Jacob Blinder & Sons, Inc. v. Gerber Products Co. , 166 F.3d 112 ( 1999 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                                                            Opinions of the United
    1999 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    1-12-1999
    Jacob Blinder & Sons v. Gerber Prod Co
    Precedential or Non-Precedential:
    Docket 97-5609
    Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1999
    Recommended Citation
    "Jacob Blinder & Sons v. Gerber Prod Co" (1999). 1999 Decisions. Paper 7.
    http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1999/7
    This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 1999 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
    Filed January 12, 1999
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    Nos.: 97-5609 and 98-5125
    In Re: Baby Food Antitrust Litigation
    JACOB BLINDER & SONS, INC., WISEWAY SUPER FOOD
    CENTER, INC., SUPER CENTER, INC., UNITED
    BROTHERS FINER FOODS, INC., L. L. HARRIS
    WHOLESALE GROCERY, PETER J. SCHMITT & CO., 3932
    CHURCH STREET SUPERMARKET, INC., ARLEEN FOOD
    PRODUCTS CO., INC., RUBIN BROOKS AND SONS, INC.,
    Appellants
    (D.C. Civil No. 92-cv-05495)
    JACOB BLINDER & SONS, INC., on behalf of itself and all
    others similarly situated
    v.
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION, (now
    dissolved) fka BEECH-NUT-NUTRITION fka BEECH-NUT
    FOODS CORPORATION (now dissolved) fka
    BAKER/BEECH-NUT CORPORATION (now dissolved) BCN
    CORPORATION, (now dissolved) fka BEECH-NUT
    CORPORATION; NESTLE HOLDINGS, INC.;
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 92-cv-05495)
    PETER J. SCHMITT CO., on behalf of itself
    v.
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION, (now
    dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT-NUTRITION aka BEECH-NUT
    FOODS CORPORATION (now dissolved) aka
    BAKER/BEECH-NUT CORPORATION (now dissolved) BCN
    CORPORATION, (now dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT
    CORPORATION; NESTLE HOLDINGS, INC.;
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 93-cv-00047)
    WISEWAY SUPER FOOD CENTER, INC., on behalf of itself
    and all others similarly situated
    v.
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION, (now
    dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT-NUTRITION aka BEECH-NUT
    FOODS CORPORATION (now dissolved) aka
    BAKER/BEECH-NUT CORPORATION (now dissolved) BCN
    CORPORATION, (now dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT
    CORPORATION; NESTLE HOLDINGS, INC.;
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 93-cv-00048)
    SUPER CENTER, INC., on behalf of itself and all others
    similarly situated
    v.
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION, (now
    dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT-NUTRITION aka BEECH-NUT
    FOODS CORPORATION (now dissolved) aka
    BAKER/BEECH-NUT CORPORATION (now dissolved) BCN
    CORPORATION, (now dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT
    CORPORATION; NESTLE HOLDINGS, INC.;
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 93-cv-00049)
    UNITED BROTHERS FINER FOODS, INC., on behalf of
    itself and all others similarly situated
    v.
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION, (now
    dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT-NUTRITION aka BEECH-NUT
    FOODS CORPORATION (now dissolved) aka
    BAKER/BEECH-NUT CORPORATION (now dissolved) BCN
    CORPORATION, (now dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT
    CORPORATION; NESTLE HOLDINGS, INC.;
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 93-cv-00050)
    L. L. HARRIS WHOLESALE GROCERY, a partnership, on
    2
    behalf of itself and all others similarly situated
    v.
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION, (now
    dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT-NUTRITION CORPORATION
    (now dissolved) aka BEECH-NUT FOODS CORPORATION
    (now dissolved) aka BAKER/BEECH-NUT CORPORATION
    (now dissolved) BNC CORPORATION, aka BEECH-NUT
    CORPORATION; (now dissolved); NESTLE
    HOLDINGS, INC.;
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 93-cv-00051)
    3932 CHURCH STREET SUPERMARKET, INC., an Illinois
    Corporation, on behalf of itself and all others similarly situated
    v.
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION,
    (formerly known successively as Baker/Beech-Nut
    Corporation, Beech Nut Foods Corporation, and Beech
    Nut Nutrition Corporation) (now dissolved); BNC
    CORPORATION, (formerly known as Beech-Nut
    Corporation) (now dissolved); NESTLE HOLDINGS, INC.;
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 93-cv-0320)
    ARLEEN FOOD PRODUCTS CO., INC., on behalf of itself
    and all others similarly situated
    v.
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION,
    (formerly known successively as Baker/Beech-Nut
    Corporation, Beech-Nut Foods Corporation, and Beech-
    Nut Nutrition Corporation) (now dissolved) BNC
    CORPORATION, (formerly known as Beech-Nut
    Corporation) (now dissolved); NESTLE HOLDINGS, INC.;
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 93-cv-0407)
    RUBIN BROOKS AND SONS, INC., on behalf of himself
    and all others similarly situated
    v.
    3
    GERBER PRODUCTS COMPANY; H.J. HEINZ COMPANY;
    RALSTON PURINA COMPANY; BNNC CORPORATION,
    (formerly known successively as Baker/Beech-Nut
    Corporation, Beech-Nut Foods Corporation and Beech-Nut
    Nutrition Corporation) (now dissolved); BNC
    CORPORATION, (formerly known as Beech-Nut
    Corporation (now dissolved); NESTLE HOLDINGS, INC.
    (Newark New Jersey Civil No. 93-cv-00802)
    Jacob Blinder & Sons, Inc., Wiseway Super Food Center,
    Inc., Super Center, Inc., United Brothers Finer Foods,
    Inc., L. L. Harris Wholesale Grocery, Peter J. Schmitt &
    Co., 3932 Church Street Supermarket, Inc., Arleen Food
    Products Co., Inc., Rubin Brooks and Sons, Inc.,
    Appellants in No. 98-5125
    Appeal for the United States District Court
    For the District of New Jersey
    D.C. Nos.: 92-cv-05495, 93-cv-00047, 93-cv-00048,
    93-cv-00049, 93-cv-00050, 93-cv-00051,
    93-cv-00320, 93-cv-00407
    District Judge: Honorable Nicholas H. Politan
    Argued: October 1, 1998
    Before: BECKER, Chief Judge, ROSENN, Circuit Judge and
    KATZ, District Judge*
    (Filed January 12, 1999)
    *The Honorable Marvin Katz, District Judge, Eastern District of
    Pennsylvania, sitting by designation.
    4
    Michael J. Freed, Esquire
    Much, Shelist, Freed, Denenberg,
    Ament, Bell & Rubenstein
    200 North Lasalle Street, Suite 2100
    Chicago, IL 60601
    and
    Joel C. Meredith, Esquire
    Daniel B. Allanoff, Esquire
    Meredith, Cohen, Greenfogel &
    Skirnick
    117 South 17th Street, 22nd Floor
    Philadelphia, PA 19103
    and
    Joseph J. De Palma, Esquire
    Allyn Z. Lite, Esquire
    Goldstein, Lite & De Palma
    Two Gateway Center, 12th Floor
    Newark, NJ 07102
    and
    Perry Goldberg, Esquire
    Granvil I. Specks, Esquire
    Specks & Goldberg
    10 South Wacker Drive, Suite 3500
    and
    Dianne M. Nast, Esquire
    Roda & Nast
    801 Estelle Drive
    Lancaster, PA 18702
    and
    Robert A. Skirnick, Esquire (Argued)
    Meredith, Cohen, Greenfogel &
    Skirnick
    63 Wall Street, 32nd Floor
    New York, NY 10005
    Counsel for Appellants
    Arnold B. Calmann, Esquire
    Saiber, Schlesinger, Satz &
    Goldstein
    One Gateway Center, Suite 1300
    Newark, NJ 07102
    5
    and
    Joseph A. Tate, Esquire (Argued)
    Judy L. Leone, Esquire
    George G. Gordon, Esquire
    Dechert, Price & Rhoads
    1717 Arch Street
    4000 Bell Atlantic Tower
    Philadelphia, PA 19103
    Counsel for Appellee Gerber
    Product Company
    Edward P. Henneberry, Esquire
    (Argued)
    Keith E. Pugh, Jr., Esquire
    Robert L. Green, Jr, Esquire
    Ellen S. Winter, Esquire
    Howrey & Simon
    1299 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W.
    Washington, DC 20004
    and
    Matthew P. Boylan, Esquire
    Lowenstein Sandler, Esquire
    65 Livingston Avenue
    Roseland, NJ 07068
    Counsel for Appellee HJ Heinz
    Company
    Mary E. Kohart, Esquire (Argued)
    Patrick T. Ryan, Esquire
    Patricia Proctor, Esquire
    Drinker, Biddle & Reath
    1345 Chestnut Street
    Philadelphia National Bank Building
    Philadelphia, PA 19107
    Counsel for Appellee Ralston
    Purina Company
    6
    Terrence C. Sheehy, Esquire
    (Argued)
    Howrey & Simon
    1299 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W.
    Washington, DC 20004
    Counsel for Appellees BNNC
    Corporation; BCN Corporation;
    and Nestle Holdings, Inc.
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    ROSENN, Circuit Judge.
    This appeal, relating to a highly concentrated nationwide
    industry, raises interesting questions of proof and law in a
    hotly-contested antitrust action. The plaintiffs, direct
    purchasers of baby food from defendant manufacturers,
    include wholesalers, supermarket chains, and other direct
    purchasers. The defendants, nationally prominent
    corporations, are Gerber Products Company ("Gerber"), H.J.
    Heinz Co. ("Heinz"), Nestle Food Company/Beech-Nut
    ("Nestle/Beech-Nut") and Ralston Purina Company/Beech-
    Nut ("Ralston/Beech-Nut") (collectively "Beech-Nut").1
    Collectively, they account for over 98% of all baby food
    products manufactured and sold in the United States.
    The plaintiffs are Jacob Blinder & Sons, Inc., Wiseway
    Super Food Center, Inc., Super Center, Inc., United
    Brothers Finer Foods, Inc., L.L. Harris Wholesale Grocery,
    Peter J. Schmitt & Co., 3932 Church Street Supermarket,
    Inc., Arleen Food Products Co., Inc., and Rubin Brooks and
    Sons, Inc. They brought this anti-trust class action against
    the defendant manufacturers under SS 4 and 6 of the
    Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. SS 15 and 26, in the United States
    District Court for the District of New Jersey. They allege
    that beginning in early 1975 and continuing until
    _________________________________________________________________
    1. Before 1989, Beech-Nut was owned by Nestle Food Co. In November
    1989, Ralston Purina purchased Beech-Nut from Nestle. Therefore, the
    four defendants are actually Heinz, Gerber, Nestle/Beech-Nut, and
    Ralston/Beech-Nut.
    7
    December 31, 1993,2 the defendants engaged in an
    unlawful conspiracy in violation of Section 1 of the
    Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. S 1) to fix, raise, and maintain
    wholesale prices and price levels of baby food in the United
    States resulting in injury and damage to the plaintiffs.
    At the conclusion of discovery, each defendant filed a
    motion for summary judgment. The District Court granted
    the motion in favor of all defendants. The clerk taxed costs
    in favor of the defendants and that court affirmed the
    award of costs.
    Defendants timely appealed from both orders to this
    court. We affirm.
    I.
    Background
    Gerber, although the smallest of the defendant
    corporations, is the nation's largest manufacturer of baby
    food products and accounts for approximately 70% of the
    total market in the United States. Heinz and Beech-Nut
    share almost equally the balance of the market. Gerber
    manufactures and sells approximately 200 different baby
    food products; Heinz follows closely with 165 and Beech-
    Nut with approximately 140. Collectively, they sell slightly
    more than 500 baby food products grouped into five broad
    categories: First Food, Second Foods, Third Foods, Cereals,
    and Juices. Together, they provide much of the nutrition for
    most of the nation's infant population.
    Through the pricing of their products, each defendant
    has sought to differentiate itself and carve out a company
    niche in the marketplace. Gerber is the undisputed market
    leader and premium brand, selling its products nationwide
    and focusing only on baby food. Heinz is the "value" brand,
    consistently adopting strategies to maintain a significant
    price spread between itself and Gerber. Heinz has had a
    strong presence in the central Midwestern and
    _________________________________________________________________
    2. The District Court certified the action as a class for the period
    beginning January 1, 1989, and ending December 31, 1992.
    8
    Southwestern parts of the country. Beech-Nut, initially
    positioned as a low-priced brand, underwent a struggle
    from 1985 through 1989 under Nestle ownership to become
    a premium brand with prices higher than Gerber's. In
    1989, when Ralston acquired Beech-Nut from Nestle,
    Ralston decided to elevate its price structure to be
    competitive with Gerber's. Beech-Nut traditionally has had
    a strong presence in New England, New York, and Eastern
    Pennsylvania.
    Many retailers have come to carry only two brands of
    baby food. Gerber is almost always one of the two.
    Significantly, each company has two pricing levels: the list
    price and the transaction price. The list price, the price
    officially announced by the company, is used as a base
    price from which customer discounts and allowances are
    deducted to obtain the transaction price. The transaction
    price is the price at which the wholesalers and supermarket
    chains actually buy the baby food; the price takes into
    account discounts, bulk-purchasing, rebates, regional
    considerations, and special promotions. The
    manufacturers, however, do not offer discounts across the
    board; at any given time, one customer may pay a different
    price than the next customer for the same product. Heinz
    claims that it sells more than 80% of its baby food at prices
    below list. In addition, Heinz and Beech-Nut do not
    implement uniform national price increases, often delaying
    increases in particular geographic regions.
    The plaintiffs' foremost allegation is that the defendants
    exchanged information with each other regarding future
    price increases before announcing any increases to the
    public. Plaintiffs maintain that the defendants had no
    legitimate business reason for informing each other of price
    increases before publicly announcing them except for their
    motivation to conspire. The plaintiffs allege that Gerber, the
    dominant company in the industry and the price leader,
    would decide to raise its prices and, if the other two
    competitors did not follow the price increase immediately,
    the time-gap between Gerber's price increase and the
    increases of the other companies would be of sufficient
    length to disturb their respective market shares. Therefore,
    giving advance notice solved this problem. The plaintiffs
    9
    claim that because advance notice did occur, this evidences
    that an agreement economically to conspire among the
    defendants was in place.
    Following exhaustive discovery over a period of three
    years, the District Court granted summary judgment for all
    defendants on the ground that plaintiffs' case was "sorely
    lacking" in any evidence pointing to an agreement among
    the defendants to fix prices. The plaintiffs timely appealed.
    II.
    The Underlying Legal Concepts
    The legal fulcrum for the plaintiffs' complaint is Section
    1 of the Sherman Act. Section 1 provides: "Every contract,
    combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or
    conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the
    several States, or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to
    be illegal." 15 U.S.C. S 1. The existence of an agreement is
    the hallmark of a Section 1 claim. Alvord-Polk, Inc. v. F.
    Schumacher & Co., 
    37 F.3d 996
    , 999 (3d Cir. 1994).
    Liability is necessarily based on some form of "concerted
    action." Id.3 Indeed, we have defined a conspiracy as a
    "conscious commitment to a common scheme designed to
    achieve an unlawful objective." Edward J. Sweeney & Sons,
    Inc. v. Texaco, Inc., 
    637 F.2d 105
    , 111 (3d Cir. 1980). In
    other words, " ``unity of purpose or a common design and
    understanding or a meeting of the minds in an unlawful
    arrangement' must exist to trigger Section 1 liability."
    
