Connecticut Fine Wine and Spirits LLC v. Seagull ( 2019 )


Menu:
  • 17-2003
    Connecticut Fine Wine and Spirits LLC v. Seagull
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT
    August Term, 2017
    (Argued: February 1, 2018         Decided: February 20, 2019)
    Docket No. 17-2003-cv
    CONNECTICUT FINE WINE AND SPIRITS, LLC, d/b/a, TOTAL WINE & MORE,
    Plaintiff-Appellant,
    — v. —
    COMMISSIONER MICHELLE H. SEAGULL, DEPARTMENT OF CONSUMER
    PROTECTION, JOHN SUCHY, DIRECTOR, DIVISION OF LIQUOR CONTROL,
    Defendants-Appellees,
    WINE & SPIRITS WHOLESALERS OF CONNECTICUT, INC., CONNECTICUT
    BEER WHOLESALERS ASSOCIATION, INC., CONNECTICUT RESTAURANT
    ASSOCIATION, CONNECTICUT PACKAGE STORES ASSOCIATION, INC.,
    BRESCOME BARTON, INC.,
    Intervenors-Defendants-
    Appellees.*
    *
    The Clerk of Court is respectfully directed to amend the official caption in this
    case as set forth above.
    1
    B e f o r e:
    POOLER, SACK, Circuit Judges, and ENGELMAYER,** District Judge.
    Connecticut Fine Wine and Spirits, d/b/a Total Wine & More (“Total
    Wine”), challenged certain provisions of Connecticut’s Liquor Control Act and
    related regulations. Total Wine alleged that these provisions were preempted by
    the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. The United States District Court for the District
    of Connecticut, Janet Hall, J., granted the defendants’ motion to dismiss the
    complaint, holding, inter alia, that the post-and-hold provisions and the
    minimum-retail-price provisions of the Connecticut Liquor Control Act were
    hybrid restraints on trade, but that Total Wine failed to plead facts that plausibly
    support the conclusion that those provisions constitute per se violations of, and
    therefore were preempted by, the Sherman Act. The District Court also held that
    Total Wine did not plausibly allege that the price discrimination provision was a
    hybrid restraint on trade; therefore, that provision imposes a unilateral restraint
    **
    Judge Paul A. Engelmayer, of the United States District Court for the Southern
    District of New York, sitting by designation.
    2
    on trade that falls outside the scope of the Sherman Act. We agree with the
    District Court that the post-and-hold, minimum-retail-price, and price-
    discrimination provisions are not preempted by the Sherman Act. We therefore
    AFFIRM.
    WILLIAM J. MURPHY (John J. Connolly, Adam B. Abelson, on the brief)
    Zuckerman Spaeder LLP, Baltimore, Maryland; James T. Shearin,
    Edward B. Lefebvre, Pullman & Comley, LLC, New York, New
    York, for Plaintiff-Appellant Connecticut Fine Wine & Spirits,
    LLC.
    GARY M. BECKER, ASSISTANT ATTORNEY GENERAL (Robert Deichert,
    Assistant Attorney General, on the brief), George Jepsen, Attorney
    General for the State of Connecticut for Defendants-Appellees
    Michelle H. Seagull, Commissioner, Department of Consumer
    Protection; John Suchy, Director, Division of Labor, Hartford,
    Connecticut.
    DEBORAH SKAKEL (Craig M. Flanders, on the brief) Blank Rome LLP,
    New York, New York; David S. Hardy, Damian K.
    Gunningsmith, Carmody Torrance Sandak & Hennessey LLP,
    New Haven, Connecticut; Robert M. Langer, Benjamin H.
    Diessel, Wiggin and Dana LLP, Hartford, Connecticut; Meredith
    G. Diette, Siegel, O’Connor, O’Donnell & Beck P.C., Hartford,
    Connecticut; Patrick A. Klingman, Klingman Law, LLC,
    Hartford, Connecticut, for Intervenors-Defendants-Appellees
    Wine & Spirits Wholesalers of Connecticut, Inc.; Connecticut
    Beer Wholesalers Association, Inc.; Connecticut Restaurant
    Association, Connecticut Package Stores Association, Inc.
    3
    Jeffrey J. Mirman, John F. Droney, Hinckley, Allen & Snyder, LLP,
    Hartford, Connecticut, for Intervenor-Defendant-Appellee
    Brescome Barton, Inc.
    PAUL A. ENGELMAYER, District Judge:
    Connecticut Fine Wine and Spirits, d/b/a Total Wine & More (“Total
    Wine”) appeals from a judgment of the United States District Court for the
    District of Connecticut (Janet C. Hall, District Judge) dismissing its complaint
    against the Connecticut Department of Consumer Protection (“DCP”) and the
    Director of the Connecticut Division of Liquor Control (“DLC”). Total Wine
    claimed that certain statutory and regulatory provisions that govern the
    distribution and sale of alcoholic beverages in Connecticut, and which often
    result in common retail-level pricing across the state for particular such
    beverages, are preempted by federal antitrust law. For the reasons that follow,
    we hold that these laws are not preempted. We therefore affirm.
    BACKGROUND
    A.     Connecticut’s Laws Regarding Alcohol Distribution and Sale
    Like many other states, Connecticut heavily regulates the distribution and
    sale of alcoholic beverages within its borders. The state’s Liquor Control Act
    4
    prohibits the sale of alcoholic beverages in a manner that fails to comply with
    that statute. See Conn. Gen. Stat. § 30-74(a).
    At issue here are three sets of provisions under Connecticut statutes and
    regulations that bear on the price at which alcoholic beverages may lawfully be
    sold: “post-and-hold” provisions; minimum retail pricing provisions; and
    provisions prohibiting price discrimination and volume discounts.1 These, in
    tandem, establish the method by which alcoholic beverage prices are set by the
    manufacturer, the wholesaler, and the retailer.
    The three sets of provisions at issue are as follows:
    Post-and-hold provisions: Connecticut’s “post and hold” provisions
    require state-licensed manufacturers, wholesalers, and “out-of-state permittees”
    (together, “wholesalers”) to post a “bottle price” and a “case price” each month
    with the DCP for each alcoholic product that the wholesaler intends to sell
    during the following month. (For beer, the wholesaler must post a “can price.”)
    1
    Total Wine challenges the following provisions: (1) section 30-63 of the
    Connecticut General Statutes and section 30-6-B12 of the Regulations of
    Connecticut State Agencies (referred to here as the “post-and-hold” provisions);
    (2) sections 30-68m(a)(1) and 30-68m(b) of the Connecticut General Statutes (the
    “minimum retail price” provisions); and (3) sections 30-63(b), 30-68(k), and 30-
    94(b) of the Connecticut General Statutes and section 30-6-A29(a) of the
    Regulation of Connecticut State Agencies (the “price discrimination prohibition”
    provisions). In the ensuing discussion, the Court reproduces the central
    provisions.
