1-800-Contacts, Inc. v. Federal Trade Comission ( 2021 )


Menu:
  • 18-3848
    1-800-Contacts, Inc. v. Federal Trade Comission
    In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    for the
    Second Circuit
    August Term, 2019
    Argued: March 5, 2020
    Decided: June 11, 2021
    Docket No. 18-3848
    1-800 CONTACTS, INC.,
    Petitioner,
    v.
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
    Respondent.
    ON PETITION FOR REVIEW OF AN ORDER OF THE
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION (DOCKET NO. 9372)
    Before:              LYNCH and MENASHI, Circuit Judges.*
    * Judge Peter W. Hall, originally a member of the panel, died on March 11, 2021. The two
    remaining members of the panel, who are in agreement, have determined the matter. See 
    28 U.S.C. § 46
    (d); 2d Cir. IOP E(b); United States v. Desimone, 
    140 F.3d 457
    , 458-59 (2d Cir. 1998).
    1-800 Contacts, Inc., petitions from a Final Order of the Federal Trade Commission
    (FTC) finding that agreements between Petitioner 1-800 Contacts, Inc. and various
    competitors to, among other things, refrain from bidding on “keyword” search
    terms for internet advertisements, violate Section 5 of the FTC Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 45
    .
    We hold that although trademark settlement agreements are not immune from
    antitrust scrutiny, the FTC (1) improperly considered the agreements to be
    “inherently suspect” and (2) incorrectly concluded that the challenged agreements
    are a violation of the FTC Act under the “rule of reason.”
    PETITION FOR REVIEW GRANTED, FINAL ORDER VACATED AND REMANDED.
    STEPHEN FISHBEIN, Shearman & Sterling
    LLP, New York, NY (Ryan A. Shores, Todd
    M. Stenerson, Brian C. Hauser, Shearman &
    Sterling LLP, Washington, D.C., on the brief)
    for Petitioner.
    IMAD ABYAD, Federal Trade Commission
    (Gail F. Levine, Deputy Director, Geoffrey
    M. Green, Assistant Director, Joel Marcus,
    Deputy General Counsel, Barbara Blank,
    Daniel J. Matheson, Mariel Goetz,
    Attorneys, on the brief), for Alden F. Abbott,
    General     Counsel,         Federal     Trade
    Commission,      Washington,       D.C.,    for
    Respondent.
    Corbin K. Barthold and Cory L. Andrews,
    Washington          Legal        Foundation,
    Washington, D.C. for Amici Curiae Richard A.
    Epstein, Keith N. Hylton, Thomas A. Lambert,
    Geoffrey A. Manne, Hal Singer and Washington
    Legal Foundation in Support of Petitioner.
    2
    Theodore H. Davis Jr., Kilpatrick Townsend
    & Stockton LLP, Atlanta, GA and Sheldon
    H. Klein, President, American Intellectual
    Property Law Association, Arlington, VA,
    for Amicus Curiae American Intellectual
    Property Law Association in Support of
    Petitioner.
    Bryan D. Gant, Seiji Niwa, White & Case
    LLP, New York, NY and Eileen M. Cole,
    White & Case LLP, Washington, D.C., for
    Amici Curiae United States Council for
    International Business in Support of Petitioner.
    Mark A. Lemley, William H. Neukom
    Professor, Stanford Law School, Stanford,
    CA for Amici Curiae Intellectual Property,
    Internet Law and Antitrust Professors in
    Support of Respondent.
    PER CURIAM:
    Between 2004 and 2013, Petitioner 1-800 Contacts, Inc. (“1-800”) entered into
    thirteen trademark settlement agreements and one sourcing and services
    agreement with competitors (the “Challenged Agreements”).             As explained
    below, the Challenged Agreements contained provisions restricting specific terms
    on which the parties could “bid” when participating in auctions held by
    companies that operate search engines. By restricting bidding on terms in these
    auctions, the competitors agreed not to advertise their products when consumers
    3
    used the search engines’ platforms to search the specific terms at issue. In August
    2016, the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC” or the “Commission”) issued an
    administrative complaint against Petitioner, alleging that the Challenged
    Agreements and Petitioner’s enforcement of the agreements unreasonably restrain
    truthful, non-misleading advertising as well as price competition in search
    advertising auctions in violation of Section 5 of the FTC Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 45
    . The
    claim was tried before an Administrative Law Judge (ALJ), who in 2017 issued an
    Initial Decision and Order finding that the agreements violate Section 5.
    Petitioner then appealed to the full Commission, which affirmed the ALJ’s
    conclusion in a three to one decision, with one Commissioner not participating.
    This timely petition for review followed the issuance of the Commission’s Final
    Order.
    Although we hold that trademark settlement agreements are not
    automatically immune from antitrust scrutiny, the Commission’s analysis of the
    alleged restraints under the “inherently suspect” framework was improper. We
    further hold that the Commission incorrectly concluded that the agreements are
    an unfair method of competition under the FTC Act. We therefore GRANT the
    4
    petition for review, VACATE the Final Order of the Commission, and REMAND
    the case to the Commission with orders to DISMISS the administrative complaint.
    BACKGROUND
    Contact lenses, prescription eyewear designed to improve the user’s vision,
    can be sold only pursuant to a prescription. Such prescriptions specify both the
    characteristics of the lens, such as its strength, and the manufacturer brand.
    Thus, when consumers purchase contact lenses, they may not substitute one brand
    for another, but must purchase the brand listed on the prescription.         Contact
    lenses are sold by four different types of retailers: independent eye care
    professionals; optical retail chains; mass merchants and club stores; and purely
    internet-based retailers, such as Petitioner. Internet-based retailers accounted for
    17 percent of all contact lens sales in 2015, the year before these proceedings began.
    1-800 accounts for a majority of all online sales of contact lenses. The price of
    contact lenses varies significantly based on retail channel; independent eye care
    professionals typically charge the most, followed by retail chains, mass merchants,
    and then online retailers. Petitioner, however, admits that it charges more than
    its rival online retailers.   It prices its lenses somewhere below independent
    professionals and retail chains but above mass merchants and other club stores.
    5
    Petitioner and its competitors pay to advertise their sales of contact lenses
    on the internet.     One way they do this is via “search advertising.”      When an
    online shopper uses a search engine such as Google or Bing, the search engine’s
    program returns two types of results to the shopper: “sponsored” and “organic,”
    both of which provide links to web pages. Sponsored results are ads; they appear
    because the owner of the featured web page has paid for its page to appear in that
    space.      Sponsored links are typically designated by a label like “Ad” or
    “Sponsored,” and by colored or shaded boxes around the link. Organic results,
    on the other hand, appear based exclusively on which results a search engine’s
    algorithm deems to be most relevant to the shopper’s search. Organic results are
    listed separately from the sponsored results.
    Search engines determine which advertisements to display on a search
    results page based in part on the relevance or relation of the consumer’s search to
    various words or phrases called “keywords.” Advertisers bid on these keywords
    during auctions hosted by the search engines.          The highest bidders’ ads are
    typically displayed most prominently on a page, though search engines consider
    other factors when determining where to place an ad on a results page, such as an
    ad’s quality and relevance to a consumer’s search. Search engines generally do
    6
    not limit the keywords available to advertisers at auction.          As a result,
    competitors often bid on each other’s brand names so that their ad runs when a
    consumer searches for a competitor. Brand name terms are often trademarked.
    Via bidding on “negative keywords,” an advertiser may also prevent its ad
    from being displayed when a consumer searches for a particular keyword. These
    negative keywords preclude ads from being displayed even when the search
    engine independently determined that the ad would be relevant to the consumer.
    The Commission suggests that this is useful when, for example, a retailer selling
    eyeglasses has bid on the advertising keyword “glasses” but wants to prevent its
    ad from appearing in response to the term “wine glasses.”
    Many online retailers of contact lenses devote the majority of their
    advertising budgets to search advertising. The Commission found that these ads
    are presented to consumers “at a time when [they are] more likely looking to buy.”
    JA 279. Unlike its online retail competitors, Petitioner also uses other methods of
    advertising, including printed materials, radio, and television.    Online search
    advertising, however, still represents a large portion of Petitioner’s advertising
    budget.   Because Petitioner charges more than other online retailers, when its
    7
    competitors’ ads appear in response to a search for 1-800’s trademark terms,
    Petitioner’s sales tend to decrease.
    In 2002, Petitioner began filing complaints and sending cease-and-desist
    letters to its competitors alleging trademark infringement related to its
    competitors’ online advertisements. 1 Between 2004 and 2013, Petitioner entered
    into thirteen settlement agreements to resolve most of these disputes. Each of
    these agreements includes language that prohibits the parties from using each
    other’s trademarks, URLs, and variations of trademarks as search advertising
    keywords. The agreements also require the parties to employ negative keywords
    so that a search including one party’s trademarks will not trigger a display of the
    other party’s ads.         The agreements do not prohibit parties from bidding on
    generic keywords such as “contacts” or “contact lenses.” 2 Petitioner enforced the
    agreements when it perceived them to be breached.
    1   Some of these trademark infringement allegations did not involve search advertising.
    2 Advertisers may designate how closely the keyword they bid on must match the consumer’s
    search in order for their ads to be displayed. For example, Google, the leading search engine in
    the United States, offers different options for advertisers on its paid search platform. An
    advertiser may designate the keyword on which they have bid as “broad match,” “phrase match,”
    “exact match,” or, as mentioned, “negative match.” An ad tied to a keyword designated as
    “broad match” may appear when a consumer’s search on Google contains the specific keyword,
    any plural forms or synonyms of the keyword, or phrases similar to the keyword. An advertiser
    selecting “phrase match” will have its ad appear when a search contains additional words along
    with the keyword. An “exact match” limits the ad’s appearance to when the consumer searches
    8
    Apart from the settlement agreements, in 2013 Petitioner entered into a
    “sourcing and services agreement” with Luxottica, a company that sells and
    distributes contacts through its affiliates. JA 283. That agreement also contains
    reciprocal online search advertising restrictions prohibiting the use of trademark
    keywords and requiring both parties to employ negative keywords.
    The FTC issued an administrative complaint against Petitioner in August
    2016 alleging that the thirteen settlement agreements and the Luxottica agreement
    (the “Challenged Agreements”), along with subsequent actions to enforce them,
    unreasonably restrain truthful, non-misleading advertising as well as price
    competition in search advertising auctions, all of which constitute a violation of
    Section 5 of the FTC Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 45
    . 3               The complaint alleges that the
    Challenged Agreements prevented Petitioner’s competitors from disseminating
    ads that would have informed consumers that the same contact lenses were
    available at a cheaper price from other online retailers, thereby reducing
    the exact keyword. “Negative keywords” can also be designated by an advertiser for broad,
    phrase, or exact match. The Challenged Agreements do not specify whether the negative
    keywords must be employed using broad, phrase, or exact match.
    3Section 5 of the FTC Act states that “[u]nfair methods of competition in or affecting commerce,
    and unfair or deceptive acts or practices in or affecting commerce, are hereby declared unlawful.”
    
