulted   in   any     antitrust      injury,     and    in     the
    alternative, that the claims lacked merit because of Dr. Levine's
    failure to show any anticompetitive effect arising out of his
    suspension.
    We    need     not   decide     whether    Dr.    Levine    has     met    the
    requirements for standing as to any of his antitrust claims,
    because as to each one he has failed to establish any violation of
    the antitrust laws.10          Because we believe Dr. Levine has failed to
    prove any anticompetitive effect resulting from the defendants'
    behavior, as is required under the Sherman Act, we follow the
    advice of Professors Areeda and Hovenkamp and decide this case on
    the merits rather than on standing:
    When a court concludes that no violation has occurred, it
    has no occasion to consider standing.... An increasing number
    of courts, unfortunately, deny standing when they really mean
    that no violation has occurred. In particular, the antitrust
    10
    Because we hold that Dr. Levine has failed to establish
    any antitrust violation, we also need not consider whether he has
    established standing to sue for injunctive relief under section
    16 of the Clayton Act.
    injury element of standing demands that the plaintiff's
    alleged injury result from the threat to competition that
    underlies the alleged violation. A court seeing no threat to
    competition in a rule-of-reason case may then deny that the
    plaintiff has suffered antitrust injury and dismiss the suit
    for lack of standing. Such a ruling would be erroneous, for
    the absence of any threat to competition means that no
    violation   has  occurred   and   that  even   suit   by the
    government—which enjoys automatic standing—must be dismissed.
    2 Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 360f, at
    202-03 (rev. ed. 1995) (footnotes omitted).                 This approach is
    consistent with our precedents.          We have ruled on the merits of an
    antitrust claim without ever deciding whether the plaintiff had
    antitrust standing.          E.g., Aladdin Oil Co. v. Texaco, Inc., 
    603 F.2d 1107
    ,    1109   n.   2   (5th   Cir.1979)   (assuming   standing   and
    affirming       grant   of   summary    judgment    for   defendants   because
    plaintiff failed to establish antitrust violations);              Hardwick v.
    Nu-Way Oil Co., 
    589 F.2d 806
    , 807 n. 3 (5th Cir.) (same), cert.
    denied, 
    444 U.S. 836
    , 
    100 S. Ct. 70
    , 
    62 L. Ed. 2d 46
    (1979);              see also
    Todorov v. DCH Healthcare Auth.,            
    921 F.2d 1438
    , 1446-47 (11th
    Cir.1991) (reaching the merits of an antitrust claim even though
    the plaintiff lacked standing to bring the claim).
    We review a district court's grant of summary judgment de
    novo.    Flores v. Carnival Cruise Lines, 
    47 F.3d 1120
    , 1122 (11th
    Cir.1995).       Viewing the facts in the light most favorable to the
    nonmovant, we must determine whether there exists a genuine issue
    of material fact or whether the movant is entitled to judgment as
    a matter of law.         Tisdale v. United States, 
    62 F.3d 1367
    , 1370
    (11th Cir.1995).
    A. THE SECTION 1 CLAIMS
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides that "[e]very contract,
    combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in
    restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with
    foreign nations, is declared to be illegal."   15 U.S.C.A. § 1 (West
    1973).   A section 1 plaintiff must prove an agreement between two
    or more persons to restrain trade, because unilateral conduct is
    not illegal under section 1.       See, e.g., Fisher v. City of
    Berkeley, Cal., 
    475 U.S. 260
    , 266, 
    106 S. Ct. 1045
    , 1049, 
    89 L. Ed. 2d 206
    (1986) ("Even where a single firm's restraints directly affect
    prices and have the same economic effect as concerted action might
    have, there can be no liability under § 1 in the absence of
    agreement.");   Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Serv. Corp., 
    465 U.S. 752
    , 761, 
    104 S. Ct. 1464
    , 1469, 
    79 L. Ed. 2d 775
    (1984);     
    Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1455
    .   Thus, the first element of a section 1 claim is
    proof of an agreement to restrain trade.
    However, not every agreement that restrains competition will
    violate the Sherman Act.    The Supreme Court long ago determined
    that section 1 prohibits only those agreements that unreasonably
    restrain competition, Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 
    221 U.S. 1
    , 58-64, 
    31 S. Ct. 502
    , 515-17, 
    55 L. Ed. 619
    (1911), thus, the
    unreasonableness of the agreement is the second element of a
    section 1 claim.    In identifying which agreements unreasonably
    restrain competition, the Supreme Court has held that certain kinds
    of agreements are unreasonable per se, such as agreements among
    direct competitors to fix prices or to restrict output.       E.g.,
    United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 
    310 U.S. 150
    , 224-26 n. 59,
    