    5
    Posted prices are then made available to industry participants. During the four
    days after the posting of the prices, wholesalers may “amend” their posted prices
    to “match” competitors’ lower prices—specifically, “to meet a lower price posted
    by another wholesaler with respect to alcoholic liquor bearing the same brand or
    trade name.” Those amended prices, however, may not be “lower than those
    [prices] being met.” Wholesalers are obligated to “hold” their prices at the
    posted price (amended or not) for a month. These post-and-hold
    provisions—variations of which are found in many states—are the heart of the
    Connecticut regulatory regime that Total Wine challenges.2
    2
    Section 30-63(c) of the Connecticut General Statutes provides:
    For alcoholic liquor other than beer, each manufacturer, wholesaler and
    out-of-state shipper permittee shall post with the department, on a
    monthly basis, the bottle, can and case price of any brand of goods
    offered for sale in Connecticut, which price when so posted shall be the
    controlling price for such manufacturer, wholesaler or out-of-state
    permittee for the month following such posting. On and after July 1,
    2005, for beer, each manufacturer, wholesaler and out-of-state shipper
    permittee shall post with the department, on a monthly basis, the
    bottle, can and case price, and the price per keg or barrel or fractional
    unit thereof for any brand of goods offered for sale in Connecticut
    which price when so posted shall be the controlling price for such
    brand of goods offered for sale in this state for the month following
    such posting. Such manufacturer, wholesaler and out-of-state shipper
    permittee may also post additional prices for such bottle, can, case, keg
    or barrel or fractional unit thereof for a specified portion of the
    following month which prices when so posted shall be the controlling
    prices for such bottle, can, case, keg or barrel or fractional unit thereof
    6
    Minimum-retail-price provisions: Connecticut’s minimum-retail-price
    provisions require that retailers sell to customers at or above a statutorily defined
    “[c]ost.” “Cost,” however, is not defined as the retailer’s actual cost. Instead,
    generally, a retailer’s “[c]ost” for a given alcoholic beverage, is determined by
    adding the posted bottle price—as set by the wholesaler—and a markup for
    for such specified portion of the following month. Notice of all
    manufacturer, wholesaler and out-of-state shipper permittee prices
    shall be given to permittee purchasers by direct mail, Internet web site
    or advertising in a trade publication having circulation among the retail
    permittees except a wholesaler permittee may give such notice by hand
    delivery. Price postings with the department setting forth wholesale
    prices to retailers shall be available for inspection during regular
    business hours at the offices of the department by manufacturers and
    wholesalers until three o'clock p.m. of the first business day after the
    last day for posting prices. A manufacturer or wholesaler may amend
    such manufacturer's or wholesaler's posted price for any month to meet
    a lower price posted by another manufacturer or wholesaler with
    respect to alcoholic liquor bearing the same brand or trade name and
    of like age, vintage, quality and unit container size; provided that any
    such amended price posting shall be filed before three o'clock p.m. of
    the fourth business day after the last day for posting prices; and
    provided further such amended posting shall not set forth prices lower
    than those being met. Any manufacturer or wholesaler posting an
    amended price shall, at the time of posting, identify in writing the
    specific posting being met. On and after July 1, 2005, all wholesaler
    postings, other than for beer, for the following month shall be provided
    to retail permittees not later than the twenty-seventh day of the month
    prior to such posting. All wholesaler postings for beer shall be
    provided to retail permittees not later than the twentieth day of the
    month prior to such posting.
    7
    shipping and delivery. The post-and-hold provision, because it supplies the
    central component of the “[c]ost” at which the retailer may sell its product, thus
    largely dictates the price at which Connecticut retailers must sell their alcoholic
    products.3
    3
    Section 30-68m of the Connecticut General Statutes provides, in pertinent part:
    (a) For the purposes of this section:
    (1) “Cost” for a retail permittee means (A) for alcoholic liquor other
    than beer, the posted bottle price from the wholesaler plus any charge
    for shipping or delivery to the retail permittee's place of business paid
    by the retail permittee in addition to the posted price, and (B) for beer,
    the lowest posted price during the month in which the retail permittee
    is selling plus any charge for shipping or delivery to the retail
    permittee’s place of business paid by the retail permittee in addition to
    the price originally paid by the retail permittee;
    (b) No retail permittee shall sell alcoholic liquor at a price below his or
    her cost.
    Relatedly, Section 30-68m(a)(C) defines “bottle price” as:
    [the] price per unit of the contents of any case of alcoholic liquor, other
    than beer [which] shall be arrived at by dividing the case price by the
    number of units or bottles making up such case price and adding to the
    quotient an amount that is not less than the following: A unit or bottle
    one-half pint or two hundred milliliters or less, two cents; a unit or
    bottle more than one-half pint or two hundred milliliters but not more
    than one pint or five hundred milliliters, four cents; and a unit or bottle
    greater than one pint or five hundred milliliters, eight cents.
    8
    Plaintiffs allege that wholesalers will occasionally lower their posted case
    prices for a given month, without lowering posted bottle prices, during what are
    called “off-post” months. Although retailers buy almost exclusively by the case,
    their prices remain fixed by the minimum-retail-price provisions, which are
    keyed to bottle prices.
    Price discrimination/volume discounts: Finally, Connecticut bans volume
    discounts and other forms of price discrimination. Wholesalers must sell a given
    product to all retailers at the same price. Wholesalers may not offer discounts to
    retailers who are high-volume purchasers.4
    4
    Section 30-68k of the Connecticut General Statutes provides:
    No holder of any wholesaler's permit shall ship, transport or deliver
    within this state or any territory therein or sell or offer for sale, to a
    purchaser holding a permit for the sale of alcoholic liquor for on or off
    premises consumption, any brand of alcoholic liquor, including
    cordials, as defined in section 30-1, at a bottle, can or case price higher
    than the lowest price at which such item is then being sold or offered
    for sale or shipped, transported or delivered by such wholesaler to any
    other such purchaser to which the wholesaler sells, offers for sale,
    ships, transports or delivers that brand of alcoholic liquor within this
    state.
    Similarly, Section 30-63(b) of the Connecticut General Statutes provides:
    No manufacturer, wholesaler or out-of-state shipper permittee shall
    discriminate in any manner in price discounts between one permittee
    and another on sales or purchases of alcoholic liquors bearing the same
    brand or trade name and of like age, size and quality, nor shall such
    9
    While multiple policy interests have been asserted in support of these
    provisions, they (particularly the post-and-hold and minimum-retail-price
    provisions) commonly have been justified as means of guarding against
    escalating price wars among alcohol retailers that may lead to excessive
    consumption. See Slimp v. Dep’t of Liquor Control, 
    687 A.2d 123
    , 129 (Conn. 1996)
    (noting “legislature’s concern that artificial inducements to purchase liquor will
    result in increased consumption”); Eder Bros. v. Wine Merchants of Conn., Inc., 
    800 A.2d 138
    , 147 (Conn. 2005) (noting that “price wars among retail dealers” for
    liquor “may induce persons to purchase, and therefore consume, more liquor
    than they would if higher prices were maintained”); Eder 
    Bros., 800 A.2d at 147
    –48 (noting that “the cutthroat competition” characteristic of price wars “is
    apt to induce the retailers to commit such infractions of the law as selling to
    minors and keeping open after hours in order to withstand the economic
    pressure”). These provisions (particularly the price-discrimination provision)
    have also been justified as guarding against favoritism within the liquor industry
    manufacturer, wholesaler or out-of-state shipper permittee allow in any
    form any discount, rebate, free goods, allowance or other inducement
    for the purpose of making sales or purchases. Nothing in this
    subsection shall be construed to prohibit beer manufacturers, beer
    wholesalers or beer out-of-state shipper permittees from differentiating
    in the manner in which their products are packaged on the basis of on-
    site or off-site consumption.
