ASCAP v. MobiTV, Inc. ( 2012 )


Menu:
  • 10-3161-cv(L)
    ASCAP v. MobiTV, Inc.
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT
    August Term 2011
    Heard: October 11, 2011                              Decided: May 22, 2012
    Docket Nos. 10-3161-cv(L), -3310-cv(CON)
    - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
    AMERICAN SOCIETY OF COMPOSERS, AUTHORS AND
    PUBLISHERS,
    Defendant-Appellant,
    v.
    MOBITV, INCORPORATION, f/k/a/ IDETIC,
    INCORPORATION,,
    Appellee.
    - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -
    Before: NEWMAN and LYNCH, Circuit Judges, and RESTANI,* Judge, U.S.
    Court of International Trade.
    Appeal from the July 6, 2010, judgment of the United States
    District Court for the Southern District of New York (Denise Cote,
    District       Judge),        setting     royalty    for   blanket   public   performance
    license      for        music    in    the   ASCAP   repertory   that   is    embodied   in
    television and radio content to be delivered to viewers and listeners
    using mobile telephones. In re Application of MobiTV, Inc., 712 F.
    Supp. 2d 206 (S.D.N.Y. 2010).
    *
    Honorable Jane A. Restani, of the United                          States   Court   of
    International Trade, sitting by designation.
    Affirmed.
    Ira M. Feinberg, Hogan Lovells US LLP,
    New York, N.Y. (Eleanor M. Lackman,
    Chava Brandriss, Hogan Lovells US LLP,
    New York, N.Y.; Catherine E. Stetson,
    Hogan Lovells US LLP, Washington, D.C.;
    Joan M. McGivern, Richard H. Reimer,
    Christine A. Pepe, ASCAP, New York,
    N.Y.;   David  Leichtman,   Hillel   I.
    Parness, Bryan J. Vogel, Oren D.
    Langer, Robins, Kaplan, Miller & Ciresi
    L.L.P., New York, N.Y., on the brief),
    for Defendant-Appellant.
    Kenneth L. Steinthal, Greenberg Traurig,
    LLP, San Francisco, Cal. (Joseph R.
    Wetzel, Harris L. Cohen, Matthew L.
    Reagan, Greenberg Traurig, LLP, San
    Francisco, Cal., on the brief), for
    Appellee.
    (Michael E. Salzman, Hughes Hubbard &
    Reed LLP, New York, N.Y.; Marvin L.
    Berenson, John Coletta, Joseph J.
    DiMona, Broadcast Music, Inc., New
    York, N.Y., for amicus curiae Broadcast
    Music, Inc., in support of Defendant-
    Appellant.)
    (Bruce G. Joseph, Andrew G. McBride, Wiley
    Rein LLP, Washington, D.C., for amicus
    curiae Cellco Partnership d/b/a Verizon
    Wireless, in support of Appellee.)
    JON O. NEWMAN, Circuit Judge.
    This appeal concerns determination of the proper royalty the
    Defendant-Appellant   American   Society   of   Composers,   Authors   and
    Publishers (“ASCAP”) is entitled to receive for a blanket public
    -2-
    performance license for music in the ASCAP repertory that is embodied
    in television and radio content to be delivered to viewers and
    listeners using mobile telephones (sometimes called “handsets”).           The
    applicant for the license is Plaintiff-Appellee MobiTV, Inc. (“Mobi”),
    which   purchases   programming    from    cable   television   networks   and
    transmits it to the wireless carriers to which consumers subscribe to
    obtain wireless service on their handsets. When the parties could not
    agree on a price for the performance rights to the music component of
    Mobi’s offerings, ASCAP sought a reasonable rate in the District Court
    for the Southern District of New York, acting as a rate court pursuant
    to a consent decree.      Following a bench trial, the District Court
    (Denise Cote, District Judge) issued a judgment on July 7, 2010,
    establishing various royalty rates, depending on the nature of the
    programming, and designating the revenue bases to which those rates
    apply. See In re Application of MobiTV, Inc., 
    712 F. Supp. 2d 206
    (S.D.N.Y. 2010) (“MobiTV”).         ASCAP appeals, contending that the
    District Court’s rate formulation should have been based on the retail
    revenues received    by   the   wireless   carriers   from   sales   to their
    customers, rather than the content providers’ wholesale revenues paid
    by Mobi.   We affirm.
    Background
    A. ASCAP
    -3-
    ASCAP represents about half of the nation’s composers and music
    publishers. These composers grant to ASCAP the non-exclusive right to
    license public performances of their music.1          ASCAP has an estimated
    8.5 million musical works in its repertoire. Because of concerns that
    ASCAP’s size grants it monopoly power in the performance-rights
    market, it is subject to a judicially-administered consent decree, the
    most recent version of which was entered into on June 11, 2001.2
    United States v. ASCAP, No. 41-1395. 