    60 S. Ct. 811
    , 845-46 n. 59, 
    84 L. Ed. 1129
    (1940).   The only inquiry
    in such cases is whether there was an agreement to do so, because
    the unreasonableness of the restraint is presumed.           See, e.g.,
    Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc'y, 
    457 U.S. 332
    , 344-45, 
    102 S. Ct. 2466
    , 2473-74, 
    73 L. Ed. 2d 48
    (1982);            United States v.
    Trenton Potteries Co., 
    273 U.S. 392
    , 397-98, 
    47 S. Ct. 377
    , 379, 
    71 L. Ed. 700
    (1927). Agreements that do not fit within an established
    per se category are analyzed under the "rule of reason," i.e.,
    courts will engage in a comprehensive analysis of the agreement's
    purpose and effect to determine whether it unreasonably restrains
    competition.    E.g., Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting
    Sys., Inc., 
    441 U.S. 1
    , 24-25, 
    99 S. Ct. 1551
    , 1565, 
    60 L. Ed. 2d 1
    (1979).
    1. The Section 1 Claim Against Healthchoice and CFMA
    A more detailed description of how the Healthchoice PPO and
    CFMA operate is necessary to a discussion of the merits of Dr.
    Levine's claims against those two defendants.
    a) How Healthchoice and CFMA Operate
    Healthchoice markets to healthcare payors a panel of select
    healthcare     providers—which     includes    physicians,   hospitals,
    pharmacies, and durable medical equipment companies.         The payors
    consist   of    employers,   insurance        companies,   third   party
    administrators, or governmental agencies.        Healthchoice maintains
    a limited panel of providers who have agreed to accept no more than
    a maximum allowable fee for services rendered or products furnished
    to Healthchoice enrollees.       These maximum fees may or may not be
    lower than the provider's ordinary charges.           In addition, the
    providers agree to be subject to Healthchoice's utilization review
    and quality control program. Providers are willing to accept these
    terms because Healthchoice membership may increase their number of
    patients.
    Healthchoice individually negotiates with each payor to arrive
    at a schedule of fees that the payor is willing to pay for various
    medical    products    and     services.         Healthchoice       presents       each
    prospective payor with its schedule of fees, and the payor is then
    free to negotiate with Healthchoice for lower fees.                  Several steps
    are involved in computing Healthchoice's schedule of fees.                        Every
    medical     product    and    service      is    identified       according       to    a
    standardized "Current Procedural Terminology" code ("CPT code").
    Healthchoice     assigns      to    each   CPT    code,    of     which    there       are
    approximately 9,000, a unit value that it adapts from information
    provided by Medicare.              The unit value is a reflection of the
    approximate cost of resources required for each procedure or
    product. Healthchoice then assigns a monetary conversion factor to
    each major medical specialty, e.g., medicine has one conversion
    factor, and radiology has another;               these conversion factors are
    collectively     called      the    "Master     Payor     Rate    Schedule."           The
    Healthchoice fee schedule is computed by multiplying the conversion
    factors on the Master Payor Rate Schedule by the unit values
    assigned to the CPT codes.            The resulting schedule of fees, once
    accepted    by   the   payor,      are   the    maximum    that    the    payor    will
    reimburse a provider for each product or service.                        Thus, when a
    payor receives a bill from a provider, it pays the provider the
    lesser of either the actual charges submitted by the provider, or
    the maximum allowable fee as reflected in the Healthchoice fee
    schedule.
    Healthchoice does not consult its various providers when it
    compiles     the   unit    values     or    the        conversion        factors.    The
    Healthchoice board of directors has eight members, four of whom are
    CFMA physicians, but when that board approves the Master Payor Rate
    Schedule, those four physician board members are not allowed to
    participate.       In     its    contract       with    a    provider,      Healthchoice
    includes the conversion factors, but it does not include the unit
    values.      Thus, the provider does not know the exact fees that
    Healthchoice has negotiated with the payors. Instead, the contract
    with each provider includes only an example of how a fee would be
    calculated for one of the more commonly used CPT codes.                         Should a
    provider     request      more    information          about      the    fee   schedule,
    Healthchoice will give the provider a few more illustrations.                        The
    provider is always allowed to "opt out" of a contract with a given
    payor if it finds the fee reimbursement unacceptable.11
    A    Healthchoice     enrollee       is    free       to   use    non-Healthchoice
    providers;     however, the enrollee's payor may require the enrollee
    to pay a higher deductible, and may require the enrollee to pay for
    any   provider     charges        over     the     payor's         maximum     allowable
    reimbursement.     The payors individually design the terms of these
    benefit packages—Healthchoice itself does not create financial
    disincentives for any enrollees who choose to use non-Healthchoice
    providers.
    The main source of Healthchoice's physician providers is CFMA,
    11
    Healthchoice charges each payor a nominal monthly fee for
    each of the payor's enrolled employees. In 1994, the fee was
    approximately $1.25 per month for each enrollee. Healthchoice
    has never earned a profit.
    which    was   organized    to     supply     Healthchoice      with   a   panel   of
    physician providers.            Four members of CFMA sit on the board of
    directors of Healthchoice. However, Healthchoice does not contract
    only with CFMA for physician providers;                    many of Healthchoice's
    physician      providers    are       not   members   of    CFMA.      Healthchoice
    providers,      whether    or    not    members   of   CFMA,     are    allowed    to
    participate in other PPOs, and most of them do participate in
    several different PPOs.
    For a short period of time after Healthchoice began doing
    business, it accepted applications from any provider who wanted to
    apply.    Thereafter, Healthchoice decided to limit the size of its
    panel, and so it adopted a need-based system for determining how
    many providers of various specialties to include on its panel.
    Healthchoice stopped accepting applications from physicians in
    those specialties that were already adequately represented on the
    provider panel.       This need-based system is administered by the
    Healthchoice staff;        providers do not participate in determining
    how many providers are needed on the Healthchoice panel.                           The
    Healthchoice staff also handles all inquiries regarding provider
    panel membership opportunities, without discussing those inquiries
    with the board of directors.
    Healthchoice considers numerous factors in deciding how many
    providers to have on its panel, including:                     (1) the number of
    enrollees in the plan;           (2) the geographic location of enrollees
    and   providers;      (3)       the    physicians'     specialties;        (4)     the
    administrative costs of managing providers;                 (5) the special needs
    of particular payors;             and (6) the availability of access to
    existing members, i.e., how long a patient has to wait to get an
    appointment with a Healthchoice provider.           Although Healthchoice's
    general policy is to add new providers only when the need arises,
    if an existing Healthchoice provider adds a physician to his group
    practice, that new physician is automatically eligible to become a
    Healthchoice      provider,   subject   to    the   new        physician   meeting
    Healthchoice's     credentialling    standards.           The    purpose    of    the
    exception to the need-based system is to avoid the administrative
    difficulties associated with cross-coverage: because physicians in
    a group practice cover for one another when they take time off,
    Healthchoice determined that it would be more cost effective to
    exercise its utilization review and quality control over the whole
    practice group.
    Healthchoice asks its providers to refer Healthchoice patients
    to other Healthchoice providers whenever feasible.                   If a provider
    continually    refers    Healthchoice      patients       to    non-Healthchoice
    physicians without justification, Healthchoice may remove that
    provider   from    the   panel.     This     provision     helps      assure     that
    Healthchoice and the payors can manage the costs of healthcare.
    Because    non-Healthchoice       physicians        are        not    subject      to
    Healthchoice's     utilization    review     system,      the    payors    have    no
    effective means of determining whether the care rendered by a
    non-Healthchoice physician is necessary or cost efficient.
    As of the date that discovery was complete in this case,
    Healthchoice had approximately 68,000 covered lives in the Orlando
    area, which had a population of more than 1.1 million.12 There were
    approximately 865 Healthchoice physician providers among the more
    than 2,200 licensed physicians in the Orlando area.           At that time,
    Healthchoice competed with thirty-seven other PPOs, eleven Health
    Maintenance     Organizations   ("HMOs"),   and    numerous    traditional
    insurance coverage companies.
    b) The Merits of the Section 1 Claim Against Healthchoice and
    CFMA
    Dr. Levine alleges that Healthchoice, CFMA, and their member
    physicians have conspired to unreasonably restrain competition in
    violation of section 1 of the Sherman Act by maintaining a closed
    panel of providers physicians, by creating a financial disincentive
    for enrollees who want to use non-Healthchoice physicians, and by
    prohibiting Healthchoice physicians from referring Healthchoice
    enrollees to non-Healthchoice physicians.         Dr. Levine argues that
    these features restrict the availability of physician services to
    Healthchoice enrollees, lead to price stabilization in the market
    for physician services, and render excluded physicians incapable of
    competing     for   Healthchoice   patients.      Dr.   Levine   primarily
    characterizes the activities of the defendants as a group boycott,
    or a concerted refusal to deal, however, he occasionally refers to
    the defendants' activities as illegal price fixing.           We will first
    discuss his contention that the defendants have illegally fixed
    prices, and then his contention that they have engaged in a
    concerted refusal to deal.
    12
    "Covered lives" includes enrolled employees and any family
    members covered by their policy. The parties define "the Orlando
    area" as Orange, Seminole, and Osceola counties.
    i) The Alleged Agreement to Fix Prices
    Although Dr. Levine did not specifically argue to this Court
    that the defendants illegally fixed prices, i.e. provider fees,
    there are portions of his brief where he appears to assume the
    existence of such an agreement. That assumption is contrary to the
    uncontroverted evidence in the record, which establishes that there
    was no agreement between Healthchoice, CFMA, and their member
    physicians to fix provider fees.       Healthchoice negotiates the
    provider reimbursement schedule directly with payors, not with
    providers.    Healthchoice does not consult any physician providers
    when it compiles the CPT code unit values or the Master Payor Rate
    Schedule, and physician members of the Healthchoice board of
    directors are excluded from the reimbursement schedule proposal and
    approval process.    Providers must either accept not more than the
    maximum reimbursement negotiated by Healthchoice with the payors
    and not charge the patient for any difference between their fee and
    the reimbursement, or else opt out of the plan.   The result is that
    the providers' actual fees are not set.     The only figure that is
    set is the maximum allowable fee that they will be reimbursed by
    Healthchoice.    Nothing prevents the physician from dropping his
    fees even further in order to compete should he choose to do so.
    This method of negotiating fees, in which the payors decide
    the maximum amount they are willing to reimburse providers for
    medical services and providers decide whether they are willing to
    accept that limitation on the reimbursement they receive, is a kind
    of "price fixing," but it is a kind that the antitrust laws do not
    prohibit.    See, e.g., Kartell v. Blue Shield, 
    749 F.2d 922
    , 923-26
    (1st Cir.1984) (Breyer, J.), cert. denied, 
    471 U.S. 1029
    , 
    105 S. Ct. 2040
    , 
    85 L. Ed. 2d 322
    (1985);        Pennsylvania Dental Ass'n v. Medical
    Serv. Ass'n, 
    745 F.2d 248
    , 256-57 (3d Cir.1984), cert. denied, 
    471 U.S. 1016
    , 
    105 S. Ct. 2021
    , 
    85 L. Ed. 2d 303
    (1985);              Medical Arts
    Pharmacy v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield,            
    675 F.2d 502
    , 504-06 (2d
    Cir.1982);     see also 8 Phillip E. Areeda,         Antitrust Law ¶ 1622b
    (1989).      Because there is no genuine issue of material fact
    regarding the existence of an agreement among Healthchoice, CFMA,
    or its member doctors to fix provider fees, and because the
    defendants are entitled to judgment as a matter of law, Dr.
    Levine's section 1 claim against these defendants, to the extent
    that it alleges illegal price fixing, fails.
    Our decision that Healthchoice's method of negotiating with
    payors the fees it pays providers does not violate the Sherman Act
    as a matter of law is supported by the Department of Justice and
    the Federal Trade Commission's recently issued "Statements of
    Enforcement Policy and Analytical Principles Relating to Health
    Care and Antitrust" ("DOJ Enforcement Policy" or "the policy"),
    available    in,    WESTLAW,    
    1994 WL 642477
      (F.T.C.).     The    DOJ
    Enforcement Policy separates those multiprovider networks wherein
    competitors agree with one another regarding prices or market
    allocation, from those networks wherein such decisions are handled
    unilaterally       by   each   competitor   or   through   a   third     party
    "messenger." The policy defines the "messenger model" as involving
    "an agent or third party conveying to purchasers information
    obtained individually from providers in the network about prices
    the network participants are willing to accept, and conveying to
    providers any contract offers made by purchasers."                    
    Id. at *38
    (footnote omitted).          The latter will "rarely present substantial
    antitrust concerns."         
    Id. The policy
    states that "[t]he critical
    antitrust issue is whether the arrangement creates or facilitates
    agreements that restrict price or other significant terms of
    competition among the provider members of the network."                   
    Id. at *39.
           In this case, there is no evidence that the Healthchoice
    method of negotiating maximum fee reimbursement facilitates any
    agreements among its provider panel members to restrict price or
    any other forms of competition.13
    ii) The Alleged Concerted Refusal to Deal
    Although there is no genuine issue of material fact regarding
    the existence of an agreement to fix prices, Dr. Levine submitted
    evidence sufficient to establish a genuine issue of material fact
    regarding the existence of a             concerted refusal to deal, i.e.
    agreements among Healthchoice, CFMA, and their member providers to
    restrict       the   size   of   the   provider   panel,   and   to   discourage
    13
    We also note that in Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical
    Soc'y, the Supreme Court implicitly sanctioned this approach to
    negotiating reimbursement rates:
    [A] binding assurance of complete insurance coverage—as
    well as most of the respondents' potential for lower
    insurance premiums—can be obtained only if the insurer
    and the doctor agree in advance on the maximum fee that
    the doctor will accept as full payment for a particular
    service. Even if a fee schedule is therefore
    desirable, it is not necessary that the doctors do the
    price fixing.... [I]nsurers are capable not only of
    fixing maximum reimbursable prices but also of
    obtaining binding agreements with providers
    guaranteeing the insured full reimbursement of a
    participating provider's fee.
    
