Unity Real Estate Co v. Hudson ( 1999 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                                                            Opinions of the United
    1999 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    3-29-1999
    Unity Real Estate Co v. Hudson
    Precedential or Non-Precedential:
    Docket 97-3234,97-3236
    Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1999
    Recommended Citation
    "Unity Real Estate Co v. Hudson" (1999). 1999 Decisions. Paper 81.
    http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1999/81
    This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 1999 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
    Volume 2 of 2
    Filed March 29, 1999
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    NOS. 97-3234 and 97-3236
    UNITY REAL ESTATE COMPANY,
    Appellant No. 97-3234
    v.
    MARTY D. HUDSON; MICHAEL H. HOLLAND; THOMAS
    O. S. RAND; ELLIOTT A. SEGAL; CARLTON R. SICKLES;
    GAIL R. WILENSKY; WILLIAM P. HOPGOOD; TRUSTEES
    OF THE UNITED MINE WORKERS OF AMERICA
    COMBINED BENEFIT FUND; THOMAS F. CONNORS;
    ROBERTS WALLACE; TRUSTEES OF THE 1992 UNITED
    MINE WORKERS OF AMERICA BENEFIT PLAN; UNITED
    STATES OF AMERICA (Intervenor in District Court)
    LTV Corporation (LTV), NACCO Industries,
    Inc. (NACCO); Amicus Curiae
    BARNES AND TUCKER COMPANY,
    Appellant No. 97-3236
    v.
    MARTY D. HUDSON, Trustee of the United Mine Workers
    of America Combined Benefit Fund and Trustee of the
    1992 United Mine Workers of America Benefit Plan;
    MICHAEL H. HOLLAND, Trustee of the United Mine
    Workers of America Combined Benefit Fund and Trustee
    of the 1992 United Mine Workers of America Benefit Plan;
    THOMAS O. S. RAND, Trustee of the United Mine
    Workers of America Combined Benefit Fund; ELLIOTT A.
    SEGAL, Trustee of the United Mine Workers of America
    Combined Benefit Fund; CARLTON R. SICKLES, Trustee
    of the United Mine Workers of America Combined Benefit
    Fund; GAIL R. WILENSKY, Trustee of the United Mine
    Workers of America Combined Benefit Fund; WILLIAM P.
    HOPGOOD, Trustee of the United Mine Workers of
    America Combined Benefit Fund; THOMAS F. CONNORS,
    Trustee of the 1992 United Mine Workers of America
    Benefit Plan; ROBERT G. WALLACE, Trustee of the 1992
    United Mine Workers of America Benefit Plan; UNITED
    STATES OF AMERICA (Intervenor in the District Court)
    LTV Corporation (LTV), NACCO Industries,
    Inc. (NACCO); Amicus Curiae
    On Appeal From the United States District Court
    For the Western District of Pennsylvania
    (D.C. Civ. No. 93-cv-01802)
    District Judge: Honorable D. Brooks Smith
    Argued: November 20, 1998
    Before: BECKER, Chief Judge, ALDISERT and WEIS,
    Circuit Judges.
    (Filed March 29, 1999)
    4. Conclusion
    We have evaluated the Coal Act against our traditional
    standards of proportionality and distaste for retroactivity,
    taking into account our deference to Congress on the evils
    to be addressed by the law. Ultimately, although the issue
    is close, we conclude that the Coal Act is targeted to
    address the problem of insufficient resources in the benefit
    funds and that it puts the burden on those who, in
    Congress's reasonable judgment, should bear it. The law's
    retroactivity is troubling, yet given the nature of the
    commitments at issue and the relationship of Coal Act
    liabilities to past acts in the industry, we cannot say that
    the Act violates due process.
    IV. Categorical Takings
    Unity and B&T also maintain that the Coal Act is an
    unconstitutional taking as applied to them. They ask us to
    46
    apply a categorical takings approach because, they claim,
    their businesses will be entirely destroyed if they have to
    pay benefits under the Act. In Eastern, the argument that
    the Coal Act would drive the plaintiff out of business
    entirely was not presented to the Court, and so the
    plaintiffs argue that they retain a viable takings claim.