    2001 WL 1589999
    , at *1 (S.D.N.Y.
    June 11, 2001).      Under this Second Amended Final Judgment (“AFJ2"),
    ASCAP    is   required   to   issue   a   “Through-to-the-Audience”   (“TTTA”)
    license to any operator “that transmits content to other music users
    with whom it has an economic relationship relating to that content.”
    AFJ2 § V.      A TTTA license effectively allows the licensee to pay a
    single fee in exchange for the right of the licensee, as well as any
    1
    The bundle of rights created by American copyright law includes
    the “exclusive right[] to do and to authorize . . . perform[ance of]
    the copyrighted work publicly.”     17 U.S.C. § 106.   Although most
    aspects of a copyright are typically owned by the studio or company
    commissioning the musical composition, it is customary to allow
    composers and music publishers to retain this “public performance”
    right. In order for music to be legally performed, the prospective
    user must first acquire a license for this public performance right.
    2
    Broadcast Music, Inc. (“BMI”) represents most of the remaining
    composers in the American market. It operates under a consent decree
    similar to ASCAP’s. See United States v. BMI (Application of Music
    Choice), 
    316 F.3d 189
    , 190 (2d Cir. 2003).
    -4-
    of its downstream partners, to perform any of the music in ASCAP’s
    repertoire.   Thus, for example, a radio broadcaster that transmits
    music to various independent stations around the country could request
    a TTTA license to cover the performances of any of the stations
    receiving and playing its programming.    The consent decree provides
    that “[t]he fee for a [TTTA] license shall take into account the value
    of all performances made pursuant to the license.”    
    Id. The AFJ2 obliges
    ASCAP to issue a TTTA license to any qualified
    applicant seeking to perform ASCAP music within the United States.
    
    Id. Upon request, ASCAP
    must quote a reasonable price for such a
    license and enter into negotiations with the applicant. AFJ2 § IX(A).
    If, following a predetermined negotiation period, the parties are
    unable to reach agreement, either one may request the District Court
    for the Southern District of New York, acting as “the rate court,” to
    determine a reasonable rate.
    B. Mobi
    Mobi acts as a middleman between “content providers” – television
    networks, record labels, and radio broadcasters – and wireless phone
    carriers.   To do that, Mobi aggregates content – television programs,
    music videos, and the like – into a number of “channels” (with themes
    such as “news,” “music,” and “comedy”) that wireless carriers then
    offer to their customers as part of their phone subscription plans.
    -5-
    In addition to aggregating content, Mobi also provides the technology
    infrastructure for delivering this content directly to viewers.3
    Mobi’s primary offerings may be roughly divided into three types:
    television   channels,   radio   channels,    and   music   video   channels.4
    Television channels consist of programs and clips acquired directly
    from the networks.       Radio channels are acquired from audio-only
    content providers, such as National Public Radio, ESPN Radio, or DMX,
    Inc (“DMX”).    Music video channels feature music videos that Mobi
    acquires from various record labels.         In the case of television and
    radio channels, Mobi has little control over the content that is
    ultimately placed into the channel by the content provider.            In the
    case of music videos, Mobi acts as a content provider itself by
    acquiring and assembling individual music videos into themed channels
    3
    Mobi’s technology infrastructure is directed to transferring
    large amounts of data quickly and fluidly over mobile phone networks.
    Mobi provides this “back-end” infrastructure to a number of carriers
    for whom it does not provide any content.      In   those cases, the
    wireless carrier acquires content directly from the networks, record
    labels, and other content providers and uses Mobi’s infrastructure to
    the deliver that content.
    4
    Depending on the type of content it provides, a given channel may
    be offered in a live, clip-linear, or video-on-demand (“VOD”) format.
    Live content is streamed directly from the networks and is the most
    popular and expensive content available from Mobi.          Clip-linear
    content delivers a repeating sequence, or “loop”, of programming set
    by the content provider and refreshed periodically.        VOD content
    allows the customer to select a particular program or clip and watch
    that piece of content immediately.
    -6-
    designed and marketed by Mobi.