    15 U.S.C. § 45
    (a)(1).
    9
    competition and making it more difficult for consumers to compare online retail
    prices. The case was tried before an ALJ, who concluded that a violation had
    occurred.
    As an initial matter, the ALJ rejected Petitioner’s assertion that trademark
    settlement agreements are not subject to antitrust scrutiny in light of FTC v. Actavis,
    
    570 U.S. 136
     (2013). Applying the “rule of reason” and principles of Section 1 of
    the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    , the ALJ determined that “[o]nline sales of contact
    lenses constitute a relevant product market.” JA 120.            He found that the
    agreements constituted a “contract, combination, or conspiracy” as required by
    the Sherman Act and held that the advertising restrictions in the agreements
    harmed consumers by reducing the availability of information, in turn making it
    costlier for consumers to find and compare contact lens prices. JA 184, 221-22.
    Having found actual anticompetitive effects, as required under the rule of
    reason analysis, the ALJ rejected the procompetitive justifications for the
    agreements offered by Petitioner. He found that while trademark protection is
    procompetitive, it did not justify the advertising restrictions in the agreements and
    also that Petitioner failed to show that reduced litigation costs would benefit
    consumers.    The ALJ issued an order that barred Petitioner from entering into an
    10
    agreement with any marketer or seller of contact lenses to limit participation in
    search advertising auctions or to prohibit or limit search advertising.
    1-800 appealed the ALJ’s order to the Commission. In a split decision, a
    majority of the Commission agreed with the ALJ that the agreements violated
    Section 5 of the FTC Act.      The majority, however, analyzed the settlement
    agreements differently from the ALJ. The majority classified the agreements as
    “inherently suspect” and alternatively found “direct evidence” of anticompetitive
    effects on consumers and search engines.         The majority then analyzed the
    procompetitive justifications Petitioner offered for the agreements and rejected
    arguments that the benefits of protecting trademarks and reducing litigation costs
    outweighed any potential harm to consumers.        Finally, the majority identified
    what it believed to be less anticompetitive alternatives to the advertising
    restrictions in the agreements. One Commissioner dissented, reasoning both that
    the majority should not have applied the “inherently suspect” framework and that
    it failed to give appropriate consideration to Petitioner’s proffered procompetitive
    justifications. This timely appeal followed.
    11
    JURISDICTION AND STANDARD OF REVIEW
    We have jurisdiction over this appeal under 
    15 U.S.C. § 45
    (c). The majority
    opinion of the Commission “adopt[ed] the ALJ’s findings of fact to the extent that
    they [were] not inconsistent” with its opinion. JA 285. Factual findings of the
    Commission are binding “if they are supported by such relevant evidence as a
    reasonable mind might accept as adequate to support a conclusion.” FTC v. Ind.
    Fed’n of Dentists (IFD), 
    476 U.S. 447
    , 454 (1986) (internal quotation marks and
    citation omitted).    The Commission’s legal conclusions are “for the courts to
    resolve, although even in considering such issues the courts are to give some
    deference to the Commission’s informed judgment that a particular commercial
    practice is to be condemned as ‘unfair.’” 
    Id.
    DISCUSSION
    I.      Actavis Considerations
    Petitioner argues, as it did below, that trademark litigation settlements are
    generally immune from antitrust review. It contends that in Actavis, the Supreme
    Court “cabin[ed] its extension of antitrust scrutiny” to the “unusual” intellectual
    property settlements at issue there and did not intend to implicate “commonplace”
    12
    settlements. Petitioner’s Br. 43. Neither the ALJ nor any participating member
    of the Commission found this argument persuasive. 4 Nor do we.
    In Actavis, the Supreme Court analyzed what are known as “reverse
    payment” patent settlements. 570 U.S. at 141. In short, manufacturers of brand
    name drugs paid manufacturers of generic drugs to keep the generic
    manufacturers from litigating the validity of the brand name manufacturers’
    patents. See id. at 145. This effectively allowed the brand name manufacturers
    to maintain exclusive sales of certain drugs for longer than they would have if the
    applicable patent, through litigation, was found to be invalid. Id. at 153-54. In
    Actavis, the Court rejected the idea that the conduct at issue was immune from
    antitrust scrutiny just because it occurred within the context of a patent litigation
    settlement. Id. at 146-48. The Court explained that “it would be incongruous to
    determine antitrust legality by measuring the settlement’s anticompetitive effects
    solely against patent law policy, rather than by measuring them against
    procompetitive antitrust policies as well.”       Id. at 148.
    4 All four participating Commissioners agreed that Actavis does not immunize trademark
    settlement agreements from antitrust scrutiny. Commissioner Wilson did not participate in the
    appeal to the Commission.
    13
    Petitioner argues that Actavis represents an exception to the general rule
    against subjecting intellectual property (IP) settlement agreements to antitrust
    scrutiny because patents, unlike trademarks, for example, are inherently
    exclusionary and because the reverse payment scheme at issue in Actavis was
    “unusual.”    Petitioner’s Br. 43 (citing Actavis, 570 U.S. at 147).     To be sure, in
    Actavis the Court detailed how certain commonplace forms of settlement
    agreements did not, by the nature of their existence alone, create antitrust liability.
    570 U.S. at 151-52. Contrary to Petitioner’s claim, however, the Court went on to
    say that the possibility that agreements may not always bring about
    anticompetitive consequences “does not justify dismissing the FTC’s complaint.
    An antitrust defendant may show in the antitrust proceeding that legitimate
    justifications are present[.]” Actavis, 570 U.S. at 156.
    As in Actavis, Petitioner’s trademark, “if valid and infringed, might have
    permitted it to” preclude competitors from bidding on its trademarked terms in
    search advertising auctions or running advertisements on those terms. Id. at 147.
    We “take this fact as evidence that the agreement’s anticompetitive effects fall
    within the scope of” the trademark protections.            Id. (internal quotation marks
    omitted). But the mere fact that an agreement implicates intellectual property
    14
    rights does not “immunize [an] agreement from antitrust attack.” Id.; see also In
    re Indep. Serv. Orgs. Antitrust Litig., 
    203 F.3d 1322
    , 1325 (Fed. Cir. 2000)
    (“Intellectual property rights do not confer a privilege to violate the antitrust
    laws.”); United States v. Microsoft Corp., 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 63 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (same). We
    have not shied away from considering antitrust claims that implicate trademark
    rights in the past, see, e.g., Clorox Co. v. Sterling Winthrop, Inc., 
    117 F.3d 50
    , 55-56 (2d
    Cir. 1997), and we decline to do so now.           As in any antitrust case, we must
    “determine whether the restraints in the agreement[s] are reasonable in light of
    their actual effects on the market and their pro-competitive justifications.” 
    Id. at 56
    .
    II.     Sherman Act Framework
    Because “[t]he FTC Act's prohibition of unfair competition and deceptive
    acts or practices . . . overlaps the scope of § 1 of the Sherman Act . . . aimed at
    prohibiting restraint of trade,” California Dental Ass'n v. FTC (Cal. Dental), 
    526 U.S. 756
    , 762 n. 3 (1999), it was appropriate that the ALJ and the Commission consulted
    Sherman Act jurisprudence to determine whether the Challenged Agreements
    violated Section 5 of the FTC Act. See Realcomp II, Ltd. v. FTC, 
    635 F.3d 815
    , 824
    (6th Cir. 2011); North Carolina Bd. of Dental Examiners v. FTC, 
    717 F.3d 359
    , 370-71
    15
    (4th Cir. 2013) (recognizing a Section 1 violation as a “species” of unfair
    competition prohibited under the FTC Act).
    To prove a Sherman Act violation – and by extension, a Section 5 violation
    – the FTC must establish (1) a contract, combination, or conspiracy exists that
    (2) unreasonably restrains trade. See Major League Baseball Props., Inc. v. Salvino,
    Inc. (MLB), 
    542 F.3d 290
    , 315-16 (2d Cir. 2008).       In this case, the Challenged
    Agreements are undeniably contracts between Petitioner and its competitors.
    We “presumptively appl[y]” what is known as the “rule of reason” analysis to the
    Challenged Agreements to determine whether they restrain trade. Texaco Inc. v.
    Dagher, 
    547 U.S. 1
    , 5 (2006).    Under that analysis an antitrust plaintiff “must
    demonstrate that a particular contract or combination is in fact unreasonable and
    anticompetitive before it will be found unlawful.”         
    Id.
       As Justice Brandeis
    famously articulated:
    The true test of legality is whether the restraint imposed is such as
    merely regulates and perhaps thereby promotes competition or
    whether it is such as may suppress or even destroy competition. To
    determine that question the court must ordinarily consider the facts
    peculiar to the business to which the restraint is applied; its condition
    before and after the restraint was imposed; the nature of the restraint
    and its effect, actual or probable. The history of the restraint, the evil
    believed to exist, the reason for adopting the particular remedy, the
    purpose or end sought to be attained, are all relevant facts. This is
    not because a good intention will save an otherwise objectionable
    16
    regulation or the reverse; but because knowledge of intent may help
    the court to interpret facts and to predict consequences.
    Chicago Board of Trade v. United States, 
    246 U.S. 231
    , 238 (1918). A plaintiff bears
    the initial burden of showing that the challenged action has had an actual adverse
    effect on competition as a whole in the relevant market. North Am. Soccer League,
    LLC v. U.S. Soccer Fed’n, Inc., 
    883 F.3d 32
    , 42 (2d Cir. 2018). After a prima facie
    case of anticompetitive conduct has been established, the burden shifts to the
    defendant to proffer procompetitive justifications for the agreement.              
    Id.
    “Assuming defendants can provide such proof, the burden shifts back to the
    plaintiffs to prove that any legitimate competitive benefits offered by defendants
    could have been achieved through less restrictive means.” Geneva Pharm. Tech.
    Corp. v. Barr Labs. Inc., 
    386 F.3d 485
    , 507 (2d Cir. 2004).
    In some cases, however, “certain agreements or practices which because of
    their pernicious effect on competition and lack of any redeeming virtue are
    conclusively presumed to be unreasonable and therefore illegal without elaborate
    inquiry as to the precise harm they have caused or the business excuse for their
    use.” Northern Pacific Ry. Co. v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5 (1958). Such agreements
    are deemed per se illegal. See MLB, 
    542 F.3d at 315
    . This designation is saved for
    certain types of restraints, e.g., geographic division of markets or horizontal price
    17
    fixing, that have been established over time to “lack . . . any redeeming virtue.”
    
