Hanover 3201 Realty, LLC v. Village Supermarkets, Inc. ( 2015 )


Menu:
  •                                          PRECEDENTIAL
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    No. 14-4183
    HANOVER 3201 REALTY, LLC,
    Appellant
    v.
    VILLAGE SUPERMARKETS, INC.; ABC
    CORPORATIONS 1-10 (names being fictitious and unknown
    but described as those corporations associated with Village
    that assisted with and promoted the use of sham litigations
    and anti-competitive acts); JOHN DOES 1-10 (names being
    fictitious and unknown but described as those individuals
    associated with Village that assisted with and promoted the
    use of sham litigations and anti-competitive acts);
    HANOVER AND HORSEHILL DEVELOPMENT LLC
    _____________
    On Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the District of New Jersey
    (D.C. Civ. No. 2-14-cv-01327)
    District Judge: Honorable Stanley R. Chesler
    _____________
    Argued: June 18, 2015
    Before: AMBRO, FUENTES, and GREENBERG, Circuit
    Judges
    (Opinion Filed: November 12, 2015)
    John M. Agnello, Esq.
    James E. Cecchi, Esq.
    Lindsey H. Taylor, Esq. [ARGUED]
    Carella Byrne Cecchi Olstein Brody & Agnello
    5 Becker Farm Road
    Roseland, NJ 07068
    Attorneys for Appellant, Hanover 3201 Realty, LLC
    Anthony Argiropoulos, Esq. [ARGUED]
    Thomas Kane, Esq.
    Epstein Becker & Green
    One Gateway Center
    Newark, NJ 07102
    David W. Fassett, Esq.
    Arseneault & Fassett
    560 Main Street
    Chatham, NJ 07928
    Attorneys for Appellees, Village Supermarkets, Inc. and
    Hanover and Horsehill Development LLC
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    FUENTES, Circuit Judge, with whom AMBRO, Circuit
    Judge, joins as to Parts II.A.2, II.B, and II.C, and
    GREENBERG, Circuit Judge, joins as to Part II.A.
    2
    Hanover 3201 Realty, LLC (“Hanover Realty”) signed
    a contract with Wegmans to develop a supermarket on its
    property in Hanover, New Jersey. The agreement required
    Hanover Realty to secure all necessary governmental permits
    and approvals prior to breaking ground.                Village
    Supermarkets, Inc. (“ShopRite”) owns the local ShopRite.
    Once ShopRite and its subsidiary Hanover and Horsehill
    Development LLC (“H&H Development”) (collectively,
    “Defendants”) caught wind that Wegmans might be entering
    the market, they filed numerous administrative and court
    challenges to Hanover Realty’s permit applications.
    Believing these filings were baseless and intended only to
    frustrate the entry of a competitor, Hanover Realty sued
    Defendants for antitrust violations. Hanover Realty alleged
    that Defendants attempted to restrain the market for full-
    service supermarkets as well as the market for full-service
    supermarket rental space. The District Court dismissed the
    suit, holding that Hanover Realty did not have antitrust
    standing because it was the wrong plaintiff—it was not a
    competitor, consumer, or participant in the restrained markets
    and thus did not sustain the type of injury the antitrust laws
    were intended to prevent. 1
    We conclude that, with respect to the claim for
    attempted monopolization of the market for full-service
    supermarkets, the District Court took too narrow a view of
    antitrust injury. Hanover Realty can establish that its injury
    1
    For the reasons set forth in Part III of Judge Ambro’s partial
    concurrence, I agree with Judge Ambro’s decision to use an
    “issue voting” approach to determine the outcome of the
    judgment in this case.
    3
    was      “inextricably    intertwined”     with    Defendants’
    anticompetitive conduct. However, as to the claim for
    attempted monopolization of the market for rental space, the
    District Court correctly found no standing because Hanover
    Realty does not compete with Defendants in that market. We
    also hold that Hanover Realty has sufficiently alleged that the
    petitioning activity here was undertaken without regard to the
    merits of the claims and for the purpose of using the
    governmental process to restrain trade. As such, Hanover
    Realty can demonstrate that Defendants are not protected by
    Noerr-Pennington immunity because their conduct falls
    within the exception for sham litigation. Accordingly, we
    will affirm in part, vacate in part, and remand to the District
    Court for further proceedings.
    4
    I.    BACKGROUND
    Plaintiff Hanover Realty is a real estate developer and
    the owner of a plot of land in Hanover, New Jersey.2 In July
    2012, Hanover Realty entered into a lease and site-
    development agreement with Wegmans for the purpose of
    constructing a “full-service supermarket.” App. 66. These
    types of supermarkets, in contrast to their local grocery store
    counterparts, provide customers with a “one-stop shopping”
    experience. App. 67. Full-service supermarkets supply not
    only traditional groceries, but also additional amenities,
    including prepared foods to go, on-site dining options, wine
    and liquor, specialty products, and other services such as
    pharmacies, banks, and fitness centers. The site-development
    agreement placed the burden on Hanover Realty to obtain all
    necessary governmental permits prior to beginning
    construction. If Hanover Realty was unable to secure the
    required permits within two years of the agreement,
    Wegmans could walk away from the deal.
    Defendant ShopRite is the proprietor of 26 ShopRite
    supermarkets in New Jersey, including a ShopRite in Hanover
    that is about two miles away from the site of the proposed
    Wegmans. The ShopRite opened in November 2013 and
    replaced the previous one in Morris Plains, which has since
    closed. Defendant H&H Development, a wholly-owned
    subsidiary of ShopRite, owns the property on which the
    Hanover ShopRite sits, and leases the land or building to
    2
    Unless otherwise indicated, the facts are taken from the
    amended complaint, documents relied upon in that complaint,
    and matters of public record. See Schmidt v. Skolas, 
    770 F.3d 241
    , 249 (3d Cir. 2014).
    5
    ShopRite. ShopRite and H&H Development have the same
    decision makers. Hanover Realty alleges that the ShopRite in
    Hanover is the only full-service supermarket operating in the
    greater Morristown area.
    Once news broke that Wegmans was coming to town,
    Defendants launched a petitioning campaign designed to
    block Hanover Realty from obtaining the permits and
    approvals it needed to proceed with the project. We describe
    these filings here.
    First, Hanover Realty applied for a Flood Hazard Area
    Permit (“Flood Permit”) from the New Jersey Department of
    Environmental Protection (“Environmental Department”).
    After Hanover Realty received the permit, ShopRite (on
    behalf of itself and H&H Development) submitted an appeal
    to the Environmental Department requesting an adjudicatory
    hearing and seeking an order that would vacate the permit.
    Defendants asserted that they had standing to bring the appeal
    because the then-existing ShopRite in Morris Plains would be
    “detrimentally impacted” by the competition from the
    Wegmans. App. 74. Over the next five months, Defendants
    submitted additional documents to the Environmental
    Department, including an objection that Hanover Realty
    failed to comply with relevant notice requirements and an
    amended request for an adjudicatory hearing.
    About a month after Hanover Realty filed its amended
    complaint in this action, the Environmental Department
    issued an order denying Defendants’ request for a hearing. It
    first found that ShopRite had no standing, explaining that
    “[c]ourts have consistently held that proximity or any type of
    generalized property right shared with other property owners
    such as recreational interests, traffic, views, quality of life,
    6
    and property values are insufficient to demonstrate a
    particularized property right required to establish third party
    standing for a hearing.” App. 157. ShopRite’s “generalized
    property rights” and its claim of “greater competition” from
    the proposed Wegmans were not enough to show that it was
    an aggrieved party. The Environmental Department also
    evaluated the substance of Defendants’ arguments and found
    them without merit.
    Second, Hanover Realty submitted a multi-permit
    application to the Environmental Department seeking various
    wetlands approvals (“Wetlands Permit”) for the Wegmans
    project. An ecological consulting firm sent a letter to the
    Environmental Department on behalf of Defendants raising
    various challenges to this permit. One objection was that
    Hanover Realty’s notice to neighboring landowners was
    “technically deficient.” App. 77. In response to this
    objection, and as “required” by the Environmental
    Department, Hanover Realty corrected this “administrative
    error” the next week and submitted a revised application.
    App. 169. The ecological consultant also voiced its concern
    that the site of the proposed Wegmans was a potentially
    suitable habitat for certain endangered species, including the
    Indiana bat.3 A few days later, Defendants submitted another
    letter to the Environmental Department, this time requesting a
    meeting to discuss the Wetlands Permit and “strongly
    3
    Indiana bats may be found over a broad swath of the United
    States, including New Jersey. But true to name, half of this
    bat population does, in fact, hibernate in Indiana. See Indiana
    Bat Fact Sheet, U.S. Fish & Wildlife Service,
    http://www.fws.gov/midwest/endangered/mammals/inba/inba
    fctsht.html (last visited Aug. 13, 2015).
    7
    urg[ing]” it to “diligently and prudently” review the permit
    and not act with “haste” in granting approval. App. 78. In
    the following months, Defendants’ ecological consultant
    complained to the United States Fish and Wildlife Service
    about the Wetlands Permit. In one email to the Wildlife
    Service, the consulting firm praised itself for “manag[ing] to
    delay the issuance of the [Wetlands] approvals based on a
    technicality” and said that its substantive objections “may
    delay things a bit longer.” App. 80. Hanover Realty
    responded to Defendants’ multifaceted challenge with its own
    submissions, explaining why, in its view, each objection was
    unsubstantiated. Moreover, Hanover Realty alleges that
    Defendants knew the wetlands at issue are not federally
    regulated waters, but nonetheless contacted the Wildlife
    Service to add friction to the review process.
    The Environmental Department issued Hanover Realty
    its requested Wetlands Permit, subject to various conditions.
    One such condition required Hanover Realty to conduct a
    survey for the presence of Indiana bats prior to construction.4
    After the Environmental Department issued the permit,
    Defendants submitted a request for an adjudicatory hearing to
    challenge the approval.5
    Third, the tract of land owned by Hanover Realty has
    been the subject of several contracts and sales over the years,
    4
    In its appellate brief, Hanover Realty informs us that it
    conducted the Indiana bat survey and no bats were found.
    5
    In a supplemental letter filed with the Court, Hanover Realty
    says that, in June 2015, the Environmental Department denied
    Defendants’ request for a hearing.
    8
    including a four-phased developer’s agreement with the New
    Jersey Department of Transportation that dates back to 1978.
    Under that agreement, the owner of the land must make
    certain road improvements as it reaches various phases of
    development. Hanover Realty believed the Wegmans project
    would trigger Phase III of the agreement. Consistent with
    that understanding, Hanover Realty submitted an application
    for a Major Street Intersection Permit (“Street Permit”) to the
    Department of Transportation in which it proposed
    improvements to a nearby intersection in connection with the
    Wegmans project. Defendants submitted a letter objecting to
    the application, and then proceeded to file a number of open
    public records requests seeking additional information upon
    which they could contest the application. Defendants then
    sent another letter to the Department of Transportation
    informing it that the Wegmans project would trigger Phase IV
    of the developer’s agreement. As a result, Defendants said,
    Hanover Realty was required to build an overpass over a
    nearby highway before it could proceed any further. Hanover
    Realty and its traffic engineering consultant submitted letters
    of their own, explaining that the Phase IV requirements
    (including the overpass) were not implicated by the Wegmans
    project. Hanover Realty alleges that Defendants knew the
    Phase IV obligations were not triggered because their counsel
    had negotiated the developer’s agreement.
    The Department of Transportation issued a letter
    responding to the parties’ various submissions relating to the
    Street Permit application. The letter began by acknowledging
    that the Department of Transportation is “required to consider
    any relevant data, analysis, and arguments submitted by third
    parties.” App. 165. It then agreed with Defendants that the
    proposed development would generate traffic at certain hours
    that would exceed the level of traffic contemplated by Phases
    9
    I, II, and III of the developer’s agreement. Moreover,
    although it did not specifically mention the overpass or
    whether Phase IV obligations would be implicated, the
    Department of Transportation said the Wegmans project
    “would trigger the need for additional highway improvements
    as stipulated in the [developer’s] agreement.” App. 167. It
    noted, however, that the “improvements may no longer be
    appropriate or feasible” and therefore recommended that
    Hanover Realty negotiate a modification to the agreement
    with the Department of Transportation. App. 167.6
    Fourth, in mid-2012, Hanover Realty applied to the
    Hanover Township Committee to rezone the property of the
    proposed Wegmans so that it could be used for retail space.
    The next summer, Hanover Realty received approval of its
    final site plan and request for a bulk variance. Defendants did
    not lodge any objections during that year-long process.
    Instead, in August 2013, ShopRite (on behalf of itself and
    H&H Development) filed an action in lieu of prerogative
    writs in New Jersey state court seeking to nullify the
    approval. Over the next several months, Defendants filed
    three amended complaints, which Hanover Realty alleges
    were filed for the purpose of delay.
    In June 2014, after Hanover Realty had filed its
    amended complaint in the present litigation, the Superior
    Court of New Jersey issued an order dismissing the
    prerogative writs action. The court found that ShopRite was
    6
    Hanover Realty informs us in a letter that, after
    renegotiating the developer’s agreement and otherwise
    revising its proposal, the Department of Transportation issued
    the Street Permit in April 2015.
    10
    not an “interested party” because it failed to allege facts
    suggesting its “right to use, acquire, or enjoy either of its
    nearby properties” would be affected by the approval of
    Hanover Realty’s site plan. App. 136. In addition, the court
    rejected ShopRite’s argument that it had standing based on its
    status as a local taxpayer. After ruling against ShopRite on
    the standing issue, the court also addressed and disposed of
    ShopRite’s arguments on the merits.
    Frustrated by Defendants’ many legal challenges,
    Hanover Realty sued Defendants in federal court. In its
    amended complaint, Hanover Realty alleges that Defendants’
    administrative objections and state-court suit were mere
    anticompetitive shams designed to keep Wegmans out of the
    market. Specifically, it asserts claims under Section 2 of the
    Sherman Act for attempted monopolization of and conspiracy
    to monopolize the greater Morristown full-service
    supermarket market (Count One) and the greater Morristown
    full-service supermarket shopping center market, which it
    describes as the market for supermarket rental space (Count
    Two). The amended complaint also contains five-state law
    claims.
    Defendants moved to dismiss the complaint for four
    independent reasons. The District Court found the threshold
    issue of antitrust standing dispositive and dismissed the
    complaint on that ground. It observed that, as a general
    matter, plaintiffs in antitrust suits must be either consumers or
    competitors of the defendant in the restrained market—here,
    the markets for supermarkets and supermarket rental space.
    Hanover Realty was neither a consumer nor competitor of
    Defendants in either market.               The District Court
    acknowledged         the     limited     exception      to    the
    consumer/competitor requirement for persons whose injuries
    11
    are “inextricably intertwined” with the harm caused by
    defendants. But it found Hanover Realty did not fit within
    that narrow exception either. As a result, Hanover Realty had
    suffered no antitrust injury and thus had no antitrust standing
    to pursue its Sherman Act claims.7 Without a federal claim in
    play, the District Court declined to exercise supplemental
    jurisdiction over the state-law claims. Hanover Realty
    appealed.8
    II.    DISCUSSION
    Defendants raise four arguments in support of the
    District Court’s order: (1) Hanover Realty does not have
    antitrust standing; (2) Defendants’ petitioning activity was
    protected by the Noerr-Pennington doctrine; (3) Hanover
    Realty has not sufficiently alleged that there is a dangerous
    probability of Defendants achieving monopoly power; and
    (4) Hanover Realty has failed to plead a specific intent to
    monopolize.
    7
    The District Court also dismissed the parts of Counts One
    and Two that assert a conspiracy to violate the Sherman Act
    because Hanover Realty failed to allege the particulars of this
    conspiracy. As Hanover Realty does not challenge this
    finding on appeal, we affirm the dismissal of Counts One and
    Two to the extent they contain conspiracy claims.
    8
    The District Court had jurisdiction under 
    15 U.S.C. § 15
     and
    
    28 U.S.C. §§ 1331
     and 1367, and we have jurisdiction to
    review the District Court’s final order under 
    28 U.S.C. § 1291
    . We review de novo a district court’s grant of a
    motion to dismiss and construe all facts in the light most
    favorable to the nonmoving party. See Rea v. Federated
    Investors, 
    627 F.3d 937
    , 940 (3d Cir. 2010).
    12
    A.     Antitrust Standing
    We begin with antitrust standing. Section 2 of the
    Sherman Act prohibits any attempt to monopolize. 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    . Section 4 of the Clayton Act, in turn, defines the class of
    persons who may bring a private antitrust suit as “any person”
    who is injured “by reason of anything” prohibited by the
    antitrust laws. 
    Id.
     § 15(a). This extraordinarily broad
    language reflects the Clayton Act’s remedial purpose and
    Congress’s intent to “create a private enforcement mechanism
    that would deter violators and deprive them of the fruits of
    their illegal actions, and would provide ample compensation
    to the victims of antitrust violations.” Blue Shield of Va. v.
    McCready, 
    457 U.S. 465
    , 472 (1982). Emphasizing § 4’s
    expansive reach, the Supreme Court has explained that the
    “statute does not confine its protection to consumers, or to
    purchasers, or to competitors, or to sellers. . . . The Act is
    comprehensive in its terms and coverage, protecting all who
    are made victims of the forbidden practices by whomever
    they may be perpetrated.” Id. (quoting Mandeville Island
    Farms, Inc. v. Am. Crystal Sugar Co., 
    334 U.S. 219
    , 236
    (1948)).
    Although a literal reading of § 4’s grant of authority to
    sue arguably is limited only by the minimal requirements of
    constitutional standing, the Supreme Court has interpreted
    this provision more restrictively than that. See Hawaii v.
    Standard Oil Co. of Cal., 
    405 U.S. 251
    , 262 n.14 (1972)
    (“Congress did not intend the antitrust laws to provide a
    remedy in damages for all injuries that might conceivably be
    traced to an antitrust violation.”). Thus, even when there is a
    clear violation of the antitrust laws, § 4 allows only a “proper
    plaintiff” to bring a private suit to remedy that violation. See
    13
    Associated Gen. Contractors of Cal., Inc. v. Cal. State
    Council of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
    , 544 (1983). In other
    words, only certain plaintiffs have “antitrust standing.” 
    Id.
     at
    535 n.31. In describing how to undertake the antitrust
    standing inquiry, the Supreme Court has warned that, because
    of the “infinite variety of claims” that may arise under § 4, a
    “black-letter rule” cannot dictate the result in every case. Id.
    at 536. Instead, the Court has articulated several guideposts.
    See id. at 536-57. We have distilled these antitrust standing
    factors as follows:
    (1) the causal connection between the antitrust
    violation and the harm to the plaintiff and the
    intent by the defendant to cause that harm, with
    neither factor alone conferring standing; (2)
    whether the plaintiff’s alleged injury is of the
    type for which the antitrust laws were intended
    to provide redress; (3) the directness of the
    injury, which addresses the concerns that liberal
    application of standing principles might
    produce speculative claims; (4) the existence of
    more direct victims of the alleged antitrust
    violations; and (5) the potential for duplicative
    recovery or complex apportionment of
    damages.
    In re Lower Lake Erie Iron Ore Antitrust Litig., 
    998 F.2d 1144
    , 1165-66 (3d Cir. 1993) (citing Associated Gen., 
    459 U.S. at 545
    ). Although we weigh these factors together on a
    case-by-case basis, the second factor, antitrust injury, “is a
    necessary but insufficient condition of antitrust standing.”
    Barton & Pittinos, Inc. v. SmithKline Beecham Corp., 
    118 F.3d 178
    , 182 (3d Cir. 1997).
    14
    Antitrust injury has proven difficult to define and
    apply. The Supreme Court has described it as “injury of the
    type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows
    from that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful.”
    Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    ,
    489 (1977). In evaluating the nature of a plaintiff’s injury,
    the Supreme Court instructs us to keep in mind that “the
    Sherman Act was enacted to assure customers the benefits of
    price competition” and “protect[] the economic freedom of
    participants in the relevant market.” Associated Gen., 
    459 U.S. at 538
    . Based on these principles, we have said that,
    “[a]s a general matter, the class of plaintiffs capable of
    satisfying the antitrust-injury requirement is limited to
    consumers and competitors in the restrained market . . . and to
    those whose injuries are the means by which the defendants
    seek to achieve their anticompetitive ends.” W. Penn
    Allegheny Health Sys., Inc. v. UPMC, 
    627 F.3d 85
    , 102 (3d
    Cir. 2010) (citing cases). As Hanover Realty offers distinct
    theories of injury for each of its attempted monopolization
    claims—one for the market for full-service supermarkets
    (Count One) and another for the market for full-service
    supermarket rental space (Count Two)—we discuss these
    claims separately.
    1.     Full-Service Supermarkets
    Hanover Realty admits it is neither a competitor nor a
    consumer in the market for full-service supermarkets; it is a
    land owner and lessor of property, not a food retailer. It
    instead argues that its injuries were “inextricably intertwined”
    with Defendants’ attempt to monopolize that market.
    The Supreme Court first recognized this form of
    antitrust injury in McCready. McCready was an employee
    covered by a group health plan purchased from the defendant
    15
    Blue Shield. McCready, 
    457 U.S. at 468
    . Under the plan,
    Blue Shield agreed to reimburse subscribers such as
    McCready for services provided by psychiatrists, but not by
    psychologists. McCready was treated by a psychologist and
    sought reimbursement for her bills, but Blue Shield denied
    payment. She then filed suit against Blue Shield and a
    psychiatric society alleging that the two had engaged in an
    unlawful antitrust conspiracy to exclude psychologists from
    receiving payment under the Blue Shield plan. 
    Id. at 469
    .
    The defendants argued that McCready had not suffered
    antitrust injury because the alleged conspiracy was directed at
    psychologists and not at subscribers of group health plans.
    