    10
    and protecting smaller retailers. See 
    Slimp, 687 A.2d at 129
    . Unsurprisingly,
    countervailing arguments have also been made, including ones noting the anti-
    competitive nature of these price restraints.
    B.     Total Wine’s Complaint
    Total Wine is the largest retailer of wine and spirits in the United States.
    Headquartered in Bethesda, Maryland, Total Wine, with its affiliates, owns and
    operates wine and liquor stores in 21 states.
    In December 2012, Total Wine opened a retail beverage store in Norwalk,
    Connecticut, its first such store in the state. Since then, Total Wine has opened
    additional stores, in Milford, Manchester, and West Hartford, Connecticut.
    On August 23, 2016, Total Wine filed suit against Jonathan Harris, the
    Commissioner of the DCP, and John Suchy, Director of the DLC, in their official
    capacities.5 Seeking injunctive and declaratory relief, it brought a facial challenge
    to the three sets of statutory and regulatory provisions reviewed above
    governing the distribution and sale of alcoholic beverages in Connecticut: (1) the
    post-and-hold provisions, (2) the minimum-retail-price provisions, and (3) the
    price-discrimination and volume-discount-prohibition provisions. Total Wine
    5
    Michelle H. Seagull replaced Jonathan Harris as Commissioner of the DCP on May 1,
    2017.
    11
    alleged that these provisions bring about per se violations of § 1 of the Sherman
    Antitrust Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, and so are preempted by that statute.
    Total Wine’s claim was that the Connecticut regulatory scheme eliminates
    incentives for alcoholic beverage wholesalers to compete on the basis of price and
    invites wholesalers to maintain prices “substantially above what fair and
    ordinary market forces would dictate.” App. at 19, Compl. ¶ 16. Total Wine
    further claimed that Connecticut’s regulations inhibit meaningful price
    competition at the retail level.
    Specifically, Total Wine claimed, the regulations, in two ways, bring about
    prices that exceed those that a competitive market would produce.
    First, it argued, the post-and-hold provisions—and the opportunity they
    give wholesalers to match a lower price during the forthcoming month for a
    given product with no risk of sparking a price war—reduce any wholesaler’s
    incentive to be the first to reduce price. The post-and-hold provisions, Total
    Wine argued, effectively bring about horizontal price fixing. As it put the point
    on appeal: “If a wholesaler were to drop its price on a particular product, its
    competitors would know immediately (from having seen the posted price), and
    would have four days to match the posted price.” Appellant Br. at 8–9. Even if
    the wholesaler who had been the first to reduce its price still wished to set a price
    12
    beneath its competitors, Total Wine noted, it would then be required to “hold the
    lower price for an entire month—during which it would have no competitive
    advantage because its competitors would be charging the same price.”6 
    Id. at 9.
    Second, Total Wine argued, Connecticut’s system precludes retailers from
    competing on the basis of cost. Fundamentally, Total Wine noted, the minimum-
    retail-price provision is keyed to a definition of “[c]ost” that turns not on the
    retailer’s actual cost but on the price charged to the retailer by the wholesaler.
    This, Total Wine argued, prevents a high-volume, lower-average-cost retailer
    such as itself from attracting customers by offering discounts enabled by its
    lower-cost structure. This result is exacerbated, Total Wine alleged, by a practice
    in which wholesalers often engage: They set high minimum bottle prices, and
    then lower the case prices for the product without making corresponding
    reductions to the bottle price. While retailers (who buy almost exclusively by the
    case) take advantage of the reduced case price and buy larger quantities during
    months where the case price is lower, this, Total Wine alleged, does not benefit
    the consumer because retailers are required to sell the product at a margin fixed
    6
    Total Wine’s claim that the Connecticut regulations promote horizontal price
    fixing was substantially developed in its briefs on the motion to dismiss and
    further refined on appeal. Its Complaint overwhelmingly focused instead on its
    claims as to vertical price fixing. We conclude, however, that the Complaint
    satisfactorily pled both theories.
    13
    by the higher minimum bottle price, which has effectively been set by the
    wholesaler. In this manner, Total Wine alleged, “wholesalers effectively control
    both retail price and retailers’ profit margins,” and retailers like Total Wine that
    wish to use their business efficiencies to reduce the prices offered to consumers
    are blocked from doing so. App. at 20, Compl. ¶ 17.
    The end result, Total Wine alleged, is a market without meaningful price
    competition: “Competing wholesalers for the same brands routinely set the same
    bottle and case prices down to the penny, month after month, with each
    wholesaler exactly tracking its competitors’ . . . case prices.” 
    Id., Compl. ¶
    19. In
    other words, Total Wine argued, the regulatory scheme promotes vertical price
    fixing. Total Wine’s complaint attached data tables reflecting that, over long
    periods, leading wholesalers often have charged the same amount for each
    alcoholic beverage product—e.g., Bombay Sapphire, Grey Goose, Jose Cuervo
    Gold—and have adjusted prices in lockstep. These prices, Total Wine claimed,
    exceed those which a competitive market would produce: Citing a study, Total
    Wine alleged that Connecticut’s regulatory scheme “result[s] in retail prices for
    wine and spirits in Connecticut that are as much as 24% higher than prices
    offered for identical products in the surrounding states.” 
    Id., Compl. ¶
    18.
    14
    Finally, Total Wine alleged, the Connecticut regulatory scheme does not
    entail active supervision by any state agency or instrumentality. Wholesalers
    post and retailers charge the prices they see fit, it alleged, without any review or
    intervention by regulators, save where a lawsuit has been brought claiming
    noncompliance with the state’s regulations.
    C.     The Motion to Dismiss
    On October 14, 2016, the defendants moved to dismiss. They were
    supported in this motion by five intervenors, four of which were trade
    associations and the fifth of which was a liquor distributor.7
    On June 6, 2017, the district court, following argument, granted the motion
    to dismiss. See Conn. Fine Wine & Spirits v. Harris, LLC, 
    255 F. Supp. 3d 355
    (D.
    Conn 2017). Analyzing the challenged provisions separately,8 the district court
    7
    These were: the Wine & Spirit Wholesalers of Connecticut (“WSWC”), the
    Connecticut Beer Wholesalers Association (“CBWA”), the Connecticut
    Restaurant Association (“CRA”) and the Connecticut Package Stores Association
    (“CPSA”) (collectively, “the trade associations”), as well as Brescome Barton, Inc.
    (“Brescome” and, with the trade associations, “intervenors”).
    8
    The district court stated that separate consideration of each challenged
    provision was required (1) under principles of federalism, (2) because each
    provision presented distinct analytic issues under principles of antitrust
    preemption, and (3) because Connecticut’s general rule of statutory construction
    provides that the invalidity of some sections of a statute should not invalidate the
    statute as a whole. See Conn. Fine Wine & 
    Spirits, 255 F. Supp. 3d at 366
    –67; Conn.
    Gen. Stat. § 1-3.