    Id.
    The Supreme Court, however, has rejected fixed categories of analysis when
    considering the anticompetitive nature of a restraint. See Cal. Dental, 
    526 U.S. at 779
    . Some restraints, therefore, fall between the type of conduct typically labeled
    per se anticompetitive and that which is analyzed under a “full-blown” rule of
    reason analysis.       MLB, 
    542 F.3d at 317
    .             When “the great likelihood of
    anticompetitive effects can easily be ascertained[,]” courts apply an abbreviated
    rule of reason analysis sometimes known as the “quick-look” approach.                          Cal.
    Dental, 
    526 U.S. at 770
    .      The Commission calls the standard it applies in these
    situations the “inherently suspect” framework. 5           JA 291.
    Under the Commission’s “inherently suspect” framework, neither direct
    evidence of harm nor proof of market power is needed to show the anticompetitive
    effect of the restraint because the “likely tendency to suppress competition” posed
    by the challenged conduct makes it “inherently suspect.” Polygram Holding, Inc.,
    
    136 F.T.C. 310
    , 344-45 (2003), aff’d, 
    416 F.3d 29
     (D.C. Cir. 2005). An “elaborate
    5The “quick-look” and “inherently suspect” approaches are similar, and Petitioner does not
    take issue with the interchangeability of the two formulations of this abbreviated analysis.
    18
    market analysis” is unnecessary, Polygram, 
    416 F.3d at 35
    , and once the
    government has identified a “suspect” agreement, the burden shifts directly to the
    defendant to show any procompetitive justifications it might have for the restraint.
    See United States v. Apple, 
    791 F.3d 290
    , 330 (2d Cir. 2015).
    This approach is only permissible when “an observer with even a
    rudimentary understanding of economics could conclude that the arrangements
    in question would have an anticompetitive effect on customers and markets.”
    Cal. Dental, 
    526 U.S. at 770
    ; see also Dagher, 
    547 U.S. at
    7 n.3 (rejecting a quick-look
    analysis because it applies only “to business activities that are so plainly
    anticompetitive that courts need undertake only a cursory examination before
    imposing antitrust liability”); Polygram, 
    416 F.3d at 37
     (explaining that the
    inherently suspect framework is only applicable when “close family resemblance
    [exists] between the suspect practice and another practice that already stands
    convicted in the court of consumer welfare”).
    Further, “[i]f an arrangement ‘might plausibly be thought to have a net
    procompetitive effect, or possibly no effect at all on competition,’ more than a
    ‘quick look’ is required.” MLB, 
    542 F.3d at 318
     (quoting Cal. Dental, 
    526 U.S. at 771
    ). In California Dental, the Supreme Court considered the California Dental
    19
    Association’s rule prohibiting price advertising, specifically discounted fees, and
    advertising relating to the quality of dental services. 
    526 U.S. at 761
    . There, the
    Court rejected the use of an abbreviated rule of reason analysis, holding that the
    existence of a plausible procompetitive justification – in that case, the prohibition
    of deceptive advertising in an asymmetrical information marketplace – effectively
    foreclosed the ability of courts to utilize the quick look approach. See 
    id. at 771
    .
    Here, the Commission viewed the advertising restrictions in the Challenged
    Agreements as inherently suspect; it also found that the agreements were a form
    of “bid rigging” that harmed search engines – i.e., an independent basis upon
    which it could apply the inherently suspect analytical framework. Petitioner and
    amici argue that the application of the inherently suspect framework was improper
    and that the Challenged Agreements should only be considered under a rule of
    reason analysis.    We agree with Petitioner that the Challenged Agreements
    cannot be classified as inherently suspect.
    Citing expert reports and economic theory, the government argues that the
    Commission was correct to employ the inherently suspect framework because
    restrictions on advertising are likely to cause consumers to pay more for contact
    lenses.   But even if restraints on truthful advertising have a tendency to raise
    20
    prices, “[t]he fact that a practice may have a tangential relationship to the price of
    the commodity in question does not mean that a court should dispense with a full
    rule-of-reason analysis.” MLB, 
    542 F.3d at 317
    .
    Crucially, the restraints at issue here could plausibly be thought to have a
    net procompetitive effect because they are derived from trademark settlement
    agreements.    In Clorox, applying the rule of reason, we considered whether a
    trademark settlement agreement illegally restrained trade under the Sherman Act
    and we explained that “[t]rademarks are by their nature non-exclusionary.” 
    117 F.3d at 55-56
    . Agreements to protect trademarks, then, should not immediately
    be assumed to be anticompetitive – in fact, Clorox tells us instead to presume they
    are procompetitive. 
    Id. at 60
    . As the Challenged Agreements restrict the parties
    from running advertisements on Petitioner’s trademarked terms, they directly
    implicate trademark policy.
    The Commission acknowledged as much, finding Petitioner’s proffered
    procompetitive justifications to be “cognizable and, at least, facially plausible[.]”
    JA 296. Rather than take that fact as an indication that it should not apply an
    abbreviated rule of reason analysis, as the Supreme Court instructed in California
    Dental, the Commission instead set out to show (i) that there was a theoretical basis
    21
    for the alleged anticompetitive effect and that the restraints were likely, in this
    particular context, to harm competition and (ii) that Petitioner could have
    minimized the anticompetitive effects and accomplished its procompetitive
    justifications through less restrictive means.                While this may be analytically
    acceptable in some situations, see Cal. Dental, 
    526 U.S. at 779
     (noting to require a
    “more extended examination” does not always translate to a call for “plenary
    market examination”), it was not appropriate here.
    Courts do not have sufficient experience with this type of conduct to permit
    the abbreviated analysis of the Challenged Agreements undertaken by the
    Commission.         See Cal. Dental, 
    526 U.S. at 781
     (explaining that the quick-look
    approach may be applicable if rule-of-reason analyses in case after case reach
    identical conclusions); Polygram, 
    416 F.3d at 36-37
     (accepting the Commission’s