    Five Justices, however, rejected the idea that a law that
    imposed only a financial burden without identifying a
    particular property right could ever consitute a taking. The
    fact that in a particular case a financial burden might
    consume all of a particular entity's assets would not seem
    to change Justice Kennedy's analysis: "The Coal Act neither
    targets a specific property interest nor depends upon any
    particular property for the operation of its statutory
    mechanisms." Eastern, 118 S. Ct. at 2156 (Kennedy, J.,
    concurring). Similarly, the dissent would require the
    governmental identification of "a specific interest in
    physical or intellectual property" in order tofind a
    compensable taking. Id. at 2161 (Breyer, J., dissenting).
    The reasoning of these five Justices was that any
    governmental regulation that costs a business money could
    become a taking if the plurality's standards prevailed, and
    that this would be an unacceptable result. See id. at 2155
    (Kennedy, J., concurring); id. at 2162 (Breyer, J.,
    dissenting). This reasoning is unaffected by the
    characterization of the burden as a "total" taking because it
    consumes all of a particular company's resources.
    Moreover, even the plurality gave no indication that it
    would extend the categorical takings approach outside the
    context of regulations of real property.
    Because the Eastern Court was not confronted with this
    situation, however, we must set forth our reasons for
    rejecting it in greater detail. To date, the categorical
    approach has only been used in real property cases such as
    Lucas v. South Carolina, 
    505 U.S. 1003
     (1992). In those
    cases, the concept of "total destruction" of value refers not
    to the owner's total assets but to some identifiable property
    interest. Indeed, even a multi-billionaire would be eligible
    for an award under a categorical takings approach if some
    small, distinct parcel of his holdings were condemned or
    rendered worthless through regulation. Therefore, the "total
    47
    destruction" language of cases concerning real property
    should not be mechanically applied to the situation at bar.
    See Branch v. United States, 
    69 F.3d 1571
    , 1576-77 (Fed.
    Cir. 1995) ("Because of ``the State's traditionally high degree
    of control of commercial dealings,' the principles of takings
    law that apply to real property do not apply in the same
    manner to statutes imposing monetary liability." (quoting
    Lucas, 
    505 U.S. at 1027
    )).
    The Supreme Court has repeatedly rejected the argument
    that a tax--even a tax on a small set of businesses--may
    violate due process or constitute a taking simply because it
    may force some of the regulated entities out of business:
    The claim that a particular tax is so unreasonably high
    and unduly burdensome as to deny due process is
    both familiar and recurring, but the Court has
    consistently refused either to undertake the task of
    passing on the "reasonableness" of a tax that otherwise
    is within the power of Congress or of state legislative
    authorities, or to hold that a tax is unconstitutional
    because it renders a business unprofitable.
    . . . . The premise that a tax is invalid if so excessive
    as to bring about the destruction of a particular
    business, the Court said, had been "uniformly rejected
    as furnishing no juridical ground for striking down a
    taxing act." [Magano Co. v. Hamilton, 
    292 U.S. 40
    ,] 47
    [(1934)]. Veazie Bank v. Fenno, 
    8 Wall. 533
    , 548, 
    19 L.Ed. 482
     (1869); McCray v. United States, 
    195 U.S. 27
    , 
    24 S.Ct. 769
    , 
    49 L.Ed. 78
     (1904); and Alaska Fish
    Salting & By-Products Co. v. Smith, 
    255 U.S. 44
    , 
    41 S.Ct. 219
    , 
    65 L.Ed. 489
     (1921), are to the same effect.
    In Alaska Fish, a tax on the manufacture of certain
    fish products was sustained, the Court saying, 
    id., at 48-49
    , 
    41 S.Ct., at
    220: "Even if the tax should destroy
    a business it would not be made invalid or require
    compensation upon that ground alone. Those who
    enter upon a business take that risk. . . ." See also
    International Harvester Co. v. Wisconsin Dept. of
    Taxation, 
    322 U.S. 435
    , 444, 
    64 S.Ct. 1060
    , 1065, 
    88 L.Ed. 1373
     (1944); Child Labor Tax Case, 
    259 U.S. 20
    ,
    30, 
    42 S.Ct. 449
    , 
    66 L.Ed. 817
     (1922); Brushaber v.