    15
    applied as to each the first step in the two-step framework used to assess claims
    of preemption by § 1 of the Sherman Act in this Circuit.9 As a threshold matter,
    the court inquired whether the restraints are unilateral (“imposed by the
    government . . . to the exclusion of private control”) and hence immune from
    preemption by § 1, or hybrid (imposed by both the government and by granting
    “private actors a degree of regulatory control over competition” and hence
    capable of preemption. 
    Id. at 364.
    Then, the court inquired whether the
    challenged provision brought about facially, or per se, unlawful restraints on
    trade, in which case they are preempted, or restraints that are subject to rule of
    reason scrutiny, in which case they are not. 
    Id. As to
    the post and hold restraint, the district court held that it is a hybrid
    restraint, but that the conduct it brings about is not per se unlawful, and so is
    subject to rule of reason analysis. 
    Id. at 371.
    Therefore, it is not preempted. 
    Id. The district
    court relied on Battipaglia v. New York State Liquor Authority, 
    745 F.2d 166
    (2d Cir. 1984), in which we upheld New York State’s post-and-hold provision
    as similarly not preempted.
    9
    The district court dismissed Total Wine’s claims at the first step of the
    preemption analysis and neither the defendants nor any of the intervenors have
    argued that Total Wine’s claims should be dismissed at the second step.
    16
    As to the minimum resale price restraint, the district court held that it too
    was hybrid, but that it also implicated only the rule of reason, not condemnation
    per se. 
    Id. at 373.
    The district court held that this provision imposed a vertical
    restraint. And, it noted, recent Supreme Court cases, in particular Leegin Creative
    Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 
    551 U.S. 877
    (2007), have held that courts are to
    apply rule of reason, not per se, analysis to vertical restraints, meaning that this
    provision is not facially preempted. 
    Id. at 378.
    Finally, the district court held that Connecticut’s provisions forbidding
    price discrimination amounted to a unilateral restraint on trade, imposed solely
    by the state and not involving private conduct. 
    Id. That was
    because these
    provisions “simply prohibit[] liquor wholesalers from charging different prices to
    different retailers,” and do not “grant[] private actors a degree of regulatory
    authority over competition.” 
    Id. at 379.
    Thus, it held that these provisions, too,
    are not preempted. 
    Id. at 380.
    Accordingly, the district court upheld all challenged aspects of
    Connecticut’s alcoholic beverage regulatory regime.
    On June 26, 2017, Connecticut Fine Wine appealed.
    17
    DISCUSSION
    This case presents questions of preemption: Does § 1 of the Sherman
    Antitrust Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, which makes illegal “[e]very contract, combination
    . . . or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce,” preempt the challenged
    provisions of Connecticut’s Liquor Control Act?
    We begin by reviewing the two key precedents that frame the § 1
    preemption inquiry: Rice v. Norman Williams Co., 
    458 U.S. 654
    (1982), and Fisher v.
    City of Berkeley, California, 
    475 U.S. 260
    (1986). Then, because the analysis differs
    by provision, we review serially the three sets of challenged provisions. We first
    address the minimum-resale-price restraint and then the prohibition on price
    discrimination. We last address the post-and-hold provisions, which are the
    primary focus of plaintiffs’ challenge. None of the provisions, we hold, are
    preempted.10
    A.     Principles of Preemption Under § 1: Rice and Fisher
    The Supreme Court’s decisions in Rice and Fisher frame the § 1 preemption
    inquiry.
    10
    While we address the three areas separately here, we have also considered
    them in tandem. The outcome is the same: considered separately or as a whole,
    the provisions are not preempted. We therefore do not reach the question of
    which analysis would have been the right one had the difference been
    determinative.
    18
    1. Rice: The Requirement That the State Law “Mandate or
    Authorize,” or “Place Irresistible Pressure” on Private Parties to
    Bring About, a Per Se Violation of § 1
    In Rice, the Court held that the preemption inquiry under § 1 requires
    courts to
    apply principles similar to those which we employ in considering
    whether any state statute is pre-empted by a federal statute pursuant
    to the Supremacy Clause. As in the typical pre-emption case, the
    inquiry is whether there exists an irreconcilable conflict between the
    federal and state regulatory schemes. The existence of hypothetical
    or potential conflict is insufficient to warrant the pre-emption of the
    state statute. A state regulatory scheme is not pre-empted by the
    federal antitrust laws simply because in a hypothetical situation a
    private party’s compliance with the statute might cause him to
    violate the antitrust laws. A state statute is not preempted by the
    federal antitrust laws simply because the state scheme might have an
    anticompetitive 
    effect. 458 U.S. at 659
    (citations omitted). Rather, the Court held, “[a] party may
    successfully enjoin the enforcement of a state statute only if the statute on its face
    irreconcilably conflicts with federal antitrust policy.” 
    Id. In other
    words, for a
    state statute to be preempted by § 1, the statute must bring about conduct that
    would require per se condemnation under § 1:
    Our decisions in this area instruct us, therefore, that a state statute,
    when considered in the abstract, may be condemned under the
    antitrust laws only if it mandates or authorizes conduct that
    necessarily constitutes a violation of the antitrust laws in all cases, or
    if it places irresistible pressure on a private party to violate the
    antitrust laws in order to comply with the statute.                 Such
    19
    condemnation will follow under § 1 of the Sherman Act when the
    conduct contemplated by the statute is in all cases a per se violation.
    If the activity addressed by the statute does not fall into that
    category, and therefore must be analyzed under the rule of reason,
    the statute cannot be condemned in the abstract. Analysis under the
    rule of reason requires an examination of the circumstances
    underlying a particular economic practice, and therefore does not
    lend itself to a conclusion that a statute is facially inconsistent with
    federal antitrust laws.
    
    Id. at 661.
    Applying these principles, the Rice Court upheld the codes at issue:
    California Alcoholic Beverage Control provisions which prohibited a licensed
    importer from importing any brand of distilled spirits for which it was not a
    designated importer. These, the Court explained, would not give rise in all
    instances to per se illegal conduct. 
    Id. at 661–62.
    2. Fisher: The Requirement of Concerted Action
    In Fisher, the Court identified a related hurdle that a claim of preemption by
    § 1 must clear. At issue was a rent stabilization law enacted by the City of
    Berkeley, California, that placed strict controls on certain classes of real property
    rented for residential use. The ordinance required landlords to adhere to the
    prescribed rent ceilings; violators were subject to civil and criminal 
    penalties. 475 U.S. at 262
    –63. A group of landlords sued the city, arguing that the ordinance
    was a traditional—and per se invalid—form of fixing prices.
    20
    The Supreme Court rejected that argument. Sherman Act § 1, it noted, can
    be violated only by collective action: “unreasonable restraints of trade effected by
    a ‘contract, combination . . ., or conspiracy’ between separate entities.” 
    Id. at 266
    (quoting Copperweld Corp. v. Indep. Tube Corp., 
    467 U.S. 752
    , 768 (1984)). But, the
    Court held, Berkeley’s unilateral imposition of rent control did not amount to
    agreement or “concerted action.” 
    Id. The Court
    acknowledged that, had the
    Berkeley landlords banded together to fix rental prices in the absence of an
    ordinance, their action would have been a per se violation of the Sherman Act. 