    definition of “inherently suspect” as describing restraints previously condemned
    by both “judicial experience and economic learning”).                       While both California
    Dental and Polygram consider advertising restraints, there are key differences
    between the restraints in those cases and the restraints here, 6 and our own
    6In California Dental, as an initial matter, the court rejected the use of an abbreviated rule of reason
    analysis for restraints on price and quality advertising. 
    526 U.S. at 781
    . And in Polygram, the
    fact that the challenged conduct also restricted the parties from offering discounts on concert
    22
    precedent suggests that trademark agreements like those at issue here need to be
    examined using a fuller analysis. See Clorox, 
    117 F.3d at 55-56, 59
     (applying a rule
    of reason analysis and rejecting the alleged anticompetitive harm of a trademark
    agreement); see also Actavis, 570 U.S. at 158-59 (rejecting the application of a quick-
    look analysis for intellectual property agreements). When, as here, not only are
    there cognizable procompetitive justifications but also the type of restraint has not
    been widely condemned in our “judicial experience,” see Polygram, 
    416 F.3d at 37
    ,
    more is required. Cf. Bogan v. Hodgkins, 
    166 F.3d 509
    , 514 n.6 (2d Cir. 1999) (noting
    pre-California Dental that “[u]nder quick look, once the defendant has shown a
    procompetitive justification for the conduct, the court must proceed to weigh the
    overall reasonableness of the restraint using a full-scale rule of reason analysis”
    (internal quotation marks and citation omitted)). The Challenged Agreements,
    therefore, are not so obviously anticompetitive to consumers that someone with
    only a basic understanding of economics would immediately recognize them to be
    albums was key to the D.C. Circuit’s affirmation of the inherently suspect analysis; the court
    thought that the agreement looked “suspiciously like a naked price fixing agreement between
    competitors[.]” See Polygram, 
    416 F.3d at 37
    .
    23
    so. 7 See Cal. Dental, 
    526 U.S. at 770
    . We are bound, then, to apply the rule of
    reason. 8
    III.    Application of the Rule of Reason
    Under the rule of reason, the Commission bears the burden of establishing
    a prima facie case of anticompetitive effect. Direct evidence of anticompetitive
    effects establishes a prima facie case of a Sherman Act Section 1 violation and
    obviates the need for a detailed market analysis or showing of market power. 9
    7 We do not discount the economic evidence cited by the Commission in coming to its conclusion,
    but the fact that it required the testimony of expert witnesses who provided empirical analyses
    in order to determine the net competitive effect of the Challenged Agreements underscores the
    point: these restraints are not obviously anticompetitive to someone with only a rudimentary
    understanding of economics. See MLB, 
    542 F.3d at 340, n.10
     (Sotomayor, J., concurring).
    8 We also reject the Commission and amici’s arguments that the restrictions constitute illegal bid
    rigging as support for their use of the inherently suspect framework. An absolute ban on
    competitive bidding, or bid rigging, would be anticompetitive on its face and may justify an
    abbreviated rule of reason analysis. Cal. Dental, 570 U.S. at 770 (citing Nat'l Soc'y of Prof'l Eng'rs
    v. FTC, 
    435 U.S. 679
    , 692-93 (1978)); see also United States v. Joyce, 
    895 F.3d 673
    , 679 (9th Cir. 2018)
    (finding bid rigging to be per se illegal). It is not clear to us, however, that the restrictions
    constitute such a ban. The Challenged Agreements do not prevent the parties from participating
    in keyword auctions, only from bidding on trademarked terms. Whether restrictions on
    advertisers’ use of particular terms leads to overall harm to the search engines is not obvious and
    therefore does not justify analyzing the agreements under the inherently suspect framework.
    Nor, as amici in support of the government argue, is it obvious that the restrictions constitute
    market division, another type of restraint that would justify an abbreviated analysis. See Palmer
    v. BRG of Georgia, Inc., 
    498 U.S. 46
     (1990) (per curiam).
    9  Though the government argued to the ALJ that the parties to the Challenged Agreements
    collectively have market power in the relevant market and that the nature of the restraints makes
    it likely that the Challenged Agreements will have an anticompetitive effect, the ALJ chose not to
    determine the prima facie case under that theory, nor did the Commission on appeal.
    24
    See IFD, 
    476 U.S. at 460
    . The Commission contends that it satisfied its burden by
    adducing evidence of increased contact lens prices and a reduction in the quantity
    of advertisements.
    A. Anticompetitive Effects
    Anticompetitive effects in a relevant market may be shown through direct
    evidence of output reductions, increased prices, or reduced quality in the relevant
    market. Ohio v. Am Express Co. (Am. Express), 
    138 S. Ct. 2274
    , 2284 (2018); see also
    North Am. Soccer League, 883 F.3d at 42.      The Commission has also defined
    sufficient evidence of anticompetitive harm to include evidence of “retarded
    innovation, or other manifestations of harm to consumer welfare.” In re Realcomp
    II Ltd., No. 9320, 
    2007 WL 6936319
     (F.T.C. Oct. 30, 2009), aff’d 
    635 F.3d 815
    . We
    reject the Commission’s argument that it has established direct evidence of
    anticompetitive effect in the form of increased prices. When an antitrust plaintiff
    advances an antitrust claim based on direct evidence in the form of increased
    prices, the question is whether it can show an actual anticompetitive change in
    prices after the restraint was implemented.      See Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown &
    Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 236-37 (1993); MacDermid, 833 F.3d at 184.
    The government could not make that showing because it did not conduct an
    25
    empirical analysis of the Challenged Agreements’ effect on the price of contact
    lenses in the online market for contacts. The evidence offered by the government
    is theoretical and anecdotal; 10 it is not “direct.” Consequently, the Commission’s
    conclusion that differences between 1-800 Contacts’ prices and those of its
    competitors constitute direct evidence of the Challenged Agreements’
    anticompetitive effects is not supported by substantial evidence. 11
    10The government argues, inter alia, that (a) Petitioner admits that it charges more than their