    48
    Union Pacific R. Co., 
    240 U.S. 1
    , 24, 
    36 S.Ct. 236
    , 244,
    
    60 L.Ed. 493
     (1916); Flint v. Stone Tracy Co., 
    220 U.S. 107
    , 168-169, 
    31 S.Ct. 342
    , 356, 
    55 L.Ed. 389
     (1911).
    City of Pittsburgh v. Alco Parking Corp., 
    417 U.S. 369
    , 373-
    74 (1974). We note in this regard that we, along with other
    Courts of Appeals, have held that Coal Act obligations are
    taxes. See Lindsey Coal Mining Co. v. Chater, 
    90 F.3d 688
    ,
    695 (3d Cir. 1996) (finding that the Act is "essentially a tax
    to continue a benefits program").
    The plaintiffs respond that these taxation cases all
    concerned prospective, not retrospective, liability, but that
    argument conflates two separate issues. The size of the
    liability does not depend on whether or not the obligation is
    retrospective. If the argument is that the complete
    consumption of a company's assets is a categorical taking,
    retroactivity would be irrelevant; if such a law would only
    be a categorical taking when it was retroactive, then we are
    not really discussing a "categorical" taking. We think that
    retroactivity, while crucial to our due process analysis, is
    not properly considered as a part of the categorical takings
    analysis.
    The Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit has also
    rejected the plaintiffs' argument, with reasoning wefind
    persuasive:
    The constitutionality of the assessment should not
    depend on the happenstance of the financial condition
    of the assessed bank at the time of the assessment. We
    are unaware of any principle of takings law under
    which an imposition of liability is deemed a per se
    taking as to any party that cannot pay it. It would be
    perverse to hold that a statute resulting in a $99
    million liability would be constitutional as applied to
    any [entity] having a net worth of more than $100
    million but unconstitutional per se as to any member
    having a net worth of less than $100 million. The
    assessment in both cases is based on the same theory
    of liability and should meet the same constitutional
    fate.
    Branch v. United States, 69 F.3d at 1577. 15 Branch
    _________________________________________________________________
    15. The plaintiffs dispute the Branch court's reasoning by citing to
    Lucas,
    in which the Court wrote:
    49
    recognizes that general regulatory laws, unlike the
    particularized applications of zoning regulations that are
    the typical targets of takings challenges, usually have the
    kind of general applicability that mutes the concerns
    behind takings jurisprudence. The broader the reach of a
    law, the less likely it is that a powerless segment of society
    is being unfairly singled out to bear a burden that society
    as a whole should bear.16
    As the concurrence and the dissent in Eastern suggest,
    considerable practical problems would arise were we to find
    plaintiffs' categorical takings claim cognizable. For example,
    we would have to decide at what point we could justify
    granting relief on these grounds. Unity will go out of
    business as soon as it is ordered to pay. B&T, by contrast,
    will apparently go under in two years, when its liabilities
    under the Act consume the last of its reserves. Should we
    wait until B&T is in the same position as Unity? Would
    being a year away from bankruptcy be enough? Should
    _________________________________________________________________
    It is true that at least in some cases the landowner with 95% loss
    will get nothing, while the landowner with total loss will recover
    in
    full. But that occasional result is no more strange than the gross
    disparity between the landowner whose premises are taken for a
    highway (who recovers in full) and the landowner whose property is
    reduced to 5% of its former value by the highway (who recovers
    nothing). Takings law is full of these "all-or-nothing" situations.
    Lucas, 
    505 U.S. at
    1019 n.8. However, Lucas is inapposite. In Lucas,
    there was a strip of affected beachfront land; that land was reduced to
    zero value by regulation; that was a taking. The Court did not inquire
    into whether the landowners had enough other resources to survive the
    reduction in value, because that was not relevant to the test. All that
    was necessary was to look at the value of the affected land. Under the
    plaintiffs' interpretation, the Court should have examined Mr. Lucas's
    financial condition before and after the regulation at issue, and there
    would not have been a categorical taking if Mr. Lucas remained in the
    black. This suggests the difficulties with a takings analysis that is
    unanchored to a specific property interest.