    Payments to Mobi from the wireless carriers.            Television, radio,
    and music video content may be packaged for consumption in one of two
    ways.       First, groups of channels may be packaged for “à la carte”
    selection, for which wireless phone customers pay a monthly fee,
    usually around $10. Second, content may be “bundled” with other types
    of non-Mobi products and services and sold to the customer as part of
    a larger offering.         When Mobi’s products are sold as part of a bundle,
    it receives a flat dollar figure per subscriber per month based on the
    relative value of the Mobi service to the bundle.              In the latter case,
    Mobi does not know how much the carrier received for the sale.                   In
    both       types   of    packaging,   payments   are   not   affected   by   whether
    subscribers actually use any of Mobi’s content.5
    In addition to the revenue from carriers for packaged content,
    Mobi also earns a small amount of income from advertising that it
    inserts into its channels.            This revenue may be retained solely by
    Mobi       or   shared   with   the   wireless   carriers    pursuant   to   license
    agreements.
    Payments from Mobi to content providers.                 For the right to
    5
    Mobi markets its services as a way to help drive demand for more
    expensive data plans, which are lucrative to the carriers.
    -7-
    distribute content to the wireless carriers, Mobi generally pays the
    networks and other content providers a per-subscriber fee.   The size
    of the fee, which Mobi negotiates with each content provider, depends
    on the popularity of the channel.    Although Mobi’s revenue-to-cost
    ratio had been improving steadily in 2008, as of 2008 it had never
    made a profit.
    C. Procedural History
    In November 2003, Mobi applied to ASCAP for a TTTA license for a
    “service that allows mobile handset users to access television and
    other content by aggregating television and other audio-visual content
    for transmission over telecommunications networks.”   Failing to reach
    agreement over an appropriate rate, ASCAP applied to the District
    Court in May 2008 for “a reasonable fee retroactive to the date of the
    written request for a license.”
    In the proceedings in the District Court, ASCAP contended that it
    was entitled to over $41 million in fees for the period between 2003
    and 2011.6 Mobi contended that it owed only $301,257.99 for the period
    from November 2003 to July 2009.
    When a party applies to the District Court to set a reasonable
    6
    In its appellate brief, ASCAP contends that the portion of this
    fee attributable to the period from November 2003 to July 2009 was
    approximately $15.8 million.
    -8-
    rate for an ASCAP license, the AFJ2 requires that court to first
    assess the reasonableness of the fee quoted by ASCAP.                       AFJ2 § IX(B),
    (D).       During this phase of the proceedings, ASCAP bears the burden of
    establishing the reasonableness of its proposed fee.                        
    Id. If ASCAP fails
    to meet its burden, the District Court must “determine a
    reasonable fee based upon all the evidence.”                      AFJ2 § IX(D).
    The     District      Court’s     rejection     of       ASCAP’s   fee     proposals.
    Pursuant to          the   AFJ2,   the   District Court          first    considered, and
    rejected, ASCAP’s fee proposals.7                  ASCAP had proposed a fee formula
    that used as a starting point the revenues wireless carriers received
    from their customers.            In a thorough review, 
    Mobi, 712 F. Supp. 2d at 236-244
    ,       the    District     Court    identified      a    number    of   errors   and
    deficiencies in that methodology.                  Among these were the unrealistic
    size of ASCAP’s starting revenue base ($54 billion), 
    id. at 239, the
    inclusion in that figure of large sums of revenues unrelated to the
    value of       Mobi’s      products,     including    the revenues         earned    by the
    wireless       carriers       on    their     primary       services       of     telephonic
    7
    ASCAP made two different fee proposals in the court below. The
    same formula was employed in each proposal, the principal distinction
    being whether the wireless carriers would share some of the burden of
    paying for the resulting fee. See 
    Mobi, 712 F. Supp. 2d at 243
    .
    -9-
    communications and Internet access, 
    id. at 240-41, the
    use of faulty
    calculations, 
    id. at 240-41, the
    use of a high royalty rate (2.5
    percent) based on an non-analogous benchmark, 
    id. at 242, and
    the
    large size of the resulting fee, 
    id. Notably, the District
    Court
    implicitly rejected the proposition that wireless carrier retail
    revenues from their customers could be used as a base for a rate
    calculation:
    In sum, ASCAP has not carried its burden of showing that its
    proposed fee for a TTTA license for Mobi is reasonable. It
    has not shown that it located a revenue base with a
    sufficient nexus to content “sourced” by Mobi within the
    wireless carriers’ revenue base or that it is entitled to a
    fee built upon any broader revenue base.      Because ASCAP
    chose a vastly inflated revenue base it faced the Herculean
    task of contracting that base through a series of
    calculations.    Each of those layers of calculations was
    laden with unsupported and faulty assumptions. The final
    fee request was a demonstrably unreasonable number. . . .
    And, of course, as the discussion of the complexity of the
    [ASCAP] calculations illustrates, the adoption of this vast
    revenue base, along with the layers of calculations required
    to reduce it to a fee proposal, imposes enormous transaction
    costs on the parties that are entirely out of line with the
    commercial realities faced by both ASCAP and all but perhaps
    the very largest communications companies in America.