    competitors in the relevant market; (b) economic theory strongly suggests that advertising
    restrictions tend to increase prices of any given product; and (c) Petitioner offered to meet or beat
    any price offered by other online retailers. Even accepting all this as true, it is not direct evidence
    that the Challenged Agreements caused the price of contact lenses in the relevant market to rise,
    as our precedent requires. MacDermid, 833 F.3d at 184.
    11 A slightly different issue plagues the government’s argument that there is direct evidence of
    reduced revenues for search engines. To show this, the government did not show that Google
    or Microsoft, the companies who control the two most popular search engines, had lower
    revenues after the Challenged Agreements were put into place. Nor did the government
    introduce evidence that Petitioner spent less money on search advertising than it did before the
    Challenged Agreements came into effect. Instead, the government offered empirical evidence
    that the Challenged Agreements reduced the price paid by Petitioner for each click on one of its
    keywords. JA 1096-99. Empirical evidence is, as noted, required under our caselaw to find
    direct evidence of an anticompetitive effect. K.M.B., 61 F.3d at 127. But showing that a price
    for certain keywords dropped is not direct evidence of the effect on the market as a whole. See
    Clorox, 
    117 F.3d at 56
     (quoting K.M.B., 61 F.3d at 127). This snapshot shows only that Petitioner
    paid less for certain keyword advertisements, no more and no less.
    While it is true that, when evaluating “whether horizontal restraints had an adverse effect on
    competition,” we do not always “need to precisely define the relevant market to conclude that
    these agreements were anticompetitive,” Am. Express, 
    138 S.Ct. at
    2285 n.7, more was needed
    under our precedent if the Commission wished to show “direct” evidence in the market as a
    whole. See Clorox, 
    117 F.3d at 56
    . The “product” offered by search engines of which the
    Challenged Agreements allegedly restrain trade is, presumably, advertisers’ use of keywords, but
    that is not clear from the record. For the same reason, we also cannot say that the Commission’s
    26
    The government also argues that “disrupted information flow” is an
    anticompetitive effect and that a reduction in the quantity of advertisements is
    direct evidence of that effect. Respondent’s Br. 63. While, to our knowledge, no
    Court of Appeals has held that a reduction of truthful information is necessarily a
    manifestation of anticompetitive harm, our sister circuits have occasionally
    considered advertising restraints in different contexts and have found the conduct
    in question to have anticompetitive effects. See, e.g., California Dental Ass’n v. FTC
    (Cal. Dental II), 
    224 F.3d 942
    , 949 (9th Cir. 2000) (considering professional
    advertising restraints in an asymmetrical information marketplace); Polygram, 
    416 F.3d at 37
     (holding that the FTC appropriately concluded an agreement to restrain
    price cutting and advertising violated the FTC Act); Realcomp II, 
    635 F.3d at
    831-
    32, 832 n.9 (denying petition for review when petitioner’s policy limited access to
    internet marketing); Blackburn v. Sweeney, 
    53 F.3d 825
    , 827-29 (7th Cir. 1995)
    (identifying an agreement not to advertise in certain geographic areas as a per se
    illegal attempt to allocate markets).           We need not decide whether the
    Commission’s theory of harm is viable, however, because we conclude that
    conclusion that the Challenged Agreements harmed search engines by reducing quality in the
    market was supported by substantial evidence.
    27
    Petitioner has shown a procompetitive justification and the Commission fails to
    carry its burden at the third step.
    B. Procompetitive Justifications
    Petitioner asserts that the Challenged Agreements are justified by two
    procompetitive effects: reduced litigation costs and protecting Petitioner’s
    trademark rights. The Commission found that, while both of these justifications
    were “cognizable and facially plausible,” Petitioner did not show that they “have
    a basis in fact,” and therefore they were not “valid.” JA 309. We disagree. The
    protection of Petitioner’s trademark interests constitutes a valid procompetitive
    justification for the Challenged Agreements.
    The Commission determined that, since “the [Challenged Agreements]
    restrict a type of competitive advertising that has never been found to violate the
    trademark laws, and the weight of authority overwhelmingly points to non-
    infringement[,]” trademark protection was not a valid procompetitive benefit that
    justified the Challenged Agreements. JA 313. This was incorrect. Trademarks
    are by their nature non-exclusionary, and agreements to protect trademark
    interests are “common, and favored, under the law.” Clorox, 
    117 F.3d at 55
    . As
    a result, “it is difficult to show that an unfavorable trademark agreement creates
    28
    antitrust concerns.” 
    Id. at 57
    . This is true even though trademark agreements
    inherently prevent competitors “from competing as effectively as [they] otherwise
    might[.]” 
    Id. at 59
    .
    In Clorox, we found that the plaintiff had failed to show adverse effects on
    the market as a whole because the restrictions at issue did not restrict competitors’
    ability to enter into the relevant market. 
    Id. at 59
    . Although we held that the
    plaintiff in that case failed to present a prima facie case of anticompetitive harm,
    we also went on to detail how the procompetitive justifications of the agreement
    weighed against finding an antitrust violation.        
    Id. at 60
    .   We stated that
    “trademark agreements are favored in the law as a means by which parties agree
    to market products in a way that reduces the likelihood of consumer confusion
    and avoids time-consuming litigation.” 
    Id.
     And again, Clorox counsels that we
    should “presume” that trademark settlement agreements are procompetitive. 
    Id.
    The Commission, however, decided that the trademark claims that led to
    the Challenged Agreements were likely meritless.        While it claimed not to be
    determining the validity of Petitioner’s trademark claims, it did just that by
    weighing the potential validity of the trademark claims in order to show that
    29
    Petitioner’s procompetitive justification was invalid. 12 Even if the Commission’s
    analysis of the underlying trademark claims were correct, trademark agreements
    that “only marginally advance[] trademark policies” can be procompetitive. 13 See
    