    16. Breadth of application has its own dangers, however, and one of
    those dangers is that a law will have irrationally large effects on
    regulated businesses. Our substantive due process jurisprudence has
    developed to address this situation, as we discuss supra in Section III.
    50
    B&T be required to show that there is no potential"white
    knight" that might rescue it from destruction? Alternatively,
    we might reduce B&T's obligations instead of eliminating
    them entirely so that it could limp along, never showing a
    profit but never going under. That would arguably be an
    appropriate, constitutional remedy for the threatened harm,
    the way that transferable use credits can mitigate what
    would otherwise be a taking when zoning restrictions are at
    issue. See Penn Central Transp. Co. v. City of New York,
    
    438 U.S. 104
     (1978). If it is the total destruction of the
    business that converts the Act into a taking, then perhaps
    we should simply declare that part of the obligation that
    will drive B&T out of business a taking and approve the
    rest. Yet this would only plunge courts further into the
    intricacies of business finance.
    Deciding for Unity and B&T because they will be forced
    into bankruptcy by the Coal Act would open up a Pandora's
    Box that would throw into question every economic
    regulation imaginable. Companies could adjust their
    accounting practices to prove that any particular regulation
    would be enough to destroy them as profitable enterprises.
    The problem would be compounded if, as counsel for
    plaintiffs suggested at oral argument, we should evaluate
    the financial status of an entity without looking at its
    corporate relatives for takings purposes. A corporation
    subject to expensive regulation at some of its production
    facilities could create a series of subsidiaries, each of which
    would be insolvent on its own if forced to comply with a
    particular set of regulations, and claim constitutional
    protection against enforcement of the regulations, even
    though a different corporate configuration would remain
    solvent.17
    _________________________________________________________________
    17. A supporting in terrorem argument is not difficult to devise. For
    example, an employer could resist an increase in the minimum wage on
    the ground that the increased cost would drive it out of business.
    Similarly, many small-business owners find that anti-discrimination laws
    generate significant expenses, and some might be forced out of business
    by compliance costs. See Mike Hudson, Jobs for Disabled People:
    Handicapping Businesses, Roanoke Times & World News, July 30, 1995,
    at F1. While such concerns might very well prove overstated in most
    cases, courts would be forced into the dismal business of economic
    51
    A decision on these grounds would also open the door to
    plaintiffs attempting to choose government regulations from
    which they wanted to be excused. It is notable that B&T
    repeatedly discusses its other expensive government-
    imposed obligations, which involve cleaning up polluted
    coal mines and paying out black lung benefits. The Coal Act
    alone, according to B&T's submissions, would not
    necessarily put B&T out of business; it is only because the
    environmental and black lung obligations are so large that
    this additional expense overwhelms B&T. There is nothing
    in B&T's constitutional argument about "total takings" that
    distinguishes its other obligations from those imposed by
    the Coal Act, nor is there a conceptual reason to confine
    this definition of total takings to retroactive laws.
    We decline to enter into the conceptual morass that
    would be engendered by the plaintiffs' total takings theory.
    That a regulation will put a particular plaintiff out of
    business cannot be proof that a taking has occurred.
    Instead, the size of the deprivation inflicted by a law must
    be evaluated in the context of the other relevant facts. In
    Connolly, the Court noted that the MPPAA "completely
    deprives an employer of whatever amount of money it is
    obligated to pay to fulfill its statutory liability." Connolly,
    475 U.S. at 225. But this did not lead to the conclusion
    that there had been a taking because "[t]here is nothing to
    show that the withdrawal liability actually imposed on an
    employer will always be out of proportion to its experience
    with the plan, and the mere fact that the employer must
    pay money to comply with the Act is but a necessary
    consequence of the MPPAA's regulatory scheme." Id. at 226.