    Id. But the
    fact that the price-fixing ordinance resulted from the city acting
    unilaterally, not the landlords acting concertedly, saved it from preemption:
    A restraint imposed unilaterally by government does not become
    concerted-action within the meaning of the [Sherman Act] simply
    because it has a coercive effect upon parties who must obey the law.
    The ordinary relationship between the government and those who
    must obey its regulatory commands whether they wish to or not is
    not enough to establish a conspiracy. Similarly, the mere fact that all
    competing property owners must comply with the same provisions
    of the Ordinance is not enough to establish a conspiracy among
    landlords. Under Berkeley’s Ordinance, control over the maximum
    rent levels of every affected residential unit has been unilaterally
    removed from the owners of these properties and given to the Rent
    Stabilization Board.
    
    Id. at 267.
    In sum, the challenged rent control laws could exist, alongside § 1,
    because “the rent ceilings imposed by the Ordinance and maintained by the Rent
    21
    Stabilization Board have been unilaterally imposed by government upon
    landlords to the exclusion of private control.” 
    Id. at 266
    . As the Court put the
    point: “There is no meeting of the minds here.” 
    Id. at 267.
    The Supreme Court in Fisher was careful to limit its holding to unilateral
    action by a government entity. It recognized that a governmentally imposed
    restraint on trade that enforces private pricing decisions would be a “hybrid
    restraint” that fulfills the Sherman Act’s “concerted action” requirement. The
    Court explained:
    Not all restraints imposed upon private actors by government units
    necessarily constitute unilateral action outside the purview of § 1.
    Certain restraints may be characterized as ‘hybrid,’ in that
    nonmarket mechanisms merely enforce private marketing decisions.
    See 
    Rice, 458 U.S. at 665
    (Stevens, J., concurring in the judgment).
    Where private actors are thus granted “a degree of private
    regulatory power,” 
    id. at 66
    n.1, the regulatory scheme may be
    attacked under § 1.”
    
    Id. at 267–68.
    We have previously read Rice and Fisher to constitute the first step in a
    two-step inquiry to decide whether a statute is preempted by § 1. See, e.g.,
    Freedom Holdings Inc. v. Spitzer, 
    357 F.3d 205
    , 223 (2d Cir. 2004).11
    11
    In cases in which alcoholic-beverage laws are claimed to be preempted by § 1,
    states have sometimes additionally defended by asserting state action immunity,
    which is the second step in our Circuit’s two-step preemption inquiry, and
    immunity derived from the Twenty First Amendment to the U.S. Constitution.
    22
    B.    Connecticut’s Minimum-Retail-Price Provisions
    The Court applies these principles, first, to the minimum-retail-price
    provisions. As noted, these provisions (e.g., Conn. Gen. Stat. § 30-68m) dictate
    the relationship between the liquor prices set by wholesalers and those set by
    retailers.
    In 324 Liquor v. Duffy Corp., 
    479 U.S. 335
    (1987), the Supreme Court
    considered a similar New York statute, which “impose[d] a regime of resale price
    maintenance on all New York liquor retailers” and required them to charge at
    least 112% of the wholesaler’s posted bottle price. 
    Id. at 337,
    341. The Supreme
    Court classified the New York statute, under Fisher, as a hybrid restraint. 
    Id. at 345
    n.8 (describing provisions as having granted “’private actors . . . a degree of
    private regulatory power’”) (quoting 
    Fisher, 475 U.S. at 268
    ). Then, applying the
    Rice framework, the Court found the statute was “inconsistent with § 1” because
    it authorized per se violations of § 1 under precedents that, “‘since the early years
    of national antitrust enforcement,’” had so treated resale price maintenance
    agreements. 
    Id. at 341
    (quoting Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 
    465 U.S. 752
    , 761 (1984)). Hence, the New York statute was preempted. 
    Id. at 343.
    Connecticut has not raised such defenses in connection with this appeal.
    23
    The Supreme Court’s classification in 324 Liquor of the minimum-retail-
    price restraints as hybrid, and hence capable of preemption by § 1, binds the
    Court here. The New York statute there is substantively identical to the
    Connecticut statute here. And the hybrid classification in 324 Liquor remains
    good law. See Freedom 
    Holdings, 357 F.3d at 223
    –24 (noting that 324 Liquor found
    a hybrid arrangement based on limited private acts: “the individual
    determinations of each wholesaler as to what bottle price to post”).
    The same, however, cannot be said for the Supreme Court’s application of
    Rice in 324 Liquor. The Court’s premise, that the New York statute mandated per
    se violations of § 1, has been overtaken by a change in antitrust law. In 2007, the
    Supreme Court, culminating a line of decisions, held that rule of reason—and not
    per se—analysis applies to all vertical restraints. See 
    Leegin, 551 U.S. at 882
    .
    Leegin overruled Dr. Miles Medical. Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 
    220 U.S. 373
    (1911), the precedent cited by 324 Liquor as the fount of the doctrine that vertical
    price fixing arrangements are per se illegal. See 324 
    Liquor, 479 U.S. at 341
    .
    Henceforth, the Supreme Court stated, “vertical price restraints are to be judged
    by the rule of reason.” 
    Leegin, 551 U.S. at 882
    . Justifying the doctrinal change, the
    Court explained that “it cannot be stated with any degree of confidence that
    resale price maintenance ‘always or almost always tend[s] to restrict competition
    24
    and decrease output,’” 
    id. at 894
    (quoting Bus. Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 
    485 U.S. 717
    , 723 (1988)), noting that Leegin capped a gradual doctrinal move “away
    from Dr. Miles’ strict approach,” 
    id. at 900.
    In light of Leegin, 324 Liquor’s holding that minimum-retail-price provisions
    constitute a per se violation of antitrust laws in all 
    cases, 479 U.S. at 343
    , is,
    necessarily, no longer good law. The need to analyze vertical pricing
    arrangements under the rule of reason means that § 1 cannot preempt as per se
    unlawful even a statute that overtly mandates such arrangements. See 
    Rice, 458 U.S. at 658
    (“If the activity addressed by the statute . . . must be analyzed under
    the rule of reason, the statute cannot be condemned in the abstract. Analysis
    under the rule of reason requires an examination of the circumstances underlying
    a particular economic practice, and therefore does not lend itself to a conclusion
    that a statute is facially inconsistent with the federal antitrust laws.”).
    We therefore hold that Connecticut’s minimum-retail-price provisions,
    compelling as they do only vertical pricing arrangements among private actors,
    are not preempted under § 1.12
    12
    Total Wine alternatively attempts to characterize minimum-retail-price
    provisions such as Connecticut’s as impelling horizontal price-fixing. For the
    reasons given by the district court, this characterization is wrong. Conn. Fine
    Wine & 
    Spirits, 255 F. Supp. 3d at 375
    .
    25
    C.     Connecticut’s Provisions Prohibiting Price Discrimination
    The Court next considers Connecticut’s provisions prohibiting price
    discrimination. These provisions, as noted, require that wholesalers sell a given
    alcoholic product to all retailers at the same price.
    For two reasons, we hold that these provisions are not preempted.
    First, as the district court recognized, these provisions impose a unilateral
    restraint. They leave each wholesaler at liberty to choose the price it will charge
    all retailers for a product while prohibiting each from charging different prices to
    different retailers. Although limiting a wholesaler’s range of motion, this
    provision does not grant any private actor “a degree of regulatory control over
    competition.” Freedom Holdings Inc. v. Cuomo, 
    624 F.3d 38
    , 50 (2d Cir. 2010).