    Id. at 478
    . The Supreme Court rejected the defendants’ view
    of antitrust standing, explaining that the § 4 “remedy cannot
    reasonably be restricted to those competitors whom the
    conspirators hoped to eliminate from the market.” Id. at 479.
    Although McCready was not a competitor of the defendants,
    “the injury she suffered was inextricably intertwined with the
    injury the conspirators sought to inflict on psychologists and
    the psychotherapy market.” Id. at 483-84 (emphasis added).
    And while McCready was a consumer in the market for
    psychotherapy services, the Supreme Court’s explanation of
    why she suffered antitrust injury emphasized not her status as
    a market participant, but rather that she was directly targeted
    for harm by parties ultimately wishing to inflict a derivative
    harm on a competitor. As the Court noted, “[d]enying
    reimbursement to subscribers for the cost of treatment was the
    very means by which it is alleged that Blue Shield sought to
    achieve its illegal ends.” Id. at 479. The harm to subscribers
    like McCready was not only clearly foreseeable, “it was a
    necessary step in effecting the ends of the alleged illegal
    conspiracy.” Id.
    16
    Underscoring that its reasoning was not limited to
    consumers, the Court offered the following hypothetical to
    crystalize the nature of McCready’s injury: “If a group of
    psychiatrists conspired to boycott a bank until the bank
    ceased making loans to psychologists, the bank would no
    doubt be able to recover the injuries suffered as a
    consequence of the psychiatrists’ actions.” Id. at 484 n.21.
    McCready and the bank “are in many respects similarly
    situated,” the Court explained, even though the bank is not a
    customer or consumer in the psychotherapy market. See id.
    Both were used as conduits to harm the defendants’ actual
    competitors. Because imposing harm on McCready was an
    indispensable aspect of the scheme, the Court concluded that
    the injury to McCready
    “reflect[ed] Congress’ core concerns” in prohibiting the
    defendants’ conduct. Id. at 481.
    In contrast to McCready, where the alleged harm to the
    plaintiff was the primary means of the defendants’
    anticompetitive conduct, harm that is secondary to the
    anticompetitive conduct cannot support antitrust injury. For
    example, we have said that, “[a]lthough a supplier may lose
    business when competition is restrained in the downstream
    market in which it sells goods and services, such losses are
    merely byproducts of the anticompetitive effects of the
    restraint,” and do not qualify as antitrust injury. W. Penn
    Allegheny, 627 F.3d at 102. To illustrate, in Ethypharm S.A.
    France v. Abbott Laboratories, 
    707 F.3d 223
    , 225-26 (3d Cir.
    2013), a foreign drug manufacturer, Ethypharm, used a
    domestic distributor to sell one of its drugs in the United
    States market. After Abbott, the distributor of another drug,
    sued the domestic distributor for patent infringement,
    Ethypharm sued Abbott for antitrust violations. We rejected
    the notion that Ethypharm’s injury was inextricably
    17
    intertwined with the alleged scheme. See id. at 237. To
    effectuate its conspiracy, Abbott needed only to place
    restrictions on Ethypharm’s domestic distributor and thus any
    harm suffered by Ethypharm was incidental, rather than
    essential, to the restraint on trade. See id. at 233. Similarly,
    in Broadcom Corp. v. Qualcomm, Inc., 
    501 F.3d 297
    , 319-20
    (3d Cir. 2007), the plaintiff’s asserted basis for antitrust
    standing was that the defendant’s restraint in one market
    injured it by suppressing the demand of participants in the
    restrained market for the plaintiff’s supply of goods in
    another market. As in Ethypharm, we said the alleged injury
    was not inextricably intertwined with the anticompetitive
    scheme because it crossed markets and was attenuated from
    the anticompetitive conduct. See 
    id. at 320-21
    . Together,
    Ethypharm and Broadcom support the proposition that
    suppliers and other non-market participants generally do not
    have antitrust standing unless their injuries were the very
    means by which the defendants carried out their illegal ends.
    As we said in West Penn Allegheny, “[a]s a general matter,
    the class of plaintiffs capable of satisfying the antitrust-injury
    requirement is limited to consumers and competitors in the
    restrained market . . . and to those whose injuries are the
    means by which the defendants seek to achieve their
    anticompetitive ends.” 627 F.3d at 102 (emphasis added).
    Because Hanover Realty alleges that its harm was the
    essential component of Defendants’ anticompetitive scheme
    as opposed to an ancillary byproduct of it, we conclude that
    Hanover Realty has sufficiently pleaded antitrust injury under
    McCready. The ultimate objective of the defendants in
    McCready was to injure psychologists, not plan subscribers.
    To achieve that goal, they refused to reimburse subscribers
    for visits to psychologists, thereby encouraging subscribers to
    visit psychiatrists. Without injuring those subscribers, there
    18
    was no conspiracy. Likewise, McCready’s hypothetical bank,
    which was neither a consumer nor competitor in the
    psychotherapy market, sustained actionable injury because it
    was directly harmed as the means of injuring psychologists.
    Similar reasoning applies here. The end goal of
    Defendants’ alleged anticompetitive conduct was to injure
    Wegmans, a prospective competitor. To keep Wegmans out
    of the market, Defendants sought to impose costs not on their
    competitor, but on Hanover Realty, the party tasked with
    obtaining the necessary permits before construction could
    begin. Absent this relationship between Hanover Realty and
    Wegmans, Defendants’ conduct “would have been without
    purpose or effect.” Steamfitters Local Union No. 420 Welfare
    Fund v. Philips Morris, Inc., 
    171 F.3d 912
    , 923 (3d Cir.
    1999). And Defendants would succeed in their scheme either
    by inflicting such high costs on Hanover Realty that it was
    forced to abandon the project or by delaying the project long
    enough so that Wegmans would back out of the agreement.
    In both scenarios, injuring Hanover Realty was the very
    means by which Defendants could get to Wegmans; Hanover
    Realty’s injury was necessary to Defendants’ plan.
    Had Wegmans purchased the property from Hanover
    Realty and itself applied for the permits, the costs imposed by
    Defendants’ challenges would have qualified as antitrust
    injuries. It should make no difference that the parties’ lease
    shifted these costs to Hanover Realty. See McCready, 
    457 U.S. at 479
     (observing that antitrust injury “cannot reasonably
    be restricted to those competitors whom [defendants] hoped
    to eliminate from the market”). Regardless of who bore these
    costs, Defendants’ objective remained the same: to keep
    Wegmans out of the relevant market.
    19
    Defendants seize on language from our precedent
    saying “we have not extended the ‘inextricably intertwined
    exception beyond cases in which both plaintiffs and
    defendants are in the business of selling goods or services in
    the same relevant market,’ though they may not directly
    compete against each other.” See Ethypharm, 707 F.3d at 237
    (quoting Broadcom, 
    501 F.3d at 320-21
    ). According to
    Defendants, because Hanover Realty and ShopRite do not
    operate in the same market, “Hanover Realty cannot establish
    antitrust injury unless the Court were to break with
    Ethypharm and Broadcom and greatly expand the scope of
    the ‘inextricably intertwined’ exception—an expansion that
    would swallow the rule.” Appellees’ Br. at 19.
    Defendants read too much into these statements.9 As
    9
    We pause to note that at least one of our cases discussing
    antitrust injury contains language that is potentially
    overstated. In Barton & Pittinos, without mentioning the
    “inextricably intertwined” doctrine, we found no antitrust
    injury because the plaintiff was “not a competitor or a
    consumer in the market in which trade was allegedly
    restrained.” 
    118 F.3d at 184
    . We later cast doubt on that
    statement, clarifying that the conclusion in Barton, “if
    construed as an absolute (which arguably it need not be), may
    in some circumstances lead to results that conflict with
    Supreme Court and other precedent.” Carpet Grp. Int’l v.
    Oriental Rug Importers Ass’n, Inc., 
    227 F.3d 62
    , 76 (3d Cir.
    2000), overruled on other grounds, Animal Science Prods.,
    Inc. v. China Minmetals Corp., 
    654 F.3d 462
     (3d Cir. 2011).
    We, of course, agree with Carpet Group and our other cases
    that have allowed for the possibility of antitrust injury based
    on a showing of harm that is inextricably intertwined with the
    20
    an initial matter, just because we have not extended the
    exception beyond parties that sell goods or services in the
    same market by no means suggests we shouldn’t (or can’t )
    do so. In fact, McCready suggests the opposite conclusion.
    McCready did not sell goods or services in the psychotherapy
    market—she was a subscriber to a health insurance plan. Nor
    was the hypothetical bank in McCready even a participant in
    the psychotherapy market. Nonetheless, both sustained harm
    that was inextricably intertwined with the defendants’
    misconduct. Because § 4 “does not confine its protection to
    consumers, or to purchasers, or to competitors, or to sellers”
    we must avoid placing artificial limits on who may bring suit
    under the antitrust laws. McCready, 
    457 U.S. at 472
    (citations omitted). Moreover, our comments in Ethypharm
    and Broadcom must be read in context. As we discussed, the
    alleged injuries to the plaintiffs in those cases were
    byproducts of anticompetitive restraints in separate markets.
    In contrast, although Hanover Realty and ShopRite operate in
    separate markets, the very essence of Defendants’ scheme
    was to impose expense and delay on Hanover Realty as a
    means of keeping Wegmans out of the relevant market.
    Defendants’ final line of defense against a finding of
    antitrust injury rests on cases from other jurisdictions. In an
    industry notorious for low profit margins, perhaps it is not
    surprising that this is just the latest in a series of cases in
    which a supermarket allegedly employed anticompetitive
    tactics to keep a competitor out of the market.10 Defendants
    defendant’s wrongdoing, rather than harm just to competitors
    or consumers.
    10
    See, e.g., Serfecz v. Jewel Food Stores, 
    67 F.3d 591
     (7th
    Cir. 1995); Southaven Land Co. v. Malone & Hyde, Inc., 715
    21
    rely mostly on the Sixth Circuit’s decision in Southaven Land
    Co. v. Malone & Hyde, Inc., 
    715 F.2d 1079
    .
    Southaven was an owner-lessor of commercial space
    and Malone operated a number of grocery stores in the
    neighborhood. Southaven, 715 F.2d at 1080. Malone
    assumed a lease to premises owned by Southaven, but the
    parties later agreed to cancel the agreement. However, upon
    learning that Southaven intended to find a grocery store to fill
    the vacancy, Malone refused to cancel the contract. Malone
    continued to pay rent on the vacant lot and did not otherwise
    breach any of its contractual obligations. Id. at 1087.
    Southaven nonetheless sued for antitrust violations, alleging
    that Malone intended to leave the space vacant so as to
    destroy competition for its other grocery stores. The Sixth
    Circuit rejected Southaven’s argument that its injury was
    inextricably intertwined with the injury Malone sought to
    inflict on the grocery market. Id. at 1086-87. It explained
    that “Southaven [a real estate lessor] is not alleged to be a
    member of a class of ‘consumers’ of grocery products or a
    class otherwise manipulated or utilized by Malone as a
    fulcrum, conduit or market force to injure competitors or
    participants” in the relevant market. Id. at 1086. Rather,
    Southaven’s injury was, at most, a “tangential by-product” of
    the alleged monopolistic conduct. Id. at 1086-87.
    We do not find Southaven persuasive here because it
    addressed a different set of facts and a different kind of
    F.2d 1079 (6th Cir. 1983); Acme Mkts., Inc. v. Wharton
    Hardware & Supply Corp., 
    890 F. Supp. 1230
     (D.N.J. 1995);
    Rosenberg v. Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen & Hamilton, 
    598 F. Supp. 642
     (S.D.N.Y. 1984).
    22
    injury. Southaven’s only economic harm was the vague
    allegation that Malone was “subvert[ing] [its] business and
    financial interests.” Id. at 1087. This supposed subversion of
    business interests was not the means by which Malone was
    trying to achieve its illegal ends; it was an incidental effect in
    the real estate rental market rather than the grocery market.
    Indeed, by continuing to pay rent and honoring its contractual
    obligations, Malone arguably did not intend to harm
    Southaven at all. As in Ethypharm and Broadcom, the
    alleged downstream harm was too attenuated to support
    antitrust injury. In fact, Southaven supports the view that
    there was antitrust injury here, for Hanover Realty was used
    as the “fulcrum, conduit or market force” that was missing in
    Southaven. Forcing Hanover Realty to pay thousands of
    dollars in legal fees to defend itself against alleged
    anticompetitive filings and imposing significant delays on the
    project were the very means by which Defendants sought to
    keep a competitor out of the market.11 For all these reasons,
    we conclude that Hanover Realty has sufficiently alleged
    antitrust injury in the market for full-service supermarkets
    because its injury was inextricably intertwined with
    Defendants’ monopolistic conduct.
    11
    Defendants also urge us to follow Rosenberg, a decades-old
    district court decision from outside this circuit. Although
    Rosenberg involved similar facts to those here—competitor
    supermarkets filing a series of lawsuits to enjoin the
    construction of a new supermarket—the court’s legal analysis
    is not persuasive. See 
    598 F. Supp. at 643-44
    . The court
    mechanically applied Southaven without even mentioning the
    possibility of antitrust injury based on the “inextricably
    intertwined” exception. 
    Id. at 645
    .
    23
    In his dissent in part, Judge Ambro says that, in his
    view, a “plaintiff has not suffered antitrust injury unless its
    own harm stems from the anticompetitive consequences of
    the defendant’s conduct.” Judge Ambro Op. at 3. According
    to Judge Ambro, the plaintiff’s injury in McCready was
    actionable because she was a consumer in the psychotherapy
    market and Blue Shield “used a classic antitrust harm—
    increased prices—as a fulcrum to distort” that market. Id. at
    4. Judge Ambro believes that McCready was “injured
    because of the anticompetitive effects” of Blue Shield’s
    conduct, but that Hanover Realty did not sustain a similar
    type of injury. Id. In our view, Judge Ambro’s analysis
    resembles that espoused by then-Justice Rehnquist in his
    dissent in McCready. Justice Rehnquist said that McCready
    could not recover under the antitrust laws because she
    “alleges no anticompetitive effect upon herself”—her harm
    did not arise from an increase in price, decrease in availability
    of services, or reduction in competition. McCready, 
    457 U.S. at 489
     (Rehnquist, J., dissenting).
    The majority agreed that McCready did not suffer one
    of these traditional forms of antitrust harm, but that did not
    foreclose relief. See 
    id. at 482-83
    . She suffered antitrust
    injury because the harm imposed on her—denying
    reimbursement for visits to her psychologist—was the very
    means by which Blue Shield sought to harm psychologists.
    Similarly, Hanover Realty does not allege a classic antitrust
    harm, but it nonetheless sufficiently alleges antitrust injury
    because its harm was the very means by which Defendants
    sought to keep Wegmans out of the market. Indeed, Hanover
    Realty was the immediate target and bore the costs of
    Defendants’ scheme.
    Moving to the other four factors of the antitrust
    24
    standing analysis, we first find that Hanover Realty
    sufficiently alleges a causal connection between the antitrust
    violation and its harm. Defendants’ alleged sham petitioning
    caused Hanover Realty to pay thousands of dollars in
    attorney’s fees and costs in filing its responses.
    The next two factors are interrelated and go to the
    directness of the injury and the existence of more direct
    victims of the antitrust violations. These both favor Hanover
    Realty as well. Under McCready, a plaintiff can suffer direct
    injury even if the defendant’s anticompetitive conduct
    ultimately targets a third party; although the defendants there
    sought to harm competing psychologists and not the plaintiff
    health plan subscriber, the Supreme Court declared that the
    denial of reimbursement for those receiving treatment from
    psychologists injured the plaintiff “directly.” 
    457 U.S. at 483
    .
    Likewise, Defendants’ legal challenges directly injured
    Hanover Realty. If Defendants’ attempt to prevent Wegmans
    from leasing the property fails, then Hanover Realty will have
    suffered the costs of responding to the legal challenges while
    Wegmans may have experienced no loss at all. In addition, to
    the extent Defendants succeed in obstructing the lease,
    Hanover Realty’s loss of rent under the contract would result
    directly and not through “several somewhat vaguely defined
    links.” Associated Gen., 
    459 U.S. at 540
    . That Wegmans is
    another possible direct victim “does not diminish the
    directness of [Hanover Realty’s] injury.” Lower Lake Erie,
    
    998 F.2d at 1168-69
    .
    The final factor, the potential for duplicative recovery
    or complex apportionment of damages, also supports
    standing.    Hanover Realty’s recovery of the costs of
    responding to the legal challenges would not pose a risk “of
    overlapping damages as no other [party has] suffered this
    25
    distinct type of injury.” 
    Id.
     at 1164 n.11. Furthermore, any
    damages awarded for the delay or obstruction of the lease
    would not yield duplicative recovery as the lost rent to
    Hanover Realty would have to be subtracted as a cost from
    any subsequent claim by Wegmans for lost profits. See 
    id.
     at
    1169 n.22. Although this last scenario would require some
    apportionment of damages, the calculation would not be
    complex.
    Accordingly, Hanover Realty has adequately alleged
    antitrust standing on its claim for attempted monopolization
    of the market for full-service supermarkets.
    2.     Full-Service Supermarket Shopping
    Centers
    Hanover Realty does not rely on the “inextricably
    intertwined” doctrine for its attempted monopolization claim
    concerning the market for full-service supermarket shopping
    centers. Instead, Hanover Realty argues that it directly
    competes in this market for rental space with H&H
    Development, which owns the land on which the ShopRite
    resides.
    Antitrust injury ordinarily is limited to consumers and
    competitors in the restrained market. See Ethypharm, 707
    F.3d at 233. If doubts arise as to whether the parties are
    competitors, we look to see whether “there is a cross-
    elasticity of demand between the plaintiffs’ offering and the
    defendants’ offering.” Carpet Grp., 
    227 F.3d at 77
    . Such
    cross-elasticity exists where customers of the defendant
    would switch to the plaintiff if the defendant raised its prices.
    