    
    Id. at 244. The
    District Court’s fee formula.   After rejecting ASCAP’s fee
    proposals, the District Court proceeded, as provided in the consent
    decree, to “determine a reasonable fee based upon all the evidence.”
    AFJ2 § IX(D).   In setting a reasonable rate, the District Court
    -10-
    largely credited Mobi’s fee expert and adopted Mobi’s proposed fee
    structure.    The District Court’s formula differs from ASCAP’s in
    several important respects.
    First, the District Court declined to use the wireless carriers’
    retail revenue from their customers as the base for the royalty
    calculations.      Instead, for programming obtained from television
    networks, it used Mobi’s costs, i.e., the amount it pays to content
    providers    for   content,   plus   any   revenue   derived   by   Mobi   from
    advertising inserted into that content. 
    Mobi, 712 F. Supp. 2d at 246-
    47.8   For programming obtained from record labels (music videos), the
    Court used Mobi’s revenues, i.e., the amount it receives from wireless
    carriers for its services, again along with advertising income. See
    
    id. at 247. Second,
    the District Court used ASCAP’s suggested rate of 2.5
    percent only for all-audio channels. See 
    id. at 248. For
    audio-visual
    content, it applied the rates used in benchmark agreements between
    ASCAP and the cable television industry. See 
    id. at 247-48. The
    District Court followed these benchmarks in applying rates of 0.9
    percent to music-intensive programming (e.g., music video channels),
    8
    One result of taking Mobi’s costs as the revenue base, as the
    District Court recognized, was that ASCAP received no fee for some
    programming that content providers offered to Mobi for free. 
    Mobi, 712 F. Supp. 2d at 250-51
    .
    -11-
    0.375 percent to general entertainment content, and 0.1375 percent to
    news and sports content. See 
    id. at 255. The
    result of these calculations was a judgment setting a fee of
    $405,000 for     the    period   from   November    2003    through    March   2010,
    substantially less than ASCAP’s proposed fee of $15.8 million for a
    somewhat shorter period.9
    Discussion
    A. Standard of Review
    On an appeal from a rate determination, this Court reviews the
    District Court’s factual findings for clear error and its conclusions
    of   law   de   novo.   See    United   States     v.    ASCAP   (Applications   of
    RealNetworks, Inc. and Yahoo! Inc.), 
    627 F.3d 64
    , 76 (2d Cir. 2010)
    (“In order to find that the rate set by the District Court is
    reasonable,     we   must     find   both   that   the    rate   is   substantively
    reasonable (that it is not based on any clearly erroneous findings of
    fact) and that it is procedurally reasonable (that the setting of the
    rate, including the choice and adjustment of a benchmark, is not based
    on legal errors).”). We have likened this distinction to that between
    the admissibility of evidence (a question of law) and an evaluation of
    the persuasive force of that evidence (a question of fact). See ASCAP
    9
    The District Court’s fee structure was also intended to govern
    the parties’ relationship through the end of the statutory contract
    period, i.e., through 2011.
    -12-
    v. Showtime/The Movie Channel, Inc., 
    912 F.2d 563
    , 569 (2d Cir. 1990).
    When setting an appropriate rate, the District Court must attempt
    to approximate the “fair market value” of a license – what a license
    applicant would pay in an arm’s length transaction. See United States
    v. BMI (Application of Music Choice), 
    316 F.3d 189
    , 194 (2d Cir. 2003)
    (“Music Choice II”).      In many cases, “the appropriate royalty rate” –
    i.e., the fair market value of the license – “is determined by
    applying the appropriate percentage rate to the fair market value of
    the music.”     
    Id. at 195 (emphasis
    supplied).      In so doing, the rate-
    setting court must take into account the fact that ASCAP, as a
    monopolist, exercises market-distorting power in negotiations for the
    use of its music. See 
    RealNetworks, 627 F.3d at 76
    .
    B. Rejection of ASCAP’s proposal
    ASCAP does not contend on appeal that the District Court erred in
    rejecting its royalty proposal.10         Instead it devotes its entire
    argument   to   claimed    deficiencies   in   the   District   Court’s   own
    determination, pursuant to the AFJ2, of a reasonable royalty.              We
    therefore limit our discussion to those alleged deficiencies.
    10
    Toward the end of its brief ASCAP asserts that the District
    Court “erred in rejecting ASCAP’s proposed methodology outright as
    unreasonable,” Brief for Appellant at 44, but this statement simply
    continues the argument that the District Court should not have based
    a royalty rate on wholesale revenues; it is not a claim that ASCAP’s
    proposal should have been adopted.