    457 U.S. 332
    , 352-53, 
    102 S. Ct. 2466
    , 2477-78, 
    73 L. Ed. 2d 48
           (1982) (footnote omitted).
    providers from referring Healthchoice enrollees to non-Healthchoice
    physicians.      Thus, for purposes of defeating summary judgment
    against him, Dr. Levine has established the first element of his
    section 1 claim to the extent that it alleges a concerted refusal
    to deal.     The question remains whether the agreements in question
    are   an    unreasonable   restraint   on   competition   as   required   to
    establish the second element of a section 1 claim.
    Before we can determine whether the Healthchoice and CFMA
    agreements are an unreasonable restraint on competition, we must
    first decide whether to analyze them under the per se rule or the
    rule of reason. "[A] restraint may be adjudged unreasonable either
    because it fits within a class of restraints that has been held to
    be "per se' unreasonable, or because it violates what has come to
    be known as the "Rule of Reason.' "          F.T.C. v. Indiana Fed'n of
    Dentists, 
    476 U.S. 447
    , 457-58, 
    106 S. Ct. 2009
    , 2017, 
    90 L. Ed. 2d 445
    (1986).     "The presumption in cases brought under section 1 of
    the Sherman Act is that the rule-of-reason standard applies."
    Seagood Trading Corp. v. Jerrico, Inc., 
    924 F.2d 1555
    , 1567 (11th
    Cir.1991).      We apply the per se rule "only when history and
    analysis have shown that in sufficiently similar circumstances the
    rule of reason unequivocally results in a finding of liability,"
    Consultants & Designers, Inc. v. Butler Serv. Group, Inc., 
    720 F.2d 1553
    , 1562 (11th Cir.1983), i.e., when the conduct involved "always
    or almost always tend[s] to restrict competition and decrease
    output."      Broadcast Music, 
    Inc., 441 U.S. at 19-20
    , 99 S.Ct. at
    1562.      We will not apply the per se rule "to restraints of trade
    that are of ambiguous effect."         Consultants & 
    Designers, 720 F.2d at 1562
    ;      see also Indiana Fed'n of 
    Dentists, 476 U.S. at 458-59
    ,
    106   S.Ct.    at   2018     (declining       "to   extend   per   se    analysis   to
    restraints imposed in the context of business relationships where
    the   economic      impact    of    certain     practices    is    not   immediately
    obvious"); National Soc'y of Professional Eng'rs v. United States,
    