    Id.
     at 77 n.13.
    Hanover Realty argues that both it and H&H
    26
    Development compete in the marketplace for supermarket
    rental space because they “both operate an enterprise in it.”
    Appellant’s Br. at 44. We are not persuaded. According to
    Hanover Realty, H&H Development is a wholly-owned
    subsidiary of ShopRite; the two have the same decision
    makers; H&H Development owns no property other than the
    land on which the ShopRite sits; and H&H Development
    leases that property to its parent. Hanover Realty fails to
    explain how it competes with H&H Development as a
    supermarket landlord in any meaningful way. For example, it
    does not argue there is any cross-elasticity between Hanover
    Realty’s and H&H Development’s offerings. If a traditional
    supermarket landlord raised rent to an excessive level, then
    the supermarket presumably would move its business to
    another property, such as Hanover Realty’s. But why would
    H&H Development raise ShopRite’s rent given that they have
    the same decision makers? As H&H Development’s sole
    purpose is to own the ShopRite property, Hanover Realty
    never alleges that H&H Development is competing for any
    tenants other than its parent—to the extent one can even call
    that “competing.” Because Hanover Realty cannot establish
    antitrust injury in the market for full-service supermarket
    shopping centers, it has no standing to bring its attempted
    monopolization claim of this market. Therefore, we affirm
    the dismissal of Count Two of the amended complaint.
    B.     Noerr-Pennington
    Having survived (in part) the threshold issue of
    antitrust standing, we proceed to Hanover Realty’s next major
    27
    obstacle:     Noerr-Pennington immunity.12       The Noerr-
    Pennington doctrine takes its name from a pair of Supreme
    Court cases that placed a First Amendment limitation on the
    reach of the Sherman Act. See E. R.R. Presidents Conference
    v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 
    365 U.S. 127
     (1961); United
    Mine Workers of Am. v. Pennington, 
    381 U.S. 657
     (1965).
    Noerr-Pennington provides broad immunity from liability to
    those who petition the government, including administrative
    agencies and courts, for redress of their grievances. Cal.
    Motor Transp. Co. v. Trucking Unlimited, 
    404 U.S. 508
    , 510
    (1972). Although Noerr-Pennington is a powerful shield, it is
    not absolute. Noerr itself recognized “[t]here may be
    situations” in which a petition “is a mere sham to cover what
    is actually nothing more than an attempt to interfere directly
    with the business relationships of a competitor and the
    application of the Sherman Act would be justified.” Noerr,
    
    365 U.S. at 144
    . And so spawned the “sham” exception.
    Two Supreme Court cases have explored the contours
    of this exception. In California Motor, the respondents, a
    group of highway carriers, alleged that the petitioners,
    another group of highway carriers, engaged in
    anticompetitive conduct by instituting state and federal
    proceedings to defeat the respondents’ applications for
    operating rights. 
    404 U.S. at 509
    . The Court held that the
    12
    Although the District Court did not discuss Noerr-
    Pennington, we will address this issue in the first instance
    because it raises questions of law over which we exercise
    plenary review and has been fully briefed by the parties. See
    Hudson United Bank v. LiTenda Mortg. Corp., 
    142 F.3d 151
    ,
    159 (3d Cir. 1998). The same goes for Defendants’ other
    arguments for dismissal, which we discuss further below.
    28
    complaint demonstrated a sham because it contained
    allegations that respondents “sought to bar their competitors
    from meaningful access to adjudicatory tribunals and . . . to
    usurp that decisionmaking process” by “institut[ing] the
    proceedings and actions . . . with or without probable cause,
    and regardless of the merits of the cases.” Id. at 512 (internal
    quotation marks omitted). In other words, the allegations, if
    proven, showed that the “administrative and judicial
    processes have been abused.” Id. at 513.
    The Court returned to the exception in Professional
    Real Estate Investors, Inc. v. Columbia Pictures Industries,
    Inc., 
    508 U.S. 49
     (1993). There, after the respondents filed a
    single copyright suit against the petitioners, the petitioners
    responded with an antitrust action, dubbing the copyright suit
    a sham. The Supreme Court outlined a two-part definition of
    sham litigation. 
    Id. at 60
    . First, “the lawsuit must be
    objectively baseless in the sense that no reasonable litigant
    could realistically expect success on the merits.” 
    Id.
     The
    existence of probable cause to institute the legal proceeding
    irrefutably demonstrates that the antitrust plaintiff has not
    proved the objective prong. 
    Id. at 63
    . If the antitrust plaintiff
    fails to satisfy the objective prong, the analysis ends and the
    defendant is immune from suit. Only if the underlying
    litigation is objectively meritless does the court address the
    second factor: the litigant’s subjective motivations. 
    Id. at 60
    .
    Under this second part of the test, the court asks whether “the
    baseless lawsuit conceals an attempt to interfere directly with
    the business relationships of a competitor . . . through the use
    [of] the governmental process—as opposed to the outcome of
    that process—as an anticompetitive weapon.” 
    Id. at 60-61
    (citations and internal quotation marks omitted).
    29
    Following California Motor and Professional Real
    Estate, questions arise as to the relationship between these
    two cases. Hanover Realty argues that, because Defendants
    filed a series of petitions without regard to merit, its
    allegations are in line with those from California Motor.
    Defendants respond by pointing to the Supreme Court’s more
    recent two-step analysis in Professional Real Estate, arguing
    that we must find each petition objectively baseless before
    assessing Defendants’ subjective motivations.13
    Three other Courts of Appeals have reconciled
    13
    Defendants maintain that Hanover Realty waived its
    argument regarding applying the California Motor analysis
    because it never raised this issue before the District Court and
    it did not raise the issue on appeal until its supplemental reply
    brief. See Gardiner v. V.I. Water & Power Auth., 
    145 F.3d 635
    , 646-47 (3d Cir. 1998). Defendants argue that, before the
    District Court, Hanover Realty agreed it had to satisfy the test
    from Professional Real Estate. We disagree that Hanover
    Realty has waived this argument. Throughout this litigation
    Defendants have consistently argued for Noerr-Pennington
    immunity and Hanover Realty has consistently responded that
    the sham exception applies. Hanover Realty’s failure to cite
    particular cases within its broader argument for the sham
    exception does not amount to a waiver. Moreover, by
    alleging an “illegal scheme” through a “series of sham
    litigations,” Hanover Realty put Defendants on notice of the
    relevant facts supporting its theory under California Motor.
    App. 63. Finally, Defendants have not been prejudiced by
    this argument because we exercise plenary review over this
    issue and they have filed a supplemental brief responding to
    Hanover Realty’s position.
    30
    California Motor and Professional Real Estate by concluding
    that they apply to different situations: California Motor to a
    series of sham petitions and Professional Real Estate to a
    single sham petition.14 See Waugh Chapel S., LLC v. United
    Food & Commercial Workers Union Local 27, 
    728 F.3d 354
    ,
    363-364 (4th Cir. 2013); Primetime 24 Joint Venture v. Nat’l
    Broad. Co., 
    219 F.3d 92
    , 101 (2d Cir. 2000); USS-POSCO
    Indus. v. Contra Costa Cnty. Bldg. & Constr. Trades Council,
    AFL-CIO, 
    31 F.3d 800
    , 810-11 (9th Cir. 1994).
    In the first case to tackle this issue, the Ninth Circuit
    explained that, in its view, the two-step inquiry in
    Professional Real Estate applies to the evaluation of a single
    suit or legal proceeding. USS-POSCO, 
    31 F.3d at 810-11
    . In
    such a case, the analysis is retrospective: if the alleged sham
    petition is not objectively baseless, defendants are immune—
    end of story. See 
    id. at 811
    . California Motor, by contrast, is
    concerned with a defendant who brings a series of legal
    proceedings. The Supreme Court there “recognized that the
    filing of a whole series of lawsuits and other legal actions
    without regard to the merits has far more serious implications
    than filing a single action.” 
    Id.
     Thus, when faced with a
    series or pattern of lawsuits, “the question is not whether any
    one of them has merit—some may turn out to, just as a matter
    14
    A staff report from the Federal Trade Commission also
    agrees with this view. See Federal Trade Commission,
    Enforcement Perspectives on the Noerr-Pennington
    Doctrine, at 28-38 (2006) (“FTC Report”), available at https:/
    /www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/advocacy_docum
    ents/ftc-staff-report-concerning-enforcement-perspectives-
    noerr-pennington-doctrine/p013518enfperspectnoerr-
    penningtondoctrine.pdf.
    31
    of chance—but whether they are brought pursuant to a policy
    of starting legal proceedings without regard to the merits and
    for the purpose of injuring a market rival.” 
    Id.
     Unlike the
    inquiry from Professional Real Estate, this inquiry is
    prospective and asks whether the legal filings were made,
    “not out of a genuine interest in redressing grievances, but as
    part of a pattern or practice of successive filings undertaken
    essentially for purposes of harassment.” 
    Id.
    We agree with the approach to California Motor and
    Professional Real Estate that has been adopted by the
    Second, Fourth, and Ninth Circuits. As stated in Noerr itself,
    the ultimate purpose of this inquiry is to determine whether
    the petitioning activity is a “mere sham to cover what is
    actually nothing more than an attempt to interfere directly
    with the business relationships of a competitor.” Noerr, 
    365 U.S. at 144
    . The best way to make that determination
    depends on whether there is a single filing or a series of
    filings. Where there is only one alleged sham petition,
    Professional Real Estate’s exacting two-step test properly
    places a heavy thumb on the scale in favor of the defendant.
    With only one “data point,” it is difficult to determine with
    any precision whether the petition was anticompetitive. See
    FTC Report at 35. Thus, Professional Real Estate requires a
    showing of objective baselessness before looking into
    subjective motivations in order to prevent any undue chilling
    of First Amendment activity. In contrast, a more flexible
    standard is appropriate when dealing with a pattern of
    petitioning. Not only do pattern cases often involve more
    complex fact sets and a greater risk of antitrust harm, but the
    reviewing court sits in a much better position to assess
    whether a defendant has misused the governmental process to
    curtail competition. As a result, even if a small number of the
    petitions turn out to have some objective merit, that should
    32
    not automatically immunize defendants from liability. See
    USS-POSCO, 
    31 F.3d at 811
     (“[E]ven a broken clock is right
    twice a day.”).
    Accordingly, when a party alleges a series of legal
    proceedings, we conclude that the sham litigation standard
    from California Motor should govern. This inquiry asks
    whether a series of petitions were filed with or without regard
    to merit and for the purpose of using the governmental
    process (as opposed to the outcome of that process) to harm a
    market rival and restrain trade. In deciding whether there was
    such a policy of filing petitions with or without regard to
    merit, a court should perform a holistic review that may
    include looking at the defendant’s filing success—i.e., win-
    loss percentage—as circumstantial evidence of the
    defendant’s subjective motivations. Compare Waugh, 728
    F.3d at 365 (finding sham where one of fourteen proceedings
    was successful), with USS-POSCO, 
    31 F.3d at 811
     (finding
    no sham where fifteen of twenty-nine lawsuits were
    successful), and Kaiser Found. Health Plan, Inc. v. Abbott
    Labs., Inc., 
    552 F.3d 1033
    , 1046 (9th Cir. 2009) (finding no
    sham where defendant “won seven of the seventeen suits” and
    each of the ten remaining cases “had a plausible argument on
    which it could have prevailed”). If more than an insignificant
    number of filings have objective merit, a defendant likely did
    not have a policy of filing “willy-nilly without regard to
    success.” See USS-POSCO, 
    31 F.3d at 811
    . A high
    percentage of meritless or objectively baseless proceedings,
    on the other hand, will tend to support a finding that the
    filings were not brought to redress any actual grievances. See
    City of Columbia v. Omni Outdoor Adver., 
    499 U.S. 365
    , 380
    (1991) (explaining that “the filing of frivolous objections . . .
    simply in order to impose expense and delay” is the “classic
    example” of a sham). Courts should also consider other
    33
    evidence of bad-faith as well as the magnitude and nature of
    the collateral harm imposed on plaintiffs by defendants’
    petitioning activity (e.g., abuses of the discovery process and
    interference with access to governmental agencies). See
    Professional Real Estate, 
    508 U.S. at 68
     (Stevens, J.,
    concurring).
    Defendants argue as a threshold matter that the four
    actions they filed against Hanover Realty are too few to even
    qualify as a pattern or series. We are not convinced. In so
    concluding, we do not set a minimum number requirement for
    the applicability of California Motor or find that four sham
    petitions will always support the use of California Motor. It
    is sufficient for our purposes that four petitions were filed
    against Hanover Realty and it alleges that Defendants filed
    these sham proceedings at every opportunity to obstruct
    Hanover Realty from “obtaining all necessary government
    approvals.” App. 71.
    Turning to Hanover Realty’s allegations, we conclude
    it can establish that Defendants had a policy of filing
    anticompetitive sham petitions. Defendants’ challenge to the
    Flood Permit was objectively baseless. The Environmental
    Department issued Hanover Realty its permit and found that
    ShopRite had only a generalized property interest and its
    claim of greater competition did not demonstrate it was an
    aggrieved party. Courts have “consistently” rejected the
    types of arguments offered by Defendants, the Environmental
    Department explained. App. 157. In addition to the lack of
    objective merit, Hanover Realty alleges indicia of bad faith.
    For example, it alleges that, five months after they submitted
    a request for an adjudicatory hearing, Defendants filed an
    amended request with “new” proposed facts that were already
    known to Defendants at the time they submitted their initial
    34
    request. The “only basis” for this filing, Hanover Realty
    alleges, was to slow down the review process. App. 76.
    Defendants’ alleged tactic suggests they were more interested
    in delay than in redressing any grievances.
    Similarly, with respect to the action in lieu of
    prerogative writs, the New Jersey state court easily found that
    ShopRite was not an interested party because it failed to show
    how any of its rights would be affected by the approval of
    Hanover Realty’s site plan. The court dismissed the
    complaint. We agree that Defendants’ arguments for why
    they had standing are objectively baseless. Hanover Realty
    also alleges that Defendants filed three amended complaints
    only for the purpose of delay. This allegation indicates that
    Defendants’ complaint was not brought out of a genuine
    desire to obtain relief, but rather to keep the suit pending as
    long as possible.
    Defendants claim two victorious moments with respect
    to the Wetlands Permit. They first point to the fact that they
    successfully identified a technical deficiency in the
    application, and that the Environmental Department required
    Hanover Realty to correct this administrative error. We liken
    this to hitting a single in the second inning. Hanover Realty
    submitted a new application within days and the problem was
    resolved. See Waugh, 728 F.3d at 365 (“[T]he fact that there
    may be moments of merit within a series of lawsuits is not
    inconsistent with a campaign of sham litigation.”).
    Defendants also remind us that the Environmental
    Department required Hanover Realty to conduct a survey for
    the presence of Indiana bats, as it had requested. But this also
    does not qualify as success.          The ostensible goal of
    Defendants’ challenge was for the Environmental Department
    to deny the Wetlands Permit. They were unsuccessful on that
    35
    front; Hanover Realty received the permit. Hanover Realty
    also alleges subjective evidence of abusing the governmental
    process. Defendants allegedly complained to the United
    States Fish and Wildlife Service even though they knew the
    wetlands at issue are not federally regulated waters.
    Moreover, in an email, Defendants’ ecological consultant
    touted its ability to delay the permit approval process.
    Defendants arguably fared slightly better in connection
    with their challenge to the Street Permit. They submitted
    objections to the Department of Transportation arguing,
    among other things, that Hanover Realty was required to
    build an overpass over a highway before beginning
    construction. In its letter responding to the parties, the
    Department of Transportation did acknowledge that it was
    required to consider any data or arguments submitted by third
    parties. Defendants extract success from that statement, but
    we do not. That the Department of Transportation was
    required to consider Defendants’ challenge does not mean
    that their arguments had any bite. Where Defendants did
    have some success, however, was in the Department of
    Transportation’s finding that the prior developer’s agreement
    triggered the need for additional highway improvements.
    But, rather than requiring Hanover Realty to make those
    improvements, the letter recognized that such construction
    might not be feasible or worthwhile.              It therefore
    recommended that Hanover Realty negotiate a modification
    to the agreement with the Department of Transportation
    before proceeding any further. This action was a partial
    success because Defendants’ challenge did have some merit,
    but it did not cause the Department of Transportation to
    actually reject the permit application.
    All in all, the allegations and the record show that
    36
    Hanover Realty received the Flood and Wetlands Permits, it
    got the state-court action dismissed, and it avoided having to
    make significant highway improvements.              Defendants’
    meager record on the merits supports Hanover Realty’s
    allegation that that the filings were not brought to redress any
    grievances. Nor have Defendants articulated any genuine
    interest in flooding or traffic near the proposed Wegmans
    (which is two miles away from the ShopRite), or in protecting
    the Indiana bat. Rather, Hanover Realty sufficiently alleges
    that Defendants brought these actions under a policy of
    harassment with the effect of obstructing Hanover Realty’s
    access to governmental bodies. The filings have imposed
    significant expense on Hanover Realty, have continued to
    delay the project, and threaten the viability of the project
    altogether. That Defendants have had some insignificant
    success along the way does not alter the analysis when
    reviewing a pattern or series of proceedings. Accordingly,
    Hanover Realty can establish that the sham exception to
    Noerr-Pennington immunity applies because it sufficiently
    alleges that Defendants “instituted the proceedings and
    actions . . . with or without probable cause, and regardless of
    the merits of the cases.” Cal. Motor, 
    404 U.S. at 516
    .15
    C.     Remaining Arguments
    15
    Defendants also argue that, because some of the
    proceedings are ongoing, Hanover Realty’s suit is premature.
    We reject this argument because the California Motor
    analysis is prospective, not retrospective. See USS-POSCO,
    