    -13-
    C. Alleged Deficiencies in the District Court’s Royalty Determination
    The District Court’s royalty determination began with selection
    of a revenue base to which the Court applied different percentage
    rates depending on the category of programming.       ASCAP’s primary
    contention on appeal is that the Court selected an incorrect revenue
    base.
    1. The appropriate revenue base
    The District Court used as a revenue base “the wholesale price
    for the musical content,” 
    MobiTV, 712 F. Supp. 2d at 247
    .    At first
    glance, this phrase might seem to involve circular reasoning: the
    revenue base is being selected to determine what Mobi must pay ASCAP
    for the right to perform ASCAP music, but what Mobi must pay ASCAP
    might also be called “the wholesale price for the musical content.”
    But, as used by the District Court, that is not what the phrase means.
    In fact, the phrase has two other meanings depending on whether Mobi
    is licensing content from content providers (typically television
    networks) or obtaining music videos from record labels.     The Court
    explained its revenue base in these words:
    For the programming that Mobi licenses from content
    providers, aggregates, and conveys to wireless carriers, the
    revenue base shall be the amounts that Mobi pays to the
    cable television networks or other providers to license the
    content, plus any revenue from advertising Mobi inserts into
    that programming, including revenue that is shared with
    wireless carriers or potentially content suppliers. For the
    -14-
    music videos that Mobi obtains from record labels, programs
    into music video channels, and then provides to the
    carriers, the revenue base will be the revenue that Mobi
    receives from the wireless carriers for this programming,
    plus any revenue from advertising Mobi inserts into that
    programming, including revenue that is shared with wireless
    carriers or potentially content providers.
    
    Id. (emphases added). As
    can readily be seen, both revenue bases use wholesale revenue,
    in one case the wholesale revenue that the cable television networks
    receive from Mobi and in the other case the wholesale revenue that
    Mobi receives from the wireless carriers.   In neither case is retail
    revenue used, i.e., the revenue the wireless carriers receive from the
    handset customers.
    At the outset, we can put aside one aspect of ASCAP’s challenge,
    which is merely a semantic quibble.      ASCAP repeatedly faults the
    District Court for using Mobi’s “cost” or “costs” to obtain rights,
    see Brief for Appellants at 30, 33.     The District Court focused on
    revenue, either the content providers’ revenue from Mobi or Mobi’s own
    revenue from record labels.   Obviously, with respect to programming
    from content providers, the providers’ revenue from Mobi is the same
    as Mobi’s payment of costs to those providers.     The labeling is a
    matter of perspective, not substance.
    ASCAP’s fundamental objection is that the revenue base should
    have been retail revenue received downstream in the distribution chain
    -15-
    by the     wireless   carriers   from    their   customers,   rather   than the
    wholesale revenue received upstream by the content providers from
    Mobi.     We consider first the adequacy of the District Court’s reasons
    for using the content providers’ revenue and then ASCAP’s complaint,
    which is based primarily on this Court’s decision in Music Choice II.
    The District Court’s reasons for using wholesale revenues.             The
    District Court expressed several reasons for using wholesale revenues
    as “the appropriate revenue base from which to measure the value of
    the public performance of the music at issue here.” MobiTV, 712 F.
    Supp. 2d at 246.       First, the Court explained that “[p]ricing the
    public performance right at the time the content is first sold gives
    direct and immediate feedback to content producers about the value of
    a component of their product.” 
    Id. Second, the Court
    accepted the
    concept of what       Mobi’s   expert,   Professor Roger      G.   Noll, called
    “derived demand”:11
    Mobi has shown that the value of the public performance
    of the music at the retail level is indeed captured at the
    wholesale level, not just theoretically by the concept of
    derived demand, but also functionally from the fact that the
    cable television networks principally generate their
    revenues by measuring the number of subscribers for their
    programming. To the extent that a channel’s content becomes
    11
    Noll explained in his 83 page declaration that “[t]he
    relationship between final product markets and the demand for inputs
    is called the theory of derived demand, and for the case of variable
    factor proportions was first developed in John R. Hicks, The Theory of
    Wages, MacMillan (1932).” Noll Declaration 47 n.40.
    -16-
    popular among consumers, the seller of content demands a
    higher rate of compensation from advertisers and from
    purchasers of the content.     And, Mobi’s payments to the
    cable television networks for the programming it distributes
    are driven by the subscriber data that Mobi tracks and
    conveys to the networks.