    Alvord-Polk, 37 F.3d at 999
    , (quoting Copperweld Corp. v.
    Independence Tube Corp., 
    467 U.S. 752
    , 771 (1984)).
    In determining whether certain concerted action amounts
    to an unreasonable restraint this court applies one of two
    methods of analysis. See e.g. Rossi v. Standard Roofing,
    
    156 F.3d 452
    , 461 (3d Cir. 1998). The concerted action is
    either analyzed (1) through the per se sta ndard, which
    _________________________________________________________________
    3. The phrase "concerted action" is often used as shorthand for any form
    of activity meeting the Section 1 " ``contract . . . combination or
    conspiracy' requirement." Bogosian v. Gulf Oil Corp., 
    561 F.2d 434
    , 445-
    46 (3d Cir. 1977) quoting L. Sullivan, Law of Anti-Trusts, p. 312 (1977).
    10
    presumes that the questionable conduct has anti-
    competitive effects without comprehensive inquiry into
    whether the concerted action produced adverse, anti-
    competitive effects, or (2) through the so-called rule of
    reason, a case-by-case method that involves consideration
    of all of the circumstances of a case to decide whether
    certain concerted action should be prohibited because it
    amounts to an anti-competitive practice. The analysis to be
    applied depends on the essence of concerted action in
    dispute. 
    Id. Generally, price-fixing
    agreements are considered a per se
    violation of the Sherman Act. See United States v. Socony-
    Vacuum Oil Co., 
    310 U.S. 150
    , 218 (1940). Per se violations
    include those types of restraints on competition that are in
    and of themselves considered unreasonable because "their
    pernicious effect on competition and lack of any redeeming
    virtue are conclusively presumed to be unreasonable."
    United States v. Cargo Service Stations, Inc., 
    657 F.2d 676
    ,
    682 n.4 (5th Cir. Unit B 1981) (quoting Northern Pacific Ref.
    v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5 (1958)). However, when the
    evidence consists of mere exchanges of information the
    presumption vanishes. See United States v. United States
    Gypsum Co., 
    438 U.S. 422
    , 441 n.16 (1978). Exchanges of
    information are not considered a per se violation because
    "such practices can in certain circumstances increase
    economic efficiency and render markets more, rather than
    less, competitive." Gypsum, 
    Id. at 441
    n.16. Therefore, such
    exchanges of information are evaluated under a rule of
    reason analysis.
    This court has previously articulated what Section 1 rule
    of reason analysis entails. We laid down four steps of proof
    that a plaintiff must present: (1) that the defend ants
    contracted, combined or conspired among each other;
    (2) that the combination or conspiracy produced ad verse
    anti-competitive effects within the relevant product and
    geographic markets; (3) that the objects of and co nduct
    pursuant to the contract or conspiracy were illegal; and
    (4) that the plaintiffs were injured as a proximat e result of
    that conspiracy. J.F. Fesser, Inc. v. Serv-A-Portion, Inc., 
    909 F.2d 1524
    , 1541 (3d Cir. 1990).4 Under the rule of reason,
    _________________________________________________________________
    4. The District Court disposed of plaintiffs' case under the first prong
    of
    Fesser; it did not reach prongs (2), (3), and (4). Only Nestle questioned
    11
    all the evidence presented must be weighed to determine
    whether the defendants' purported price fixing practices
    violated the Sherman Act.
    III.
    The Evidence
    Although there are some subordinate questions, the
    instant case stands or falls on the question whether the
    plaintiffs produced sufficient probative evidence to meet the
    demanding standard of proof required in the context of an
    antitrust case. Accordingly, we turn to an analysis of the
    voluminous evidence introduced by the plaintiffs.
    The plaintiffs have produced extensive circumstantial
    evidence, but claim that their direct evidence sufficiently
    proves a price-fixing conspiracy. They spiritedly claim that
    their direct evidence of reciprocal price exchanges and a
    collusive truce is sufficient to support a Section 1
    conspiracy claim. Direct evidence in a Section 1 conspiracy
    must be evidence that is explicit and requires no inferences
    to establish the proposition or conclusion being asserted.
    As we noted recently in Rossi, with direct evidence "the fact
    finder is not required to make inferences to establish 
    facts." 156 F.3d at 466
    .
    The plaintiffs heavily rely on the deposition testimony of
    Brian Anderson, formerly employed by Heinz as a sales
    representative until 1986, and Marshall Gibbs, formerly
    employed by Heinz as a district sales manager until 1984.
    Their testimony reveals that they were required to submit
    competitive activity reports to their superiors concerning
    baby food sales from information they picked up from
    competitor sales representatives. The information they
    obtained was verbal and usually passed on orally to their
    superiors. There was no organized system to secure the
    _________________________________________________________________
    whether   the defendants provided sufficient proof of fact of injury and
    damages   under prong (4). Because the District Court did not address
    and the   defendants did not argue that plaintiffs' evidence fell short with
    respect   to prongs (2) and (3), we do not consider them.
    12
    information; it was obtained sporadically, verbally, and
    informally in conversations among the representatives.
    Anderson testified that his supervisor, Area Manager Fred
    Runk, informed him on a regular basis before any
    announcement to the trade as to when Heinz's competitors
    were going to increase the wholesale list prices of their baby
    food products. Anderson also testified that he exchanged
    future price information with various sales representatives
    of Beech-Nut and Gerber as to whether Heinz, Beech-Nut,
    and Gerber were planning to announce future price
    increases. Moreover, according to Anderson, such
    exchanges between sales representatives were common in
    the baby food industry.
    Gibbs similarly testified that he personally exchanged
    pricing information with sales representatives of the other
    companies. Specifically, Gibbs stated "[I] would, obviously,
    get with another rep., and say, you can give me and I can
    give you and we can pat each other on the back and get
    this information in because we both have the same
    accountability." Beech-Nut also required its sales
    representatives to gather competitive information. In their
    depositions, Neils Hoyvald, President of Beech-Nut prior to
    1988, and James Nichols, who succeeded Hoyvald, testified
    that it was company policy for sales representatives to
    gather and report pricing information of their competitors.
    On September 1, 1986, Gerber's New York Division
    Manager, Don Beaudoin, sent a competitive price change
    and activity report to Gerber's Regional Manager for the
    Eastern Region and Vice President of Sales. Attached to the
    report was an unsigned Beech-Nut announcement of a
    forthcoming September 29, 1986 price increase. Beech-Nut
    executives admitted that Gerber appears to have had
    possession of the September 29 price increase
    announcement as early as September 1, 1986, but claim
    ignorance as to how Gerber obtained the document.
    Beech-Nut obtained advance notice of a February 13,
    1989 Gerber price increase at least a week before it was
    announced to the trade. Each page of the memorandum
    was stamped "HIGHLY CONFIDENTIAL." The memorandum
    instructed the division managers not to notify their
    accounts of the price increase until February 13, 1989, the
    13
    effective date of the increase. Gerber did not notify the
    trade of the price increase until February 13, 1989, yet
    Beech-Nut knew of the increase at least as early as
    February 6, 1989.
    Gerber had advance knowledge of a May 1, 1989 Beech-
    Nut price increase at least a day before it was announced
    to the trade. A March 31, 1989 memorandum from Norman
    Knorr of Gerber confirms this by describing a March 27
    conference call between Gerber's Al Gorsky, Vice President
    of Sales, and Gerber's regional managers. The
    memorandum stated in part: "We received a report from the
    Boston Division that a [Beech-Nut] price increase will be in
    effect on May 1. Details were telexed to the field."
    Beech-Nut had advance knowledge of a planned February
    1990 Gerber list price increase as early as two months and
    no less than eight days before its announcement to the
    trade on December 28, 1989. In an October 13, 1989
    memorandum to Theuer, Joseph Gaeto, Vice President of
    Marketing of Beech-Nut, wrote, "I strongly suspect that
    Gerber will increase their prices on Friday, March 2, 1990."
    In a December 20, 1989, memorandum to Beech-Nut's
    regional and zone managers, Humbarger (Beech-Nut's
    Operation Manager in New York) stated "We have heard
    very strong rumors that Gerber will most likely increase
    their base price in February, 1990."5
    In a competitive activity report one week before Beech-
    Nut's announcement on November 27, 1991, of a list price
    increase that excluded the West Coast, Dick Grainger,
    Gerber's Los Angeles District Manager, reported to Jerri
    Jean Wilson, Gerber Director of Field Communications, a
    "[r]umor that Beech-Nut will not advance prices for at least
    three months [on the West Coast]." The same day, Grainger
    also sent a report to Gerber's Vice-President, Al Gorsky,
    _________________________________________________________________
    5. Plaintiffs assert that in the baby food industry a communication from
    a competitor is referred to as "rumor," a term of art. This
    characterization is attributed to an exchange between plaintiffs' counsel
    and Jerri Jean Wilson, Gerber's Director of Field Communications,
    during her deposition, where she stated that "rumor" means chit-chat
    that occurs among employees of the defendants on "the street."
    14
    that advised "Beech-Nut has no plans for a price increase
    within the next three months."
    A September 25, 1992, e-mail from Beech-Nut's Bob
    Butcher related the details of a conversation between
    Beech-Nut's District Manager Joe Piscola and Frank
    Garritano of Gerber, in which Piscola told Garritano that
    Beech-Nut would not be taking "a price increase at this
    time." A handwritten note on the Gerber e-mail printout
    stated, "Keep me advised on any price increases by
    competition! We will be in a world of hurt if Heinz/Beech-
    Nut does not increase." Al Gorsky, among others at Gerber,
    received copies of this document. James Nichols, President
    of Beech-Nut, also testified that at least two to three times
    a year Mick Humbarger would inform him of conversations
    between Beech-Nut and Gerber personnel in metropolitan
    New York.
    Plaintiffs also point to a varied assortment of documents
    and memoranda they introduced into evidence, the most
    significant of which are: (1) A September 1, 198 6 Gerber
    memorandum which plaintiffs assert proves that Gerber
    had advance knowledge of a September 29, 1986 Beech-
    Nut list price increase on all of its products. Notice of the
    increase was not officially sent to the Beech-Nut brokers
    and sales force for announcement to the trade until
    September 4, 1986. (2) A February 6, 1989, letter from
    Nestle's President, Theuer, to the Chairman of his Board
    notifying him that "[w]e have unconfirmed news from the
    trade that on February 13, Gerber will increase prices." On
    February 10, Theuer wrote that "it is confirmed that Gerber
    will increase prices on February 13, 1989." Theuer testified
    that he assumes that he received this information from the
    trade, in light of his language in the February 6 memo.
    (3) Plaintiffs' remaining examples show that Gerber knew of
    a Beech-Nut price increase one day before it was
    announced.
    In addition, plaintiffs point to defendants' expert Dr.
    William C. Myslinski's testimony that "when two defendants
    . . . get together and they mutually exchange information"
    and "indicate to each other what they are going to charge
    in the future," such conduct "would be consistent with a
    conspiracy." In addition, they highlight the defendants'
    15
    failure to explain how Gerber knew of the September 4,
    1986 price increase three days early, when Beech-Nut's
    sales force and customers were not told of the increase
    until September 4.
    Furthermore, the plaintiffs submitted evidence of a 1984
    Heinz communication from Gerber's area manager, Ron
    Coble, to his superior, Terry Ryan. The background for
    Coble's communications, the plaintiffs claim, was an
    important shift in the early 1980s in the baby food
    industry. Baby food distributors realized that it was no
    longer economically beneficial to stock each of the
    defendants' products. They decided to turn to a "two-brand"
    system and stock the market leader, Gerber, and either
    Heinz or Beech-Nut. Coble's memorandum to Ryan stated:
    In Nov. 1983, I was told by MDI management [a
    prospective Heinz customer] that they wanted to stock
    only two brands of baby food -- Gerber and someone
    else. Their main objective was to stock the lines that
    were preferred by the retailers. I advised them that we
    would make every effort to secure a majority base of
    distribution. However, with our "truce" in effect, I knew
    our hands were tied.
    The plaintiffs regard this memorandum as significant direct
    evidence of price-fixing. At his deposition, Coble testified
    that he did not recall why he used the word "truce," but
    believed that it referred to the Heinz Marketing Department.
    They, he stated, made the policies "based on costs" as to
    the territories where the company was to do business.
    The plaintiffs hypothesize that in the early 80s, changes
    in consumers' purchasing practices caused a change in the
    wholesalers' market strategy that "provoked a new market
    dynamic characterized by a price struggle between Heinz
    and Beech-Nut for the second brand position, a struggle in
    which Gerber was forced to join in order to preserve its own
    market share." Although this episode does not appear to
    relate to price-fixing but to unfair competition, the plaintiffs
    argue that the "truce" had the effect and purpose of
    enabling the defendants to fix prices.
    The plaintiffs assert that their version of the "truce" is
    supported by statements and correspondence from other
    16
    Heinz employees. For instance, the plaintiffs note that Tim
    Senft, Heinz's Manager of Sales Planning, explained to a
    subordinate that "[t]he days of 3/store are gone - B/N's
    [Beech-Nut's] move to Stages[6] nationally should abate the
    war. We don't want it to start again."
    Furthermore, the plaintiffs contend that the impact of the
    "truce" on the level of competition is evidenced by (1) a
    letter from Neils L. Hoyvald, President of Beech-Nut, to
    James Biggar, Chairman of Nestle Enterprises, Inc., in
    which he states that they were able to accomplish"[t]he
    elimination of all competitive counter offers, which was
    stopped late 1983 and the situation has held, with Heinz
    following our initiative";7 (2) a 1984 internal Heinz
    memorandum from Holscher and Haviland requesting
    extension of an allowance on strained food in the Florida
    district, which contained a statement that Heinz lost
    distribution in fiscal year 1983 in Miami "and since Heinz
    has taken the position that we do not want to [pursue] the
    business in Miami," a Beech-Nut market App. at 1739; and
    (3) a note to a 1985 Heinz memorandum from Senft t o
    Costello stating: "There are people who think . .. [that
    Heinz's] . . . previous attempts to gain distribution in Miami
    . . . started the last ``Tet Offensive.' "
    To boost their claim that the 1984 "truce" in price
    competition existed, plaintiffs point to the absence of any
    list price increases for the two and one half years preceding
    the "truce," but note that after it became effective, list
    prices increased at least once a year. Plaintiffs also claim
    that Heinz's refusal to enter the Chicago market
    demonstrated the truce's success.
    We have reviewed the documentary evidence and the
    testimony of Anderson and Gibbs and we conclude that
    they do not make out a case of direct evidence. The
    plaintiffs here have been unable to present evidence of
    conspiracy to fix prices without drawing on inferences from
    all of the evidence they have introduced. The direct
    _________________________________________________________________
    6. According to plaintiffs, "Stages" marked the beginning of Beech-Nut's
    effort to displace Gerber as the premium price brand of baby food and
    end its competition with Heinz for the more price sensitive consumer.
    7. At the time, Beech-Nut was owned by Nestle.
    17
    evidence evinces only an exchange of information among
    the defendants. Accordingly, we apply the rule of reason.
    