    31 F.3d at 810-11
    . If we were to agree with Defendants on
    this point, they could keep filing petitions and avoid judicial
    review indefinitely.
    37
    Defendants contend that Hanover Realty has failed to
    allege facts showing that there is a “dangerous probability of
    [Defendants] achieving monopoly power.”            W. Penn
    Allegheny, 
    627 F.3d at 108
    . In support of this position,
    Defendants argue that Hanover Realty has not adequately
    alleged a product or geographic market.16
    According to Defendants, Hanover Realty has not
    properly defined the alleged product market for full-service
    supermarkets because it has not distinguished full-service
    supermarkets from any other supermarkets or grocery stores.
    Defendants believe this supposed submarket is a contrivance.
    We disagree. “Competing products are in the same market if
    they are readily substitutable for one another; a market’s outer
    boundaries      are    determined      by     the    reasonable
    interchangeability of use between a product and its substitute,
    or by the cross-elasticity of demand.” Broadcom, 
    501 F.3d at
    307 (citing Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    ,
    325 (1962)). Moreover, “in most cases, proper market
    definition can be determined only after a factual inquiry into
    the commercial realities faced by consumers.” Queen City
    Pizza, Inc. v. Domino’s Pizza, Inc., 
    124 F.3d 430
    , 436 (3d
    Cir. 1997). We cannot say, at this very early stage in the
    litigation, that Hanover Realty’s product market is
    implausible.     Hanover Realty alleges that full-service
    supermarkets are distinct from other grocery suppliers
    because they provide customers with additional amenities,
    16
    Because we already found that Hanover Realty does not
    have antitrust standing for its claim of attempted
    monopolization of the full-service supermarket shopping
    center market (Count Two), we address here only the claim
    relating to full-service supermarkets (Count One).
    38
    including prepared foods to go, on-site dining options, wine
    and liquor, specialty products, and other services such as
    pharmacies, banks, and fitness centers. Hanover Realty
    further alleges that consumers have come to enjoy full-service
    supermarkets as a one-stop shopping experience that allows
    them to avoid driving to different stores to check off the items
    on their grocery lists. Because consumers plausibly treat full-
    service supermarkets as a distinct submarket, the allegations
    here support the position that the market for full-service
    supermarkets “encompass[es] all interchangeable substitute
    products.” 
    Id.
     Through discovery, Hanover Realty may be
    able to demonstrate that a price increase at the ShopRite
    would not cause consumers to shop at other more traditional
    grocery stores.
    Defendants also argue that the proposed geographic
    market—greater Morristown—is too imprecise.                  In
    Defendants’ view, Hanover Realty has not alleged facts
    suggesting that ShopRite could raise prices without causing
    consumers to drive elsewhere. Again, we disagree. “[T]he
    relevant geographic market is the area in which a potential
    buyer may rationally look for the goods or services he or she
    seeks.” Eichorn v. AT&T Corp., 
    248 F.3d 131
    , 147 (3d Cir.
    2001) (internal quotation marks omitted). Hanover Realty
    alleges that, when it comes to buying groceries, consumers
    like to shop near their homes. Thus, it alleges, proximity to a
    large upscale population is an important factor in determining
    where to locate a full-service supermarket. We find it
    plausible that greater Morristown, which includes Morristown
    and its neighboring communities, is a distinct geographic
    market. If the ShopRite in Morristown raised its prices, it is
    plausible that only the most diligent and frugal customer
    39
    would move his or her grocery shopping to a more distant
    supermarket.17
    III. CONCLUSION
    For the foregoing reasons, we will affirm in part,
    vacate in part, and remand to the District Court for further
    proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    17
    We have considered and rejected Defendants’ remaining
    arguments. They argue there is no dangerous probability of
    achieving a monopoly because there is another full-service
    supermarket in the area—the Stop & Shop of Morris Plains.
    Defendants maintain that Hanover Realty has admitted this
    fact. But in making that argument, Defendants rely on
    Hanover Realty’s initial complaint, not its amended
    complaint, which is operative. In the amended complaint,
    Hanover Realty alleges that the Stop & Shop is a “grocery
    store,” App. 72, and that ShopRite is the “only full-service
    supermarket” in Greater Morristown, App. 73. We must
    accept those allegations as true. Defendants’ final argument
    is that Hanover Realty has failed to allege a specific intent to
    monopolize. For the reasons discussed above in connection
    with the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, we conclude Hanover
    Realty sufficiently alleges that Defendants filed a series of
    sham proceedings with the intent to interfere with a
    prospective competitor and restrain trade.
    40
    Hanover 3201 Realty LLC v. Village Supermarkets
    No. 14-4183
    AMBRO, Circuit Judge, dissenting in part and concurring in
    part.
    I respectfully disagree with my colleagues’ view that
    Hanover 3201 Realty has suffered antitrust injury, a necessary
    component of antitrust standing. In my view, because the
    anticompetitive effects of Village Supermarkets’ actions (as
    opposed to the damages sustained directly from any tort) do
    not hurt Hanover, a landlord and not a player in the market
    for full-service supermarkets, it lacks antitrust standing to
    bring this suit.
    However, I recognize that my colleagues’ view of
    antitrust standing is, by virtue of their ruling, the holding of
    our Court and now the law of this Circuit. In this context, I
    believe I am obliged to consider the merits of Hanover’s suit.
    Among other things, I agree with Judge Fuentes that Village’s
    Noerr–Pennington immunity defense is a sham and hence
    unavailing at this stage. Thus I vote to vacate the judgment of
    the District Court and remand.
    This sets the stage for a most interesting interplay of
    whether to vote by issue (in which case Hanover wins, as,
    while I lose on the issue of standing, I align with Judge
    Fuentes on the lack of merit for Village’s claim of immunity
    under Noerr-Pennington) or outcome (whereby Village wins,
    as my outcome, though for different reasons, aligns with
    Judge Greenberg’s). I opt for the former for the reasons
    noted below.
    I.     Hanover Lacks Antitrust Standing
    A.     Law of Antitrust Injury
    In order to state a claim for violation of the antitrust
    laws, a plaintiff must show that it has suffered “antitrust
    injury, which is to say injury of the type the antitrust laws
    were intended to prevent and that flows from that which
    makes [the] defendants’ acts unlawful.” Brunswick Corp. v.
    Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 489 (1977).
    Antitrust injury is a necessary but not sufficient component of
    antitrust standing, a prudential limitation on the Clayton Act’s
    broad language concerning the right to sue. Barton &
    Pittinos, Inc. v. SmithKline Beecham Corp., 
    118 F.3d 178
    ,
    182 (3d Cir. 1997).
    We have held that a plaintiff ordinarily does not suffer
    “antitrust injury” if it is “not a competitor or a consumer in
    the market allegedly restrained,” 
    id. at 181
    , unless “there
    exists a ‘significant causal connection’ such that the harm to
    the plaintiff . . . [is] ‘inextricably intertwined’ with the
    antitrust conspiracy,” Gulfstream III Associates, Inc. v.
    Gulfstream Aerospace Corp., 
    995 F.2d 425
    , 429 (3d Cir.
    1993) (quoting Blue Shield v. McCready, 
    457 U.S. 465
    , 484
    (1982)). This exception is narrow, and antitrust injury is
    “almost exclusively suffered by consumers or competitors.”
    Steamfitters Local Union No. 420 Welfare Fund v. Philip
    Morris, Inc., 
    171 F.3d 912
    , 926 (3d Cir. 1999).1
    1
    Our law that a plaintiff ought to be a consumer or
    competitor and that the “inextricably intertwined” injury
    presents a limited “exception” to this “requirement” is not the
    only way to read the relevant Supreme Court cases. The
    leading case on antitrust standing treated consumer-or-
    2
    My principal disagreement with my colleagues
    concerns how to read the “inextricably intertwined”
    exception. As I understand their opinion, they hew closely to
    the meaning of those two particular words and believe that a
    plaintiff has suffered an antitrust injury if its injury is closely
    related to a defendant’s actions that also amount to an
    antitrust violation. By contrast, I believe the rule remains that
    “antitrust injury should reflect the anticompetitive effect
    either of the violation or of anticompetitive acts made
    possible by the violation.” Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at 489
    . In
    my view, even if a plaintiff has suffered direct harm from a
    defendant’s acts, and even if those acts violate the antitrust
    laws, it has not suffered antitrust injury unless its own harm
    stems from the anticompetitive consequences of the
    defendant’s conduct.
    As the majority notes, the “inextricably intertwined”
    language comes from the Supreme Court’s decision in
    McCready, a case with exceptionally broad dicta about
    antitrust standing. In that case, the plaintiff, who was insured
    by Blue Shield, saw a psychologist. McCready, 
    457 U.S. at 468
    . Blue Shield allegedly colluded with psychiatrists to
    divert patients like McCready from psychologists by
    declining to reimburse the latter’s services. 
    Id.
     at 469–70. It
    argued that McCready had not suffered antitrust injury
    because neither psychiatrists’ nor psychologists’ prices
    competitor status as one of several factors a court should
    weigh in considering whether a plaintiff has antitrust
    standing, Associated Gen. Contractors v. Cal. State Council
    of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
    , 539 (1983), and in other circuits
    consumer-or-competitor status is less strongly emphasized.
    See, e.g., Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 
    505 F.3d 302
    , 311
    (4th Cir. 2007). However, it is the settled law of our Court.
    3
    increased as a result of its scheme (ignoring the de facto price
    increase of the insurance company’s failure to reimburse the
    insured), 
    id.
     at 481–84, and that the point of the alleged
    scheme was to harm psychologists, not their insured patients,
    
    id.
     at 478–79.2 But the Supreme Court held that “[a]lthough
    McCready was not a competitor of the conspirators
    [psychiatrists and Blue Shield], the injury she suffered was
    inextricably intertwined with the injury the conspirators
    sought to inflict on psychologists and the psychotherapy
    market.” 
    457 U.S. at
    483–84.
    The reason McCready’s injury was inextricably
    intertwined with the harm inflicted on the psychotherapy
    market was that she was a consumer in that market and her
    “injuries [were] the essential means by which defendants’
    illegal conduct brought about its ultimate injury to the
    marketplace.” Ethypharm S.A. France v. Abbott Labs., 
    707 F.3d 223
    , 237 n.21 (3d Cir. 2013) (quoting IIA Philip E.
    Areeda, et al., Antitrust Law ¶ 339, at 123 (3d ed. 2007)).
    However, the term “essential means” does not mean that
    anyone who suffers any injury in the context of an
    anticompetitive scheme may sue under the antitrust laws. In
    McCready, although the plaintiff was not the ultimate target
    of the cartel’s activity, Blue Shield and the psychiatrists used
    a classic antitrust harm—increased prices—as a fulcrum to
    distort the psychotherapy market, specifically to the detriment
    of psychologists. The McCready Court affirmed that a person
    who suffers antitrust injury— i.e., who is injured because of
    2
    Blue Shield’s argument was based in part on a now-
    outmoded theory that only the “target” of an antitrust
    violation could bring suit. 
    Id.
     at 478 n.14 & 479 n.15; see
    also Associated Gen. Contractors, 
    459 U.S. at
    536 n.33
    (rejecting “target area” theory).
    4
    the anticompetitive effects of a cartel or monopolist’s
    activity—may bring suit even if that person is not a consumer
    from whom the defendant seeks to extract supracompetitive
    rents or a competitor the defendant seeks to eliminate. See
    IIA Areeda, supra, ¶ 339, at 144 (4th ed. 2014) (“[T]he result
    of the alleged antitrust conspiracy would be higher prices in
    the very market in which McCready was a purchaser. . . .
    McCready is thus like a purchaser from a cartel at cartel
    prices.”).
    B.     Hanover Has Not Suffered Antitrust
    Injury
    Here, Hanover alleges monopolization of two markets,
    one for “full service supermarkets,” and one for “full service
    supermarket shopping centers,” the latter defined as the
    market for real property that can be used for full-service
    supermarkets. It does not participate in the supermarket
    business; it is a landlord and developer. It operates a
    development enterprise in the real-estate market, but it does
    not sell goods or provide consumer services the way Village
    does. And although Hanover does participate in the market
    for real property that can be used for full-service
    supermarkets, Village’s actions have not affected that market.
    In other words, Hanover does not participate in the market
    that was allegedly restrained, and the market it does
    participate in was not restrained. Hanover has thus not
    suffered an antitrust injury.
    1.     Full-service Supermarket Market
    Unlike the relationship in McCready between the
    plaintiff and the market for psychotherapy services, whether
    the market for full-service supermarkets is ultimately
    restrained does not matter to Hanover. Its injuries flow from
    Village’s alleged wrongful use of civil proceedings and from
    5
    Hanover’s contract with Wegmans that allocated to Hanover
    some portion of the risk of failing to develop the parcel within
    a certain period of time. Village’s alleged attempted
    monopolization of the relevant markets hurts Wegmans, a
    full-service supermarket, and it hurts consumers who would
    prefer a choice among supermarkets, but as Village is not
    alleged to have restrained the market for real estate in
    Morristown or anywhere else, it is hard to see why Hanover is
    a proper antitrust plaintiff even if it has valid tort claims
    arising out of otherwise anticompetitive conduct. In short,
    because the anticompetitive effects of Village’s allegedly
    illegal activity have not caused any injury to Hanover, it does
    not have an antitrust claim.
    Several sources of authority support the notion that a
    landlord is an improper antitrust plaintiff when it complains
    of injury flowing from antitrust harm directed at a tenant.
    The leading treatise deals with the situation in one terse
    paragraph: “The landlord receiving a set rather than variable
    rent is simply a supplier of an input . . . . Such landlords are
    almost always denied standing for antitrust violations that
    target their tenants or that occur in the product market.” IIA
    Areeda, supra, ¶ 351c, at 286. We have also disposed of
    claims brought by landlords without much analysis beyond
    indicating that any injury the landlord suffered, even when its
    rent was tied to the tenant’s revenue, was too remote from the
    antitrust violation to allow the landlord to bring suit.
    [A] non-operating lessor-owner of a motion
    picture theatre who is entitled to rental based on
    a percentage of receipts is nonetheless not a
    “person . . . injured in his business or property”
    within the meaning of section 4 of the Clayton
    Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 15
    , and, therefore, is not
    entitled to bring suit under the Act for an
    alleged conspiracy relating to the licensing of
    6
    pictures at the theatre by the lessee-operator.
    Melrose Realty Co. v. Loew’s, Inc., 
    234 F.2d 518
    , 519 (3d
    Cir. 1956) (per curiam); see also Harrison v. Paramount
    Pictures, Inc., 
    211 F.2d 405
    , 405 (3d Cir. 1954) (affirming for
    the reasons stated in the District Court’s opinion, see 
    115 F. Supp. 312
     (E.D. Pa. 1953), which held that a movie theater
    lessor was too remote from antitrust harm directed at movie
    distributors). More recently, we held that “[a] supplier does
    not suffer an antitrust injury when competition is reduced in
    the downstream market in which it sells goods or services.”
    W. Penn Allegheny Health Sys., Inc. v. UPMC, 
    627 F.3d 85
    ,
    102 (3d Cir. 2010). And a landlord is in the same shoes as a
    supplier from an antitrust-injury perspective. IIA Areeda,
    supra, ¶ 351c at 286.
    Other courts of appeals that have faced facts similar to
    our case have rejected the landlord’s standing. Most closely
    on point is Serfecz v. Jewel Food Stores, 
    67 F.3d 591
     (7th Cir.
    1995), where owners and operators of a shopping mall sought
    to recover damages from an anchor tenant, a grocery store.
    The tenant opened another store nearby, vacated its old
    premises, and would not sublease them to another grocery
    store. The Seventh Circuit Court held that the “plaintiffs
    d[id] not have the requisite direct injury to have standing to
    assert that [the defendant] ha[d] monopolized, or conspired
    with others to monopolize, the retail grocery market,” 
    id.
     at
    598–99, because plaintiffs were players in the shopping
    center market, not the retail grocery business.
    Similarly, in a Sixth Circuit case a grocery store
    subleased to a competitor grocery store and then engaged in
    anticompetitive conduct to ruin it. Southaven Land Co. v.
    Malone & Hyde, Inc., 
    715 F.2d 1079
    , 1081 (6th Cir. 1983).
    The plaintiff, a landlord that owned the rest of the shopping
    center of which the grocery store was a part, found a
    7
    replacement grocery store, but the defendant would not
    sublease to it, presumably lowering the value of the shopping
    center. The Court noted that “Southaven’s [the land owner’s]
    injury [was] charged to have accrued as a result of its contract
    negotiations with the alleged antitrust violator.           The
    complaint noticeably fail[ed] to aver that Southaven sustained
    any injury as a competitor, purchaser, consumer or other
    economic actor in the grocery industry.” 
    Id. at 1081
    .
    Ultimately, the Court held that as “Southaven is not a
    consumer, customer, competitor or participant in the relevant
    market or otherwise inextricably intertwined with any such
    entity[, i]ts injury [was] not sufficiently linked to the pro-
    competitive policy of the antitrust laws” to confer standing on
    it. 
    Id. at 1087
    ; accord Rosenberg v. Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen &
    Hamilton, 
    598 F. Supp. 642
    , 645–46 (S.D.N.Y. 1984) (“No
    matter how causal a relationship may exist between the
    alleged violation and injury, the defendants’ actions were not
    undertaken to interfere with the economic freedom of
    participants in the construction business.”).
    Because I read the Supreme Court’s and our cases on
    antitrust standing to require a plaintiff’s harm to be at least
    “inextricably intertwined” with whatever makes a defendant’s
    conduct specifically an antitrust violation—e.g., higher prices
    or reduced output—I believe Hanover lacks standing with
    respect to the allegedly unlawful restraint of the full-service
    supermarket market. Hence I respectfully dissent from the
    decision of my colleagues to reverse on this issue.
    2.     Full-Service Supermarket
    Shopping Center Market
    Hanover also alleges that it competes directly with
    H&H, the special purpose entity that owns the land for
    Village’s supermarket, in the “full service supermarket
    shopping center market” of greater Morristown. This title for
    8
    the market, besides being a mouthful, is confusing, as the
    market players are said to be landowners “whose property is
    or can be utilized by or rented to a full-service supermarket.”
    Am. Compl. ¶ 32, J.A. 69. Thus the market is for certain real
    property. The Serfecz plaintiffs, who lacked standing insofar
    as they alleged monopolization of the retail grocery market,
    nevertheless had standing with respect to the shopping center
    market. 67 F.3d at 599. This was because they had
    ownership interests in a mall, and the defendant (a former
    anchor tenant and grocery store) allegedly colluded with a
    different shopping center to drive Serfecz’s mall out of
    business. Id. at 595, 599. Hanover argues that H&H and
    Village are trying to keep Hanover out of the full-service
    supermarket shopping center market in the same way that the
    Serfecz defendants allegedly drove the plaintiffs out of the
    mall business.
    Unlike the plaintiffs in Serfecz, neither Hanover nor
    H&H is specifically in the business of operating shopping
    centers. Instead, they are owners and developers of real
    property. Hanover does not allege, for example, that its
    parcel’s value decreased following Village and H&H’s
    attempts to exclude competitors from the market for owning
    land on which supermarkets can be leased. And the
    Complaint does not allege that Village’s efforts have affected
    the market for real property in Morristown or anywhere else
    to any significant degree. As Hanover has not plausibly
    alleged that Village’s monopolistic conduct has injured it as a
    landowner, it cannot be said that the frustration of its contract
    with Wegmans “reflect[s] the anticompetitive effect . . . of the
    violation.” Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at 489
    ; cf. IIA Areeda,
    supra, ¶ 351b1, at 284 (“In the movies cases, for example, the
    defendant’s conduct . . . depriv[ed] rival film producers,
    distributors, or exhibitors of adequate access to markets or
    supplies. The landlord is a stranger to those interests: the real
    estate market as a whole is not significantly affected.”).
    9
    Thus, and for the reasons ably expressed in Part II.A.2
    of Judge Fuentes’ opinion, I agree that Hanover lacks
    antitrust standing with respect to what it calls the full-service
    supermarket shopping center market.
    II.    Noerr–Pennington and Remaining Issues
    I agree with Judge Fuentes’ views on Noerr–
    Pennington and Village’s other objections to Hanover’s
    Complaint. Hence I join Part II.B–C of his opinion.
    III.   How to Decide This Case?
    This case presents what academic literature terms a
    “voting paradox.” On the one hand, two judges (Judge
    Greenberg and I) believe that the outcome should be that
    Hanover’s suit not proceed, though we do so for different
    reasons. However, one majority of this Court (Judges
    Fuentes and Greenberg) believes that Hanover has antitrust
    standing (I do not because I do not discern antitrust injury),
    while another majority (Judge Fuentes and I) believes that
    Hanover should survive Village’s motion to dismiss
    (assuming it has antitrust standing). The paradox is that, if I
    vote on the judgment of this case (affirm or reverse) based on
    my individual views, a majority of the Court will have ruled
    against the prevailing party on each relevant issue, meaning
    that our Court’s reasoning would not support its judgment.
    However, if I follow, despite my dissent, Judge Fuentes and
    Greenberg on the antitrust standing issue, my individual vote
    would be inconsistent with my view of who should win were
    I alone ruling.
    But to me it is significant that we are not acting alone.
    Because we need to act as a Court, I think it is more
    appropriate for me to be bound by the majority’s opinion on
    antitrust standing despite my disagreement with it. Before I
    10
    explain my choice in detail, I shall survey the current state of
    thinking on this issue.
    A.     Law and Scholarship on the Voting Paradox
    Although I do not write on an entirely blank slate with
    respect to this issue, there is surprisingly little discussion in
    judicial opinions about how one ought to vote when facing
    such a paradox. Where a majority agrees on the bottom-line
    outcome in a case, shifting majorities with varied lines of
    reasoning are more common; these variable groups
    unquestionably describe the holdings of the relevant courts.
    See, e.g., United States v. Booker, 
    543 U.S. 220
     (2005)
    (resolving whether there was a constitutional violation by one
    majority per Justice Stevens over Justice Breyer’s dissent but
    ordering remedy via a different majority per Justice Breyer
    over Justice Stevens’ dissent); Blunt v. Lower Merion Sch.
    Dist., 
    767 F.3d 247
    , 302 (3d Cir. 2014) (“Although a majority
    of the Court thus does not accept the District Court’s ruling
    that CBP did not have standing, this conclusion does not
    change our outcome in light of a different majority’s
    independent conclusion that the Court properly entered
    summary judgment against the plaintiffs.”); United States v.
    Aguila-Montes de Oca, 
    655 F.3d 915
    , 916 (9th Cir. 2011); O
    Centro Espirita Beneficiente Uniao Do Vegetal v. Ashcroft,
    