    
    Id. Third, the District
      Court   pointed   out   the   administrative
    advantages of using wholesale revenue:
    [T]he administrative advantages of basing a rate on
    wholesale revenue are amply illustrated in this case by the
    challenges that ASCAP’s expert sought to surmount as she
    endeavored to construct calculations that might result in a
    reasonable fee and to justify those calculations.     Fully
    appreciating that the retail revenue base vastly overstates
    the value of the public performance of the musical
    composition, since it reflects so many inputs that bear
    little or no relation to that content, she designed layers
    of formulae to reduce the retail revenue base. At each step
    of the process, those formulae raised a multitude of
    questions about their intellectual rigor, fairness, and the
    cost and burden associated with their implementation.
    
    Id. Fourth, the District
    Court relied on two factors that our Court
    in Music Choice II had pointed out counsel against using retail
    revenues as a revenue base:
    This is a case in which many of the retail customers pay a
    single fee for a bundle of programming, making it difficult
    to determine what part of the fees is paid for music. Music
    Choice 
    II, 326 F.3d at 195
    n.2. And the digital revolution,
    which has turned handsets into computers and permitted
    television programming to be included among the many
    innovative products to which a consumer has immediate and
    constant access, makes it an extremely complex task to tease
    -17-
    out one component of the retail price and identify the
    extent to which retail price is driven by the musical
    content of the television programming. 
    Id. at 196 n.3.
    MobiTV, 712 F. Supp. 2d at 246-47
    .
    ASCAP challenges the District Court’s reasons for using wholesale
    revenues as the royalty base by disputing the validity of Prof. Noll’s
    use of the principle of derived demand. See Brief for Appellant at 33-
    36.    Prof. Noll justified his use of that principle, which the
    District Court accepted, in these words:
    If consumers value musical performances more highly, they
    will increase their purchases of musical performances, which
    in turn will cause the derived demand      for content that
    contains music to increase. The resulting increase in sales
    of content that contains music will lead to higher payments
    for rights holders even if the royalty rate is unchanged.
    Noll Declaration 45.      He gave three reasons for using wholesale
    revenue as the appropriate base:
    First, using the revenue of the channel supplier leads to
    royalties that are most closely connected to the intensity
    of music use. Second, basing royalties on the revenue of
    the channel supplier also avoids unreliable and expensive
    methods for allocating revenue among bundled products and
    services and to other inputs of retailers (here, the
    wireless carriers). Third, the revenue of channel suppliers
    includes sources of revenue that accrue to the channel but
    not to the retailer, such as advertising that is inserted by
    the channel supplier.
    
    Id. at 48. Despite
      cross-examining   Prof.   Noll   in   120   pages   of   trial
    transcript, ASCAP failed to provide the District Court with any basis
    -18-
    for discounting, much less rejecting, his analysis.
    ASCAP’s challenge to wholesale revenues based on Music Choice II
    and IV.      The Music Choice litigation, see Music Choice II, 
    316 F.3d 189
    , and United States v. Broadcast Music, Inc. (Application of Music
    Choice), 
    426 F.3d 91
    (2d Cir. 2005) (“Music Choice IV”), concerned the
    appropriate royalty rate to be paid by Music Choice to Broadcast
    Music, Inc. (“BMI”), for a TTTA license for the performance rights to
    music   in    BMI’s   repertory.   Music    Choice   is   a   partnership   that
    transmits numerous music channels to listeners’ television sets via
    cable and satellite and to their computers via the Internet.                Like
    ASCAP, BMI is subject to a consent decree that designates the Southern
    District of New York as the rate court in the event of a royalty fee
    dispute. Music Choice 
    II, 316 F.3d at 190
    .           BMI urged the Court to
    follow an agreement between BMI and DMX, a competitor of Music Choice.
    Under that agreement, DMX paid BMI 3.75 percent (later 4 percent) of
    DMX’s wholesale revenue, which in this context meant the money paid by
    the cable or satellite operators to DMX for music programming. See 
    id. at 192. That
    rate was designed to be approximately double the rate
    previously applied to the retail revenues of the cable or satellite
    operators on the theory that these operators charged their retail
    customers approximately double what they were paying to the providers
    of the music programming. See 
    id. -19- The District
    Court in the Music Choice litigation ruled that a
    3.75 percent rate based on the wholesale revenues of Music Choice was
    not appropriate. See 
    id. at 193. The
    District Court explained that
    this rate had been used in the DMX contracts to approximate the use in
    previous contracts of a 2 percent rate of DMX’s wholesale revenues
    plus 2 percent of the cable or satellite operators’ retail revenues.
    Then the District Court reasoned that retail revenues did not reflect
    the fair market value of music because the subscriber paying the
    retail price was paying for materials and services not provided by the
    author of the music. See 
    id. at 194. The
    Court therefore deducted 2
    percentage points (the retail rate) from the 3.75 percent that had
    been applied to wholesale revenues and set 1.75 percent of wholesale
    revenues as the appropriate rate. See 
    id. This Court reversed.