    We do not gainsay that the liability imposed on Unity in
    particular is troubling. Unity's assets are tiny, and its Coal
    Act liabilities dwarf them. If we uphold the defendants'
    _________________________________________________________________
    prediction. Every economic regulation would have to be litigated on a
    case-by-case basis. See Sheila A. Moloney, The Lady in Red Tape, Policy
    Review, Sept./Oct. 1996, at 48 (discussing various regulations that
    threaten the financial viability of specific businesses, including OSHA
    safety regulations, FTC franchising rules, ADA accessibility
    requirements, Endangered Species Act development restrictions, and
    EPA Superfund clean-up costs).
    52
    position, this small family business will be bankrupted
    instantly. But the size of a liability only weighs in favor of
    finding a taking insofar as it is out of proportion to the
    legitimate obligations society may impose on individual
    entities. And, as we have discussed in Part III, wefind the
    proportionality test satisfied in this instance.
    V. Conclusion
    We hold that Congress could reasonably determine that
    the plaintiffs, along with other coal operatiors in similar
    situations, placed the coal industry retiree benefit funds in
    jeopardy after creating an expectation of lifetime benefits.
    Moreover, the actions that created the need for the Coal Act
    are not so far in the past as to make it fundamentally
    unjust to impose liability upon the plaintiffs, because the
    burden is proportional to their contribution to the problem
    and the retroactivity is not too extensive. We do not deny
    that Unity, in particular, presents a sympathetic case. This
    family business has slowly decreased in size as the
    economic changes of the past decades have buffeted it. Yet
    small businesses, even businesses that have suffered from
    the eroding pressures of time and economic change, cannot
    be immune from reasonable government regulation simply
    because that regulation has harsh effects. The Coal Act
    may not be an ideal law; it may not even be a wise one. But
    its wisdom, or lack thereof, in a particular case does not
    determine its constitutionality.
    For the foregoing reasons, the judgment of the District
    Court will be affirmed.
    53
    ALDISERT, Circuit Judge, concurring:
    I agree with the majority's determination that the 1992
    Coal Industry Retiree Health Benefit Act, 26 U.S.C.
    SS 9701-9722 (1994 and Supp II) ("Coal Act"), as applied to
    Unity Real Estate Company and Barnes and Tucker
    Company does not violate substantive due process and is
    not an unconstitutional taking. I agree also that the
    retroactive scope of the Act is not beyond appropriate
    legislative power.
    Although Appellants vigorously contend that their cases
    are analogous to Eastern Enterprises v. Apfel, 
    118 S. Ct. 2131
     (1998), their analogical argument fails because the
    decisive material facts of the cases bear no similarity. The
    decisive material facts in Eastern Enterprises are that the
    company (1) left the coal industry in 1965 and (2) was
    never a party to the 1974 and later Wage Agreements that
    first suggested the commitment to lifetime benefits for
    retirees and family members. See Eastern Enterprises, 
    118 S. Ct. at 2150
     (plurality opinion). Unlike the former coal
    operator in Eastern Enterprises, Appellants remained in the
    coal industry until 1981 and 1984 respectively, and
    participated in negotiations for the 1974 and later Wage
    Agreements. As emphasized in Eastern Enterprises, "It is
    the 1974, 1978 and subsequent agreements that first
    suggest an industry commitment to the funding of lifetime
    health benefits for both retirees and their family members."
    
    Id.
     Appellants' act of signing the 1974 and subsequent
    National Bituminous Coal Wage Agreements (NBCWA or
    "Wage Agreement") precludes the rote application of Eastern
    Enterprises to these cases.
    I.
    On the due process question of "promises" and
    "representations" made to the miners, I would sustain the
    constitutionality of the Act as applied to the Appellants for
    one reason only: The evidence before Congress provided a
    rational basis to believe that a promise of lifetime benefits
    had been made. Congress relied on the Coal Commission
    Report, its appendices and the Commissioners' testimony at
    the Senate hearing. For example, the Coal Commission
    Report stated:
    54
    The Commission firmly believes that retired miners are
    entitled to the health care benefits that were promised
    and guaranteed them and that such commitments
    must be honored. . . .