    435 U.S. 679
    , 692, 
    98 S. Ct. 1355
    , 1365, 
    55 L. Ed. 2d 637
    (1978).
    Dr. Levine characterizes the agreement to limit the size of
    the   provider      panel    and    to    discourage     provider       members   from
    referring Healthchoice patients to non-Healthchoice physicians as
    a group boycott and urges this Court to apply the per se rule.                      But
    this Court has stated that "[t]he attachment of the group boycott
    label does not necessarily require as a consequence an application
    of the per se approach."           Consultants & 
    Designers, 720 F.2d at 1561
    (citation and quotation marks omitted) (alteration in original).
    "The labeling of a restraint as a group boycott does not eliminate
    the necessity of determining whether it is a "naked restraint of
    trade with no purpose except stifling competition.' " 
    Id. (quoting White
    Motor Co. v. United States, 
    372 U.S. 253
    , 263, 
    83 S. Ct. 696
    ,
    702, 
    9 L. Ed. 2d 738
    (1963)).              In   F.T.C. v. Indiana Federation of
    Dentists, the Supreme Court described the kind of the boycotts
    subject to the per se rule:
    Although this Court has in the past stated that group boycotts
    are unlawful per se, we decline to resolve this case by
    forcing the [defendant's] policy into the "boycott" pigeonhole
    and invoking the per se rule. As we observed last Term in
    Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery &
    Printing Co., 
    472 U.S. 284
    , 
    105 S. Ct. 2613
    , 
    86 L. Ed. 2d 202
          (1985), the category of restraints classed as group boycotts
    is not to be expanded indiscriminately, and the per se
    approach has generally been limited to cases in which firms
    with market power boycott suppliers or customers in order to
    discourage them from doing business with a 
    competitor.... 476 U.S. at 458
    , 106 S.Ct. at 2018 (emphasis added) (citation
    omitted).
    Dr. Levine bases his concerted refusal to deal claim on
    Healthchoice's     denial   of   his   repeated   attempts   to   apply   for
    membership, and its rule discouraging panel members from referring
    patients to physicians outside the network.           This case does not
    involve the kind of group boycott that warrants application of the
    per se rule, i.e., it is not a "naked restraint of trade with no
    purpose except stifling competition." Consultants & 
    Designers, 720 F.2d at 1562
    .      We will analyze the facts of this case under the
    rule of reason, instead of the per se approach, for two reasons.
    First, we are persuaded that because Dr. Levine has not proven that
    Healthchoice and CFMA have market power,14 the Supreme Court's
    decision in Indiana Federation of Dentists,          a pertinent part of
    which is quoted above, precludes us from applying the per se rule
    to these facts.
    Second, the DOJ Enforcement Policy supports our decision to
    apply the rule of reason instead of the per se rule.              The policy
    states that "[b]ecause multiprovider networks are relatively new to
    the health care industry, the Agencies do not yet have sufficient
    experience evaluating them to issue a formal statement of antitrust
    enforcement     policy."    DOJ Enforcement Policy,          available    in,
    WESTLAW, 
    1994 WL 642477
    , at 37 (F.T.C.). As previously noted, this
    Court is loath to condemn a practice as per se violative of the
    antitrust laws unless experience has shown that it always leads to
    anticompetitive effects in the market, Consultants & Designers, 720
    14
    For a discussion of market power, see infra pp. 776-78.
    F.2d at 1562, and the DOJ policy statement evidences that such
    experience is lacking with respect to multiprovider networks.
    The DOJ Enforcement Policy also provides guidance on how to
    analyze the multiprovider network practice of excluding particular
    providers:
    Most multiprovider networks will contract with some, but
    not all, providers in an area. Such selective contracting may
    be a method through which networks limit their provider panels
    in an effort to achieve quality and cost containment goals and
    enhance their ability to compete against other networks. One
    reason often advanced for selective contracting is to ensure
    that the network can direct a sufficient patient volume to its
    providers to justify price concessions or adherence to strict
    quality controls by the providers. Where a geographic market
    can support several multiprovider networks, there are not
    likely to be significant competitive problems associated with
    the exclusion of particular providers by particular networks.
    A rule of reason analysis usually is applied in judging
    the legality of excluding providers from a multiprovider
    network.   The focus of the analysis is not on whether a
    particular provider has been harmed by the exclusion, but
    rather whether the exclusion reduces competition among
    providers in the market and thereby harms consumers.
    Therefore, exclusion may present competitive concerns if
    providers are unable to compete effectively without access to
    the network, and competition is thereby harmed. The Agencies
    also recognize, however, that there may be procompetitive
    reasons associated with the exclusion, such as the provider's
    competence or ability and willingness to meet the network's
    cost-containment goals. In addition, in certain circumstances
    network membership restrictions may be procompetitive by
    giving non-member providers the incentive to form other
    networks in order to compete more effectively with the
    network.
    DOJ Enforcement Policy at 42.   We find no fault with that analysis,
    and consistent with it we conclude that the rule of reason applies
    to Dr. Levine's section 1 claim against Healthchoice and CFMA.
    Under the rule of reason, the "test of legality is whether
    the restraint imposed is such as merely regulates and perhaps
    thereby promotes competition or whether it is such as may suppress
    or even destroy competition."      Chicago Bd. of Trade v. United
    States, 
    246 U.S. 231
    , 238, 
    38 S. Ct. 242
    , 244, 
    62 L. Ed. 683
    (1918).
    Rule of reason analysis requires the plaintiff to prove (1) an
    anticompetitive effect of the defendant's conduct on the relevant
    market, and (2) that the conduct has no procompetitive benefit or
    justification.    E.g., Consultants & 
    Designers, 720 F.2d at 1562
    .
    In order to prove an anticompetitive effect on the market,
    the plaintiff may either prove that the defendants' behavior had an
    "actual detrimental effect" on competition, or that the behavior
    had "the potential for genuine adverse effects on competition." In
    order to prove the latter, the plaintiff must define the relevant
    market and establish that the defendants possessed power in that
    market.    Indiana Fed'n of 
    Dentists, 476 U.S. at 460-61
    , 106 S.Ct.
    at 2019;    Capital Imaging Assoc., P.C. v. Mohawk Valley Medical
    Assoc., Inc., 
    996 F.2d 537
    , 546 (2d Cir.) ("[W]here the plaintiff
    is unable to demonstrate ... actual effects, it must at least
    establish that defendants possess the requisite market power so
    that their arrangement has the potential for genuine adverse
    effects on competition."   (citation and quotation marks omitted)),
    cert. denied, --- U.S. ----, 
    114 S. Ct. 388
    , 
    126 L. Ed. 2d 337
    (1993).
    We analyze the concerted refusal to deal in this case first for
    actual detrimental effect on competition, and then for potential
    adverse effect.
    Dr. Levine contends that he has shown actual detrimental
    effects, i.e., that the defendants intended to, and did, restrict
    competition.      But Dr. Levine has failed to support with any
    evidence his conclusory assertion that the defendants' behavior
    actually had the effect of restricting competition.    Indeed, the
    evidence    in   the      record      suggests     the     contrary.        Although
    Healthchoice and CFMA denied him membership, Dr. Levine had no
    trouble establishing a booming practice.                 Dr. Levine opened a solo
    practice in 1989 with one patient, and in a little more than a year
    his practice was so busy that he began advertising to hire another
    physician. Dr. Levine acknowledges his extraordinary success—which
    earned him more than half a million dollars in his first full year
    of practice and nearly three quarters of a million dollars his
    second    year—but   he      argues   that   had    he    been    allowed   to   join
    Healthchoice, he would have been able to "score a touchdown."                     The
    antitrust    laws      are     intended      to    protect       competition,     not
    competitors, see Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    ,
    344, 
    82 S. Ct. 1502
    , 1534, 
    8 L. Ed. 2d 510
    (1962);                  
    Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1450
    , and we will not depart from that purpose in order to
    improve Dr. Levine's income standings in the physician league or
    help him win the Super Bowl of remuneration.
    Dr. Levine also contends that he has shown actual detrimental
    effects on competition by showing that Healthchoice's closed panel
    resulted in fees rising and stabilizing, but there is no evidence
    of that in the record.           Dr. Levine relies upon the Healthchoice
    Master Payor Rate Schedules from several years as evidence of
    rising fees, but those schedules do not establish that provider
    fees have risen.       The Master Payor Rate Schedules include only one
    of the two factors that goes into calculating a fee—the conversion
    factor.15   They do not include the other critical factor, which is
    15
    For an explanation of how the fees are calculated, see
    supra pp. 769-70.
    the unit values for the more than 9,000 CPT codes.                      Without the
    unit   values     for   the    years    covered    by    the   Master    Payor   Rate
    Schedules, which Dr. Levine has not provided, the actual fees
    cannot be calculated.          Moreover, evidence in the record indicates
    that Healthchoice has on many occasions lowered both the conversion
    factors and the unit values when its analysis of the market
    indicated the need for a more competitive fee structure.                     In any
    event, evidence of rising fees is insufficient unless placed in
    context with evidence about the fees charged by non-Healthchoice
    physicians, the resource costs underlying the physician services,
    and the rate of inflation.                Thus, Dr. Levine has failed to
    establish     a   genuine       issue   of   material       fact   about    whether
    Healthchoice and CFMA have had an actual detrimental effect on
    competition.
    In the face of his failure to show an actual detrimental
    effect on competition, Dr. Levine argues that he still need not
    prove market power if he shows that the defendants intended to