    Amey, 758 F.2d at 1505
    .
    We, therefore, turn to the parallel pricing evidence on
    which the plaintiffs also rely to prove joint collaborative
    action.
    IV.
    Parallel Pricing
    In the absence of direct evidence, the plaintiffs may
    nevertheless support their claim with circumstantial
    evidence of conscious parallelism. Weit v. Continental
    Illinois National Bank & Trust Company, 
    641 F.2d 457
    , 462
    (7th Cir. 1981). Conscious parallelism, sometimes called
    oligopolistic price coordination, is described as the process
    "not in itself unlawful, by which firms in a concentrated
    market might in effect share monopoly power, setting their
    prices at a prefixed maximizing, supracompetitive level by
    recognizing their shared economic interests and their
    interdependence with respect to price and output
    decisions." Brooke Group, 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 227 (1993). The
    theory of conscious parallelism is that uniform conduct of
    pricing by competitors permits a court to infer the existence
    of a conspiracy between those competitors. Todorov v. DCH
    Healthcare Authority, 
    921 F.2d 1438
    , 1456 n.30 (11th Cir.
    1991). The theory is generally applied to highly
    concentrated markets where few sellers exist and where
    they establish their prices, not by express agreement, but
    rather in a consciously parallel fashion. Shapiro v. General
    Motors, 
    472 F. Supp. 636
    , 647 (D.Md. 1979). Thus, when
    two or more competitors in such a market act separately
    but in parallel fashion in their pricing decisions, this may
    provide probative evidence of the existence of an
    understanding by the competitors to fix prices. 
    Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1456
    n.30.
    In an oligopolistic market, meaning a market where there
    are few sellers, interdependent parallelism can be a
    necessary fact of life but be the result of independent
    pricing decisions.
    18
    [I]n a market served by three large companies, each
    firm must know that if it reduces its price and
    increases its sales at the expense of its rivals, they will
    notice the sales loss, identify the cause, and probably
    respond. In short, each firm is aware of its impact
    upon the others. Though each may independently
    decide upon its own course of action, any rational
    decision must take into account the anticipated
    reaction of the other two firms. Whenever rational
    decision-making requires an estimate of the impact of
    any decision on the remaining firms and an estimate of
    their response, decisions are said to be
    "interdependent." Because of their mutual awareness,
    oligopolists' decisions may be interdependent although
    arrived at independently."
    Areeda, Antitrust Law S 1429 (1986). See Bogosian v. Gulf
    Oil Corp., 
    561 F.2d 434
    , 446 (3d Cir. 1977).
    Because the evidence of conscious parallelism is
    circumstantial in nature, courts are concerned that they do
    not punish unilateral, independent conduct of competitors.
    Matsushita Elec. Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 594 (1985). They therefore require that evidence
    of a defendant's parallel pricing be supplemented with "plus
    factors." Petruzzi's IGA v. Darling-Delaware, 
    988 F.2d 1224
    ,
    1243 (3d Cir. 1993). The simple term "plus factors" refers
    to "the additional facts or factors required to be proved as
    a prerequisite to finding that parallel action amounts to a
    conspiracy." Areeda, Antitrust Law S 1433(e). They are
    necessary conditions for the conspiracy inference. Venzie
    Corp. v. United States Mineral Products Co., 
    521 F.2d 1309
    ,
    1314 (3d Cir. 1975); Areeda, S1434. They show that the
    allegedly wrongful conduct of the defense was conscious
    and not the result of independent business decisions of the
    competitors. The plus factors may include, and often do,
    evidence demonstrating that the defendants: (1) ac ted
    contrary to their economic interests, and (2) were motivated
    to enter into a price fixing conspiracy. See 
    Petruzzi's, 998 F.2d at 1242
    .
    The concept of "action against self-interest" is ambiguous
    and one of its meanings could merely constitute a
    restatement of interdependence. As the court pointed out in
    19
    Coleman v. Cannon Oil Company, 
    849 F. Supp. 1458
    , 1467
    (N.D. Ala. 1993), refusing to raise or lower prices unless
    rivals do the same could be against a firm's self-interest but
    nevertheless could spring from independent behavior.
    Similarly, conspiratorial motivation is ambiguous because it
    "can describe mere interdependent behavior and, therefore,
    it could mean that interdependent behavior is a Sherman
    Act Section 1 conspiracy." Areeda, S 1434(c). Thus, no
    conspiracy should be inferred from ambiguous evidence or
    from mere parallelism when defendants' conduct can be
    explained by independent business reasons.
    Once the plaintiffs have presented evidence of the
    defendants' consciously parallel pricing and supplemented
    this evidence with plus factors, a rebuttable presumption of
    conspiracy arises. 
    Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1456
    n.30. "[T]he
    mere presence of one or more of these ``plus factors' does
    not necessarily mandate the conclusion that there was an
    illegal conspiracy between the parties, for the court may
    still conclude, based upon the evidence before it, that the
    defendants acted independently of one another, and not in
    violation of antitrust laws." Balaklaw v. Lovell, 822 F.
    Supp. 892 (N.D. N.Y. 1993); 
    Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1456
    n.30.
    In an effort to reinforce their claim of collusive price-
    fixing, plaintiffs presented the testimony of an expert for the
    purpose of showing a pattern of parallel price increases in
    each of the five baby food product categories throughout
    the certified time period, except for the First Food category
    in August 1992. The plaintiffs requested Dr. Albert
    Madansky to conduct statistical analyses of the defendants'
    list price increases for the period January 1989 through
    December 1992. He concluded that the results of his
    analyses established a pattern of parallel pricing by the
    defendants. Dr. Madansky's conclusion is depicted infive
    charts. The charts represent each of the five categories of
    baby food: First Foods, Second Foods, Third Foods, Cereals,
    and Juices.
    Through his analysis of the defendants' average monthly
    list prices, Dr. Madansky further concluded that
    transaction prices likewise increased in parallel fashion
    from 1989 to 1992. Again, similar to what he did with list
    20
    prices, his analysis of transaction price trend lines is
    depicted in five charts that reflect the five categories of baby
    foods. According to Dr. Madansky, the charts show that the
    defendants' prices moved upward in parallel fashion on
    99.5% of the total volume analyzed.
    The plaintiffs argue documentary and testimonial
    evidence also confirm that the defendants engaged in
    parallel pricing and prove that the price increases resulted
    from concerted action by the defendants. They point to an
    internal Beech-Nut memo of February 24, 1989, from
    Joseph Gaeto, Beech-Nut's Vice-President of Marketing, to
    Theuer stating: "We have taken a position [of] parity with
    Gerber to reflect our current plan for a price increase this
    year." In addition, Beech-Nut's 1988 Long Term Plan
    pontificated "Gerber will accept the price leadership of
    Beech-Nut and will accept price increases as a means of
    improving profitability." They also cite the testimony of
    Heinz's area manager, Ron Coble, that Heinz's "selling
    philosophy" from 1970 to the early 1990s was to sell their
    products at 29È a case below the prices of Beech-Nut and
    Gerber on all 24-pack merchandise. Plaintiffs argue that
    the maintenance of more or less constant differentials
    between defendants' prices is clear evidence of parallel
    pricing.
    The plaintiffs also contend that the evidence they
    produced showed that the defendants' pricing was
    "conscious." For this purpose, they rely heavily on the
    reciprocal exchange in pricing information previously
    referred to, including the deposition testimony of Anderson
    and Gibbs. The plaintiffs therefore argue that sales
    representatives of each defendant, largely at the behest of
    senior management and mostly by word of mouth,
    maintained a continuous network to exchange price
    information as well as a system to communicate that
    information to executive decision makers. The plaintiffs
    claim that the evidence shows that the defendants on a
    consistent basis ordered their sales representatives to
    gather competitive information, such as their competitors'
    pricing plans and strategies. The plaintiffs aver that once
    this information was obtained, the sales representatives
    reported the information to their area or territory manager,
    who in turn passed the information on to their superiors.
    21
    In addition, the plaintiffs argue that the defendants'
    pricing data represents parallel list and transaction pricing.
    They assert that following the "truce" an understanding
    existed among the defendants not to intrude upon the
    other's position in the market place, which culminated in
    an agreement to jointly coordinate and implement price
    increases. In support of their theory of the defendants' price
    parallelism, plaintiffs claim that their expert's testimony
    shows statistical analysis of the defendants' list price
    increases per pack between January 1989 and December
    1992. The plaintiffs also contend that the parallel list price
    increases caused the transaction prices to increase and,
    thus, the transaction prices suffered from parallel pricing
    as well. Specifically, as to the period certified for the class
    action, January 1, 1989 to December 31, 1992, plaintiffs
    maintain that defendants' list prices and actual transaction
    prices were higher than they would have been had the
    defendants not engaged in price fixing.
    V.
    Summary Judgment Principles
    This court's review of the District Court's grant of
    summary judgment is plenary. Erie Telecommunications,
    Inc. v. City of Erie, 
    853 F.2d 1084
    , 1093 (3d Cir. 1988). We
    evaluate the evidence using the same standard the District
    Court applied in reaching its decision.
    Summary judgment is warranted where "there is no
    genuine issue as to any material fact and that the moving
    party is entitled to a judgment as a matter of law." Fed. R.
    Civ. P. 56(c). In the context of an antitrust case, the
    nonmoving party's burden "is no different than any other
    case." Big Apple BMW, Inc. v. BMW of North America, Inc.,
    