    Rather, like the rent cap set by the Berkeley municipality in Fisher, it is a restraint
    “imposed by government . . . to the exclusion of private control.” 
    Id. (citing Fisher,
    475 U.S. at 266). Such a restraint does not implicate the concerns of
    concerted activity animating § 1.
    Second, the price restraint worked by § 30-68k is purely vertical in
    operation. It limits the ability of a wholesaler that has already charged one
    retailer a given price to charge another retailer a different price. Therefore, even
    if this provision could be viewed as a hybrid, rather than a unilateral, price-fixing
    26
    provision, after Leegin, it would no longer implicate a category of conduct that
    remains per se unlawful. While its impact may be to harmonize prices at a retail
    level of beverages sold by a common wholesaler, the provision does not
    mandate—or even incent—collaboration among horizontal competitors. For this
    separate reason, under Rice, it is not preempted by § 1.
    D.     Connecticut’s Post-and-Hold Provisions
    The Court finally considers the post-and-hold provisions, described above.
    On the question whether § 1 preempts these provisions, the parties primarily
    dispute whether, as the district court held, Battipaglia, 
    745 F.2d 166
    , which
    rejected a claim that § 1 preempted a New York liquor-pricing statute, is
    controlling here.
    1.     Review of Battipaglia
    In Battipaglia, decided after Rice and before Fisher, a divided panel of this
    Court, per Judge Friendly, upheld a New York statute whose price restraint
    components governing the sale of liquor were strikingly similar to those at issue
    here. The New York law contained post-and-hold provisions that obliged
    wholesalers to file monthly price schedules with the state liquor authority by the
    fifth day of the preceding month, 
    Id. at 168
    (citing N.Y. Alco. Bev. Cont. § 101-
    b(3)(b)), and authorized wholesalers to amend their filed schedules “to meet
    27
    lower competing prices and discounts ‘provided such amended prices and
    discounts are not lower and discounts are not greater than those to be met,’” 
    id. (quoting N.Y.
    Alco. Bev. Cont. Law § 101-b(4)). The New York law also
    contained price-discrimination and minimum-retail-price provisions that
    constrained sales prices at the retail level. See 
    id. (citing N.Y.
    Alco. Bev. Cont. §
    101-b(2)).
    In the relevant portion of its analysis,13 Battipaglia held that the challenged
    post-and-hold provisions were not preempted because they “do not compel any
    agreement” among wholesalers, but only individual action. 
    Id. at 170.
    The
    Court stated: “The schedules required to be filed by the wholesalers are their
    individual acts.” 
    Id. And the
    Battipaglia plaintiffs (a liquor store owner and a
    wholesaler) had not alleged that “any agreement among the wholesalers” arose
    as a result of these laws. 
    Id. Battipaglia addressed
    and rejected two arguments the plaintiffs had made
    for preemption.
    13
    Battipaglia addressed two other issues not presented here. It discussed—but
    did not resolve—whether, if the New York law were in conflict with § 1, it was
    nonetheless insulated from attack by the “state action” doctrine of Parker v.
    Brown, 
    317 U.S. 341
    (1943). See 
    Battipaglia, 745 F.2d at 176
    –77. And it addressed
    whether, if the New York law were in conflict with § 1, the state’s important
    policy interests warranted deference under § 2 of the Twenty-First Amendment.
    
    Id. at 177–79
    (holding that, on the case record, such deference was warranted).
    28
    First, the Court distinguished California Retail Liquor Dealers Ass’n v. Midcal
    Aluminum, 
    445 U.S. 97
    (1980), which, like 324 Liquor, had held preempted a state
    statute that “created a resale price maintenance system for wine.” 
    Battipaglia, 745 F.2d at 170
    ; see also 
    id. at 171
    (describing California statute as having forced “all
    persons at various levels of the chain of distribution . . . to establish identical
    prices fixed by the brand owner for each brand of wine” and stating that this
    type of “vertical control” was impermissible under § 1). In contrast, the Court
    stated, New York’s post-and-hold provisions “plainly are not a resale price
    maintenance scheme.” 
    Id. at 172.
    And, the Court again noted, the New York law
    did not constrain wholesalers, each of which “is completely free to file whatever
    price schedule he desires.” 
    Id. As Judge
    Friendly put the point: “Midcal simply
    did not deal with a statute like New York’s which merely requires wholesalers to
    post and adhere to their own unilaterally determined prices and nothing more.”
    
    Id. Second, the
    Court addressed the argument that the post-and-hold law gave
    rise to a per se violation of § 1 because (1) it “forces each wholesaler to inform
    other wholesaler[s] of its prices and then to adhere for a month to them (or a
    lowered price meeting that of a competitor filed within three days)” and (2) “if
    this had been done pursuant to an agreement [among wholesalers], the
    29
    agreement would have constituted a violation of § 1.” 
    Id. Rejecting this
    argument, the Court reiterated that § 1 “is directed only at joint action and does
    not prohibit independent business actions and decisions.” 
    Id. (internal citations
    omitted).
    The Court then paused on the conceptual issue of whether, to be
    preempted by § 1, a state law must compel an actual agreement among
    competitors. The Court described as “appealing” the reasoning that:
    Section 1 requires an agreement, state compulsion of individual
    action is the very antithesis of an agreement, and the argument that
    an agreement could have been inferred if the wholesalers had
    voluntarily done what they been compelled to do is simply too ‘iffy.’
    
    Id. at 173.14
    At the same time, the Court acknowledged “some force” to the
    counterargument: that “a statute compelling conduct which, in its absence,
    would permit the inference of an agreement unlawful under § 1 is inconsistent
    with that section.” 
    Id. In the
    end, the Court stated, there was no need to resolve
    this conceptual issue. That was because the New York law did not meet the Rice
    standard for preemption. 
    Id. 14 As
    support for this view, the Court cited a district court decision finding
    against preemption and rejecting the argument that “simply because the statute
    compelled individual actions which, if taken pursuant to an agreement, might
    have constituted a violation,” the statute was preempted. 
    Id. at 173
    (quoting U.S.
    Brewers Ass’n, Inc. v. Healy, 
    532 F. Supp. 1312
    , 1329–30 (D. Conn.), rev’d on other
    grounds, 
    692 F.2d 275
    (2d Cir. 1982), aff’d, 
    464 U.S. 909
    (1983)).
    30
    Rice, the Court emphasized, had held that “[a] state regulatory scheme is
    not pre-empted by the federal antitrust laws simply because in a hypothetical
    situation a private party’s compliance with the statute might cause him to violate
    the antitrust laws.” 
    Id. at 174
    (quoting 
    Rice, 458 U.S. at 659
    ). Rather, under Rice, a
    state law could be “condemned under the antitrust laws only if it mandates or
    authorizes conduct that necessarily constitutes a violation of the antitrust laws in
    all cases, or if it places irresistible pressure on a private party to violate the
    antitrust laws in order to comply with the statute.” 
    Id. (quoting Rice
    , 458 U.S. at
    661). New York’s statute did not do that, the Court stated, because the only
    conduct that it compelled—“the exchange of price information” among
    competitors—does not “constitute a violation of the antitrust laws in all cases.”