    restrict competition.           The rule of reason analysis is concerned
    with the actual or likely effects of defendants' behavior, not with
    the intent behind that behavior.              See U.S. Healthcare, Inc. v.
    Healthsource, Inc., 
    986 F.2d 589
    , 596 (1st Cir.1993) (stating that
    "effects are ... the central concern of the antitrust laws," and
    that motivation is but "a clue").                 Thus even if Dr. Levine had
    established       that        the   defendants          intended    to     restrict
    competition—which he has not—proof of such intent would not relieve
    him of the necessity of either proving the defendants' market power
    or proving an actual detrimental effect on competition, and we have
    already decided that he has failed to create a genuine issue of
    material fact as to actual detrimental effect.
    In view of that, Dr. Levine's claim may only succeed under
    our section 1 rule of reason analysis if he proves that the
    defendants' acts had "the potential for genuine adverse effects on
    competition."    To do this, Dr. Levine must define the relevant
    product and geographic markets and prove that the defendants had
    sufficient market power to affect competition.       See Indiana Fed'n
    of 
    Dentists, 476 U.S. at 460-61
    , 106 S.Ct. at 2019.           Dr. Levine
    contends that the relevant product market should be the provision
    of   internist   services   to   Healthchoice     patients,   which   he
    characterizes as an "aftermarket," relying on Eastman Kodak Co. v.
    Image Technical Services, Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 
    112 S. Ct. 2072
    , 
    119 L. Ed. 2d 265
    (1992), and that the relevant geographic market is the
    Orlando area.    He argues that the product market he has defined is
    separate from the market for all other physician services in the
    Orlando area.    We disagree.
    "To define a market is to identify producers that provide
    customers of a defendant firm (or firms) with alternative sources
    for the defendant's product or services."       2A Phillip E. Areeda et
    al., Antitrust Law ¶ 530a, at 150 (1995) (footnote omitted);          see
    also Eastman 
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 481
    , 112 S.Ct. at 2090.               The
    "market   is     composed   of   products   that     have     reasonable
    interchangeability."    United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours &
    Co., 
    351 U.S. 377
    , 404, 
    76 S. Ct. 994
    , 1012, 
    100 L. Ed. 1264
    (1956);
    see also United States Anchor Mfg., Inc. v. Rule Indus., Inc.,          
    7 F.3d 986
    , 995 (11th Cir.1993), cert. denied, --- U.S. ----, 
    114 S. Ct. 2710
    , 
    129 L. Ed. 2d 837
    (1994). Therefore, in order to provide
    an   accurate     market   definition      in     this   case,    Dr.   Levine     must
    identify the physician services that Healthchoice enrollees would
    deem to be reasonably interchangeable with the services provided by
    Healthchoice      providers.       It   is      undisputed       that   Healthchoice
    enrollees are free to choose non-Healthchoice physicians, and that
    Healthchoice      payors   will    cover     at    least   some    portion    of     the
    non-Healthchoice physician's fee.               Dr. Levine contends, however,
    that it is financially impractical for Healthchoice enrollees to
    visit non-Healthchoice physicians because the enrollees have to pay
    more money out of their own pockets to do so.                     Thus, he argues,
    non-Healthchoice        internists      are        not     interchangeable         with
    Healthchoice internists, which means Healthchoice internists are a
    separate product market.          We are not persuaded.
    Dr. Levine has failed to present evidence showing how much
    more,      if   any,   Healthchoice     enrollees        must    pay    to   visit    a
    non-Healthchoice physician. In fact, Dr. Levine admits that he has
    treated two Healthchoice enrollees in his practice, and that for
    one of those patients he waived the payor's copayment requirement
    so that the patient did not have an additional out-of-pocket
    expense.16      Moreover, Dr. Levine has offered no evidence to show
    that the cost to the enrollee of switching to another healthcare
    plan would be prohibitively expensive.                     Although Dr. Levine's
    expert assumed that Healthchoice enrollees are locked in to the
    16
    Dr. Levine says that this patient stopped seeing him
    because she felt too guilty about his having waived the copayment
    requirement. That purported reason is somewhat ironic in view of
    Dr. Levine's income level. See supra p. 776.
    Healthchoice plan, he admitted that he had seen no evidence that
    the enrollees' choice of plan had been so restricted.                      To the
    contrary, the evidence in the record establishes that the largest
    Healthchoice    payor    offers    its    enrollees    several     choices    for
    healthcare coverage, and that those enrollees are allowed to switch
    plans.    There is nothing to indicate that the other Healthchoice
    payors offer their enrollees any less choice.              Thus, we hold that
    Dr. Levine's narrow definition of the relevant product market does
    not satisfy his burden of presenting prima facie evidence of the
    relevant market.17       See L.A. Draper & Son v. Wheelabrator-Frye,
    Inc., 
    735 F.2d 414
    , 422 (11th Cir.1984) ("An antitrust plaintiff
    ... makes out a prima facie case under the rule of reason only upon
    proof of a well-defined relevant market upon which the challenged
    anticompetitive actions would have substantial impact."              (citation
    and quotation marks omitted));            see also Bathke v. Casey's Gen.
    Stores, Inc., 
    64 F.3d 340
    , 345 (8th Cir.1995);               Pastore v. Bell
    Tel. Co., 
    24 F.3d 508
    , 512 (3d Cir.1994).
    Even if Dr. Levine had adequately defined the relevant market,
    he has presented no evidence to prove the defendants' market power.
    Absent evidence that the defendants had sufficient market power to
    affect    competition,    Dr.    Levine's    section   1   claim    must    fail.
    Therefore, because Dr. Levine has not established either that the
    defendants'    behavior    had    an     "actual   detrimental     effect"     on
    competition or "the potential for genuine adverse effects on
    17
    Dr. Levine was required to define both the relevant
    product market and the relevant geographic market; however,
    because we have held that he failed to adequately define the
    relevant product market, we need not reach whether the Orlando
    area is a proper relevant geographic market.
    competition," Indiana Fed'n of 
    Dentists, 476 U.S. at 460-61
    , 106
    S.Ct. at 2019, we hold that the district court properly dismissed
    Dr. Levine's section 1 claim against Healthchoice and CFMA.18
    2. The Section 1 Claim Against ORHS and Sand Lake Hospital
    Dr. Levine claims that ORHS, Sand Lake Hospital, and other
    unnamed co-conspirators on the Sand Lake Hospital medical staff
    violated section 1 of the Sherman Act by conspiring to suspend his
    staff     privileges      without   good   cause,      and    that    this   activity
    constituted     a    concerted      refusal      to    deal     resulting     in    an
    unreasonable restraint of trade.            As Dr. Levine conceded at oral
    argument, the per se rule does not apply to the defendants'
    decision to suspend his staff privileges.                    As with Dr. Levine's
    section 1 claim against Healthchoice and CFMA, we will apply the
    rule of reason to his section 1 claim against ORHS and Sand Lake
    Hospital.
    We need not decide whether Dr. Levine has offered sufficient
    proof of a conspiracy to restrain trade between ORHS, Sand Lake
    Hospital, and members of its medical staff, the first element of a
    section 1 claim, because once again Dr. Levine has failed to
    demonstrate     that      any   resulting     restraint       on     competition    is
    unreasonable, the second element of a section 1 claim.                             More
    particularly,       Dr.    Levine   has    not   met    the    rule     of   reason's
    requirement of proving an actual or potential detrimental effect on
    competition.
    18
    Because we hold that Dr. Levine has failed to establish
    any anticompetitive effect, we need not reach the second part of
    the rule of reason analysis and decide whether the defendants'
    conduct may be excused by some procompetitive benefit or
    justification.
    The   only    evidence    Dr.    Levine     offers    to       show    that   his
    suspension had an actual detrimental effect on competition is that
    one of his patients came to the Sand Lake Hospital ER during his
    suspension and was unable to use Dr. Levine's services.                              The
    practical effect of this incident is no different than if Dr.
    Levine's patient had been taken to the ER at a hospital where he
    had never even applied for staff privileges—the patient would be
    unable to see Dr. Levine at that location at that particular time.
    However, had the patient gone or been taken to Florida Hospital
    (which   has   five    locations),      where    Dr.    Levine    did        have   staff
    privileges, she would have been able to use Dr. Levine's services.
    We are convinced that a patient's inability to see Dr. Levine in
    the Sand Lake Hospital ER when she asked for him does not rise to
    the level of an actual detrimental effect on competition.                       Cf. Lie
    v. St. Joseph Hosp., 
    964 F.2d 567
    , 569-70 (6th Cir.1992) (holding
    that   plaintiff      doctor's   proof    that     hospital      staff       suspension
    resulted in him having a lower income did not rise to level of
    actual detrimental effects on competition); Tarabishi v. McAlester
    Regional Hosp., 
    951 F.2d 1558
    , 1569 n. 15 (10th Cir.1991) (holding
    that plaintiff's staff privileges suspension was not an actual
    detrimental effect on competition because it did not result in
    restriction     of    choice     to    consumers       or   in    a    reduction       of
    competition), cert. denied, 
    505 U.S. 1206
    , 
    112 S. Ct. 2996
    , 
    120 L. Ed. 2d 872
    (1992).       Thus Dr. Levine's only remaining recourse for
    establishing his section 1 claim is to demonstrate the potential
    for detrimental effects on competition, and to do that he must
    establish that the defendants had sufficient market power to affect
    competition.        Indiana Fed'n of 
    Dentists, 476 U.S. at 460-61
    , 106
    S.Ct. at 2019.
    Dr. Levine maintains, however, that he need not prove the
    defendants' market power, and for that proposition he relies on
    Summit Health, Ltd. v. Pinhas, 
    500 U.S. 322
    , 
    111 S. Ct. 1842
    , 
    114 L. Ed. 2d 366
    (1991), Boczar v. Manatee Hosp. & Health Sys., Inc.,
    