    389 F.3d 973
     (10th Cir. 2004) (en banc); United States v.
    Johnson, 
    256 F.3d 895
    , 897 (9th Cir. 2001) (en banc); Davis
    v. U.S. Steel Corp., 
    779 F.2d 209
    , 210 (4th Cir. 1985).
    It is thus commonplace that majorities composed of
    different allotments of judges lay down the law, and it would
    seem to follow that a judge may vote on a judgment based on
    the relevant court’s legal conclusions even if the judge
    disagrees with the court’s resolution of a dispositive issue.
    However, it is quite rare that judges are actually faced with a
    voting paradox where it is debatable whether the proper result
    11
    is to vote according to the judge’s personal preference or to
    vote according to shifting majorities’ statements of the law.
    In three Supreme Court cases, justices have noted that their
    votes on the judgment were inconsistent with their individual
    views of the proper outcome of the case. Arizona v.
    Fulminante, 
    499 U.S. 279
    , 313 (1991) (Kennedy, J.,
    concurring in the judgment); Pennsylvania v. Union Gas Co.,
    
    491 U.S. 1
    , 45 (1989) (White, J., concurring in the judgment
    in part and dissenting in part); United States v. Vuitch, 
    402 U.S. 62
    , 96 (1971) (Harlan, J., dissenting as to jurisdiction);
    
    id. at 97
     (opinion of Blackmun, J.).
    Fulminante and Vuitch are especially relevant. In the
    former case, the Arizona Supreme Court held that a
    confession was coerced and thus inadmissible. State v.
    Fulminante, 
    778 P.2d 602
    , 627 (Ariz. 1988), aff’d, 
    499 U.S. 279
     (1991). In deciding whether to affirm or reverse, the U.S.
    Supreme Court faced three issues: (1) whether the
    defendant’s confession was coerced; (2) if so, whether
    harmless error analysis applied; and (3) if so, whether the
    admission of the confession was harmless error. Fulminante,
    
    499 U.S. at 279, 282, 295
    . Five justices concluded the
    confession was coerced, 
    id. at 287
    ; a different group of five
    justices concluded harmless error applies to coerced
    confessions, 
    id.
     at 311–12; and still a third group of five held
    that the admission there was not harmless, 
    id. at 302
    . At the
    same time, five justices thought the Arizona Supreme Court
    should have been reversed, though for no consistent reason.
    See 
    id. at 306
     (opinion of Rehnquist, C.J., that confession was
    not coerced, joined by O’Connor, Kennedy & Souter, JJ.); 
    id. at 312
     (opinion of Rehnquist, C.J., joined by Scalia, J., that
    admission of confession was harmless). Justice Kennedy
    yielded to the majority on the question of whether the
    confession was coerced and thus reached the harmless-error
    issue; he concluded the admission was not harmless and thus
    supported the judgment affirming the Arizona Supreme
    12
    Court. 
    Id.
     at 313–14. Likewise, in Vuitch Justices Harlan and
    Blackmun acceded to a majority’s disposition as to
    jurisdiction, but—together with other justices—formed a
    separate majority on the merits. 
    402 U.S. at 96, 97
    .3
    Similarly, in the panel opinion of United States v.
    Andis, 
    277 F.3d 984
    , 985 (8th Cir. 2002), rev’d, 
    333 F.3d 886
    (8th Cir. 2003) (en banc), two judges held that the right to
    3
    Union Gas is less squarely on point because no majority
    supported that judgment on every point. The issues were (1)
    whether two Congressional statutes were intended to abrogate
    state sovereign immunity and (2) whether Congress had that
    power under the Commerce Clause. 
    491 U.S. at 5
    . Five
    justices held the statutes purported to annul state sovereign
    immunity and five that Congress had the power to do so. 
    Id. at 13
    . However, only four justices agreed on a rationale for
    Congress’s constitutional power. Justice White’s cryptic
    concurrence stated on the constitutional question only that “I
    agree with the conclusion reached by Justice Brennan in Part
    III of his opinion, that Congress has the authority under
    Article I to abrogate the Eleventh Amendment immunity of
    the States, although I do not agree with much of his
    reasoning.” Union Gas Co., 
    491 U.S. at 57
     (White, J.,
    concurring in the judgment in part and dissenting in part). It
    was this absence of reasoning—not, as Judge Greenberg’s
    dissent suggests, Justice White’s yielding to his colleagues on
    the statutory interpretation question—that caused the
    “confusion” noted in Seminole Tribe of Florida v. Florida,
    
    517 U.S. 44
    , 64 (1996) (“Justice White, who provided the
    fifth vote for the result, wrote separately in order to indicate
    his disagreement with the plurality’s rationale.”).
    13
    appeal an illegal sentence could not be waived, but a different
    majority held that the sentence should be vacated. Two
    judges, acting independently, would have affirmed the
    sentence—one because he viewed the waiver as valid and
    another because he thought the sentence was legal. 
    Id.
    However, the judge who viewed the waiver as valid voted to
    remand the case for further proceedings because on the
    merits, assuming the issue was not waived, he believed the
    sentence was illegal. Id. at 989 (Morris Sheppard Arnold, J.,
    dissenting in part and concurring in the judgment). This vote
    was made without much comment except that “otherwise the
    court could not issue a mandate.” Id. (In fact, a mandate
    could have just as easily issued if the two judges preferring
    affirmance voted to affirm.) 4
    At the same time, there have been cases where judges
    or justices stick to their individual guns with the result that,
    although a majority supports a given judgment, a careful
    reading of all the opinions in the case reveals that no majority
    supports the prevailing party on any issue logically necessary
    4
    There may also be some support for issue voting in our
    decision in United States v. Bazzano, 
    712 F.2d 826
     (3d Cir.
    1983) (en banc) (per curiam). In that case, nine of the ten
    judges would have voted to remand the case to the District
    Court. But no majority could agree on what the District
    Court should do on remand. 
    Id. at 829
     (noting that the
    “differing grounds on which these various votes for remand
    are rested cannot be reconciled so as to yield a majority vote
    for a remand with consistent instructions to the district
    court”). We thus affirmed the District Court’s judgment,
    despite nine of the ten judges agreeing on the outcome,
    because no majority could agree on rationale.
    14
    to its victory. For example, Miller v. Albright, 
    523 U.S. 420
    (1998), presented four questions, and shifting majorities of
    the Supreme Court sided with Miller on each one; nonetheless
    six justices, for differing reasons, thought Miller should lose,
    which she did. Maxwell L. Stearns, Should Justices Ever
    Switch Votes? Miller v. Albright in Social Choice
    Perspective, 7 Sup. Ct. Econ. Rev. 87, 102 (1999). To muddy
    the waters further, scholars believe that in other cases justices
    or judges have cast votes in favor of analyses with which they
    did not agree in order to mask voting paradoxes. See, e.g.,
    Michael Abramowicz & Maxwell L. Stearns, Beyond
    Counting Votes: The Political Economy of Bush v. Gore, 
    54 Vand. L. Rev. 1849
    , 1938–41 (2001).
    Given this array of paradoxical (or potentially so)
    cases and the striking absence of analysis of how to vote in
    any of them, it is not surprising that there is no set rule on
    how an appellate judge should vote. Generally, scholars who
    analyze voting paradoxes (and there are several) discuss two
    possibilities: “issue voting” and “outcome voting.” Broadly
    speaking, the former occurs when a judge surveys the holding
    on each question of law presented; a majority vote on any
    given issue counts as a holding of the court, and the
    remaining judge is bound by it as if it occurred in a prior
    precedential case.5 The latter, and more common, scenario
    5
    This equation of precedent with an issue is problematic in a
    court that has power to overrule its precedent, like the en banc
    Third Circuit or the Supreme Court. Indeed, when a panel is
    in a position to overrule prior precedent, a voting paradox
    may be more likely. See David S. Cohen, The Precedent-
    Based Voting Paradox, 
    90 B.U. L. Rev. 183
    , 184 (2010).
    Luckily, that is not the case with a panel of this Court. See
    Third Circuit I.O.P. 9.1 (“It is the tradition of this court that
    15
    occurs when a judge votes on the result of a case (affirm,
    vacate, reverse, etc.) according to his or her view of the
    proper outcome and without regard to the views of the other
    judges on a panel. Even if a careful reading of the judges’
    opinions in a case shows that a majority would rule for the
    losing party on each relevant issue, an outcome-vote, as that
    term is usually used in the relevant literature, results in a win
    for the party the majority of judges think should win
    regardless of reasoning.
    Before discussing the pros and cons of each voting
    protocol, I note that one thing is clear: as a formal matter,
    judges vote on the result of a case, i.e., whether to affirm,
    reverse, vacate, dismiss, remand, or some combination of
    these; otherwise, the clerk of a court could not enter judgment
    pursuant to Fed. R. App. P. 36. But even though “result” and
    “outcome” are synonyms, it does not follow that my vote on
    the disposition must be what I have just defined as an
    “outcome vote.” I am aware of no source of law that tells me
    whether my vote must be based on how I view our Court’s
    holding on each relevant issue or on how I personally view
    the best outcome of the case.
    B.     An Issue Vote is Preferable Here
    There are two closely related reasons why I choose to
    vote by issue in this case, and I will discuss them in turn: (1)
    the execution of our dual responsibilities to resolve disputes
    and declare the law; and (2) the role of a judge on a
    multimember court.
    the holding of a panel in a precedential opinion is binding on
    subsequent panels. Thus, no subsequent panel overrules the
    holding in a precedential opinion of a previous panel. Court
    en banc consideration is required to do so.”).
    16
    1.      Our Dual Responsibilities: Dispute
    Resolution and Law Declaration
    Those who sit on, appear before, or study federal
    courts are familiar with the notion that we serve two primary
    functions: dispute resolution and law declaration. The former
    role is rooted in the limitation that courts only decide “cases”
    and “controversies.” U.S. Const., art. III, § 2. To carry out
    this role, a court issues judgments in the cases before it; in the
    case of an appellate court, the judgment, as noted, will usually
    be to affirm, reverse, vacate, dismiss, remand, or some
    combination thereof.
    A court’s second role is “to say what the law is.”
    Marbury v. Madison, 5 U.S. (1 Cranch) 137, 177 (1803).
    This role flows directly from the first. “Those who apply the
    rule to particular cases . . . must of necessity expound and
    interpret that rule.” Id. To fulfill its law-declaration function,
    a court often writes opinions explaining the law and reasoning
    underlying its judgments. See also Jonathan Remy Nash, A
    Context-Sensitive      Voting     Protocol      Paradigm       for
    Multimember Courts, 
    56 Stan. L. Rev. 75
    , 86–87 (2003)
    (“Courts function as arbiters of particular disputes between
    litigants. Those litigants are concerned with the outcome of
    the case as determined by the courts. But, in handing down
    decisions, courts serve another important role: They announce
    (or aid in the evolution and development of) generally
    applicable rules of law.”).
    To me, issue voting better accomplishes both roles by
    deciding all necessary (including threshold) issues and
    proceeding from that point to explain what the law is and
    why. By voting on issues, a multimember court announces
    discrete holdings that can be applied in later cases.
    There is thus an obvious reason to vote on a case’s
    17
    disposition based on the Court’s resolution of each relevant
    issue—to align rationale and outcome. A related reason to do
    so is that voting paradoxes often arise because of the
    operation of the final-judgment rule. Nash, supra, at 84-85.
    Because legal rulings are usually not appealable before final
    judgments in most jurisdictions, appeals are more likely to
    present multiple issues that can create paradoxes, whereas if
    we heard appeals piecemeal, far less opportunity for voting
    problems would arise. The final-judgment rule is sound
    because it supports efficient resolution of cases at little cost:
    claims of reversible error can be preserved and, as a general
    matter, the litigant who is right on the law will prevail.
    But that is not true if we allow the final judgment rule
    to affect our substantive resolution of the issues in a case.
    Take this case. Imagine that the final-judgment rule did not
    apply, and Hanover prevailed on antitrust standing in the
    District Court. Village then appealed, and we affirmed (over
    my dissent). Then, on remand, Village prevailed on the
    Noerr–Pennington issue in the District Court, and Hanover
    appealed and won (over Judge Greenberg’s dissent). There
    would be no doubt in that case that Hanover would have
    properly won its appeals even though two judges thought at
    different phases of the litigation it should have lost, and no
    justification for the final-judgment rule requires a contrary
    bottom-line outcome in such a seriatim case. To generalize
    from that example, the final-judgment rule helps create the
    voting paradox without providing a satisfactory rationale for
    the usual practice of outcome voting, thus posing the question
    of why, other than habit, we typically vote by outcome.
    Judge Greenberg points out that we could avoid the
    voting paradox if I didn’t bother to reach the Noerr–
    Pennington issue. If so, a majority would conclude that
    Hanover had standing, and then a majority would conclude
    that Hanover loses but without a majority supporting any
    18
    particular reason for its loss. This avoids the problem of an
    incoherent precedent but replaces it with no opinion to
    provide even the hint of a rationale. Arguably, no reasoning
    is an improvement over reasoning that contradicts a
    judgment, but, as Judge Greenberg notes, we never have to
    issue an opinion. We could just issue judgment orders
    without reasoning in every case and save everyone a lot of
    time and paper.         In my view, we issue judgments
    accompanied by reasoned opinions because the rule of law
    ought neither to be nor appear to be arbitrary. It follows that
    judgments should be supported by reasoning, that the
    reasoning should actually support the outcome in a particular
    case, and that in this case I should yield to my colleagues on
    antitrust standing and vote on the Noerr-Pennington issue that
    follows.
    2.     A Multimember Court: Deliberative
    Body or so Many Noses to Count?
    The possibilities of issue and outcome voting expose a
    tension between the independence of individual judges and
    our membership on multimember panels of multimember
    courts. As we are independent, it could be thought that a
    litigant is entitled to the sum of independent votes in its favor
    and that a judge should not change his or her vote out of
    deference to colleagues’ shared views. The widely (though
    not universally) accepted practice of writing separate opinions
    when a judge disagrees with another’s analysis supports this
    view of voting one’s views alone.
    There are at least two reasons why appellate courts
    should be deemed to act as an entity reasoning through the
    case issue by issue rather than a collection of individual
    judges with a judgment reflecting a vote tally divorced from
    the reasoning of the majority of the court. The first is the
    nature of multimember appellate courts as collegial, and not
    19
    just redundant, enterprises. Kornhauser and Sager explain
    that redundant and collegial enterprises “aim to produce
    performances that could in principle represent the unenhanced
    effort of a single person, but to bring that performance closer
    to the ideal.” Lewis A. Kornhauser & Lawrence G. Sager,
    The One and the Many: Adjudication in Collegial Courts, 
    81 Calif. L. Rev. 1
    , 4 (1993). Redundant enterprises “rely on an
    external structure of multiple independent efforts.” 
    Id.
     For
    example, in the case of gymnastics judges, “[e]ach judge
    ranks the performance before her without consulting her
    peers, and the rankings are aggregated by rule.” 
    Id.
     By
    contrast, collegial bodies “are like team enterprises in that
    each participant must consider and respond to her colleagues
    as she performs her tasks. Collaboration and deliberation are
    the trademarks of collegial enterprise.”          
    Id.
        “While
    interaction and exchange are irrelevant or even antithetical to
    redundant enterprises, they are crucial to collegial enterprises,
    and the product of a collegial enterprise often belongs to that
    enterprise in a uniquely collective way.” 
    Id.
     at 4–5.
    Appellate courts are collegial enterprises. Judges
    collaborate on and deliberate about cases and issues at all
    levels of the appeals process, from deciding whether to hold
    oral argument to conferencing to circulating opinions. At the
    end of the process a judgment of the Court typically emerges
    supported by an opinion. In some sense that product is akin
    to what a team produces. “Team enterprises do not merely
    multiply product or amplify effort: they transform the
    performance into something that only a group could have
    produced.” Id. at 3. Put another way, while an individual
    judge could do the job of an appellate court, the process of
    multimember panels produces a product that is typically
    better qualitatively than what an individual appellate judge
    20
    could do. The whole is greater than the sum of its parts.6
    In some cases, then, outcome voting lessens the value
    of an appellate court’s deliberative process. If judges engage
    in issue voting, there are multiple deliberations and votes; that
    is, there are deliberations and votes on each issue. A judge is
    not effectively on the sideline for disagreeing with the
    majority on a threshold issue. Applying issue voting in this
    case, for example, I reach the Noerr–Pennington issue, even
    though I perceive no standing, because my individual view on
    the antitrust standing question is subsumed (despite my filing
    a dissent) into that of the panel; we act as a single deliberative
    body in a process that produces a judgment that depends on
    the majority’s reasoning (whatever the composition of that
    majority) at each step of the process. With outcome voting,
    by contrast, though judges deliberate on separate issues
    (unless they decide not to reach them), a judgment depends
    not on reasoning but a tallying of who should win were each
    judge to vote a result without reasons. There is, therefore,
    less of an opportunity for synthesis or transformation of each
    judge’s reasoning into the larger whole. This provides the
    answer to Judge Greenberg’s lack of “understand[ing] why
    the circumstance that we are all on the panel should lead to a
    different result than that which would be reached individually
    by a majority of the panel.” Greenberg Op. at 29. The result
    should be different because we sit on a panel.
    Second,      issue    voting     treats     judges    as
    interchangeable—the premise of the black robe and an
    assumption on which our legal system is based. In our case,
    for example, Hanover prevails because two out of three
    judges find antitrust standing for the plaintiff and two out of
    6
    This is not to say that judges should not dissent. In that
    sense, courts are not fully team enterprises.
    21
    three judges find no immunity for the defendant. Voting by
    issue better reflects our role as members of a single
    deliberative body striving to craft a sensible corpus juris. As
    noted above, if we voted by outcome, the precedential value
    of this case would be unclear if the same set of facts came
    before us (or a district court) a second time. For a body like a
    court that has no means to enforce its mandate other than
    persuasion, it is of great concern that “in cases where the
    doctrinal paradox arises, judgment and reason are
    immediately and inexorably pulled apart, to the potential
    detriment of the orderly development of legal doctrine.”
    Kornhauser & Sager, supra, at 5.
    C.     Arguments to the Contrary are Not Persuasive.
    Thoughtful proponents of an outcome-based voting
    protocol argue that it promotes principled (i.e., not strategic)
    identification of issues and, at least in some cases, also
    promotes principled resolution of those issues.             See
    Abramowicz & Stearns, supra, at 56–58; John M. Rogers,
    “Issue Voting” by Multimember Appellate Courts: A
    Response to Some Radical Proposals, 
    49 Vand. L. Rev. 997
    ,
    1002 (1996); Maxwell L. Stearns, How Outcome Voting
    Promotes Principled Issue Identification: A Reply to
    Professor John Rogers and Others, 
    49 Vand. L. Rev. 1045
    ,
    1050 (1996). In short, these scholars argue that if appellate
    courts vote by issue, judges and litigants will have an
    incentive to identify and sequence legal issues in
    disingenuous ways to cobble together shifting majorities that
    will eventually support their favored positions. By contrast, if
    the only vote is on the outcome, each judge will present the
    issues in the case as he or she actually views them without
    regard to the potential gains from gamesmanship in framing
    22
    issues.7
    There are a number of replies to this argument. First,
    professional norms of the bench and bar go a long way in
    preventing deceptive strategies in brief- and opinion-writing.
    Second, it is unclear to me that the resolution of issues in an
    outcome-vote is more principled than in an issue vote; indeed,
    a principal problem with outcome voting is that occasionally
    7
    Judge Greenberg also relies on an article by then-Professor
    Rogers, who concluded that “over 150 Supreme Court cases
    involving plurality majority opinions indicate that a justice
    should not [aggregate votes by issue and therefore] defer to a
    majority that disagrees on a dispositive issue.” John M.
    Rogers, “I Vote This Way Because I’m Wrong”: The Supreme
    Court Justice as Epimenides, 
    79 Ky. L.J. 439
    , 459 (1990–91).
    But not one of that large number of cases actually purports to
    say how a judge “should” vote. Moreover, by Judge Rogers’
    own count, only between fourteen and sixteen cases involved
    situations where the justices voted by outcome when an issue-
    vote would have yielded a different result. 
    Id.
     at 448 & n.24.
    In light of the three cases where justices voted by issue and
    the Supreme Court’s silence in all cases on whether issue- or
    outcome-based voting is preferable, I do not see how we can
    fairly understand the Court to have settled the question of the
    proper voting protocol. Kornhauser & Sager, supra, at 57
    (“Current appellate practice with regard to paradoxical cases
    is in shambles. The Supreme Court, in particular, has been
    unmindful of the existence of the paradox, even when
    confronted with cases whose dispositions turn on the choice
    of alternative voting protocols.”).
    23
    issues are left entirely unresolved. For example, Wedderburn
    v. I.N.S., 
    215 F.3d 795
    , 801 (7th Cir. 2000), applied Miller,
    