    Retired coal miners have legitimate expectations of
    health care benefits for life; that was the promise they
    received during their working lives and that is how
    they planned their retirement years. That commitment
    should be honored.
    See Supp. App. at 350, 360 (Secretary of Labor's Advisory
    Commission on United Mine Workers of America Retiree
    Health Benefits, Coal Commission Report (1990)). These
    were important findings that were accepted by Congress.
    Whether the Commission Report accurately portrayed the
    state of affairs in the coal mining industry at the time the
    1974 Wage Agreement was negotiated and signed is largely
    irrelevant to what should be our analysis of the Coal Act's
    constitutionality. In considering the question of who
    promised what to whom, I do not believe that it is
    appropriate for any reviewing court to review de novo the
    history of the agreements or to parse their language.
    I say this because, to paraphrase Holmes, "That's not our
    job."1 Once we get beyond that portion of the Due Process
    or Takings Clause analysis relating to the Coal Act's
    financial effect on the Appellants, we must address whether
    there was deprivation of property without due process of
    law on the theory that the Appellants never promised any
    benefits beyond the lifetime of the Wage Agreements. Our
    job is not to examine the materials and to make an
    independent determination of this issue, a sort of ersatz
    fact-finding by either a federal trial or appellate court.
    _________________________________________________________________
    1. Learned Hand once reminisced: "I remember once I was with [Holmes];
    it was a Saturday when the Court was to confer. It was before we had
    a motor car, and we jogged along in an old coup). When we got to the
    Capitol, I wanted to provoke a response, so as he walked off, I said to
    him: ``Well, sir, goodbye. Do justice!' . . . He replied: ``That is not my
    job.
    My job is to play the game according to the rules.' " Learned Hand,
    Continuing Legal Education for Professional Competence and
    Responsibility, Report on the Arden House Conference, at 116-123
    (1958).
    55
    On this issue, as I see it, our job is merely to determine
    whether substantial evidence was presented before
    Congress on this issue. And I conclude that there was. The
    Coal Commission Report and other testimony before the
    Senate Committee informed Congress that "[r]etired coal
    miners have legitimate expectations of health care benefits
    for life; that was the promise they received during their
    working lives and that is how they planned their retirement
    years. That commitment should be honored." Supp. App. at
    360 (Secretary of Labor's Advisory Commission on United
    Mine Workers of America Retiree Health Benefits, Coal
    Commission Report (1990)). This determination serves as
    the rational basis for the legislation.
    Our sole obligation is "to assure that, in formulating its
    judgments, Congress has drawn reasonable inferences
    based on substantial evidence." Turner Broadcasting Sys.
    Inc. v. Federal Communications Comm'n, 
    520 U.S. 180
    , 195
    (1997) (internal quotations omitted). Substantial evidence
    "does not mean a large or considerable amount of evidence,
    but rather ``such relevant evidence as a reasonable mind
    might accept as adequate to support a conclusion.' " Pierce
    v. Underwood, 
    487 U.S. 552
    , 565 (1988) (quoting
    Consolidated Edison Co. v. National Labor Relations Bd.,
    
    305 U.S. 197
    , 229 (1938)). "We owe Congress'findings
    deference in part because the institution is far better
    equipped than the judiciary to amass and evaluate the vast
    amounts of data bearing upon legislative questions."
    Turner, 
    520 U.S. at 195
     (internal quotations omitted). On
    the basis of the record before Congress, I would conclude
    that there was substantial evidence to provide Congress
    with a rational basis for believing that the Coal Act was
    consistent with promises that had been made by coal
    operators to their former employees.
    II.
    Important prudential considerations undergird the
    Court's limitations on the judicial role. In the case at bar,
    reasonable persons can differ in evaluating the history of
    the critical Wage Agreements and interpreting its
    provisions. For example, although the majority has made a
    thorough and scholarly analysis of these circumstances, my
    56
    own conclusions would be somewhat different. I would not
    rely on promises and representations made apparently
    dehors the explicit language of the Wage Agreements.