    993 F.2d 1514
       (11th    Cir.),    reh'g     denied,    
    11 F.3d 169
      (11th
    Cir.1993), and Bolt v. Halifax Hosp. Medical Ctr., 
    891 F.2d 810
    (11th Cir.), cert. denied, 
    495 U.S. 924
    , 
    110 S. Ct. 1960
    , 
    109 L. Ed. 2d 322
    (1990).          None of those decisions supports Dr. Levine's
    position.
    The    sole    issue    to    be   decided    in   Pinhas      was    whether    a
    hospital's exclusion of a physician from its medical staff could
    satisfy      the    "effect    on    interstate      commerce"       jurisdictional
    
    requirement. 500 U.S. at 324
    , 111 S.Ct. at 1844.                   Dr. Levine
    quotes the following language from Justice Scalia's dissent in
    Pinhas to support his argument:            "Since group boycotts are per se
    violations     ...    [the    plaintiff]     need    not     prove    an    effect    on
    competition in the Los Angeles area to prevail...."                        
    Id. at 337,
    111 S.Ct. at 1851.       However, this is no more than a restatement of
    the basic analysis under the per se rule.                  Because Dr. Levine has
    already conceded that the per se rule does not apply to his claim
    against the hospital, the language from Justice Scalia's dissent
    does not help him.       Moreover, Dr. Levine ignores Justice Scalia's
    final position in his dissent, which is that the Sherman Act should
    not even apply to the hospital's actions because the hospital
    suspension did not effect interstate commerce.                 
    Id. at 341-43,
    111
    S.Ct. at 1853-54.
    Dr. Levine's reliance on Bolt is no more persuasive.             He
    interprets Bolt to stand for the proposition that, in his words,
    "there was no requirement to prove [market definition or market
    share] when there is evidence of anticompetitive intent."              Dr.
    Levine's interpretation of Bolt misses the point that our focus in
    that opinion was only on the first element of the section 1
    claim—whether    there   was   sufficient   evidence   of    a   contract,
    combination, or conspiracy to submit to the 
    jury. 891 F.2d at 818
    ,
    829.     We held that as to some of the defendants, there was
    sufficient evidence of a conspiracy to go to the jury, and thus
    remanded the case to the district court.      All discussion of intent
    in Bolt was in the context of its value as circumstantial evidence
    of the existence of an agreement.    
    Id. at 819-20.
       As to the second
    element of the section 1 claim in Bolt, we explained that the
    district court had granted a motion for directed verdict "before
    [the plaintiff] reached that part of his case involving restraint
    on competition."    
    Id. at 829.
       We criticized the district court's
    premature ruling and stated that "[t]he better course would have
    been to defer ruling on the motions for directed verdict until
    after [the plaintiff] had presented his entire section 1 case."
    