    523 U.S. 420
     (where, as noted above, majorities on every
    issue undermined the judgment), to reject a similar challenge
    to a different statute. In Wedderburn, the Court reasoned not
    by legal analysis but by prediction about the votes of
    individual justices. 
    215 F.3d at 801
    . Finally, each judge on a
    multimember panel always has to vote ultimately on the
    outcome of a case; what is debatable is whether that vote
    should be based on the way majorities of judges resolve
    individual issues or how the individual judge views the
    preferred outcome. In some cases, like this one, where all
    agree on what the issues are, each relevant one is dispositive,
    and they all arise in an agreed-on logical sequence, issue-
    voting strikes me as preferable. But I do not mean to promise
    that I will always vote by issue, and I do not mean to suggest
    that my colleagues should or must follow my lead. As we
    have seen, Supreme Court justices are inconsistent in their
    voting bases, and no source of law resolves the question of
    how to vote. And in some cases, especially capital ones, the
    practical implications of a judgment—life or death— may be
    more important than the choice of one voting protocol over
    another. See David Post & Steven C. Salop, Rowing Against
    the Tidewater: A Theory of Voting by Multijudge Panels, 
    80 Geo. L.J. 743
    , 761 (1992).
    D.     The Next Case: Toward a Voting Protocol
    Protocol
    As we have seen, appellate judges have little to guide
    their discretion in choosing a voting protocol. This case
    prompts me to argue for one guidepost: when an appellant
    raises “arguments that would constitute independent appeals
    were interlocutory appeals permissible,” issue voting is
    preferable. Nash, supra, at 147–48.
    24
    Because in this case I view a coherent precedent from
    our Court as more valuable than a resolution in favor of the
    party I would have sided with were I deciding this case by
    myself, and because all agree the two issues presented here
    are easily separated, I concur with Judge Fuentes in a
    disposition that ultimately favors Hanover.
    IV.    Conclusion
    Hanover should lack antitrust standing because it has
    not suffered antitrust injury within the meaning of the
    Supreme Court’s exposition of that term. However, I am
    outvoted on this issue, which sets the precedent for our Court
    and the predicate for addressing the remaining issue (Noerr–
    Pennington). It has divided my colleagues, and thus my vote
    is needed to resolve it. I agree with Judge Fuentes that
    Noerr–Pennington poses no bar to relief at this stage in the
    litigation. Although I would affirm the District Court on
    antitrust standing grounds, I yield to my colleagues’
    resolution of that issue and vote to vacate and remand on the
    lack of a Noerr-Pennington defense to Village.
    25
    Re: Hanover 3201 Realty, LLC v. Village Supermarkets,
    No. 14-4183
    GREENBERG, Circuit Judge, dissenting.
    I concur with and join in Sections I, the background
    section, and II.A., the antitrust standing section, of Judge
    Fuentes’s opinion. Thus, I agree with his conclusion in Section
    II.A. that plaintiff, Hanover 3201 Realty, LLC (“3201 Realty”),
    has antitrust standing in the full-service supermarket market but
    not in the full-service supermarket rental space market. I cannot
    agree, however, with Judge Fuentes’s opinion to the extent that I
    believe it expands the sham exception to Noerr-Pennington
    immunity. I decline to join in this aspect of Judge Fuentes’s
    opinion because: (1) 3201 Realty has not properly preserved the
    issue; (2) no court of which I am aware has applied the
    expanded exception in circumstances comparable to those here;
    and (3) the expansion of the sham exception comes with a
    questionable pedigree. I therefore conclude that the legal
    challenges to 3201 Realty’s development project that Village
    Supermarkets, Inc. (“Village”) brought on behalf of itself and
    Hanover and Horsehill Development LLC fall within the
    antitrust immunity afforded to petitioning activity under the
    Noerr-Pennington doctrine.1 In light of this conclusion and
    Judge Ambro’s conclusion that 3201 Realty does not have
    antitrust standing, two of the three members of this panel believe
    that the District Court correctly dismissed the complaint.
    In coming to my conclusion that the District Court
    correctly dismissed the complaint I recognize that a majority of
    1
    I refer to Village and Hanover and Horsehill Development
    LLC together as defendants.
    the panel, Judge Fuentes and I, believe that the District Court in
    part erred in concluding that 3201 Realty lacks antitrust
    standing. But that error does not require us to reverse the
    Court’s judgment because an appellate court may affirm an
    order granting a motion to dismiss on “any ground supported by
    the record.” Hildebrand v. Allegheny Cnty., 
    757 F.3d 99
    , 104
    (3d Cir. 2014) (quoting Tourscher v. McCullough, 
    184 F.3d 236
    , 240 (3d Cir. 1999)), cert. denied, 
    135 S.Ct. 1398
     (2015).
    Here, the opinions of the members of the panel demonstrate that
    a majority of the panel believe that there is such support in the
    record because I accept defendants’ contention that the Noerr-
    Pennington doctrine immunizes them from antitrust liability for
    their allegedly anticompetitive judicial and administrative
    challenges to 3201 Realty’s development project, and Judge
    Ambro accepts defendants’ contention that 3201 Realty did not
    have antitrust standing.2 Thus, I reiterate that Judge Ambro and
    I believe that the District Court reached the correct result,
    though in part on a basis that differs from that on which the
    Court relied. Accordingly, though the panel is reversing, it
    should be affirming.
    I. THE NOERR-PENNINGTON DOCTRINE IMMUNIZES
    2
    Defendants raised this argument both in the District Court and
    in their answering brief on appeal. 3201 Realty failed to address
    the merits of the argument in its reply brief, but we afforded it
    an opportunity to do so in a supplemental reply brief and it did
    so.
    2
    DEFENDANTS’ CONDUCT FROM ANTRITRUST
    LIABILITY.
    A.     Relevant Law
    The Noerr-Pennington doctrine draws its name from the
    Supreme Court’s opinions in Eastern Railroad Presidents
    Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 
    365 U.S. 127
    , 
    81 S.Ct. 523
     (1961), and United Mine Workers of America v.
    Pennington, 
    381 U.S. 657
    , 
    85 S.Ct. 1585
     (1965). It derives in
    part from the First Amendment right to petition the government.
    Octane Fitness, LLC v. ICON Health & Fitness, Inc., 
    134 S.Ct. 1749
    , 1757 (2014); BE & K Constr. Co. v. NLRB., 
    536 U.S. 516
    , 524-25, 
    122 S.Ct. 2390
    , 2395-96 (2002). Under the
    doctrine, petitioners for “government . . . redress are generally
    immune from antitrust liability” when defending against
    antitrust claims predicated on this petitioning activity. Prof’l
    Real Estate Investors, Inc. v. Columbia Pictures Indus., Inc., 
    508 U.S. 49
    , 56, 
    113 S.Ct. 1920
    , 1926 (1993) (“PRE”); see A.D.
    Bedell Wholesale Co. v. Philip Morris Inc., 
    263 F.3d 239
    , 250
    (3d Cir. 2001). The doctrine applies not only to lobbying
    activity but also “to efforts to influence administrative agency
    action and efforts to access the court system.” Santana Prods.
    Inc. v. Bobrick Washroom Equip., Inc., 
    401 F.3d 123
    , 131 n.13
    (3d Cir. 2005) (citation omitted); see Cal. Motor Transp. Co. v.
    Trucking Unlimited, 
    404 U.S. 508
    , 510, 
    92 S.Ct. 609
    , 611-12
    (1972); Cheminor Drugs, Ltd. v. Ethyl Corp., 
    168 F.3d 119
    , 122
    (3d Cir. 1999). Indeed, “[c]alling concerns about a proposed
    development to the attention of the responsible state agencies
    [and courts] lies at the core of privileged activity.” Herr v.
    Pequea Twp., 
    274 F.3d 109
    , 121 (3d Cir. 2001).
    3
    3201 Realty argues that the Noerr-Pennington doctrine
    does not immunize defendants for their conduct because the
    allegedly anticompetitive legal challenges to the development
    project fall within the so-called “sham” exception to the
    doctrine. In PRE, the Supreme Court established a two-prong
    test for determining the applicability of this exception including
    both objective and subjective components. See 
    508 U.S. at
    60-
    61, 
    113 S.Ct. at 1928
    . Under the objective prong, the plaintiff
    must show that the defendant’s petitioning was “objectively
    baseless in the sense that no reasonable litigant could
    realistically expect success on the merits.” BE & K Constr., 
    536 U.S. at 526
    , 
    122 S.Ct. at 2396
     (quoting PRE, 
    508 U.S. at 60
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1928
    ). A plaintiff cannot make this showing if the
    defendant’s petitioning activity has succeeded as “a successful
    ‘effort to influence governmental action . . . certainly cannot be
    characterized as a sham.’” PRE, 
    508 U.S. at 58
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1927
     (alteration in original) (quoting Allied Tube & Conduit
    Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc., 
    486 U.S. 492
    , 502, 
    108 S.Ct. 1931
    ,
    1938 (1988)).
    On the other hand, even if a defendant’s petitioning
    activity was unsuccessful, that failure does not prove that it did
    not have an objective basis for the activity. See 
    id.
     at 60 n.5,
    
    113 S.Ct. at
    1928 n.5; Herr, 
    274 F.3d at 119
    . Moreover, “even
    when the law or the facts appear questionable or unfavorable at
    the outset, a party may have an entirely reasonable ground for
    bringing suit.” PRE, 
    508 U.S. at
    60 n.5, 
    113 S.Ct. at
    1928 n.5
    (quoting Christiansburg Garment Co. v. EEOC, 
    434 U.S. 412
    ,
    422, 
    98 S.Ct. 694
    , 701 (1978)). The second, subjective prong
    for establishing the sham exception to Noerr-Pennington
    immunity, comes into play only if the plaintiff first makes a
    4
    showing satisfying the exception’s objective prong. See PRE,
    
    508 U.S. at 60
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1928
    ; Cheminor, 
    168 F.3d at
    123
    n.10. Accordingly, a defendant’s anticompetitive intent in
    engaging in petitioning activity is immaterial if it had probable
    cause for its activity. See PRE, 
    508 U.S. at 62
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1929
    .
    In an effort to avoid the need to satisfy PRE’s threshold
    objective prong, 3201 Realty contends that the PRE test applies
    only where the defendants institute a single legal action and not
    where, as here, the defendants brought multiple legal challenges
    to the plaintiff’s enterprise. 3201 Realty supports this position
    by pointing to cases from other courts of appeals holding that
    “where the defendant is accused of bringing a whole series of
    legal proceedings,” “the question is not whether any one of them
    has merit -- some may turn out to, just as a matter of chance --
    but whether they are brought pursuant to a policy of starting
    legal proceedings without regard to the merits and for the
    purpose of injuring a market rival.” USS-POSCO Indus. v.
    Contra Costa Cnty. Bldg. & Constr. Trades Council, AFL-CIO,
    
    31 F.3d 800
    , 811 (9th Cir. 1994); accord Waugh Chapel S., LLC
    v. United Food & Commercial Workers Union Local 27, 
    728 F.3d 354
    , 363-64 (4th Cir. 2013); Primetime 24 Joint Venture v.
    Nat’l Broad., Co., 
    219 F.3d 92
    , 101 (2d Cir. 2000).
    Judge Ambro and Judge Fuentes accept 3201 Realty’s
    argument circumventing the need to satisfy the objective prong
    of the dual-prong PRE test. I believe, however, that the
    argument should fail for at least three independent reasons.
    First, 3201 Realty did not raise this argument until it filed its
    supplemental reply brief in this Court. Beyond a mere “failure
    to cite particular cases within its broader argument for the sham
    5
    exception,” majority typescript at 30 n.12, 3201 Realty
    conceded before the District Court that it had to satisfy PRE’s
    two-prong test and first show that any allegedly anticompetitive
    “lawsuit or other petitioning activity [was] objectively baseless,”
    Pl.’s Br. in Opp’n to Mot. to Dismiss at 9 (citing PRE, 
    508 U.S. at 60
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1928
    ). I therefore would hold that 3201
    Realty has waived any argument excusing it from having to
    establish that defendants’ actions were objectively baseless. See
    Erdman v. Nationwide Ins. Co., 
    582 F.3d 500
    , 507 n.2 (3d Cir.
    2009) (holding that plaintiff waived argument by conceding the
    point at issue on the appeal in the district court and explaining
    that her discovery of the argument upon “‘further reading’ while
    preparing [her] appeal” did not justify overlooking the waiver);
    Bryant v. Military Dep’t of Miss., 
    597 F.3d 678
    , 694 (5th Cir.
    2010) (holding that by not raising it before the district court,
    plaintiff waived the argument that “the ‘objectively baseless’
    standard ought to be applied in some different, and presumably
    favorable way in this case because multiple lawsuits were filed
    against him”).
    Second, even putting aside the waiver problem, the very
    case law applying the alternative test for which 3201 Realty
    advocates, i.e., not applying the PRE two-prong test which
    includes an objective component in situations in which a
    defendant has instituted a series of legal actions, demonstrates
    that the single lawsuit and three administrative challenges that
    defendants initiated do not rise to the level of “a whole series of
    legal proceedings” so as to trigger the applicability of the
    alternative test. See In re Flonase Antitrust Litig., 
    795 F. Supp. 2d 300
    , 309 n.10 (E.D. Pa. 2011) (“No court has applied the
    USS-POSCO test to a ‘series’ of five petitions . . . .”); see also
    6
    ERBE Elektromedizin GmbH v. Canady Tech. LLC, 
    629 F.3d 1278
    , 1291-92 (Fed. Cir. 2010) (even assuming alternative test
    applied, no “series” based on defendant filing three lawsuits);
    Amarel v. Connell, 
    102 F.3d 1494
    , 1519 (9th Cir. 1996) (no
    “series” where defendants initiated two lawsuits and
    administrative proceedings); Ludwig v. Superior Court, 
    43 Cal. Rptr. 2d 350
    , 365 n.33 (Ct. App. 1995) (“[A] total of four
    activities, two of which are not meritless as a matter of law,
    cannot constitute such a pattern [of baseless opposition].”).
    Thus, while Judge Ambro and Judge Fuentes adopt the test of
    other courts of appeals limiting this application of PRE, it seems
    to me that they do not correctly apply the case law based on that
    test, declaring instead that in the present circumstances, though
    not in others, four actions qualify as a “series.”3 Majority
    typescript at 33-34. In reality, the four legal challenges that
    defendants initiated pale in comparison to the 29 in USS-
    POSCO, 
    31 F.3d at 811
    ; the 14 in Waugh Chapel, 728 F.3d at
    365; and the thousands in Primetime 24, 
    219 F.3d at 101
    .
    Third, even overlooking both 3201 Realty’s waiver of a
    challenge to the applicability of the two-prong PRE test and the
    consideration that the courts that have adopted the alternative
    intent-based test would not apply it in the circumstances we
    face, I harbor doubts about whether the courts limiting the
    applicability of PRE have identified a proper exception to that
    case’s two-part test. This purported exception rests on a case on
    which Judge Ambro and Judge Fuentes heavily rely decided
    3
    As I explain below there now is an additional case that Village
    has initiated to consider. See infra note 5. But the addition of
    this case does not change my conclusion.
    7
    prior to PRE in which the Supreme Court explained: “One
    claim, which a court or agency may think baseless, may go
    unnoticed; but a pattern of baseless, repetitive claims may
    emerge which leads the factfinder to conclude that the
    administrative and judicial processes have been abused.” Cal.
    Motor Transp., 
    404 U.S. at 513
    , 92 S.Ct. at 613. Yet it seems to
    me that the Court’s reference to “a pattern of baseless, repetitive
    claims” makes clear that this language comes into play only
    where a plaintiff first can satisfy what ultimately became PRE’s
    first prong; otherwise, the Court’s use of the word “baseless”
    would serve no purpose. But the use of “baseless” did serve a
    purpose because the Court in PRE pointed to this very language
    as demonstrating that “[n]othing in California Motor Transport
    retreated” from “an indispensable objective component” in
    establishing the sham exception. 
    508 U.S. at 58
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1927
    .
    In a ruling employing the understanding of PRE that I
    think is appropriate, we applied the objective prong to uphold a
    claim of Noerr-Pennington immunity in a case similar to this
    one where the defendants challenged a plaintiff’s land
    development project in multiple judicial and administrative
    proceedings. See Herr, 
    274 F.3d at 115-16, 118-19
    . Other
    courts also have rejected the proposed exception to the PRE test
    advanced here that would dispense with the need to show that
    the defendant’s activity lacked an objectively reasonable basis.
    See Travelers Express Co. v. Am. Express Integrated Payment
    Sys. Inc., 
    80 F. Supp. 2d 1033
    , 1042 (D. Minn. 1999) (applying
    PRE rather than Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit’s test
    even though defendant filed “a series of allegedly meritless
    suits”); Christian Mem’l Cultural Ctr., Inc. v. Mich. Funeral
    8
    Dirs. Ass’n, 
    998 F. Supp. 772
    , 777 n.2 (E.D. Mich. 1998)
    (“[T]he courts in this circuit that have confronted similar issues
    [of whether an exception to PRE exists where the defendant
    initiated multiple lawsuits] have declined to read [PRE] so
    narrowly.” (citation omitted)).
    I appreciate the animating concern of other courts of
    appeals that an antitrust defendant’s fortuitous success in a small
    number of lawsuits should not automatically immunize the
    defendant from the antitrust consequences of initiating a whole
    series of anticompetitive legal challenges. See Waugh Chapel,
    728 F.3d at 365; Primetime 24, 
    219 F.3d at 101
    ; USS-POSCO,
    