    974 F.2d 1358
    , 1363 (3d Cir. 1992). Hence, "summary
    judgment should be granted if, after drawing all reasonable
    inferences from the underlying facts in the light most
    favorable to the nonmoving party, the court concludes that
    there is no genuine issue of material fact to be resolved at
    trial and the moving party is entitled to judgment as a
    matter of law." Petruzzi's IGA v. 
    Darling-Delaware, 998 F.2d at 1230
    (3d Cir. 1993).
    22
    The extent of what constitutes a reasonable inference in
    the context of an antitrust case, however, is somewhat
    different from cases in other branches of the law in that
    "antitrust law limits the range of permissible inferences
    from ambiguous evidence in a S 1 case." 
    Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 588
    . The acceptable inferences which we can draw
    from circumstantial evidence vary with the plausibility of
    the plaintiffs' theory and the danger associated with such
    inferences. 
    Petruzzi's, 998 F.2d at 1232
    . Therefore, the
    Supreme Court has held in the antitrust context "that
    conduct consistent with permissible competition as with
    illegal conspiracy does not, standing alone, support an
    inference of antitrust conspiracy." 
    Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 588
    , (citing 
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764
    ). Thus, to withstand
    a motion for summary judgment "a plaintiff seeking
    damages for a violation of S 1 must present evidence that
    tends to exclude the possibility that the alleged competitors
    acted independently." 
    Id. The reason,
    of course, is that
    mistaken inferences in such a context "are especially costly
    because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are
    designed to protect." 
    Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 594
    .
    In deciding whether summary judgment is warranted, the
    District Court may not weigh the evidence or make
    credibility determinations. Big Apple 
    BMW, 974 F.2d at 1363
    . Moreover, the non-movants' evidence should be
    analyzed as a whole and not be tightly compartmentalized
    to see if together it supports an inference of concerted
    action. Big Apple 
    BMW, 974 F.2d at 1364
    .
    A plaintiff in a Section 1 conspiracy can establish a case
    solely on circumstantial evidence and the reasonable
    inferences to be drawn therefrom, and the movant
    defendant for summary judgment bears the burden of
    proving that drawing inferences of unlawful behavior is
    unreasonable. 
    Petruzzi's, 998 F.2d at 1230
    . "Nonetheless,
    in drawing favorable inferences from underlying facts, a
    court must remember that often a fine line separates
    unlawful concerted action from legitimate business
    practices." 
    Id. Therefore, care
    must be exercised to ensure
    that inferences drawn of unlawful behavior from ambiguous
    evidence do not infringe upon the defendants' freedom. 
    Id. Thus, the
    court must ascertain whether the plaintiffs have
    23
    presented "evidence that is sufficiently unambiguous"
    showing that the defendants conspired. 
    Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 597
    .
    With these principles in mind, we address the evidence
    before us.
    VI.
    Analysis of the Evidence
    The District Court carefully considered the plaintiffs'
    evidence concerning the reciprocal exchange of price
    information by the defendants. The court concluded that
    the evidence did not support an inference of a conspiracy to
    fix prices but portrayed nothing more than intense efforts
    on the part of three large and strong competing companies
    in the baby food industry to ascertain:
    [w]hat their competitors would be doing with regard to
    pricing, promotions and products. . . . These instances
    do not allow the inference of some conspiracy to fix
    prices. Much of the specific instances cited by plaintiffs
    concern not pricing information, but promotional or
    product information of certain defendants which were
    reported by other defendants." D.C. Op. at p. 27.
    With respect to the written documents of one competitor
    found in the files of another, the court determined that
    many of them reflect competitive information concerning
    the discontinuance of products or changes in product
    ingredients or in packaging. It concluded that the presence
    of this information was consistent with independent action
    and not grounds for assuming "some shadowy conspiracy."
    
    Id. The plaintiffs
    assert that the exchange of pricing
    information by lower level employees is sufficient to defeat
    a motion for summary judgment in Section 1 cases.8 We
    _________________________________________________________________
    8. At oral argument, the plaintiffs cited the following cases as authority
    for this assertion: Vernon v. Southern Calif. Edison Co., 
    955 F.2d 1361
    (9th Cir. 1992); In re Coordinated Pretrial Proceedings, 
    906 F.2d 432
    (9th
    24
    disagree. Evidence of sporadic exchanges of shop talk
    among field sales representatives who lack pricing authority
    is insufficient to survive summary judgment. Krehl v.
    Baskin Robbins Ice Cream Co., 
    664 F.2d 1348
    , 1357 (9th
    Cir. 1982). Furthermore, to survive summary judgment,
    there must be evidence that the exchanges of information
    had an impact on pricing decisions. See 
    Krehl, 664 F.2d at 1357
    . Plaintiffs, for this purpose, rely on their expert's
    opinion that concerted action drove the transaction prices
    up 6.16%.
    The plaintiffs here contend that the holdings of United
    States v. Container Corp. of America, 
    393 U.S. 333
    (1969)
    and United States v. United States Gypsum Co., 
    438 U.S. 422
    (1978) compel the conclusion that the evidence they
    presented concerning the exchange of future pricing
    information impacted the market as a whole and is more
    than sufficient to survive summary judgment. We do not
    agree.
    In Container Corp., the court held that the reciprocal
    exchange of price information pursuant to an agreement by
    the defendants was concerted action sufficient to establish
    a price-fixing conspiracy. It analogized the agreement
    among the defendants there with the "sophistication and
    well-supervised plan for the exchange of price information
    between competitors" in American Column & Lumber Co. v.
    United States, U.S. 
    257 U.S. 377
    (1921) and the "elaborate
    plan for the exchange of price data among competitors" in
    United States v. American Linseed Oil Co., 
    262 U.S. 371
    (1923).
    _________________________________________________________________
    Cir. 1990); Rosenfield v. Falcon Jet Corp., 
    701 F. Supp. 1053
    (D.N.J.
    1988). However, we conclude that none of these cases support the
    plaintiffs. Vernon did not involve price-fixing; rather, it concerned
    whether the defendant denied the plaintiff access to certain power
    transmission lines. In Pretrial Proceedings, testimony indicated that
    upper level executives engaged in secret conversations regarding product
    pricing. 
    Id. at 450.
    Similarly, in Rosenfield, testimony showed that
    several upper level executives "were aware of the price information
    exchange and considered the data obtained by sales engineers to set the
    price of business jets." 
    Id. at 1064.
    25
    In Container Corp., the plaintiffs presented direct
    evidence of an agreement among the defendants to
    exchange pricing information, as well as evidence that once
    a defendant had the competitors' pricing information, in a
    "majority of instances," the defendant quoted the same
    price as his competitor. This compared to evidence of
    periods where there were no pricing exchanges and
    "exceptionally sharp and vigorous price reductions
    resulted." 
    See 393 U.S. at 340
    (Fortas, J., concurring).
    Conversely, in Gypsum, the Court could not have been
    more clear: "The exchange of price data and other
    information among competitors does not invariably have
    anticompetitive effects; indeed such practices can in certain
    circumstances increase economic efficiency and render
    markets more, rather than less, 
    competitive." 438 U.S. at 443
    n.16.
    The plaintiffs also complain that the District Court
    improperly weighed Anderson's testimony and failed to even
    consider Gibbs' testimony. Anderson was a salesman, who
    characterized his status as "a little mouse." He had no
    authority to set the prices for the baby food he sold. His
    superior did not instruct him to provide competitors with
    information. He considered himself a good salesman, and,
    therefore, his practice was to garner as much information
    as he could find "in the street" about the competition.
    Whatever competitive information he acquired he passed on
    to his superior. The information came from chit-chat during
    chance encounters in the field among competitors'
    employees with whom he was acquainted. Runk, his
    superior, never directed him to disseminate Heinz price
    information to competitors in the field.
    We have held previously that communications between
    competitors do not permit an inference of an agreement to
    fix prices unless "those communications rise to the level of
    an agreement, tacit or otherwise." 
    Alvord-Polk, 37 F.3d at 1013
    . See also 
    Amey, 758 F.2d at 1505
    (11th Cir.
    1985)(Exchange of pricing information by itself is an
    insufficient basis upon which to allow an inference of
    agreement to fix prices); Market Force Inc. v. Wauwatosa
    Realty Co., 
    906 F.2d 1167
    , 1173 (7th Cir. 1990)("[i]t is well
    established that evidence of informal communications
    26
    among several parties does not unambiguously support an
    inference of a conspiracy.") Gathering competitors' price
    information can be consistent with independent competitor
    behavior. See e.g., Stephen Jay Photography Ltd. v. Olan
    Mills, Inc., 
    903 F.2d 988
    , 996 (4th Cir. 1990); Wallace v.
    Bank of Bartlett, 
    55 F.3d 1166
    , 1169 (6th Cir. 1995).
    The District Court appropriately discounted Gibbs's
    testimony entirely because he gave it in another proceeding
    involving Heinz's vinegar product, not baby food. Neither
    Gerber nor Beech-Nut manufactured vinegar. Moreover, he
    testified that (1) any communications he had wit h
    competitors were neither related to setting the price of
    vinegar nor related to any agreement with competition on
    the price of vinegar, (2) the information he commu nicated
    was all current or public, and (3) Heinz generally did not
    act on any information obtained through those
    communications. We see no error in the court's treatment
    of Gibbs's testimony.
    The plaintiffs also argue that the assortment of
    memoranda found in the files of the defendants concerning
    advance prices of competition, one or two of which were
    unexplained, proved "a pervasive exchange of confidential
    information concerning future promotions." We do not
    believe that the mere possession of competitive memoranda
    is evidence of concerted action to fix prices. In a highly
    competitive industry, as is the baby food industry, intensely
    dependent on marketing strategy, it makes common sense
    to obtain as much information as possible of the pricing
    policies and marketing strategy of one's competitors.
    The fact that the price information about one company
    is found in a competitor's files or an employee reports
    a competitor's pricing policy to his home office and the
    two companies charge similar prices for their products,
    without more, cannot support an inference that the
    two competitors entered into an agreement to share
    prices. To successfully raise an inference that two
    competitors agreed to share price information, a
    complainant must produce some evidence which tends
    to exclude the possibility that the competitors acted
    independently.
    27
    Stephen Jay 
    Photography, 903 F.2d at 996
    (citing
    