    
    Id. at 174
    . Such an exchange might or might not signify an agreement among
    them. See 
    id. at 175
    (“[T]he dissemination of price information is not a per se
    violation of the Sherman Act.” (quoting United States v. Citizens & S. Nat’l Bank,
    
    422 U.S. 86
    , 113 (1975) (internal citations omitted)). That the post-and-hold law
    might result in common wholesaler pricing did not support inferring an
    agreement either, the Court stated. Absent “plus factors” signifying an
    agreement, “conscious parallelism” among competitors did not equate to an
    agreement. 
    Id. (citations omitted).
    31
    The Battipaglia Court concluded:
    Section 101-b thus does not mandate or authorize conduct that
    necessarily constitutes a violation of the antitrust laws in all cases.
    New York wholesalers can fulfill their obligations under the statute
    without either conspiring to fix prices or engaging in consciously
    parallel pricing. So, even more clearly, the New York law does not
    place irresistible pressure on a private party to violate the antitrust
    laws in order to comply with it. It requires only that, having
    announced a price independently chosen by him, the wholesaler
    shall stay with it for a month.
    
    Id. (internal quotation
    marks omitted).
    In dissent, Judge Winter faulted Judge Friendly’s majority opinion for
    dwelling on the “post” component of New York’s law and paying too little heed
    to the law’s “hold” component. Were competitors to enter into an agreement to
    hold their prices in place for 30 days, he observed, such a private agreement
    would be horizontal price fixing and per se illegal. 
    See 745 F.2d at 179
    –80 (Winter,
    J., dissenting). The Fourth and Ninth Circuits, the only two circuit courts to
    address similar laws, have sided with Judge Winter. Each has emphasized that
    the statutory requirement of adherence to posted prices, were it adopted by
    private agreement, would be per se illegal price fixing. See Costco Wholesale Corp.
    v. Maleng, 
    522 F.3d 874
    (9th Cir. 2008) (holding Washington provisions
    preempted by § 1); Miller v. Hedlund, 
    813 F.2d 1344
    (9th Cir. 1987) (holding
    Oregon provisions not exempt from § 1 and remanding the case to the district
    32
    court for a determination whether the Twenty First Amendment shielded the
    challenged regulations); TFWS, Inc. v. Schaefer, 
    242 F.3d 198
    , 210 (4th Cir. 2001)
    (holding Maryland provisions preempted by § 1, while reserving on whether,
    under the Twenty First Amendment, Maryland’s regulatory interests with
    respect to alcohol trumped federal interest under the Sherman Act); see also 1
    Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 217, at 388–89 &
    nn.45–53 (4th ed. 2013) (reviewing reported decisions, including lower court
    decisions in each direction).
    2.     Battipaglia Controls Here
    We find Battipaglia controlling authority here.
    Connecticut’s post-and-hold provisions are substantially identical to the
    New York post-and-hold provisions upheld in that case. Total Wine does not
    contend otherwise. Both sets of provisions required the wholesaler to set and
    publicly file a price that it is going to charge the retailer; both provided a brief
    time window in which wholesalers may match a lower price set by a competitor;
    and both required the wholesaler to hold that price for one month.
    Further, as the above discussion reflects, the Court in Battipaglia considered
    at length the § 1 preemption question in the face of similar arguments to those
    Total Wine makes here. The Court applied the controlling standards, from Rice,
    33
    to these provisions. The Court held that the post-and-hold provisions did not
    “mandate or authorize conduct ‘that necessarily constitutes a violation of the
    antitrust laws in all cases’” or “place[ ] irresistible pressure on a private party to
    violate the antitrust laws in order to comply” with it. 
    Id. at 175
    (quoting 
    Rice, 458 U.S. at 661
    ). Those are the questions presented here.
    Finally, Total Wine has not identified any later precedent of the Supreme
    Court or this Court that fairly calls Battipaglia’s vitality into question.
    Total Wine argues that 324 Liquor and our decision in Freedom 
    Holdings, 357 F.3d at 223
    (Winter, J.) are such precedent. A footnote in 324 Liquor suggested
    that a statute need not bring about an actual agreement between private parties
    to be preempted by § 1. See 324 
    Liquor, 479 U.S. at 345
    –46 n.8 (rejecting New
    York’s defense that provisions at issue had not yielded a “contract, combination,
    or conspiracy in restraint of trade”). Freedom Holdings picked up on that footnote
    to suggest, in a footnote of its own, that “an actual ‘contract, combination, or
    conspiracy’ need not be shown for a state statute to be preempted by the
    Sherman Act.” 
    See 357 F.3d at 223
    n.17 (Winter, J.) (citing 324 
    Liquor, 479 U.S. at 345
    –46 n.8). Total Wine argues, on account of these statements, that these
    decisions vitiate Battipaglia.
    For three reasons, they do not.
    34
    First, Freedom Holdings itself distinguished Battipaglia and treated it as good
    law. Freedom Holdings recognized that, although the Battipaglia majority had
    discussed whether a state law must give rise to an actual agreement for § 1 to
    preempt it, Battipaglia ultimately did not resolve nor rule on the basis of that
    conceptual issue. Rather, Battipaglia had relied on its application of the Rice
    standard to New York’s post-and-hold provision. See 
    id. (recognizing that
    Battipaglia “did not reach the question” whether “a private contract, combination,
    or conspiracy” must be shown for Sherman Act preemption to occur (internal
    citation omitted)).
    Second, to the extent that Freedom Holdings and 324 Liquor opine on
    whether the state law at issue must give rise to an actual private agreement for
    there to be preemption, these cases are readily distinguished factually because
    they involved express or readily implied agreements. Freedom Holdings involved
    an express contract among horizontal competitors—a “Master Settlement
    Agreement” among major tobacco manufacturers pursuant to which the
    challenged New York legislation had been enacted. Freedom 
    Holdings, 357 F.3d at 208
    . Its discussion of whether the state law must give rise to such an agreement
    was, therefore, dicta. See 
    id. at 224
    (“Even if a ‘contract’ among private parties is
    required in the first step of preemption analysis, therefore, it exists in the present
    35
    matter.”). As for 324 Liquor, it addressed vertical restraints affecting a
    wholesaler-retailer relationship. In that context, the wholesaler and each of its
    retailers were in privity and necessarily had an agreement to buy from and/or
    sell to each another. They entered into these agreements against the backdrop
    (and presumably with the knowledge) of the price-fixing term that state law
    would supply. In fact, every Supreme Court case to hold state liquor laws
    preempted by § 1, has done so on the ground that these laws either mandated or
    authorized forms of then per se unlawful vertical price-fixing arrangements
    between wholesalers and retailers. See, e.g., Midcal, 
    445 U.S. 97
    (California law
    mandated resale price maintenance among wholesaler and its retailers); 324
    Liquor, 
    479 U.S. 335
    (same as to New York law); Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert
    Distillers Corp., 
    341 U.S. 384
    (1951) (same as to Louisiana law per an interpretation
    of § 1 as amended by the now-repealed Miller-Tydings Act). Of course, as noted
    earlier, the application of preemption doctrine to vertical price fixing
    arrangements has been overtaken by Leegin’s removal of vertical restraints from
    per se condemnation.