    id. at 57
    . Under Clorox, “[e]fforts to protect trademarks, even aggressive ones,
    serve the competitive purpose of furthering trademark policies.” 
    Id. at 61
    .
    That does not mean that every trademark agreement has a legitimate
    procompetitive justification. If the “provisions relating to trademark protection
    are auxiliary to an underlying illegal agreement between competitors,” or if there
    were other exceptional circumstances, 14 we would think twice before concluding
    the challenged conduct has a procompetitive justification. See 
    id. at 60
    . As in
    12Though the Luxottica agreement was not the result of a trademark dispute, the agreement
    contains trademark protections similar to those in the other Challenged Agreements. And while
    the restrictions in the Luxottica Agreement may best be considered under the doctrine of ancillary
    restraints, see MLB, 
    542 F.3d at 334
     (Sotomayor, J., concurring), the government does not attempt
    here to offer direct evidence differentiating the reductions in advertising stemming solely from
    that agreement. In any event, because we hold that protecting trademarks is a valid
    procompetitive justification for the restrictions, we see no further need to differentiate the
    Luxottica Agreement from the other agreements.
    13 At the time the agreements were entered into, the law regarding the validity of Petitioner’s
    trademark claims was unsettled, and it remains so in this Circuit. The fact that the law was
    unsettled at the time is one reason a party might enter into a settlement agreement.
    14It has not been argued that exceptional circumstances exist in this case. We, therefore, need
    not decide what circumstances might qualify as exceptional, von Hofe v. United States, 
    492 F.3d 175
    , 185 n.3 (2d Cir. 2007), such as, for example, agreements between parties with unequal
    bargaining power. See Clorox, 
    117 F.3d at 60
     (“There is no evidence that [a party to the challenged
    agreement] entered the agreement under duress.”).
    30
    Clorox, however, there is a lack of evidence here that the Challenged Agreements
    are the “product of anything other than hard-nosed trademark negotiations.” 15
    