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764
    ).
    The plaintiffs stressed during trial and on appeal the
    significance of the evidence concerning the "truce." They
    argue that the District Court simply erred in its treatment
    of all the evidence presented regarding this incident. They
    contend that the District Court failed to discuss the 1984
    memorandum from Hoyvald to Biggar, in which Hoyvald
    stated that all large competitive counter-offers have been
    eliminated, or Heinz's rejection of McCloskey's
    recommendation for Heinz to enter the Chicago market in
    1988 and 1991. Further, they take issue with the court's
    conclusion that the 1984 truce memorandum was
    "irrelevant to Gerber" and "clearly as consistent with
    normal business conduct as it is with some alleged
    conspiracy between Heinz and Beech-Nut."
    The plaintiffs failed to present any evidence
    demonstrating that Gerber was involved in a "truce." In
    considering the evidence relating to the "truce," the District
    Court concluded:
    [t]here is evidence that 1984 marked the end of a trade
    war in the baby food business, and certain customers
    at that time, in certain areas of the country, utilized a
    "two-brand approach." This meant that those
    customers would stock Gerber products and either
    Heinz or Beech-Nut products. . . . The Court notes that
    it would be irrelevant to Gerber if this truce did in fact
    exist, so the Court declines to make the leap that
    Gerber had any input into an alleged "truce."
    Op. at 33. As to Coble's explanation for his isolated, single
    use of the term in his 1984 memorandum, the District
    Court concluded that the deposition testimony of other
    Heinz employees "corroborate[d] the fact that Heinz was
    skittish about doing anything which might erupt in another
    conflagration in the industry. This evidence is clearly as
    consistent with normal business conduct as it is with some
    alleged conspiracy between Heinz and Beech-Nut." 
    Id. at 33-34.
    We agree.
    The "truce" expression relied on by the plaintiffs was
    largely intended to buttress their case on reciprocal price-
    28
    fixing. However, the single use of the term in a highly
    competitive business environment and in the face of
    continuing fierce competition is as consistent with
    independent behavior as it is with price-fixing.
    Furthermore, the explanation for the use of the term by an
    employee without price-fixing authority is more plausibly
    explained as an exercise of independent business judgment
    by Heinz not to enter a new market. The evidence reflects
    Heinz's strategic planning as to whether and when to
    pursue particular business opportunities. We are unwilling
    to question such business judgment. Furthermore, the
    price-fixing inferences that the plaintiffs would have us
    draw from this evidence, which relates ostensibly to
    business competition and not price-fixing, require us to
    make an unjustified jump in judgment that this record does
    not warrant, especially in the face of the District Court's
    conclusion.
    The plaintiffs place great weight on Heinz's decision not
    to invest in the Chicago and the Miami markets. 9 However,
    such investment required substantial capital expenditures
    and resource commitments. Only Heinz was in a position to
    decide whether it was in its best interest to make such
    commitments, particularly in light of its interests in many
    other products in the general food industry. Only it knew
    how much spending on promotion and allowances would be
    required to penetrate the Chicago market, and how much
    competitive resistance it would encounter, whether the cash
    flow generated would justify committing a portion of its
    finite marketing budget, or whether there were better
    opportunities elsewhere. We can discover no hard evidence
    that allowances and promotion activity was abandoned at
    the time or in the geographic territory referred to in these
    documents.
    Moreover, Coble's 1984 memorandum, which used the
    _________________________________________________________________
    9. Plaintiffs assert that Heinz's McCloskey strongly advocated that Heinz
    enter the Chicago market in 1988 and 1991 and its unwillingness to
    enter proves that the 1984 "truce" remained in place. Plaintiffs ignore,
    however, the effort of Heinz to enter the Chicago market in 1988,
    evidenced by its formal, written proposal to Dominick's, a large Chicago
    supermarket chain. Dominick's rejected the proposal.
    29
    term "truce," also reports aggressive competition: "We
    attempted to expand our distribution from July to
    November 1983, but were unsuccessful in obtaining any
    significant distribution gains. Every attempt to dislodge
    Beech-Nut was met with defensive programs that were
    substantial." Furthermore, there would be strategic issues
    for Heinz to consider, that might draw fire from its
    competitors. They could aggressively respond to Heinz's
    territorial expansion in the expanded area and in other
    territories that might prove the expansion to be eruptive,
    destructive, and expensive. These considerations may have
    weighed against the likelihood of long-run success in
    Heinz's ability to maintain its presence on retail shelves
    and gain market share in the face of its competitors'
    response. Such decisions are consistent with permissible,
    rational competitive conduct. We therefore hold that
    plaintiffs' evidence pertaining to the alleged "truce" is not
    sufficiently probative of unlawful concerted action.
    The plaintiffs argue that they presented substantial
    evidence that the defendants' list and transaction prices
    increased in parallel fashion. In addition to their expert's
    affidavit, they also state that the testimony of other
    witnesses and documentary evidence confirm that the price
    increases were attributable to the defendants' consciously
    parallel action. On appeal, therefore, they vigorously assert
    that the District Court overlooked and otherwise
    disregarded this important evidence of conspiratorial price-
    fixing.
    In the absence of direct evidence, as we previously stated,
    consciously parallel business behavior can be important
    circumstantial evidence from which to infer an agreement
    in violation of the Sherman Act. 
    Weit, 641 F.2d at 462
    .
    Although "mere consciously parallel behavior alone is
    insufficient to prove a conspiracy, it is circumstantial
    evidence from which, when supplemented by additional
    evidence, an illegal agreement can be inferred." 
    Petruzzi's, 998 F.2d at 1242
    . In an oligopoly consisting of no more
    than three companies at one time and collectively
    controlling almost the entire market, there is pricing
    structure in which each company is likely aware of the
    pricing of its competitors. The District Court in this case
    30
    concluded that upon examining the charts prepared by
    plaintiffs' expert, Dr. Madansky, the defendants' prices were
    not parallel. The plaintiffs were "unable to show that
    defendants' prices moved in a parallel fashion. This is true
    both for list prices and transaction prices. . . . On this basis
    alone, plaintiffs' case fails." D.C. op. at 21.
    The District Court noted that there were many "clear
    instances," for example, when Gerber raised its prices and
    Beech-Nut lowered theirs or kept them the same. For
    instance, "in March of 1990, Gerber raised the prices . . .
    [and] [i]n that same period, Heinz lowered its prices." D. C.
    op. at 23-24. The court also pointed to many instances
    where Gerber either lowered its prices or kept them the
    same when Heinz and/or Beech-Nut raised theirs. 
    Id. at 24.
    The court also observed upon examining Dr. Madansky's
    report that all during the alleged conspiracy period, "there
    were fifteen instances (out of 175) where Gerber, Beech-
    Nut, and Heinz all raised their prices. There were seven
    instances where the three lowered their prices, and there
    were five where they kept them the same." Thus, it
    concluded that "15.5% of the time, Gerber, Beech-Nut, and
    Heinz made similar pricing decisions. . . . That leaves,
    however, 84.5% of the time during which defendants priced
    their products differently." (Id. at 24).
    From our own analysis of the evidence, we perceive no
    error on the part of the District Court in concluding that
    the evidence was insufficient to prove conscious
    parallelism. Because Gerber controlled 70% of the market
    in baby foods and was the acknowledged leader in this
    industry, Gerber's pricing understandably may have had an
    influence on its competitors' pricing. Conscious parallelism,
    however, will not be inferred merely because the evidence
    tends to show that a defendant may have followed a
    competitor's price increase. See, e.g., Theatre Enterprises v.
    Paramount Film Dist. Corp., 
    346 U.S. 537
    , 541 (1954);
    Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Inst., 
    851 F.2d 478
    ,
    484 (1st Cir. 1988).
    The plaintiffs complain that the District Court
    disregarded the testimony of their expert, Dr. Madansky,
    with respect to parallelism. We can well understand the
    District Court's attitude toward this expert's testimony and
    31
    supporting charts. In an industry with hundreds of
    products and a pervasive policy of allowing discounts and
    promotional allowances to purchasers, allowances that
    varied even to the same customer if it conducted business
    in different geographical areas, charts and reports focusing
    on list prices rather than transactional prices have little
    value. "Especially in an oligopoly setting, in which price
    competition is most likely to take place through less
    observable and less regular means than list prices, it would
    be unreasonable to draw conclusions about the existence of
    tacit coordination or supracompetitive pricing from data
    that reflect only list prices." Brooke 
    Group, 509 U.S. at 236
    .
    Yet, the plaintiffs focus on the defendants' list pricing. In
    their initial brief, they assert that Dr. Madansky proffered
    substantial, uncontroverted evidence from which a jury
    could find "list price parallelism." They also point to Dr.
    Madansky's January 14, 1997 affidavit in which he
    analyzed "defendants' list prices and submitted five charts
    . . . graphically depicting the parallel movement of
    defendants' list prices over time." 
    Id. (Emphasis added)
    Without making any effort, or offering any explanation for
    his failure to do so, Dr. Madansky made no statistical
    analysis of the movement of defendants' transaction prices.
    His conclusion with respect to transaction prices is reached
    by simply comparing defendants' list prices over time with
    the corresponding trend line of average monthly transaction
    prices on a per pack basis to show that following list price
    increases, transaction prices increased. Dr. Madansky's
    original testimony and report made no reference to
    transactional prices. Dr. Madansky made no in-depth
    analysis of transaction prices. His affidavit of January 14,
    1997, came as a response to the District Court's request
    and arguments of defendants' counsel at the oral hearing
    on the motion for summary judgment.
    Furthermore, Dr. Madansky's analysis did not consider
    any transaction pricing for Nestle/Beech-Nut.10 Moreover,
    _________________________________________________________________
    10. Dr. Madansky initially set out to determine the prices paid by the
    plaintiffs to the defendants for baby food products. His results were
    based on "the monthly dollar-volume weighted average of the per ounce
    price paid by Gerber and Beech-Nut customers who qualified for pricing
    at the 40,000 lb. or over price bracket and by all Heinz customers for the
    baby foods comprising Gerber's First Foods, Second Foods, Third Foods,
    Juices, and Cereals categories . . . ." The purpose at the time apparently
    was to provide a basis for damages.
    32
    he relies on "trend lines" of average transaction prices, not
    actual prices of the other companies, to reach a conclusion
    that transaction prices increased following list price
    increases. We do not believe that trend lines of average
    prices are a reliable indicator of transactional prices.
    Moreover, a trend line showing an increase in transaction
    prices for baby foods during a period of the economy when
    general food prices were increasing is readily
    understandable and charts depicting it are not helpful as
    evidence of parallelism. See Consumer Price Index -- All
    Urban Consumers, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Food and
    Beverages, 1967-1998.
    We see a further weakness in the methodology of Dr.
    Madansky's report that also furnished a sufficient basis for
    the District Court to reject it as proof of parallelism. The
    defendants sold their baby food products by the case and
    priced their sales by the case. Dr. Madansky's report of
    conscious parallelism is predicated on a per ounce basis. In
    response to the criticism his initial report evoked at the
    summary judgment hearing, Dr. Madansky submitted his
    January 1997 affidavit in which he concluded that"a per
    pack (i.e. per unit) basis during the period January 1989
    through December 1992 in each product category reveal[ed]
    that defendants increased their list prices in parallel
    fashion." (Emphasis added). He then leaped to the
    conclusion, ipse dixit, that "[a] per case analysis . . . would
    yield the same results as [his] per pack analysis because
    case sizes in the relevant baby food categories did not
    change during the period." Again his conclusion is based on
    list prices.
    The plaintiffs also point to the charts provided in Dr.
    Madansky's January 1997 affidavit as proof that the
    defendants' prices exhibited parallel behavior. There are 31
    charts. Charts 1-5 represent a comparison of defendants'
    list price increases on a per pack (i.e. per unit) basis and
    purport to show that defendants' list prices increased in
    parallel fashion. However, the pertinent inquiry is on the
    prices actually paid, the transaction prices. Thus, these
    charts' probity is minimal. Charts 6-20 represent"[a]
    comparison of defendants' list price increases over time
    with the corresponding trend line of average monthly
    33
    transaction prices on a per pack basis." However, the
    defendants sell baby food to their customers by the case.
    Therefore, these charts do not reflect case transaction
    prices.
    Charts 21-26 purport to compare "defendants' list prices
    to defendants' monthly average transaction prices on a per
    pack basis in the month immediately preceding their next
    list price increase." These charts focus on Dr. Madansky's
    use of trend lines. These trend lines reveal nothing more
    than that the transaction prices tended to increase over
    time. However, such analysis has been explicitly rejected by
    the Supreme Court. "[R]ising prices do not themselves
    permit an inference of a collusive market dynamic. Even in
    a concentrated market, the occurrence of a price increase
    does not in itself permit a rational inference of conscious
    parallelism or supracompetitive pricing." Brooke 
    Group, 509 U.S. at 237
    .
    The explanation proffered by the plaintiffs for Dr.
    Madansky's calculations on a per ounce basis is that it