    Third, and finally, two post-Battipaglia decisions of the Supreme Court,
    each involving claims of horizontal price-fixing, lend support to Judge Friendly’s
    reasoning in finding against preemption. One, Fisher, discussed earlier, does so
    36
    by narrowing the scope of state action within § 1’s preemptive reach. The other,
    Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 
    550 U.S. 544
    (2007), does so by underscoring the
    limited scope of private conduct capable of per se violating § 1.
    Fisher, as noted, upheld Berkeley’s rental-cap ordinance in the face of a § 1
    preemption claim that it brought about horizontal price fixing. The Supreme
    Court recognized that “[h]ad the owners of residential rental property in
    Berkeley voluntarily banded together to stabilize rents in the city,” that concerted
    activity would have worked a per se violation of § 1. 
    Fisher, 475 U.S. at 266
    . But,
    the Court emphasized, more was required. There needed to be concerted action.
    “A restraint imposed unilaterally by government does not become concerted-
    action within the meaning of the statute simply because it has a coercive effect
    upon parties who must obey the law.” 
    Id. at 267.
    “[T]he mere fact that all
    competing property owners must comply with the same provisions of the
    Ordinance is not enough to establish a conspiracy among landlords.” 
    Id. This requirement
    is significant here. We do not take issue with the holding
    of the district court here that, given the participation that a post-and-hold law
    requires of each wholesaler in connection with the posting component,
    37
    Connecticut’s law, viewed as a whole, qualifies as hybrid under Fisher.15 But we
    doubt that such a law mandates or authorizes “concerted action” among the
    wholesalers subject to it. Particularly as to the “hold” component of the law that
    was the basis of the Battipaglia dissent, Connecticut’s prohibition on altering
    prices for a 30-day period is a purely negative restraint. It does not call for any
    private action, let alone concerted action. See Hertz Corp. v. City of New York, 
    1 F.3d 121
    , 127 (2d Cir. 1993) (finding hybrid, but upholding, city statute that
    “eliminate[d] an element of price competition” among rental-car industry
    competitors); cf. Flying J, Inc. v. van Hollen, 
    621 F.3d 658
    , 662--63 (7th Cir. 2010)
    (“[I]t is only when a state law mandates or authorizes collusive conduct that it is
    preempted by federal antitrust law.” (citing 
    Fisher, 475 U.S. at 265
    )). Fisher’s
    emphasis on the need for concerted action reinforces that Judge Friendly was
    right both to focus on the posting, rather than the holding, component of New
    York’s post-and-hold law, and to find the law non-preempted.
    As to Twombly, although it is more commonly cited for its articulation of
    pleading standards, the Court in its substantive discussion homed in on the
    15
    In finding that the statute grants private actors “a degree of private regulatory
    power” so as to qualify as hybrid, 
    Fisher, 475 U.S. at 268
    , the district court relied
    on 324 Liquor, which had held hybrid a resale-price maintenance law with similar
    price-posting features. See Conn. Fine Wines & 
    Spirits, 255 F. Supp. 3d at 369
    .
    38
    discrete evil prohibited by § 1. “§ 1 of the Sherman Act does not prohibit [all]
    unreasonable restraints of trade.” 
    Twombly, 550 U.S. at 553
    . It prohibits “only
    restraints effected by a contract, combination, or conspiracy.” 
    Id. (emphasis added).
    The Court explained, therefore, that in § 1 cases, “[t]he crucial question is
    whether the challenged anticompetitive conduct stem[s] from independent
    decision or from an agreement.” 
    Id. (internal citations
    omitted). Even conscious
    parallel acts based on competitors’ mutual recognition of “shared economic
    interests” are not “’in [themselves] unlawful.’” 
    Id. at 553--54
    (quoting Brooke Grp.
    Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 227 (1993)); see also United
    States v. Apple, Inc., 
    791 F.3d 290
    , 315 (2d Cir. 2015) (“[P]arallel behavior that does
    not result from an agreement is not unlawful even if it is anticompetitive.”). In
    other words, under § 1, that conscious parallel conduct can create an equally
    uncompetitive market to parallel conduct achieved by agreement is of no
    moment. The gravamen of § 1 is an agreement among competitors.
    On this basis, Twombly upheld the dismissal of a complaint that alleged
    consciously parallel decisions among recently deregulated telecommunications
    carriers not to compete in one another’s (horizontal) regional markets. The
    complaint had not alleged actual agreement among the carriers, and its
    allegations were consistent with “natural” and “unilateral” behavior by each
    39
    carrier, as each had good reason to appreciate that its self-interest lay in
    forebearing from initiating competition. 
    See 550 U.S. at 564
    , 566; see also 
    id. at 568
    (“[The carriers] doubtless liked the world the way it was, and surely knew the
    adage about him who lives by the sword. Hence, a natural explanation for the
    noncompetition alleged is that the former Government-sanctioned monopolists
    were sitting tight, expecting their neighbors to do the same thing.”)
    Twombly’s reasoning resonates here because, under a post-and-hold law,
    there is a “natural” explanation—independent of any agreement or coordination
    among liquor wholesalers—for these competitors to arrive at common monthly
    product prices. Such a law authorizes a wholesaler, during the four days after
    initial posting, to match a competitor’s lower price, with such prices then held for
    a month. Under these circumstances, the law itself invites and facilitates
    conscious parallelism in pricing. It puts in public view each competing
    wholesaler’s price quotes. And it authorizes, but it does not oblige, wholesalers
    during a defined window unilaterally to match (or parallel) a competitor’s lower
    price as the “held” price for the coming month. Nothing about this arrangement
    requires, anticipates, or incents communication or collaboration among the
    competing wholesalers. Quite the contrary: A post-and-hold law like
    Connecticut’s leaves a wholesaler little reason to make contact with a competitor.
    40
    The separate, unilateral acts by each wholesaler of posting and matching instead
    are what gives rise to any synchronicity of pricing. To mirror Twombly: “[A]
    natural explanation for the noncompetition alleged,” 
    id. at 568
    , is that the state-
    regulated wholesalers are independently making pricing decisions within a
    framework aimed at avoiding price wars that invites them, before being held to a
    price for a month, to match that of their competitors. A post-and-hold law,
    therefore, does not implicate the evil against which § 1 guards: an agreement to
    unreasonably restrain trade. It would make little sense to preempt a state statute
    which facilitates parallel conduct that parties can legally undertake on their own
    under § 1.
    Under these circumstances, we do not find reason to conclude that
    Battipaglia has been, sub silentio, overruled. If anything, its reasoning has been
    fortified by intervening decisions like Fisher and Twombly. Battipaglia therefore
    controls Total Wine’s challenge to Connecticut’s post-and-hold provisions. See
    United States v. Moore, 
    949 F.2d 68
    , 71 (2d Cir. 1991) (prior opinions of a Second
    Circuit panel bind future panels “in the absence of a change in the law by higher
    authority” or a ruling by the en banc Court). Any application to revisit Battipaglia
    is beyond this panel’s authority. Battipaglia remains good—and persuasive—law.
    41
    CONCLUSION
    For the reasons above, we affirm the decision below. We hold that the
    challenged provisions of Connecticut law governing liquor pricing are not
    preempted by § 1 of the Sherman Act.
    42