    We faulted the District Court for rejecting
    retail revenues in determining an appropriate rate. See 
    id. at 195. In
    language embraced by ASCAP in the pending case, we said:
    As to the court’s rejection of retail revenues, absent some
    valid reason for using a different measure, what retail
    customers pay to receive the product or service in question
    (in this case, the recorded music) seems to us to be an
    excellent indicator of its fair market value. While in some
    instances there may be reason to approximate fair market
    value on the basis of something other than the prices paid
    by consumers, in the absence of factors suggesting a
    different measure the price willing buyers and sellers agree
    upon in arm’s length transactions appears to be the best
    measure.
    -20-
    It is true without doubt that to make the music
    available to its customers, the retail seller must incur
    expenses for various processes and services not provided by
    the owner of the music, such as the laying of cable, the
    establishment of satellite systems, etc. However, this is
    in no way incompatible with the proposition that retail
    revenues derived from the sale of music fairly measure the
    value of the music.    The customer pays the retail price
    because the customer wants the music, not because the
    customer wants to finance the laying of cable or the
    launching of satellites.
    
    Id. (citation and footnote
    omitted).
    In the pending case, we are of course obliged to follow the
    holding of Music Choice II, which was that the District Court had
    erred by reducing a percentage rate that had been applied to wholesale
    revenues by the rate previously applied to retail revenues.               Nothing
    of that sort occurred in our case.           Of course, ASCAP urges us to heed
    not   merely   the   holding   of   Music     Choice   II   but   its   language,
    particularly the observation that “what retail customers pay to
    receive the product of service in question (in this case, the recorded
    music) seems to us to be an excellent indicator of its fair market
    value.”   For several reasons we conclude that the quoted words do not
    compel a reversal of the District Court’s decision in this case.
    First, the quoted words were preceded by the important qualifying
    phrase “absent some valid reason for using a different measure.”               In
    the pending case, the District Court had a very valid reason for using
    -21-
    a   different   measure:     the   unimpeached        testimony       of   Prof.   Noll
    explaining several reasons why wholesale revenue was far superior to
    retail revenue as a basis for a royalty rate in this case.
    Second,   in   Music    Choice    II     our   Court    added    a   significant
    footnote, observing that “where the customers pay a single fee for a
    package of audio and visual programming, which includes the music, it
    will be difficult to determine what part of the fees paid was for the
    music, as opposed to other programming.” 
    Id. at 195 n.2.
                         That is
    precisely the sort of “bundling” that occurs with Mobi’s transmission
    of programming to wireless carriers.            The wireless carriers typically
    offer Mobi’s television products as part of a bundle of services that
    also includes Internet access and text messaging, and then charge a
    single data plan fee for the whole bundle.            As ASCAP’s fee proposal to
    the District Court illustrated, separating out the relative value of
    each individual product is fraught with methodological difficulty.
    ASCAP’s   proposal   was     premised   on     the   notion    that    the   value   of
    different products in the bundle could be determined based upon how
    much data each product used.            As the District Court noted, this
    proposal made the essentially arbitrary assumption “that a consumer
    would pay the same amount of money to receive a kilobyte of text
    messaging as a kilobyte of television programming, even though a
    kilobyte might give a consumer several back-and-forth exchanges of
    -22-
    text messages but only the briefest glimpse of an image from a
    television program.” 
    MobiTV, 712 F. Supp. 2d at 241
    .   ASCAP’s failure
    to develop a rational formula for valuing the component parts in the
    bundle of products sold by the wireless carriers confirms the wisdom
    of the District Court’s decision to reject the use of a retail base in
    this case.   The products bundled by Mobi differed considerably from
    the programming channels in Music Choice II, which were essentially
    audio channels devoted exclusively to music.
    Third, although not disagreeing with the holding of Music Choice
    II, we are not persuaded that its contention that “retail revenues
    derived from the sale of the music fairly measure the value of the
    music,” 
    id. at 195, is
    universally true.   Indeed, an example offered
    in that opinion seems to undermine that assertion.        The example
    concerned purchasers of music on a compact disc sold for $12.       Music
    Choice II noted that the purchasers
    were not motivated to spend their money to pay the salaries
    of truck drivers, warehousemen, bookkeepers, office
    administrators, salespersons and executives, all of whom
    played necessary roles in bringing the record to market.
    What the customers wanted was a record of certain music, and
    they were willing to pay $12 to get it.
    
    Id. (emphasis added). At
    an earlier time, the customer who wanted to hear the music in
    that example had a choice between a then-novel compact disc and an
    -23-
    old-fashioned vinyl plastic record, which (unless it had value as a
    rarity) would have sold for considerably less than the $12 for the CD.