    provided a common unit for the defendants' products
    because they sold some of the same products in different
    size jars. The use of a per ounce calculation, however,
    especially when utilizing list prices, reflected prices within
    a fraction of one cent of each other. The District Court
    commented that such a methodology was at odds with
    marketing practices for "the industry does not use [per
    ounce prices] when setting list prices. Per ounce prices are
    necessarily within a fraction of one cent of each other due
    to the relatively minimal per ounce cost." D.C. Op. at 24. As
    the defendants observe, if Dr. Madansky had performed his
    analysis on the basis of quarter-ounces, the distribution
    prices would appear even closer together. They claim his
    conversion into ounces "is an attempt to mask the real
    price differential." The defendants argue that analyzing
    price differentials on a per ounce basis is misleading.
    For example, by reducing prices from a per-case basis
    to a per-ounce basis, plaintiffs reduced the unit of
    measurement by a factor of almost 100 in the case of
    Gerber Second Foods (one case equals approximately
    96 ounces) and by a factor of 30 in the case of Gerber
    First Foods (one case equals 30 ounces). When prices
    34
    are measured properly, in terms of price per case,
    plaintiffs cannot argue that each of the defendants'
    prices are within cents of each other.
    In response to this telling criticism of the inappropriate
    use of the per-ounce calculation, Dr. Madansky's January
    affidavit moved to a per-pack comparison. He then leaps
    the gap to a per-case analysis. He accomplishes this with
    the aid of a slender, unsupported strand in his affidavit
    stating that a "per case analysis (adjusting for Gerber's
    smaller case size in First Foods) would yield the same
    results as my per ounce analysis because case sizes in the
    relevant baby food categories did not change during the
    period." This amounts to nothing more than an observation
    which adds little substance, if any, to his opinion.
    In their appeal to this court, the plaintiffs rely on the per-
    pack analysis made in Dr. Madansky's January affidavit.
    Although this is a more reasonable unit size, the
    defendants observe that the plaintiffs do not argue that the
    per-package analysis of defendants' list or transaction
    prices were within cents or fractions of cents of each other,
    nor could they. Moreover, the defendants argue that the
    step graphs generated by Dr. Madansky in his January
    1997 affidavit compress the time axes to a minute scale to
    create the illusion of parallel pricing. In addition, as we
    have previously mentioned, the step graphs are based on
    list prices and the accompanying charts (Numbers 27-31)
    depict average monthly price trend lines on a per pack
    basis.
    Even when measured in ounces, as the defendants'
    analysis of the Madansky data illustrates, the evidence
    shows that the defendants' actual transaction prices moved
    in different directions more often than not. The undisputed
    evidence shows similar disparities with respect to list
    prices: sometimes competitors did not follow price increases
    at all, other times they followed by less, sometimes by the
    same amount, and sometimes they followed only in certain
    geographic areas.
    With respect to the plaintiffs' contention that the District
    Court ignored substantial testimony of defendants' own
    employees that confirmed the parallel movement of
    35
    defendants' list prices, as well as their expert, we turn to
    the specific documents and testimony to which they point
    in support of this argument. The plaintiffs refer to two
    documents: (1) a February 24, 1989 memorandum from
    Joseph Gaeto, Beech-Nut Vice President of Marketing, to
    Richard Theuer, Beech-Nut's then President, stating "we
    have taken a position [of] parity with Gerber to reflect our
    current plan for a price increase," and (2), a Heinz
    communication dated Nov. 5, 1991, from employee Wyker
    to his superior that "requests approval to implement a
    Grocery Baby Food Price Increase to match the recently
    announced Gerber Price Increase." The plaintiffs note that,
    in sharp contrast to the District Court's conclusion, the
    defendants' own economic expert, Dr. Almarin Phillips, as
    well as Coble, testified that it was Heinz's general policy to
    maintain a "more or less constant differential" between
    Gerber's list prices and Heinz's list prices. 
    Id. The District
    Court may not have specifically addressed
    this testimony but that does not mean the court ignored it.
    Nonetheless, we will address it in light of the plaintiffs'
    argument on appeal. The Beech-Nut memorandum
    regarding cereal prices confirms the plaintiffs' assertion
    that Beech-Nut has "taken a position [of] parity with
    Gerber." However, plaintiffs omitted the preceding phrase
    explaining that the position was taken "[F]or market
    reasons. . . ." Furthermore, the charts Dr. Madansky
    generated show that Nestle/Beech-Nut's list cereal prices
    were not at parity with Gerber's prices. The charts show
    that in February 1989, the same month as the date on the
    Beech-Nut document, Gerber's cereal prices jumped from
    slightly below Beech-Nut's prices to well above those prices,
    and that Beech-Nut's cereal prices did not rise again until
    seven months later, shortly before Nestle left the baby food
    business. The same Nestle/Beech-Nut document upon
    which plaintiffs rely repeatedly emphasizes that prices were
    being raised due to market factors, including increased
    costs in raw materials and packaging, and that the
    incremental price increase was less than the increase in
    costs. This document, therefore, reflects Beech-Nut's
    competitive behavior and not conscious parallelism.
    Contemporaneous documents also show that Heinz made
    independent pricing decisions in 1989. On February 14,
    36
    1989, Joe Fay, Heinz's product manager, sent Robert
    Roussey, Heinz's general business manager, a
    memorandum obtained from the trade, attaching a copy of
    Gerber's announced wholesale price advance effective
    February 13, 1989. Fay recommended that Heinz follow
    immediately on four of its food categories, but delay
    announcing any strained 4.2 oz juice price increase"till
    we've analyzed the strained retail pricing analysis study."
    On March 2, 1989, Fay recommended that Heinz
    implement a price increase effective May 4, 1989, to"match
    Gerber's and maintain our per ounce case differentials
    versus Gerber" on Junior, Meat, Cereal, and Juice.
    Conversely, Fay also recommended Heinz increase prices
    by only 11c or 2% on Beginner Foods, compared to
    Gerber's price increase of 40c on the same product
    segment due to Heinz's "inability to obtain our desired retail
    price differential using larger LTA [long term allowance] and
    smaller base cost differential." A revised Fay memorandum
    dated March 23, 1989, reflecting Heinz's decision to depart
    from Fay's original recommendation, was attached to the
    final product price change form. Furthermore, the memo
    revealed Heinz's decision not to match Gerber increases in
    Meats or Junior Foods, and "to expand our retail price
    differentials to levels (2-3c on Meats, 4c on Junior Foods)
    which will improve the volume of these historically
    declining businesses."11 Thus, these memoranda show in-
    depth, unilateral behavior, not collusive conformation.
    The defendants' personnel and expert testified that it was
    Heinz's general policy to maintain a "more or less constant
    differential" between Gerber's list prices and Heinz's list
    prices. Contrary to the plaintiffs' argument, the District
    Court did not ignore this testimony. Rather, the testimony
    _________________________________________________________________
    11. We observe that most of the documents introduced by the plaintiffs
    merely discuss "rumors" that the authors heard or "suspicions" that they
    had. As such, the documents can be discounted as non-probative for
    they show a lack of knowledge about the competitors' pricing and are
    inconsistent with a price-fixing scheme. For example, in the March 2,
    1990, Beech-Nut document to which the plaintiffs point, the author
    merely states that he "anticipates" a Gerber price increase in the first
    quarter of 1987. In another Beech-Nut document the author has had
    heard "very strong rumors" of a Gerber price increase. App. at 3893a.
    37
    shows a business judgmental policy to offer the public
    consumer a "value brand" at a price less costly than the
    price offered by the market leader, Gerber. This policy fails
    to prove parallel price behavior.
    Market realities also clearly controvert the plaintiffs'
    contention. On March 30, 1987, six months after Beech-
    Nut's price increase, Heinz increased the list price on cereal
    by an amount that was less than Gerber and Beech-Nut to
    maintain its traditional position "as the price value brand."
    The same fiscal year 1987 price increase memorandum
    recommendation to Roussey noted that "[i]n September
    FY87, Beech-Nut attempted to lead the industry with a
    price increase (+20È per case) but they were not followed by
    Gerber or Heinz at that time." In 1988, Heinz did not raise
    prices on Junior Foods, despite Gerber's price increase.
    Heinz chose this strategy because "[a]ny increase to these
    differentials due to a price increase will decrease Heinz's
    Junior Foods volume as a result of a weakening of its
    price/value positioning and possibly due to reduced
    distribution."
    Beech-Nut, who increased its list prices three months
    before Heinz's increase, did not increase list prices for
    Junior Foods. In 1990, Heinz did not match Gerber's price
    increase on Junior Foods "to widen the objective Heinz-
    Gerber retail price differential from 4c to 5c." Supp. App. at
    4892. In addition, Heinz did not match Gerber's price
    increase on Meats "in an effort to stabilize [its] Meats
    business." 
    Id. However, in
    so doing, it "widen[ed] [its] retail
    price differential from 3c to 4c." 
    Id. In 1991,
    Heinz's D. F. Ryan recommended fiscal year
    1991 baby food price increases to match Gerber's increase
    to "maintain our price differentials versus Gerber." The
    recommendation, however, excluded any price increase for
    Second or Third Food meats and suggested an increased
    price for cereal of 61c as against Gerber's increase of 80È
    so as to expand the unit differential between them from
    4.4c to 6.0. An August 1992 memo from Heinz employee
    Deborah Billow informed G. Price that "Bob and I have
    agreed to not follow Gerber's most recent price increase on
    Beginner Food until January 1, 1993 when it is currently
    budgeted."
    38
    Although we recognize that parallel pricing does not
    require "uniform prices," and permits prices within an
    agreed upon range, 
    Socony-Vacuum, 310 U.S. at 222
    , the
    memoranda to Roussey and the subsequent memoranda of
    Ryan and Billow demonstrate that the defendants did not
    blindly raise their prices to follow Gerber, the price leader.
    The defendants' prices were neither uniform nor within any
    agreed upon price range of each other. These memoranda
    reveal that the defendants engaged in independent pricing
    determined by market conditions at the time, profit
    margins, and the effect of price increases or decreases on
    sales volume and distribution. They provide a striking
    insight into the defendants' marketing strategy which
    negates the plaintiffs' inference of conscious parallelism.
    Thus, we see no substance to plaintiffs' argument that
    the District Court ignored testimony and documents of the
    defendants' witnesses which would have confirmed the
    plaintiffs' case for conscious parallelism. On the contrary,
    defendants' marketing activities refute rather than support
    parallel pricing.
    VII.
    The Plus Factors
    The plaintiffs strenuously argue on appeal that, in
    addition to direct and circumstantial evidence showing the
    defendants' joint action, they presented more than
    sufficient evidence of "plus factors" to defeat summary
    judgment. They claim that the record contains substantial
    evidence that all the defendants (1) had an econom ic
    motive to conspire in order to increase their profits, (2) had
    ample opportunity to conspire, and (3) acted again st their
    independent economic self-interests by exchanging price
    information, including information concerning future price
    increases. They assert that the District Court, in
    discovering no plus factors, simply ignored the evidence.12
    _________________________________________________________________
    12. Despite its earlier conclusion "that there is no permissible inference
    of parallel pricing," the District Court devoted approximately 20% of its
    34-page opinion to the discussion of the plus factors. The extensive
    discussion by the district court at least negates the plaintiffs'
    complaint
    that the district court ignored the evidence.
    39
    In Petruzzi, we stated that a conspiracy based on
    consciously parallel behavior requires a plaintiff not only to
    show parallel behavior and awareness in their decision
    making, but also certain plus factors. 
    Id. at 1242;
    see also
    Shoenkopf v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    637 F.2d 205
    , 208 (3d Cir. 1980). Moreover, the Supreme Court has
    stated that evidence of plus factors must tend to exclude
    the possibility of independent conduct. 
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764
    .
    We have undertaken a comprehensive review of the
    record and we do not agree with the plaintiffs that the
    District Court "ignored the evidence" in discovering no plus
    factors. On the contrary, the court determined that the
    evidence showed that each defendant independently was
    able to obtain information concerning its competitors'
    product pricing and promotions. The District Court
    concluded that the evidence did not permit it to reasonably
    infer a price-fixing conspiracy. D.C. Op. at 27. It stated that
    "[t]here [was] a paucity of written documentation evidencing
    any concerted exchange of pricing information." D.C. Op. at
    27. Moreover, the court determined that the record simply
    showed that the defendants were sophisticated corporations
    that sought and prized competitive information concerning
    the activities of their competitors. D.C. Op. at 28.
    In keeping with its consideration of the plus factors, the
    court discussed the evidence as to the defendants' advance
    price announcements. It noted that other courts have
    determined that advance price announcements " ``served an
    important purpose in the industry.' " D.C. Op. at 29,
    (quoting Reserve Supply Corp. v. Owens-Corning Fiberglass
    Corp., 
    971 F.2d 37
    , 54 (7th Cir. 1992)). The court
    concluded the defendants' advance notices do not support
    proof of concerted action by them; many of the documents
    to which plaintiffs point speak only in terms of "a suspicion
    or rumor that one of the defendants would be raising prices
    or making changes to a particular product." D.C. Op. at 29.
    As examples, it pointed to a Beech-Nut budget document
    dated December 31, 1986, in which Beech-Nut President
    Theuer stated that he "anticipated a Gerber price increase."
    