    Id.
     Consequently, we find Petitioner met its burden at step two.
    C. Less Restrictive Alternatives
    Because Petitioner has carried its burden of identifying a procompetitive
    justification, the government must show that a less restrictive alternative exists
    that achieves the same legitimate competitive benefits. 16 Am. Express, 
    138 S. Ct. at 2284
    ; North Am. Soccer League, 883 F.3d at 42.                 That is, the restraint “only
    survives a rule of reason analysis if it is reasonably necessary to achieve the
    legitimate objectives proffered by the defendant.” United States v. Brown Univ., 
    5 F.3d 658
    , 678-79 (3d Cir. 1993). “Less restrictive alternatives are those that would
    15Intent plays a role in this conclusion. See Clorox, 
    117 F.3d at
    60 (citing Chicago Bd. of Trade, 
    246 U.S. at 238
    ). There is ample evidence that, if Petitioner’s competitors had not been precluded by
    the Challenged Agreements from running ads on Petitioner’s trademarks, they would have done
    so; the competitors’ use of the terms is what spawned the agreements in the first place. This is
    unlike a typical market division case, where the two parties agree not to compete in the same
    geographic areas because it would benefit both of their bottom lines. Cf. Palmer, 
    498 U.S. at
    49-
    50 (holding an agreement between bar review course providers dividing market territories for
    the purpose of raising prices was per se illegal).
    16 The government argues that if we find that the Commission improperly weighed the
    procompetitive justification of Petitioner’s trademark protections, we should remand to allow the
    Commission to reconsider in the first instance. The Commission, however, already determined
    that, assuming the procompetitive justifications were legitimate, they were not reasonably
    necessary to achieve the proffered procompetitive benefits. We need not remand to allow them
    to rearticulate the same point.
    31
    be less prejudicial to competition as a whole.”    North Am. Soccer League, 883 F.3d
    at 45 (internal quotation marks omitted).         The Commission found that the
    government had shown a viable less restrictive alternative, namely that the parties
    to the Challenged Agreements could have agreed to require clear disclosure in
    each search advertisement of the identity of the rival seller rather than prohibit all
    advertising on trademarked terms. According to the government, therefore, the
    Challenged Agreements are overbroad.
    In Clorox, however, we noted that “it is usually unwise for courts to second-
    guess” trademark agreements between competitors.           
    117 F.3d at 60
    .    In this
    context, what is “reasonably necessary,” Brown Univ., 
    5 F.3d at 679
    , is likely to be
    determined by competitors during settlement negotiations, Clorox, 
    117 F.3d at 60
    .
    And, as articulated above, absent something that would negate the typically
    procompetitive nature of these agreements, “the parties’ determination of the
    scope of needed trademark protections is entitled to substantial weight.”     Clorox,
    