    31 F.3d at 811
    . But we should not alleviate this concern by
    excusing a plaintiff from having to show the objective
    baselessness of even a single action brought by the defendant.
    After all, if Noerr-Pennington immunity shields objectively
    reasonable actions when considered individually, it should
    continue to shield them when they are aggregated. Cf.
    Pennington, 
    381 U.S. at 670
    , 
    85 S.Ct. at 1593
     (holding that
    immunity extends to petitioning conduct “either standing alone
    or as part of a broader scheme”).
    Judge Ambro and Judge Fuentes reason that the
    alternative test makes more sense when dealing with multiple
    legal challenges because having a larger sample of challenges
    than a single challenge enables the court to better “assess
    whether a defendant has misused the governmental process to
    curtail competition.” Majority typescript at 32. Yet this
    approach treats PRE’s objective prong as more akin to an
    evidentiary rule of thumb for determining whether the defendant
    possessed an anticompetitive purpose, rather than the
    independent and threshold requirement that it unmistakably
    9
    represents. See 
    508 U.S. at 57
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1926
     (“[A]n
    objectively reasonable effort to litigate cannot be sham
    regardless of subjective intent.”); 
    id. at 59-60
    ; 
    113 S.Ct. at 1928
    (“We [earlier] dispelled the notion that an antitrust plaintiff
    could prove a sham merely by showing that its competitor’s
    ‘purposes were to delay [the plaintiff’s] entry into the market
    and even to deny it a meaningful access to the appropriate . . .
    administrative and legislative fora.’” (second and third
    alterations in original) (quoting Columbia v. Omni Outdoor
    Adver., Inc., 
    499 U.S. 365
    , 381, 
    111 S.Ct. 1344
    , 1354 (1991)).
    Perhaps for this reason, some courts applying an approach
    similar to that of Judge Ambro and Judge Fuentes have
    preserved the need for showing the objective baselessness of the
    defendant’s action as a prerequisite for establishing the sham
    exception. See, e.g., In re Terazosin Hydrochloride Antitrust
    Litig., 
    335 F. Supp. 2d 1336
    , 1367 (S.D. Fla. 2004) (rejecting
    claim of sham litigation because “none of the lawsuits,
    individually, can be considered objectively baseless”); Gen-
    Probe, Inc. v. Amoco Corp., 
    926 F. Supp. 948
    , 959 (S.D. Cal.
    1996) (“[U]nder either the PRE or the USS-POSCO test, [the
    plaintiff’s] claims against [the defendants] must demonstrate
    objective baselessness.”).
    When I consider these questions regarding the legal
    support for abandoning a threshold objective baselessness
    requirement, I cannot acquiesce in the adoption of a test where
    the argument supporting the adoption has not been advanced
    properly and the test is being applied in circumstances beyond
    those recognized by other courts that have adopted the test
    abandoning the objective component of PRE. I therefore would
    hold that 3201 Realty cannot circumvent a Noerr-Pennington
    10
    immunity defense without first showing that defendants’ legal
    challenges were objectively baseless.4
    4
    I agree with Judge Ambro and Judge Fuentes that the
    circumstance that some of defendants’ legal actions are ongoing
    does not preclude application of the sham exception, although I
    do so based on Supreme Court precedent and not based on the
    “prospective” character of the alternative test. Majority
    typescript at 37 n.14. In Vendo Co. v. Lektro-Vend Corp., 
    433 U.S. 623
    , 
    97 S.Ct. 2881
     (1977), the Court faced the question of
    whether a district court could enjoin an ongoing state court
    proceeding that allegedly violated federal antitrust law. The
    Court fractured into three opinions, none of which obtained a
    majority. See 
    id. at 626
    , 97 S.Ct. at 2885 (plurality opinion of
    Rehnquist, J.); id. at 643, 97 S.Ct. at 2893 (Blackmun, J.,
    concurring in result); id. at 645, 97 S.Ct. at 2894 (Stevens, J.,
    dissenting). Nevertheless, although a majority of the Court
    concluded that the Anti-Injunction Act barred the district court
    from enjoining the state court proceeding at issue, all nine
    justices either explicitly or implicitly acknowledged that
    plaintiffs can seek some form of relief, such as damages or
    injunctions against future legal actions, based on ongoing sham
    proceedings brought in violation of the antitrust laws. See id. at
    635 n.6, 637 n.8, 97 S.Ct. at 2889 n.6, 2890 n.8 (plurality
    opinion of Rehnquist, J.); id. at 644, 97 S.Ct. at 2894
    (Blackmun, J., concurring in result); id. at 653-54, 97 S.Ct. at
    2899 (Stevens, J., dissenting). Indeed, six of the justices
    declared that, in appropriate circumstances, such antitrust relief
    could include an injunction against the ongoing sham
    proceedings themselves. See id. at 644, 97 S.Ct. at 2894
    (Blackmun, J., concurring in result); id. at 654, 660, 97 S.Ct. at
    11
    B.     Application of PRE to Present Case
    I now turn to the question of whether 3201 Realty can
    show that defendants’ activities were objectively baseless. I
    initially point out that 3201 Realty arguably has waived this
    issue, which is distinct from the question of whether to apply the
    alternative test that does not require objective baselessness, by
    not adequately arguing it on appeal.              3201 Realty’s
    supplemental reply brief starts from the premise that the
    alternative test to PRE applies but does not assert that
    defendants’ legal challenges lacked an objectively reasonable
    basis, and only briefly suggests that defendants did not have
    standing to bring these challenges or that the challenges
    otherwise lacked merit. See, e.g., John Wyeth & Bro. Ltd. v.
    CIGNA Int’l Corp., 
    119 F.3d 1070
    , 1076 n.6 (3d Cir. 1997)
    2899, 2902 (Stevens, J., dissenting). Subsequently, in a case
    arising under federal labor law, the Court drew on the sham
    exception to Noerr-Pennington to hold that an ongoing baseless
    lawsuit may be enjoined if it was brought for an improper
    purpose. See Bill Johnson’s Rests., Inc. v. NLRB, 
    461 U.S. 731
    , 744, 
    103 S.Ct. 2161
    , 2170 (1983).
    These Supreme Court cases illustrate that a plaintiff can
    bring an antitrust claim circumventing Noerr-Pennington
    immunity by relying on the sham exception even if the allegedly
    sham legal actions remain pending. This conclusion is logical
    given that a determination of whether anticompetitive legal
    actions fall within the sham exception turns not on their ultimate
    outcomes but on the existence of a reasonable basis (or a proper
    motive) for instituting and pursuing them in the first place. See
    PRE, 
    508 U.S. at
    60 n.5, 
    113 S.Ct. at
    1928 n.5.
    12
    (“[A]rguments raised in passing . . . , but not squarely argued,
    are considered waived.”). Nevertheless, I will give 3201 Realty
    the benefit of the doubt and consider the arguments that
    defendants’ actions were objectively baselessness to which it
    alluded in its supplemental reply brief. 3201 Realty simply
    cannot meet the objective baselessness standard that PRE
    recognized.
    Where the complaint fails at least to raise a question of
    fact on a sham petitioning issue, a court may reject the claim by
    granting a motion to dismiss. See PRE, 
    508 U.S. at 63
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1930
     (“Where, as here, there is no dispute over the
    predicate facts of the underlying legal proceeding, a court may
    decide probable cause as a matter of law.”); A.D. Bedell, 
    263 F.3d at 241
     (affirming dismissal under Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6)
    of antitrust claims based on Noerr-Pennington doctrine).
    In arguing that defendants’ legal challenges were
    objectively baseless, 3201 Realty primarily contends that they
    lacked standing when they made these challenges. For support,
    3201 Realty points to the decisions of the New Jersey Superior
    Court and the New Jersey Department of Environmental
    Protection (“NJDEP”) respectively concluding that Village
    lacked standing in its prerogative writs action and flood hazard
    area (“FHA”) permit challenges. But as I already have noted,
    the ultimate failure of an underlying action does not establish its
    objective baselessness. See PRE, 
    508 U.S. at
    60 n.5, 
    113 S.Ct. at
    1928 n.5 (“[W]hen the antitrust defendant has lost the
    underlying litigation, a court must ‘resist the understandable
    temptation to engage in post hoc reasoning by concluding’ that
    an ultimately unsuccessful ‘action must have been unreasonable
    or without foundation.’” (quoting Christiansburg, 
    434 U.S. at
    13
    421-22, 
    98 S.Ct. at 700
    )); Herr, 
    274 F.3d at 119
     (rejecting
    plaintiff’s claim of sham litigation where opinions in underlying
    actions demonstrated that courts analyzed relevant issues “with
    care and some detail” and did not consider them “frivolous”);
    Balt. Scrap Corp. v. David J. Joseph Co., 
    237 F.3d 394
    , 400 (4th
    Cir. 2001) (rejecting antitrust plaintiff’s claim of sham litigation
    notwithstanding that state court had dismissed underlying suit
    for lack of standing).
    3201 Realty has not shown that a reasonable litigant in
    Village’s position would have perceived that it did not have a
    realistic possibility of establishing standing in the relevant
    actions. To the contrary, the New Jersey Superior Court’s
    decision in the prerogative writs action demonstrates that a
    reasonable litigant could have perceived such a possibility in
    that case. In particular, Village cited several cases before that
    court in support of its claim that it had standing based on its
    status as a local taxpayer. For example, the court had stated in
    one of those cases that “[t]here is some support for the
    proposition that any local taxpayer has standing to object to a
    variance application, although the question has not clearly been
    resolved.” Vill. Supermarket, Inc. v. Mayfair Supermarkets,
    Inc., 
    634 A.2d 1381
    , 1385 (N.J. Super. Ct. Law Div. 1993)
    (citing Booth v. Bd. of Adjustment of Rockaway Twp., 
    234 A.2d 681
    , 682 (N.J. 1967)). The Superior Court ultimately
    decided this issue against Village, but “[i]n light of the unsettled
    condition of the law,” Village had a reasonable basis for its
    position. PRE, 
    508 U.S. at 65
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 1930
    .
    Similarly, in the FHA permit challenge, Village argued
    that its expected loss of business as a direct competitor of the
    proposed supermarket qualified as a sufficiently particularized
    14
    property interest to establish standing. But I need look no
    further than the discussion of antitrust standing in Judge
    Fuentes’s opinion to see that status as a direct competitor
    sometimes can demonstrate a unique property interest in filing a
    legal challenge. See, e.g., majority typescript at 26 (“Antitrust
    injury ordinarily is limited to consumers and competitors in the
    restrained market.”). Although the NJDEP ultimately decided to
    treat Village’s business interests as equivalent to other
    generalized interests that do not support standing, the cases on
    which it relied did not involve challenges brought by
    competitors and therefore did not foreclose Village’s argument.
    Village therefore had a reasonable basis for its position in this
    action as well. See 
    id.,
     
    113 S.Ct. at 1931
     (“Even in the absence
    of supporting authority, [the antitrust defendant] would have
    been entitled to press a novel . . . claim as long as a similarly
    situated reasonable litigant could have perceived some
    likelihood of success.”).
    Furthermore, 3201 Realty has not demonstrated that
    Village’s argument for standing in its wetlands permit challenge
    was any weaker than the foregoing arguments for standing.
    Finally, as to the major street intersection (“MSI”) permit
    challenge, the New Jersey Department of Transportation
    (“NJDOT”) affirmatively acknowledged Village’s standing to
    raise its objections, noting that the department was “required to
    consider any relevant data, analysis, and arguments submitted
    by third parties in reaching its decisions concerning the approval
    of access permits.” J.A. 165. I therefore reject 3201 Realty’s
    argument that defendants’ legal challenges should be regarded
    as objectively baseless because defendants lacked standing to
    make the challenges. See Balt. Scrap Corp., 
    237 F.3d at 400
    ;
    15
    Liberty Lake Invs., Inc. v. Magnuson, 
    12 F.3d 155
    , 157 (9th Cir.
    1993).
    Nor has 3201 Realty demonstrated that defendants’
    challenges were objectively baseless on their merits. Indeed, the
    relevant adjudicators upheld some of Village’s objections in two
    of these challenges. In the MSI permit challenge, the NJDOT
    agreed with Village that a prior development agreement required
    3201 Realty either to construct certain highway improvements
    or negotiate a new agreement before it could proceed with its
    project. Likewise, in the wetlands permit challenge, the NJDEP
    first “required” 3201 Realty to re-notice its application due to a
    defect that Village identified in the original application. J.A.
    169. Then, based on another objection raised by Village, the
    NJDEP required 3201 Realty to conduct a wildlife survey for
    the presence of an endangered species of bats before beginning
    work on the property. Although Village did not prevail in its
    other two challenges, the Superior Court’s and the NJDEP’s
    opinions in those proceedings each addressed Village’s
    contentions “with care and some detail” and without indicating
    that those reviewing bodies considered Village’s positions
    “frivolous.” See Herr, 
    274 F.3d at 119
    .
    In these circumstances, 3201 Realty has not shown that
    defendants’ petitioning activity was objectively baseless.
    Defendants’ conduct therefore falls within the immunity
    afforded by the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, and 3201 Realty’s
    antitrust claims must fail. Therefore, we should affirm the
    District Court’s order dismissing the complaint. Inasmuch as I
    have reached this conclusion, I do not address the other
    arguments that defendants raise in support of the District Court’s
    16
    order dismissing the complaint.5
    II. JUDGE AMBRO’S AND MY AGREEMENT THAT THE
    DISTRICT COURT ENTERED THE CORRECT JUDGMENT
    MANDATES AN AFFIRMANCE.
    As I stated at the outset of this opinion, Judge Ambro and
    I agree that the District Court correctly dismissed the complaint.
    Judge Ambro reaches this conclusion because he believes that
    3201 Realty did not have the antitrust standing necessary to
    bring this action, and I do so because I believe that defendants
    were immune under the Noerr-Pennington doctrine. A
    reasonable observer might think it is obvious that the
    inescapable consequence of this agreement is that we must
    affirm the District Court’s judgment dismissing the complaint.
    But Judge Ambro avoids this outcome by regarding himself as
    “bound by the majority’s [Judge Fuentes’s and Judge
    Greenberg’s] opinion on antitrust standing despite [his]
    disagreement with it,” Ambro typescript at 11, an application of
    the principle of stare decisis. He therefore effectively switches
    5
    On September 10, 2015, 3201 Realty’s attorneys filed a letter
    with attachments pursuant to Fed. R. App. P. 28(j) indicating
    that Village’s chief operating officer on August 12, 2015, filed a
    complaint in the Superior Court of New Jersey seeking an
    injunction stopping the clearing work on 3201 Realty’s property
    on the ground that 3201 Realty obtained its wetland permit by
    fraud. To the best of my knowledge this case has not been
    resolved so I do not take it into account as I do not know if the
    suit is objectively baseless.
    17
    what should be his vote from an affirmance of the Court’s order
    to a reversal. As a result a majority of the panel consisting of
    Judge Fuentes and Judge Ambro announce the Court’s judgment
    based on the following shifting majorities as to individual
    issues: (1) Judge Fuentes’s and my view that 3201 Realty has
    antitrust standing and (2) Judge Fuentes’s and Judge Ambro’s
    view that 3201 Realty’s complaint overcomes a Noerr-
    Pennington defense. I regard it as ironical that even though I
    believe we should affirm the judgment of the District Court, my
    view on an issue on which I would not decide the case is a factor
    leading to its reversal. Indeed, if I only stated my views on the
    Noerr-Pennington issue, then for certain we would be affirming
    because Judge Ambro surely would not have seen himself as
    bound by Judge Fuentes’s views if they stood alone. But I took
    a position on standing because courts usually if not always
    decide whether a plaintiff has standing before they consider the
    merits of a case.
    Although it is not my place to tell Judge Ambro how and
    on what issues to vote, I write here to express my view that a
    multimember panel should reach the result that follows from the
    independent views of its members. Judge Ambro’s willingness
    to be bound by the Fuentes-Greenberg majority’s position on
    antitrust standing trumps his own conclusion on the standing
    issue and runs counter to the longstanding and widespread
    practice of the federal courts of appeals of counting judges’
    views as to outcome and not as to individual issues. Although
    some scholars have criticized this prevailing practice, critics and
    proponents alike acknowledge its acceptance among the courts.
    See David S. Cohen, The Precedent-Based Voting Paradox, 
    90 B.U. L. Rev. 183
    , 222 (2010) (“[T]he [Supreme] Court currently
    18
    uses outcome voting to reach a result, as it votes on the outcome
    and then the Justices write their opinions to support the
    outcome.”); Lewis A. Kornhauser & Lawrence G. Sager, The
    One and the Many: Adjudication in Collegial Courts, 
    81 Cal. L. Rev. 1
    , 31 (1993) (“[T]he case-by-case protocol has been the
    encompassing norm of the Court throughout its existence.”);
    Jonathan Remy Nash, A Context-Sensitive Voting Protocol
    Paradigm for Multimember Courts, 
    56 Stan. L. Rev. 75
    , 86
    (2003) (“[T]he standard voting protocol is generally to
    determine the ultimate outcome in a case . . . based upon each
    judge’s views as to the outcome in the case.”); David Post &
    Steven C. Salop, Rowing Against the Tidewater: A Theory of
    Voting by Multijudge Panels, 
    80 Geo. L.J. 743
    , 750 (1992) (“It
    is clear that courts most frequently utilize outcome-voting.”);
    John M. Rogers, “Issue Voting” by Multimember Appellate
    Courts: A Response to Some Radical Proposals, 
    49 Vand. L. Rev. 997
    , 998 (1996) (“[T]he overwhelming practice of the
    justices on the Court has been to vote for the consequence of the
    individual justice’s own reasoning.”); Maxwell L. Stearns,
    Standing and Social Choice: Historical Evidence, 
    144 U. Pa. L. Rev. 309
    , 313-14 (1995) (“Within particular cases, the Court --
    along with virtually all appellate courts -- employs case-by-case,
    rather than issue-by-issue, decisionmaking.”).
    This practice of outcome voting comports with the
    general primacy that our law affords to judgments over
    opinions. See Jennings v. Stephens, 
    135 S.Ct. 793
    , 799 (2015);
    Edward A. Hartnett, A Matter of Judgment, Not a Matter of
    Opinion, 
    74 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 123
    , 127-34 (1999). It is well
    established that we review a district court’s judgment, not its
    opinion. See Jennings, 
    135 S.Ct. at 799
    ; Blunt v. Lower Merion
    19
    Sch. Dist., 
    767 F.3d 247
    , 303 n.73 (3d Cir. 2014), cert. denied,
    