    Id. (Emphasis added)
    . The court also observed in another
    Beech-Nut document that the author stated that he
    40
    "strongly suspects" that Gerber would increase prices on
    March 2, 1990. 
    Id. The court
    determined that the nature of the exchanges of
    information among the defendants' sales representatives
    amounted to mere "chit chat" at chance meetings or trade
    shows among persons with no pricing authority. Op. at 30.
    The court further noted that courts generally reject
    conspiracy claims that "seek to infer an agreement from . . .
    communications despite a lack of independent evidence
    tending to show an agreement and in the face of
    uncontradicted testimony that only informational
    exchanges took place." Op. at 31, (quoting 
    Alvord-Polk, 37 F.3d at 1014
    ). The trial judge's perceptive observation is
    correct.
    The District Court also dealt with the evidence of
    opportunity to conspire emphasized by the plaintiffs. In
    Petruzzi, this court, in considering plus factors, did not
    attach much weight to evidence of opportunity. We noted
    that evidence of social contacts and telephone calls among
    representatives of the defendants was insufficient to
    exclude the possibility that the defendants acted
    
    independently. 998 F.2d at 1242
    n.15. The trial court also
    concluded that "[s]uch evidence of ``opportunity' should be
    accorded little, if any weight. Company personnel do not
    often operate in a vacuum or ``plastic bubble'; they
    sometimes engage in the longstanding tradition of social
    discourse." Op. at 32.
    The court concluded that there were a number of reasons
    to reject plaintiffs' argument with respect to motive to
    conspire. The court reasoned that if there were a
    conspiracy, Gerber, the market leader, would not lower its
    prices from time to time while at or about the same time,
    Beech-Nut or Heinz, or both, raised their prices.
    Furthermore, if, as the plaintiffs contend, the defendants
    had a motive to achieve higher prices, "then every company
    in every industry would have such a ``motive.' " (D.C. op. at
    32). Accordingly, it concluded that Heinz and Beech-Nut
    had no motive to enter into a price-fixing conspiracy with
    Gerber.
    In further consideration of the plus factors, the court also
    turned to the Coble testimony concerning the alleged truce
    41
    and the testimony of other employees. The court found that
    the testimony failed to support the plaintiffs' argument as
    to plus factors. This evidence, the court found, showed only
    Heinz's fear that penetrating territory dominated by a
    competitor "might erupt in another conflagration in the
    industry." (D.C. op. at 33).
    We agree with the District Court that the plaintiffs'
    evidence of alleged plus factors do not prove concerted,
    collusive behavior, although our reasoning may differ. We
    also have examined the testimony of plaintiffs' expert, Dr.
    Sam Peltzman, on whom the plaintiffs largely depend for
    proof of motive and conduct contrary to self-interest. Dr.
    Peltzman supplied the plaintiffs with two affidavits, the
    latest and more substantive of which was dated January
    1997.
    In summary, his affidavits opine that there is a perfectly
    plausible motive for a firm like Heinz or Beech-Nut to
    engage in a conspiracy even if it "locks" itself into a 15%
    market because their profits from the conspiracy would be
    greater than from acting independently. (Peltzman Aff. I at
    P3) He rejects the claim that Heinz or Beech-Nut could have
    obtained the full benefit of a conspiracy by merely following
    Gerber's price increases as inconsistent with economic
    theory because, absent a conspiracy, Gerber would have set
    a lower price. Further, he stated that if Heinz or Beech-Nut
    determined their prices independently, their respective
    prices would have been lower, and their sales of baby food
    would have been higher, than under a price-fixing
    agreement. (Peltzman Aff. I at P4) Finally, he avers that
    economic theory suggests that Nestle and Ralston would do
    better with conspiratorial prices than without them so that,
    absent the conspiracy, their losses on the Beech-Nut
    business would have been greater still. (Peltzman Aff. I at
    P5)
    Without examining the validity of Dr. Peltzman's
    economic speculations, serious consideration may not be
    attributed to them because his opinion was based on the
    express assumption that the defendants had agreed to
    conspire. His assumptions and conclusions rest on the
    basic premise that there is an ongoing conspiracy. In his
    deposition of February 1996, he acknowledged that his
    42
    opinion assumed there was a conspiracy beginning January
    1, 1984 and lasting until December 31, 1993. For example,
    he rationalizes:
    If Heinz or Beech-Nut determined their sales
    independently, free of any restraint imposed by a
    conspiratorial agreement, the total sales of baby food
    would be higher and prices lower than would be
    obtained under an agreement. It is precisely this
    specter of lower prices and profit margins from
    independent behavior which provides the incentive for
    the parties to enter into and maintain a price-fixing
    agreement.
    Moreover, he knew nothing about the baby food industry
    other than "the knowledge one acquires as a casual
    consumer."
    When Dr. Peltzman was subsequently deposed, he
    acknowledged that he had not undertaken any independent
    study of the baby food business in connection with his
    assignment in this case. He further conceded that he had
    no analysis of pricing by these defendants, except to review
    the average transaction prices reported in Table 1, as
    revised, by Dr. Madansky. He further acknowledged that he
    had not undertaken any review or study of the particular
    buyers of baby foods from the defendants in this case.
    Neither had he made any analysis of promotional programs
    nor looked at whether the baby food industry fits the model
    of manufacturers following in their pricing practices the
    price leader.
    With such limited information before him, Peltzman
    opined that each of the defendants had a motive to engage
    in a conspiracy, even if they "locked" themselves into a 15%
    market share because "their profits from the conspiracy
    would be greater than from acting independently," and that
    any benefit that Heinz and Beech-Nut could have obtained
    by simply following Gerber's list price increases is
    inconsistent with basic economic theory. Peltzman's opinion
    is nothing more than an abstract statement based on
    "economic theory" that the interest in enhancing profits
    motivated the defendants to conspire. He never made any
    reference to the evidence in this case; he never analyzed the
    43
    pricing conduct of any of the defendants. In a free
    capitalistic society, profit is always a motivating factor in
    the conduct of a business. Profit is a legitimate motive in
    pricing decisions, and something more is required before a
    court can conclude that competitors conspired tofix pricing
    in violation of the Sherman Act. Here, there is nothing more
    or unusual other than the alleged instances of trade wars
    between the defendants. Thus, if a firm's motivation is
    merely to meet rival prices, it would constitute only
    interdependence. Accordingly, to prove conspiracy, evidence
    of action that is against self-interest or motivated by profit
    must go beyond mere interdependence. Parallel pricefixing
    must be so unusual that in the absence of an advance
    agreement, no reasonable firm would have engaged in it.
    Coleman v. Cannon Oil Co., 849 Supp. 1458, 1467 (M.D.
    Ala. 1993).
    With respect to the defendants' alleged conduct contrary
    to self-interest, Peltzman also assumes that as
    conspirators, the defendants "exchanged with each other
    information about price changes and changes in marketing
    plans, such as increased couponing and changed
    promotional allowances prior to the announcement to the
    trade." No evidence in this record, however, shows that any
    executive of any defendant exchanged price or market
    information with any other executive. As we have already
    noted, any information obtained about a competitor was
    information plucked from the trade in the marketplace,
    "chit-chat" of field representatives, and their informal and
    casual conversations at trade shows or while stocking
    shelves. This desultory collection of information"on the
    street" by sales representatives is far removed from a
    concerted reciprocal exchange of important pricing and
    marketing information by the officers of major companies,
    particularly an exchange pursuant to an agreement.
    Even assuming the admissibility of Dr. Peltzman's
    opinion, we conclude that his testimony and report offers
    little substance, if any, to advance the defendants'
    argument that the defendants acted contrary to their self-
    interest. An expert opinion based on the meager superficial
    information on which Peltzman relied is highly speculative,
    unreliable, and of dubious admissibility before a jury.
    44
    "When an expert opinion is not supported by sufficient
    facts to validate it in the eyes of the law, or when
    indisputable record facts contradict or otherwise render the
    opinion unreasonable, it cannot support a jury's verdict."
    Brooke 
    Group, 509 U.S. at 242
    . See also Advo v.
    Philadelphia Newspapers, Inc., 
    51 F.3d 1191
    , 1199 (3d Cir.
    1995). We, therefore, conclude Dr. Peltzman's opinion offers
    meager evidence of defendants' behavior contrary to self-
    interest and of motivation to conspire.
    We need not dwell on plaintiffs' contention that evidence
    of the "alleged" truce and the unwillingness of Heinz to
    enter the Chicago or Florida areas as conduct against its
    own self-interest. We previously discussed this argument
    and our rationale then is sufficient reason to reject this
    evidence as a plus factor. Plaintiffs cite to Milgrim v. Loews,
    