    117 F.3d at 60
    .
    The government attempts to differentiate Clorox by arguing that the FTC is
    different than a private plaintiff, and when it brings an antitrust claim we should
    not give the settling parties as much latitude to negotiate a trademark agreement
    32
    as a court would in a private antitrust suit.       Even if we were to accept the
    Commission’s argument that its presence in a case warrants less solicitude for
    trademark interests, the government still needs to show more than the mere
    possibility there could be crafted an alternative form of the trademark agreement.
    The alternative must be “substantially less restrictive.”       Phillip E. Areeda &
    Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their
    Application ¶ 1502 (3rd & 4th eds., 2019 Cum. Supp. 2010-2018). The alternative
    must also achieve the same legitimate competitive benefits outlined by the
    Petitioner. North Am. Soccer League, 883 F.3d at 42. And at the end of the day,
    our job is to “weigh[] the competing evidence to determine if the effects of the
    challenged restraint tend to promote or destroy competition.” Apple, 791 F.3d at
    329 (internal quotation marks omitted).
    The Commission majority thought that a disclosure requirement was
    enforceable because, inter alia, it has ordered similar requirements in the past.
    But the majority failed to consider the practical reasons for the parties entering into
    the Challenged Agreements. Under Clorox, this was insufficient. 
    117 F.3d at
    60-
    61.   The Commission did not consider, for example, how the parties might
    enforce such a requirement moving forward or give any weight to how onerous
    33
    such enforcement efforts would be for private parties. When the restraint at issue
    in an antitrust action implicates IP rights, Actavis directs us to consider the policy
    goals of the relevant IP law. See 570 U.S. at 149. Here, those considerations must
    include the practical implications of the government’s proffered alternatives on
    the parties’ ability to protect and enforce their trademarks.
    While trademark agreements limit competitors from competing as
    effectively as they otherwise might, we owe significant deference to arm’s length
    use agreements negotiated by parties to those agreements. Clorox, 
    117 F.3d at
    59-
    60. Doing so may give rise to collateral harm in a relevant market. But forcing
    companies to be less aggressive in enforcing their trademarks is antithetical to the
    procompetitive goals of trademark policy. 17                 See 
    id. at 61
    .       And without
    considering the downstream effects of requiring less aggressive enforcement, the
    17We acknowledge a concern that the Challenged Agreements require the parties to employ
    negative keywords, which prevent ads of competitors from appearing in a consumer search for
    each other’s trademarked terms – even absent purchase of a keyword (but rather due to a search
    engine’s independent determination that an ad is relevant to the consumer). Even if we were
    inclined to consider whether this aspect of the settlement agreement goes beyond any legitimate
    claim of trademark infringement, and therefore imposes a restraint on competition not justified
    by the procompetitive value of enforcing trademark rights, the Commission has neither made
    separate findings with respect to the specific anticompetitive effects of this narrow aspect of the
    settlement agreements, nor urged that we should evaluate this issue separately. Accordingly, we
    have no reason to consider that issue.
    34
    government has failed to show that the proffered alternatives achieve the same
    legitimate procompetitive benefits as those advanced by the Petitioner.
    CONCLUSION
    In this case, where the restrictions that arise are born of typical trademark
    settlement agreements, we cannot overlook the Challenged Agreements’
    procompetitive goal of promoting trademark policy.           In light of the strong
    procompetitive justification of protecting Petitioner’s trademarks, we conclude the
    Challenged Agreements “merely regulate[] and perhaps thereby promote[]
    competition.”     Chicago Bd. of Trade, 
    246 U.S. at 238
    .   They do not constitute a
    violation of the Sherman Act, and therefore an asserted violation of the FTC Act
    fails of necessity.
    The petition for review is GRANTED, the Final Order of the Federal Trade
    Commission is VACATED, and the case is REMANDED with instructions to
    DISMISS the administrative complaint.
    35
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 18-3848

Filed Date: 6/11/2021

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 6/11/2021

Authorities (18)

California Dental Ass'n v. Federal Trade Commission , 119 S. Ct. 1604 ( 1999 )

geneva-pharmaceuticals-technology-corp-as-successor-in-interest-to , 386 F.3d 485 ( 2004 )

The Clorox Company, Plaintiff-Counter-Defendant-Appellant v.... , 117 F.3d 50 ( 1997 )

in-re-independent-service-organizations-antitrust-litigation-csu-llc , 203 F.3d 1322 ( 2000 )

united-states-v-brown-university-in-providence-in-the-state-of-rhode , 5 F.3d 658 ( 1993 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Indiana Federation of Dentists , 106 S. Ct. 2009 ( 1986 )

Board of Trade of Chicago v. United States , 38 S. Ct. 242 ( 1918 )

PolyGram Holding, Inc. v. Federal Trade Commission , 416 F.3d 29 ( 2005 )

California Dental Association v. Federal Trade Commission , 224 F.3d 942 ( 2000 )

Thomas Blackburn and Raymond T. Green v. Charles Sweeney, ... , 53 F.3d 825 ( 1995 )

Robert Bogan and Scott Bogan v. Austin E. Hodgkins, Jr., ... , 166 F.3d 509 ( 1999 )

Von Hofe v. United States , 492 F.3d 175 ( 2007 )

Ohio v. American Express Co. , 201 L. Ed. 2d 678 ( 2018 )

Northern Pacific Railway Co. v. United States , 78 S. Ct. 514 ( 1958 )

Major League Baseball Properties, Inc. v. Salvino, Inc. , 542 F.3d 290 ( 2008 )

Realcomp II, Ltd. v. Federal Trade Commission , 635 F.3d 815 ( 2011 )

Texaco Inc. v. Dagher , 126 S. Ct. 1276 ( 2006 )

United States v. Microsoft Corp. , 253 F.3d 34 ( 2001 )

View All Authorities »