    True, the purchaser was not motivated to pay the salaries of all the
    personnel whose efforts made possible the production and delivery of
    the CD (or the vinyl record), but preference for a CD would have
    resulted in payment of a higher price than for a record, even though
    both contained the same music.            The retail price of the CD was
    reflecting not just the value the purchaser assigned to the music but
    also the value assigned to the mode of delivery of that music.               In
    another significant footnote, Music Choice II acknowledged this very
    fact:
    If it were demonstrated that retail purchasers were
    motivated to pay more because of advantages that resulted
    from a particular mode of delivery, such as better quality,
    better accessability or whatever, this might justify a
    conclusion that retail price of the service purchased by the
    customer exceeded the fair market value of the music.
    
    Id. at 196 n.3.
          Whether or not in some contexts the retail price of
    a product containing music is a good measure of the fair market value
    of the music, the District Court in the pending case, on the record
    before it, did not err in concluding that the retail price paid by
    customers for     a   service   that   delivers   video   and   audio   channels
    containing music to their handsets is not a good measure of the value
    -24-
    of the music itself.12
    ASCAP’s challenge to wholesale revenues based on uncompensated
    rights.        ASCAP also faults the District Court’s use of wholesale
    revenues because such use fails to provide any compensation to ASCAP
    in the few instances where Mobi acquired programming without paying
    anything to content providers.       Prof. Noll recognized that this would
    occur     in   some   instances   because   a   new    channel   trying   to   get
    established sometimes cannot command any price, and providers of such
    content would rather offer it for free in order to have it included in
    a package of bundled content.          He explained, however, that such a
    channel would either disappear for lack of an audience or achieve an
    audience, in which event the popularity of its programming would
    subsequently be reflected in the later revenues that content providers
    could demand, thereby increasing ASCAP’s royalty for the benefit of
    the music composers. See Trial Tr. 985-88.            Either way, the temporary
    use of free content would not undermine the overall reasonableness of
    the District Court’s royalty determination.              As the District Court
    12
    Although our Court’s decision in Music Choice IV noted that the
    District Court in that litigation “should not have rejected the retail
    price of music as an indication of its fair market 
    value,” 426 F.3d at 95
    , it also acknowledged that “in spite of our endorsement of retail
    price as generally a good marker for fair market value, we did not
    require it to be used in all circumstances, but only absent some valid
    reason for using a different measure,” 
    id. at 97 (internal
    quotation
    marks omitted).
    -25-
    explained, “The market for television content has spoken, and this
    content would receive no airing at all through a wireless distribution
    platform unless the content were provided for free and given the
    opportunity to build a 
    base.” 712 F. Supp. 2d at 251
    .
    2. ASCAP’s Remaining Objections
    ASCAP’s   remaining   objections     were   properly   rejected   by   the
    District Court.      For clarification, we discuss briefly two such
    matters.
    ASCAP contends that the District Court erred in failing to “test”
    the resulting fee for reasonableness.         Although the size of the fee is
    clearly relevant to its reasonableness, there is no requirement that
    the District Court explicitly engage in a testing of the fee resulting
    from its formula.     On the contrary, the AFJ2 requires only that the
    District Court “determine a reasonable fee.”           AFJ2 § IX(D).
    ASCAP also contends that the District Court erred by failing to
    include the value of licenses for content acquired by others but
    streamed to customers using Mobi’s back-end technology infrastructure.
    Such   content   would   include,   for     example,   television   programming
    acquired by Sprint directly from the networks, and then provided to
    its customers using Mobi’s servers and patented technology.               ASCAP
    argues that Mobi is required to obtain a performance license for all
    unlicensed content that it streams, regardless of whether it has been
    -26-
    assured by its upstream partner that such a license has already been
    procured.   This objection also lacks merit.   If an upstream content
    provider has already acquired a TTTA license from ASCAP, it would be
    unfair to require Mobi to make a second payment for the same content.
    See United States v. ASCAP (In re Application of AT&T Wireless), 
    607 F. Supp. 2d 562
    , 570-71 (S.D.N.Y. 2009).        Furthermore, Mobi is
    entitled to rely on its upstream partner’s assurances that it is
    protected – and to manage the accompanying risk that the partner has
    not obtained the promised right.13   ASCAP, for its part, retains the
    power to protect its rights by bringing an infringement action against
    Mobi or any other party.   As a result, the District Court did not err
    by construing the license to exclude such content.
    Conclusion
    For the foregoing reasons, the judgment of the District Court is
    affirmed.
    13
    Mobi   would,  presumably,    manage this  risk  through  an
    indemnification agreement or similar arrangement with the upstream
    provider.
    -27-