    192 F.2d 579
    (3d Cir.), cert. denied, 
    343 U.S. 929
    (1952),
    in support of their argument that Heinz's rejection of
    advantageous offers constitutes a plus factor. Milgrim
    involved the distribution of films in the movie industry in
    which eight distributors were charged under the Sherman
    Act for refusing to distribute first run films to plaintiff's
    drive-in theaters. All eight distributors acted in"complete
    unanimity" in refusing to license features onfirst-run films
    to plaintiff even when offered a higher rental. All acted in
    substantial unanimity in refusing to make sure that feature
    films were available to plaintiff until after a 28-day run in
    conventional theaters. 
    Id. at 583.
    The court therefore
    concluded that "each distributor has thus acted in
    apparent contradiction to its own self interest . . . for the
    conduct of the distributors is, in the absence of a valid
    explanation, inconsistent with decisions independently
    arrived at." 
    Id. Milgrim is
    inapposite. Instead of joint and conspiratorial
    activity to fix prices and eviscerate competition as the
    plaintiffs in this case claim, our review of the record
    convinces us that the evidence overwhelmingly establishes
    that the defendants in their marketing activities acted
    independently rather than in "complete unanimity,"
    competitively rather than conspiratorially, and aggressively
    rather than supinely.
    45
    Some illustrations follow. In an intra-corporate
    memorandum dated December 15, 1989, from Heinz's
    Gorsky to all division and assistant division managers, he
    explained that the reason for a price increase was "[r]ising
    costs for raw ingredients, packaging materials, and fringe
    benefits." Heinz continued to emphasize a "two brand
    strategy" to oust Beech-Nut from markets and accounts,
    and Beech-Nut countered with aggressive competitive
    activity against Heinz. Heinz's Five Year Business Plan,
    dated October 1989, constituted a ninety million dollar
    program approved by the Heinz board of directors to
    renovate its Pittsburgh factory and lower its operating costs
    "in the face of intense competitive activity from Beech-Nut
    and Gerber." This demonstrates aggressive competitor
    activity, not collusive, price fixing behavior.
    Continuing, a Sales Division Activity Report for January
    1989, reflects Heinz's loss of several important accounts to
    substantial competitive offers by Beech-Nut. A Heinz Baby
    Food Presentation for Dallas, Texas, refers to
    implementation of a "Texas Defense Program" in 1988
    undertaken specifically to protect against Beech-Nut's
    major push to enter Texas's principal markets. A November
    1988 Heinz report noted that "Beech-Nut continues to be
    aggressive and as a result has forced us to spend heavily to
    defend our distribution base." A September 27, 1988 Heinz
    Activity Report noted that Beech-Nut was aggressively
    pursuing Heinz's accounts in a number of markets and that
    Heinz's defensive measures had been generally effective. A
    November 1988 Heinz report noted that "Beech-Nut
    continues to be aggressive and as a result has forced us to
    spend heavily to defend our distribution base." A May 1992
    Heinz report describing a Detroit business program
    initiated in May 1990 after Beech-Nut "assaulted the
    Detroit district" noted a fiscal year 1991 increase of 74% in
    discounts and allowances. This too demonstrates
    independent, aggressive action, not collaborative, concerted
    conduct.
    Various business documents also reflect Heinz's desire to
    gradually reduce "deal spending," i.e., promotions and
    allowances as early as September 1984. This was met by
    continued, competitive pressures as reflected by Heinz's
    46
    Business Plan FY86 referring to "Beech-Nut's continuing
    roll-out of Stages as a full line replacement for Heinz Wet."
    The Plan shows that by the end of 1985, Heinz was worried
    about the "fiercely competitive environment," viewing
    Beech-Nut as "a formidable competitor" whose"aggressive
    new distribution efforts have again increased the cost of
    doing business for Heinz Wet." Furthermore, the Plan
    concluded that "[i]ncreased competitive trade spending will
    continue to make it difficult for the Product Group and
    Sales to implement riskier trade spending reductions."
    As for Beech-Nut, in a document dated October 30, 1984,
    Hoyvald wrote to Biggar regarding the 1984 fiscal budget.
    He stated that the problem confronting Beech-Nut was
    "rising costs and no general offset in selling price
    increases." As a consequence of the rising costs, Hoyvald
    stated that "we are forced to include a planned price
    increase in STAGES products April 1st." 
    Id. At the
    same
    time, he observed that the baby food industry had not
    made a general price increase since May 1982. Finally, he
    noted that their budget allowed no new investments, but
    they planned "to work on and have ready an alternate
    aggressive expansion plan to be submitted at a time when
    a solid success story is projectable."
    In a weekly position letter for the week ending September
    13, 1986, a Beech-Nut employee recommended, based on
    Gerber's decision to reformulate the size of their first foods
    products, that Beech-Nut repackage its Stages One
    products "to maintain our exclusivity in small wholesaler
    and independent sources." In a January 16, 1990 Status
    Report, Beech-Nut's Humbarger stated that "once the sale
    of Beech-Nut Nutrition was announced July 5th, the
    competition in the category began to heat up. Both Gerber
    and Heinz were trying to take advantage of the situation."
    In a May 10, 1990 Status Report, he noted that "Gerber
    continues to call on our exclusive stores with money offers
    and free goods. Gerber has presented a program to King
    Kullen for consideration." This report and the earlier
    communications unequivocally refute any price-fixing
    agreement on the part of Beech-Nut with any of the other
    defendants.
    47
    With the exception of a $7,000 pre-tax profit in 1980, the
    first year Nestle's ownership of Beech-Nut, Nestle made no
    profit on its baby food business in any of the ten years
    during which it owned Beech-Nut. For instance, shortly
    before Nestle sold Beech-Nut to Ralston, Beech-Nut Baby
    Food Presentation documents illustrate that the
    Nestle/Beech-Nut's company-wide average selling price per
    case of baby food was $7.51 and the average cost per case
    was $8.23. Thus, at that time, Nestle lost an average of 72È
    per case for every case it sold. It is inconceivable that with
    losses running at least 10% for every case sold, Nestle
    would have remained a party to a conspiracy to fix prices,
    preserve Gerber's market share year after year, and run up
    its own losses.
    As to Ralston, the plaintiffs offer no references to any
    Ralston business plans, internal documents, testimony, or
    any other evidence of record that even suggests that
    Ralston acted with the intention of preserving Gerber's
    market share. No evidence was presented establishing that
    Ralston ever had knowledge of price increases by either
    Gerber or Heinz before Gerber or Heinz announced those
    increases to their customers. No evidence was presented
    showing that either Gerber or Heinz had prior knowledge of
    price increases by Ralston prior to Ralston's
    announcements to the trade. No evidence was presented to
    support any claim that Ralston entered into a "truce" with
    Gerber or Heinz. Only expert Dr. Peltzman made reference
    to Ralston, and we perceive no probative value in his
    testimony.
    With the foregoing evidence of strong, intensive
    competition and hardly a scintilla of evidence of concerted,
    collusive conduct, we can see no error in the District
    Court's conclusion that there was insufficient evidence to
    satisfy the "plus factor" requirement. The plaintiffs'
    argument that the record shows "that all defendants had
    an economic motive to conspire in order to increase their
    profit margins" rests solely on the unsupported opinion of
    Dr. Peltzman. In a free capitalistic society, all entrepreneurs
    have a legitimate understandable motive to increase profits.
    Profit is the essence of a capitalistic economy. Dr.
    Peltzman's bare opinion of an obvious fact cannot avoid
    48
    summary judgment. We can discover nothing in this record
    to show that any of the defendants acted unlawfully. The
    best that the plaintiffs can do is to point to ambiguous
    inferences.
    VIII.
    Conclusion
    Price-fixing, we have been instructed by the Supreme
    Court, "includes more than the mere establishment of
    uniform prices." 
    Socony-Vacuum, 310 U.S. at 222
    . The
    circumstantial evidence addressed by plaintiffs, though
    voluminous, lacks the essential substance to find a
    conspiracy. There is no evidence of record showing
    reciprocal exchange of information by any executive of the
    defendants with price-fixing authority. Despite exhaustive
    and prolonged discovery, no evidence has been produced
    showing that, during the alleged 17-year conspiratorial
    period, any executive of any of the defendants with price-
    fixing authority communicated with executives of the other
    defendants, either by writing, telephone or meeting.
    Whatever information sales representatives culled from the
    trade or from each other amounted to no more than an
    accumulation of sporadic market snippets, not an
    organized, concerted exchange of information among
    company executives or their authorized agents.
    The evidence of conscious parallelism to prove tacit
    collusion falls far short of being probative proof of concerted
    action. The market here is nationwide for the two largest
    defendants and considerably smaller for Nestle/Ralston;
    their varied products are in the hundreds. Allowances and
    discounts to specific customers and in specific areas are
    pervasive, even varying at times between the same
    customer and with the quantities purchased and the areas
    served. There is no evidence that in such a diffuse and
    frenetic discount market there was any mechanism in place
    to detect conspirator cheating. Without such a mechanism,
    no conspiracy, if it existed, could long endure.
    Because Gerber, Heinz and either Nestle or Ralston
    collectively controlled 98% of the baby food industry
    49
    nationwide, and during a prolonged period of time when
    wholesale food prices generally were escalating, they were
    an especially inviting target to attack under the Sherman
    Act for price-fixing. However, there is positive and
    unequivocal evidence that the defendants engaged in
    unilateral, aggressive competition limited only by budgetary
    considerations, cash, and market conditions.
    We are cognizant that the baby food industry is highly
    concentrated with only three companies controlling the
    nationwide manufacture and distribution of their baby food
    products. We realize that such a scenario could facilitate
    explicit or tacit price-fixing. We also are aware that during
    the period spanned by the alleged conspiracy, wholesale
    food prices in the nation generally escalated; this upward
    movement could provide cover for non-competitive pricing
    practices. Furthermore, the baby food industry carries the
    crucial responsibility for providing much of the nutrition for
    almost all of the infants nationwide, an obligation that
    emphasizes the necessity for total compliance under the
    Sherman Act. As a court, however, we have the duty to
    examine the record carefully and decide the case fairly on
    the law and not on mere conjecture, ambiguous
    circumstantial evidence, and suspicion. The plaintiffs have
    not produced any evidence of an explicit agreement to fix
    prices and preserve market share. Drawing all inferences in
    their favor, they have failed to produce sufficient
    circumstantial evidence to prove concerted collusion that
    tends to exclude the possibility of independent action. See
    
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 768
    .
    Accordingly, the judgment of the district will be affirmed.
    IX.
    Taxation of Costs
    Following the District Court's grant of summary
    judgment, three of the defendants moved the Clerk of the
    District Court to tax costs for, inter alia, deposition
    transcripts used by the court in reaching its decision. The
    Clerk, relying on 28 U.S.C. S 1920(2), awarded costs to the
    defendants in the following amounts: Gerber: $24,299.52,
    50
    Heinz: $18,833.01, Nestle: $1,507.10, and Ralston:
    $12,221.00. On appeal to the District Court, it affirmed the
    Clerk's award. See Order of January 27, 1998.13
    The plaintiffs take no issue with the amount of the costs.
    Their contention is that the District Court erred by ignoring
    the clear mandate of L.Civ.R.54.1(g)(7),14 as well as the
    principal commentary accompanying that section. The
    commentary provides that "L.Civ.R.54.1(g)(7) allows for the
    taxation of deposition costs directly related to the use of the
    deposition transcript at trial. The key to taxability under
    this provision is that the transcript be ``used at trial'
    pursuant to Fed.R.Civ.P.32.' " Lite, N.J. Federal Practice
    Rules, Comment 4.e to Rule 54.1(Gann 1998 ed.) at 106.
    The plaintiffs argue that the Clerk lacked the authority to
    award tax costs because this case never reached the trial
    stage. Alternatively, the plaintiffs contend that the District
    Court erred because it was "bound by the local rules of the
    district where [it] reside[s]." Pl. Br. at 53. Accordingly, the
    court was obligated to apply L.Civ.R.54.1(g)(7). Finally, they
    assert that this court should review the District Court's
    decision de novo, because the latter made a legal
    interpretation of a rule of procedure.
    The plaintiffs' contentions fail. First, a District Court's
    grant of costs is reviewed for abuse of discretion. Tilton v.
    Capital Cities/ABC, Inc., 
    115 F.3d 1471
    , 1474 (10th Cir.
    1997) See also, Morgan v. Perry, 142 F.3d 670,682 (3d Cir.
    1998). Second, section 1920 has been interpreted as
    permitting the taxation of costs for depositions used in
    deciding summary judgment motions. See, e.g., 
    Id. This makes
    common sense, for to hold otherwise would penalize
    _________________________________________________________________
    13. 28 U.S.C. S 1920(2) provides that a federal court may tax costs "for
    all or any part of the stenographic transcript necessarily obtained for
    use
    in the case."
    14. New Jersey Local Rule 54.1(g)(7) provides, in pertinent part:
    In taxing costs, the Clerk shall allow all or part of the fees and
    charges incurred in the taking and transcribing of depositions used
    at the trial under Rule 32 of the Civil Rules. Fees and charges for
    the taking and transcribing of any other deposition shall not be
    taxed as costs unless the Court otherwise orders. . . .[emphasis
    added.]
    51
    the prevailing party for winning in the early stages of the
    proceeding. Third, L.Civ.R.54.1(g)(7) provides a
    discretionary mechanism. More particularly, it provides
    "fees and charges for the taking and transcribing of any
    other deposition shall not be taxed as costs unless the
    Court otherwise orders." 
    Id. The "otherwise
    orders" provision
    was explicitly utilized by the District Court in this case. The
    court explained that "it is clear from the Rule that this
    Court has the authority to award costs for any other
    depositions." D.C. Op. at 4.
    We hold that the District Court was well within its
    discretion to order the plaintiffs to pay costs. Fed. R. Civ.
    P. 32 suggests that the "used at trial" language in the local
    rule should be interpreted in accordance with Rule 32,
    which takes a broader approach to deposition use than the
    literal use "at trial." Furthermore, to the extent that it
    conflicts with S 1920, L.Civ.R.54.1(g)(7) must give way. See
    Fed. R. Civ. P. 83. The order of the District Court taxing
    costs will be affirmed.
    A True Copy:
    Teste:
    Clerk of the United States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    52
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 97-5609, 98-5125

Citation Numbers: 166 F.3d 112

Judges: Becker, Rosenn, Katz

Filed Date: 1/12/1999

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 11/4/2024

Authorities (25)

Rosefielde v. Falcon Jet Corp. , 701 F. Supp. 1053 ( 1988 )

Theatre Enterprises, Inc. v. Paramount Film Distributing ... , 74 S. Ct. 257 ( 1954 )

alvord-polk-inc-american-blind-factory-inc-delta-paint-and-wallpaper , 37 F.3d 996 ( 1994 )

in-re-coordinated-pretrial-proceedings-in-petroleum-products-antitrust , 906 F.2d 432 ( 1990 )

market-force-incorporated-v-wauwatosa-realty-company-coldwell-banker , 906 F.2d 1167 ( 1990 )

Shapiro v. General Motors Corp. , 472 F. Supp. 636 ( 1979 )

The Venzie Corporation, and F. M. Venzie & Company, Inc. v. ... , 521 F.2d 1309 ( 1975 )

alexandre-b-todorov-md-individually-and-neurology-clinic-pc-an , 921 F.2d 1438 ( 1991 )

jf-feeser-inc-and-juniata-foods-inc-v-serv-a-portion-inc , 909 F.2d 1524 ( 1990 )

United States v. American Linseed Oil Co. , 43 S. Ct. 607 ( 1923 )

Erie Telecommunications, Inc. v. City of Erie, Pennsylvania , 853 F.2d 1084 ( 1988 )

Tilton v. Capital Cities/ABC, Inc. , 115 F.3d 1471 ( 1997 )

paul-j-bogosian-on-behalf-of-himself-and-all-those-similarly-situated-v , 561 F.2d 434 ( 1977 )

Northern Pacific Railway Co. v. United States , 78 S. Ct. 514 ( 1958 )

Advo, Inc. v. Philadelphia Newspapers, Inc., D/B/A ... , 51 F.3d 1191 ( 1995 )

stephen-jay-photography-ltd-larry-lemasters-individually-and-ta-classic , 903 F.2d 988 ( 1990 )

City of Vernon v. Southern California Edison Company , 955 F.2d 1361 ( 1992 )

Reserve Supply Corporation v. Owens-Corning Fiberglas ... , 971 F.2d 37 ( 1992 )

Norman E. Krehl v. Baskin-Robbins Ice Cream Company , 664 F.2d 1348 ( 1982 )

Clamp-All Corporation v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Institute , 851 F.2d 478 ( 1988 )

View All Authorities »