    135 S.Ct. 1738
     (2015). Just as this principle requires us to
    affirm a district court’s judgment even if that court’s reasoning
    differs from our own, it also should lead us to affirm even if our
    respective grounds for doing so diverge. See Blunt, 767 F.3d at
    303 n.73 (affirming district court’s order even though only
    Judge Greenberg agreed with that court’s rationale because
    Judge Ambro reached same disposition on other grounds).
    In view of the primacy of judgments over opinions, we
    may enter judgments without even issuing opinions. See, e.g.,
    Quaciari v. Allstate Ins. Co., 
    172 F.3d 860
     (3d Cir. 1998);
    Hoover v. Watson, 
    74 F.3d 1226
     (3d Cir. 1995); see also Fed. R.
    App. P. 36. In fact, until some years ago this Court regularly
    disposed of appeals by issuing judgment orders without
    accompanying opinions, sometimes even in complex cases.
    Indeed, our internal operating procedures still authorize the use
    of judgment orders to announce the outcome of a case though
    the practice of using judgment orders has fallen into disuse. 3d
    Cir. I.O.P. 6.1. And in cases that do result in the issuance of
    opinions, both the Supreme Court and this Court issue the
    judgment supported by the independent views of a majority of
    the judges even if a majority does not coalesce around a single
    rationale. See, e.g., Kerry v. Din, 
    135 S.Ct. 2128
    , 2131 (2015)
    (plurality opinion); United States v. Dupree, 
    617 F.3d 724
    , 726
    (3d Cir. 2010); Cruz v. Chesapeake Shipping, Inc., 
    932 F.2d 218
    , 220 (3d Cir. 1991) (Rosenn, J., announcing the judgment of
    the court); cf. Michael v. Horn, 
    459 F.3d 411
    , 429 n.18 (3d Cir.
    2006) (Greenberg, J., concurring) (“[I]t is always true that even
    though judges agree on the appropriate outcome of a case, they
    would not write identical opinions.”). “That the court is able to
    20
    issue any judgment at all in such cases clearly demonstrates that
    outcome-voting has been utilized.” Post & Salop, Rowing
    Against the Tidewater, supra, at 750. Accordingly, “the
    outcome of a case in a multimember court depends on the tally
    of votes concerning the judgment even if the tally of votes
    concerning each issue resolved by opinion would logically
    produce a different conclusion.” Hartnett, supra, at 134.
    Judge Ambro declines to follow this accepted practice of
    independent outcome voting because of the “voting paradox”
    that arises if issue-by-issue resolution of a case would lead to a
    conclusion that is opposite to that reached based on outcome
    voting. But in the absence of the voting paradox it would not
    matter if a court decided a case on an issue-by-issue or outcome
    basis. Moreover, the Supreme Court repeatedly and consistently
    has utilized outcome voting even in cases implicating the voting
    paradox. See, e.g., Miller v. Albright, 
    523 U.S. 420
    , 
    118 S.Ct. 1428
     (1998); Am. Trucking Ass’ns, Inc. v. Smith, 
    496 U.S. 167
    ,
    
    110 S.Ct. 2323
     (1990); Nat’l Mut. Ins. Co. of D.C. v. Tidewater
    Transfer Co., 
    337 U.S. 582
    , 
    69 S.Ct. 1173
     (1949); see also
    Cohen, supra, at 183-84 (noting existence of more than 30 such
    cases in Supreme Court history). Moreover, as Judge (then
    Professor) Rogers has pointed out “[O]ver 150 Supreme Court
    cases involving plurality majority opinions indicate that a justice
    should not [aggregate votes by issue and therefore] defer to a
    majority that disagrees on a dispositive issue.” John M. Rogers,
    “I Vote This Way Because I’m Wrong”: The Supreme Court
    Justice as Epimenides, 
    79 Ky. L.J. 439
    , 459 (1990-91).
    So far as I can ascertain the only support in Supreme
    Court cases for Judge Ambro’s vote which leads to a result on a
    controlling issue in the case different from that which should
    21
    follow from his view of the case comes from three cases in
    which justices deferred to a majority on an issue that they would
    have resolved differently and therefore provided the decisive
    vote or votes in favor of a judgment that contradicted their own
    reasoning. See Arizona v. Fulminante, 
    499 U.S. 279
    , 313-14,
    
    111 S.Ct. 1246
    , 1267 (1991) (Kennedy, J., concurring in the
    judgment); Pennsylvania v. Union Gas Co., 
    491 U.S. 1
    , 56-57,
    
    109 S.Ct. 2273
    , 2295-96 (1989) (White, J., concurring in the
    judgment in part and dissenting in part); United States v. Vuitch,
    
    402 U.S. 62
    , 96, 
    91 S.Ct. 1294
    , 1311 (1971) (Harlan, J.,
    dissenting); 
    id. at 97-98
    , 
    91 S.Ct. at 1312
     (separate opinion of
    Blackmun, J.). Significantly, each of the other justices in these
    cases maintained the normal practice of voting for the judgment
    supported by the justice’s own reasoning. See Hartnett, supra, at
    137; Kornhauser & Sager, supra, at 18-19, 24. Moreover, the
    justices who gave the “structurally aberrant” votes did not offer
    any explanation for their divergence from accepted practice.
    Kornhauser & Sager, supra, at 2; see Nash, supra, at 84 (noting
    that judges who have employed issue-based voting have “simply
    do[ne] so by fiat”); Rogers, “Issue Voting”, supra, at 998
    (“There was no tenable justification given for the anomalous
    votes in each case . . . .”). These few deviations, “supported by
    simple ipse dixit, are pretty meager authority compared to the
    overwhelming precedent against” the majority’s approach.
    Rogers, “I Vote This Way Because I’m Wrong”, supra, at 463.
    Judge Ambro explains his use of issue voting and his
    consequent vote that results in an outcome that as an individual
    judge he rejects as a consequence of Judge Fuentes’s and my
    view on “the scope of the law of antitrust standing [which is]
    now the law of this Circuit . . . I am obliged to consider the
    22
    merits of [3201 Realty’s] suit.” Id. at 1. Thus, to Judge Ambro
    the principal of stare decisis applied on an internal basis within a
    case controls the outcome of this appeal even though he does not
    use the term stare decisis in explaining his view of how to
    decide the case. I believe, however, that this reasoning is
    incorrect. To start, at the time that Judge Ambro wrote these
    words, and even now, the panel had not yet filed an opinion in
    this case, so Judge Fuentes’s opinion cannot be the law of this
    Circuit. This point cannot be dismissed as a mere timing
    technicality because the draft opinion must be circulated to all
    the active judges of the Court who then have an opportunity to
    vote for initial en banc consideration of the case before the
    opinion is filed. 3d Cir. I.O.P. 5.5.
    Nor does Judge Ambro’s decision to defer in this case to
    a majority’s view on the standing issue present an apt analogy to
    the application of the principle of stare decisis. Deferring to a
    majority resolution of an issue within the same case does not
    serve the policies underlying stare decisis, including the
    protection of individuals’ reliance on earlier cases, the need to
    maintain consistency with earlier cases, the judicial efficiency of
    not revisiting issues that already have been decided, and the idea
    that the collective wisdom of courts over the years should
    supersede the limited insights of a court hearing a single case.
    See Rogers, “I Vote This Way Because I’m Wrong”, supra, at
    463-65. Furthermore, if a judge had an obligation to follow a
    panel majority’s conclusion there never should be a dissent.
    Yet as discussed, rather than following a rule of
    deference to a majority within the same case, judges nearly
    invariably vote for the result supported by their individual
    reasoning, whether the case involves a voting paradox or not. It
    23
    is obvious that each instance in which a judge dissents reflects
    an example of a judge declining to defer to a majority view.
    Accordingly, Judge Ambro’s use of the principle of stare decisis
    to support his vote runs “contrary to the overwhelming weight
    of precedent.” Rogers, “I Vote This Way Because I’m Wrong”,
    supra, at 440. Such rare and selective deference constitutes little
    deference at all, let alone a proper analogue to the rule of stare
    decisis, which serves very different purposes.
    I recognize that in voting-paradox cases, outcome voting
    does produce an apparently odd result when compared with the
    outcome that results when a case is decided on the basis of the
    judges’ individual reasoning regarding each underlying issue.
    But, contrary to Judge Ambro’s suggestion, outcome voting
    does not render the precedential value of such cases “unclear.”
    Ambro typescript at 22.
    Outcoming voting in this case would yield the following
    straightforward body of law for district courts in this Circuit to
    apply: (1) if a case arises that only implicates the standing issue,
    then, if the facts of that case cannot be distinguished from those
    here, the court should hold that the plaintiff has antitrust
    standing based on Judge Fuentes’s and my resolution of that
    issue; (2) if a case arises that implicates the Noerr-Pennington
    issue in a situation that factually cannot be distinguished from
    that in this case, the court should hold that the defendant lacks
    such immunity based on Judge Fuentes’s and Judge Ambro’s
    resolution of that issue; but (3) if a case arises presenting both
    issues, then, again, if the facts of that case cannot be
    distinguished from the facts here, the court should dismiss the
    case. See, e.g., Greene v. Teffeteller, 
    90 F. Supp. 387
    , 388
    (E.D. Tenn. 1950) (applying Supreme Court case that involved
    24
    voting paradox and emphasizing that “precedent is established
    by the votes of the justices, not by the reasons given for their
    votes.”). Although no judge would reach all of these three
    conclusions if acting alone, district courts could apply this
    tripartite rule both “easily” and “consistently.” Rogers, “Issue
    Voting”, supra, at 1013. Hence, outcome voting would produce
    “clear” guidance to district courts. Id. at 1009.
    Moreover, issue voting does not offer a panacea to the
    problem of voting paradoxes. Rather, issue voting raises its own
    set of potential difficulties, including indeterminacy in how to
    identify the relevant issues, the prospect of a judge strategically
    flipping the judgment by dividing an issue into deeper sub-
    issues where a majority of the judges agree as to the meta-issue
    but not as to the sub-issues, the possible inability of the court to
    issue a judgment due to cycling in how a majority would prefer
    to resolve the relevant issues, and the thwarting of a majority’s
    view as to the correct judgment. See Cohen, supra, at 223-24;
    Michael I. Meyerson, The Irrational Supreme Court, 
    84 Neb. L. Rev. 895
    , 947-49 (2006); Rogers, “Issue Voting”, supra, at
    1002-06; Maxwell L. Stearns, How Outcome Voting Promotes
    Principled Issue Identification: A Reply to Professor John
    Rogers and Others, 
    49 Vand. L. Rev. 1045
    , 1063-65 (1996);
    Maxwell L. Stearns, The Misguided Renaissance of Social
    Choice, 
    103 Yale L.J. 1219
    , 1267 n.177 (1994). Thus, even
    proponents of issue voting concede that “there is potential
    incoherence in an issue voting system” as well. David G. Post
    & Steven C. Salop, Issues and Outcomes, Guidance, and
    Indeterminacy: A Reply to Professor John Rogers and Others,
    
    49 Vand. L. Rev. 1069
    , 1083 (1996).
    The difficulties introduced by issue voting even may
    25
    undermine the clarity and usability of precedents, the very
    problem that Judge Ambro identifies as a consequence of
    outcome voting. See Rogers, “Issue Voting”, supra, at 1009-11.
    After all, just seven years after Justice White employed issue
    voting to change the outcome in Union Gas, the Supreme Court
    overruled that case partly because of the “confusion” it had
    created “among the lower courts that ha[d] sought to understand
    and apply the deeply fractured decision.” Seminole Tribe of
    Fla. v. Florida, 
    517 U.S. 44
    , 64, 
    116 S.Ct. 1114
    , 1127 (1996).
    The Court’s about-face can be viewed as “a criticism of the
    practice of vote switching” and may “stand[] for the proposition
    that holdings produced as a result of a vote switch will have
    only limited stare decisis value.” Maxwell L. Stearns, Should
    Justices Ever Switch Votes?: Miller v. Albright in Social Choice
    Perspective, 7 Sup. Ct. Econ. Rev. 87, 155 (1999). Problems
    therefore attend to either voting protocol. “Rather than rail at
    the dilemma wrought by the imperfections of our system [of
    outcome voting], . . . we should recognize that these
    imperfections are simply part of the inherent limitations of
    humanity.” Meyerson, supra, at 952.
    To the extent that judges find the voting paradox
    dissatisfying, instead of abandoning the longstanding and
    widespread practice of independent outcome voting, they can
    avoid the paradox by not considering issues after addressing an
    issue that would for them resolve the case. See id. at 951; Post
    & Salop, Issues and Outcomes, supra, at 1072 (noting that the
    paradox can only occur if “the judges reveal their views on each
    of the underlying issues presented by the case”). Unlike issue
    voting, the decision not to reach unnecessary questions, even
    when that decision involves not deferring to a majority on an
    26
    issue and results in a judgment not supported by a single
    majority rationale, has firm roots within our appellate court
    practice. See, e.g., Cruz, 
    932 F.2d at 233
     (Cowen, J., concurring
    in the judgment only); Lowry v. Balt. & Ohio R.R. Co., 
    707 F.2d 721
    , 723 (3d Cir. 1983) (en banc) (per curiam); see also
    Rogers, “I Vote This Way Because I’m Wrong”, supra, at 449
    n.27 (collecting more than two dozen such Supreme Court
    cases). Indeed, the voting paradox may so seldom appear in
    appellate court opinions because the judges in the majority as to
    outcome “typically do not reveal their views on issues that they
    ‘do not need to reach’ in order to vote for” that outcome. Post &
    Salop, Rowing Against the Tidewater, 
    supra, at 748
    .
    Again, it surely is not for me to tell another judge how to
    vote. Yet I cannot help being aware that there would not be a
    voting paradox here if Judge Ambro had gone no further after
    concluding that the District Court’s dismissal of the complaint
    should be affirmed on the ground that 3201 Realty lacks
    antitrust standing. There is no doubt that if Judge Ambro had
    followed this approach, we would affirm based on his and my
    independent reasoning. See Hartnett, supra, at 142-43 (“In
    [Union Gas and Fulminante], not only did the judgment
    ultimately entered fail to reflect how a majority of Justices
    believed the case should have been decided, but worse,
    unnecessary statements in opinions altered the judgment in the
    case. . . . That is not a result we should welcome . . . .”).
    In fact, if Judge Ambro had gone no further after
    concluding that the District Court’s judgment should be
    affirmed because 3201 Realty lacks antitrust standing, we
    inescapably would affirm regardless of whether we used
    outcome or issue voting. If we used outcome voting, then two
    27
    judges, Judge Ambro and I, would be voting to affirm. If we
    used issue voting, then the vote on the Noerr-Pennington issue
    would have been equally divided, with Judge Fuentes rejecting
    the defense of immunity and with me accepting it. The
    consequence of that even split is that the District Court’s order
    of dismissal would have been affirmed by an equally divided
    vote. See Exxon Shipping Co. v. Baker, 
    554 U.S. 471
    , 484, 
    128 S.Ct. 2605
    , 2616 (2008); In re Mkt. Square Inn, Inc., 
    978 F.2d 116
    , 121 (3d Cir. 1992). Though the District Court did not
    address the Noerr-Pennington issue as it had no need to do so
    because 3201 Realty did not convince the Court that it had
    antitrust standing, still defendants advanced the defense in that
    Court so that the claim of Noerr-Pennington immunity was
    preserved and thus defendants properly could raise it on this
    appeal. Accordingly, the usual rule that an equally divided
    appellate court leads to an affirmance of the trial court’s
    judgment would apply.
    Judge Ambro contends that if 3201 Realty had prevailed
    on the standing issue in the District Court and if the defendants
    were not barred from appealing by the final judgment rule and
    had appealed, we would have affirmed on the standing appeal.
    Then if defendants prevailed on the Noerr-Pennington issue in
    the District Court and 3201 Realty appealed we would have
    reversed. Thus, 3201 Realty would win the case even though a
    majority of the panel thought it should lose. While Judge
    Ambro may be correct on this point this hypothetical set of facts
    did not happen.
    Furthermore, a different hypothetical supports the use of
    outcome voting. Suppose this appeal had been decided by a
    single judge. If I had been that judge, then the District Court’s
    28
    order would be affirmed. If Judge Ambro had been that judge,
    once again the District Court’s order would be affirmed. Only if
    Judge Fuentes had been that judge, would the District Court’s
    order have been reversed. I cannot understand why the
    circumstance that we are all on the panel should lead to a
    different result than that which would have been reached
    individually by a majority of the panel.
    Issue voting “is in considerable tension with the
    traditional emphasis, rooted in Article III, on courts as case
    deciders.” Hartnett, supra, at 134 n.58. As has long been true,
    “[t]he question before [us as] an appellate Court is, was the
    judgment correct, not the ground on which the judgment
    professes to proceed.” McClung v. Silliman, 19 U.S. (6 Wheat.)
    598, 603 (1821). Although almost two centuries have passed
    since the Supreme Court decided McClung, the law that the
    Court stated there remains good law and no court has better
    expressed the principle that it recognized. Inasmuch as two of
    the three members of the panel agree that the judgment was
    correct, though for different reasons, surely we are constrained
    to affirm.6 Because the Court does not reach this result and
    because I believe that defendants have a Noerr-Pennington
    defense, I respectfully dissent from the outcome the Court
    reaches even though I agree with Judge Fuentes on his
    resolution of the standing issue.
    6
    In my view, this case can be resolved by making simple
    mathematical calculations that do not require that we use a super
    computer: (1) one and one make two, and (2) two out of three is
    a majority.
    29