    Id. at 828.
        If anything, Bolt is inconsistent with Dr. Levine's
    position that he should be relieved of proving market power.
    His reliance on Boczar is equally misplaced.         In Boczar, we
    reviewed the district court's grant of a post-verdict motion for
    judgment as a matter of law in favor of the defendants based on its
    finding that there was insufficient evidence of a conspiracy.          We
    reversed   the    district    court      and   held   that     the    plaintiff    had
    presented sufficient evidence to support the jury's 
    verdict. 993 F.2d at 1519
    .       As to the anticompetitive effect element of the
    plaintiff's      case,   we   simply      observed—without           discussing   the
    evidence that had been presented at trial—that the defendants'
    actions had "effectively ended [the plaintiff's] ability to compete
    and to practice ... and burdened her ability to compete generally."
    
    Id. That was
    nothing more than a fact-specific observation that
    the plaintiff in Boczar had proven anticompetitive effect.                          By
    contrast, the record in this case establishes beyond legitimate
    dispute that Dr. Levine's ability to compete and practice have
    flourished.      Nothing in Boczar supports his position that he need
    not prove the defendants' market power.
    In order to prevail in a rule of reason case, absent a
    demonstrated adverse effect on competition, a plaintiff must define
    the market and prove that the defendants had sufficient market
    power to adversely affect competition.                  See Indiana Fed'n of
    
    Dentists, 476 U.S. at 460-61
    , 106 S.Ct. at 2019.                     Because he has
    offered no evidence defining the relevant product or geographic
    market, and because he has not established ORHS's or Sand Lake
    Hospital's    market     power,    the    district     court    properly    granted
    summary judgment to the defendant on this section 1 claim.
    B. THE SECTION 2 CLAIMS
    In Count 2 of his complaint Dr. Levine claimed that CFMA
    monopolized,      attempted       to     monopolize,     and     conspired        with
    Healthchoice, ORHS, and Sand Lake Hospital to monopolize the market
    for physician medical services to Healthchoice enrollees in the
    Orlando area in violation of section 2 of the Sherman Act.19                         "The
    offense of monopoly under § 2 of the Sherman Act has two elements:
    (1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and (2)
    the   willful      acquisition     or    maintenance        of       that    power    as
    distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a
    superior product, business acumen, or historic accident."                        United
    States v. Grinnell Corp., 
    384 U.S. 563
    , 570-571, 
    86 S. Ct. 1698
    ,
    1704, 
    16 L. Ed. 2d 778
    (1966);            see also T. Harris Young & Assocs.,
    Inc. v. Marquette Elec., Inc., 
    931 F.2d 816
    , 823 (11th Cir.), cert.
    denied, 
    502 U.S. 1013
    , 
    112 S. Ct. 658
    , 
    116 L. Ed. 2d 749
    (1991);
    Austin v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield, 
    903 F.2d 1385
    , 1391 (11th
    Cir.1990).        "Monopoly     power    under    §    2   requires,        of   course,
    something greater than market power under § 1." Eastman 
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 480
    , 112 S.Ct. at 2090.
    To   establish   a   violation    of       section    2    for    attempted
    monopolization, "a plaintiff must show (1) an intent to bring about
    a monopoly and (2) a dangerous probability of success."                          Norton
    Tire Co. v. Tire Kingdom Co., 
    858 F.2d 1533
    , 1535 (11th Cir.1988).
    To have a dangerous probability of successfully monopolizing
    a market the defendant must be close to achieving monopoly
    power.   Monopoly power is "the power to raise prices to
    supra-competitive levels or ... the power to exclude
    competition in the relevant market either by restricting entry
    of new competitors or by driving existing competitors out of
    the market."
    United States Anchor 
    Mfg., 7 F.3d at 994
    (quoting American Key
    19
    Section 2 provides that "[e]very person who shall
    monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with
    any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade
    or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations,
    shall be deemed guilty of a felony." 15 U.S.C.A. § 2 (West
    1973).
    Corp. v. Cole Nat'l Corp., 
    762 F.2d 1569
    , 1581 (11th Cir.1985)).
    A claim for conspiracy to monopolize, on the other hand, does not
    require a showing of monopoly power.        Instead, a plaintiff proves
    a section 2 conspiracy to monopolize by showing:          "(1) concerted
    action deliberately entered into with the specific intent of
    achieving a monopoly;     and (2) the commission of at least one overt
    act in furtherance of the conspiracy."        
    Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1460
    n. 35.
    Although Dr. Levine's complaint is somewhat ambiguous, it
    appears     that   he     is     alleging     all    three       types   of
    claims—monopolization, attempted monopolization, and conspiracy to
    monopolize—only against CFMA.         Healthchoice, ORHS, and Sand Lake
    Hospital are each alleged only to have conspired to monopolize the
    relevant market.   Even assuming that Dr. Levine is alleging that
    all four defendants are liable for all three section 2 claims, the
    defendants are entitled to summary judgment as a matter of law.
    Proof of monopoly power in the relevant market is the first
    element of a monopolization claim, and proof that there is a
    dangerous   probability    of   the   defendant   successfully    attaining
    monopoly power is the second element of an attempted monopolization
    claim.    Dr. Levine's failure to adequately define the relevant
    market, and his failure to prove that the defendants possessed or
    were close to possessing monopoly power in that relevant market,
    are fatal to his section 2 claims for monopolization and for
    attempted monopolization. Moreover, as to his claim for conspiracy
    to monopolize, Dr. Levine has presented no evidence that the
    defendants possessed a specific intent to monopolize, which is the
    first element of a conspiracy to monopolize claim, when they denied
    him   membership   or   when   they   suspended   his   staff   privileges.
    Because Dr. Levine has failed to establish a genuine issue of
    material fact as to necessary elements of these section 2 claims,
    we affirm the district court's grant of summary judgment in favor
    of the defendants as to these claims.20
    IV. CONCLUSION
    The district court's grant of summary judgment in favor of the
    defendants is AFFIRMED.
    20
    We also reject Dr. Levine's argument that the district
    court erroneously granted summary judgment against him on his
    state law antitrust claims. Florida's statute regulating
    combinations in restraint of trade provides: "It is the intent
    of the Legislature that, in construing this chapter, due
    consideration and great weight be given to the interpretations of
    the federal courts relating to comparable federal antitrust
    statutes." Fla.Stat.Ann. § 542.32 (West 1988); see also All
    Care Nursing Serv., Inc. v. Bethesda Memorial Hosp., Inc., 
    887 F.2d 1535
    , 1539 n. 1 (11th Cir.1989) (Tjoflat, J. concurring);
    Ad-Vantage Tel. Directory Consultants, Inc. v. GTE Directories
    Corp., 
    849 F.2d 1336
    , 1340 (11th Cir.1987) ("In applying this
    provision, the Florida courts held that the Florida legislature
    has, in effect, adopted as the law of Florida the body of
    anti-trust law developed by the federal courts under the Sherman
    Act. St. Petersburg Yacht Charters, Inc. v. Morgan Yacht, Inc.,
    
    457 So. 2d 1028
    (Fla.App.1984). Thus, in analyzing this case, we
    may, and indeed must, apply the federal precedent developed under
    Section 2 of the Sherman Act."). Therefore, the district court's
    grant of summary judgment on the state law antitrust claims was
    proper for the same reasons its grant of summary judgment on the
    federal antitrust claims was proper.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 94-3145

Judges: Anderson, Carnes, Owens

Filed Date: 1/23/1996

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 11/5/2024

Authorities (37)

United States v. Trenton Potteries Co. ( 1927 )

White Motor Co. v. United States ( 1963 )

Vernal Forbus Earl J. Beacham Rudolph Caddell Frank R. ... ( 1994 )

pennsylvania-dental-association-delaware-county-dental-society-erie-county ( 1984 )

Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc. ( 1979 )

Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery &... ( 1985 )

Ad-Vantage Telephone Directory Consultants, Inc., Cross v. ... ( 1987 )

dennis-w-austin-individually-and-as-representatives-of-the-plaintiffs ( 1990 )

Richard A. Bolt and Richard A. Bolt, M.D. v. Halifax ... ( 1990 )

U.S. Healthcare, Inc., Etc. v. Healthsource, Inc., Etc. ( 1993 )

norton-tire-company-inc-a-florida-corporation-v-tire-kingdom-company ( 1988 )

m-hisham-tarabishi-md-and-m-hisham-tarabishi-inc-individually-and ( 1991 )

james-p-kartell-md-v-blue-shield-of-massachusetts-inc-james-p ( 1984 )

Summit Health, Ltd. v. Pinhas ( 1991 )

Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc. ( 1992 )

linda-m-boczar-md-and-obstetricsgynecology-womens-group-inc-v ( 1993 )

gilbert-bathke-valoris-bathke-ronald-condon-lanina-condon-panora-oil ( 1995 )

us-anchor-mfg-inc-counterclaim-v-rule-industries-inc ( 1993 )

consultants-designers-inc-cross-appellees-v-butler-service-group ( 1983 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Indiana Federation of Dentists ( 1986 )

View All Authorities »