    Critical to me is that the Wage Agreements expressly
    limited all of the promised retiree health benefits to the
    term of each agreement. Miners who retired after 1975, but
    whose former employers were no longer in the coal mining
    business, were promised benefits through the United Mine
    Workers of America 1974 Benefit Plan and Trust ("1974
    Plan"). See Eastern Enterprises, 
    118 S. Ct. at 2139-2140
    .
    Article XX(c)(3)(ii) of the NBCWA stated that the purpose of
    the 1974 Plan was to provide employee health benefits only
    "during the term of this Agreement." Similarly, Article II of
    the 1974 Plan expressly stated that if the plan assets were
    to "become insufficient" to continue providing benefits after
    the NBCWA had expired, "the benefits may be suspended or
    reduced to amounts which, in the judgment of the
    Trustees, can be paid from the net assets." The NBCWA
    contained a "General Description" of all promised benefits
    that expressly stated that health benefits were"guaranteed"
    at fixed levels only "during the term of this Agreement."
    Similar provisions are found or incorporated in other
    agreements. I simply can find no evidence of any"promise"
    of lifetime benefits contained in any Wage Agreement. Any
    reliance on extra-contractual "promises" looks to a novel
    theory of law that turns a blind eye to the centuries-old law
    of contracts and to the current law on collective bargaining
    agreements.
    To suggest that the clear language limiting benefits to the
    term of the Wage Agreement is trumped by the "lifetime"
    health card is a stretch.2 By analogy, one could say that
    possession of a Social Security card "for life," without more
    and without any proof of disability, entitles one to benefits.
    _________________________________________________________________
    2. The basis for the claim of a "lifetime" health card is in the "General
    Description" of the 1974 NBCWA, which states:
    Any pensioned miner covered in this Plan will retain his Health
    Services card until death, and upon his death his widow will retain
    a health Services card until her death or remarriage.
    See Appellants' Supp. Br. at 6-7.
    57
    The "evergreen" clauses included in the 1978 Wage
    Agreement do not persuade me to reach a different result:
    My reading of these clauses is that they addressed only
    employer funding, not the scope of the underlying employee
    benefits.
    As a native of Carnegie, Pennsylvania--a coal mining and
    steel mill town near Pittsburgh--who is old enough to
    remember the organizational efforts of John L. Lewis in the
    coal fields in the 1930s and the 1947 Krug-Lewis
    Agreement, I no doubt have a unique perspective. I know
    first-hand the mantra of every coal miner through decades
    of strikes and picketing: "No Contract, No Work."
    To the miner, the actual contract controlled, not the
    expectation of future agreements. Without the contract in
    hand, the miners would not pick up their lamps at the
    lamp house and descend into the shafts. They worked
    under the precise language in a given contract and under
    no other representations. The sordid history of the coal
    company towns that surrounded Carnegie, and the
    inhumane treatment of the miners and their families prior
    to effective unionization in the mines, impelled the miners
    to require thereafter that every representation of working
    conditions and benefits be set forth in clear language in a
    hard-fought written collective bargaining agreement.
    The foregoing discussion is but my gratuitous
    interpretation of some of the history and contents of the
    Wage Agreements, and admittedly, it may be contrary to
    that expressed in most other judicial opinions. My views
    and those of judges with contrary interpretations are
    important in one respect only: My views and those of other
    judges are totally irrelevant. What is relevant is only that on
    the basis of evidence before it, Congress concluded that a
    promise of lifetime benefits had been made. This furnished
    the rational basis for enacting the controversial provisions
    of the Coal Act.
    III.
    This, too, must be said. I am conscious that in light of
    the view that we take here, the handwriting is on the wall
    that a kind of hydraulic pressure will generate economic
    58
    disasters in companies whose financial circumstances are
    similar to Unity and Barnes and Tucker. Without additional
    and more realistic Congressional intervention, we may see
    a phenomenon of the "last man standing," as companies
    disappear from the economic scene and responsibility for
    paying benefits shifts to surviving companies. If this case is
    any example and a forerunner of things to come, the
    operation of the present statutory solution to the vexing
    health benefit problem of retirees and their dependents may
    serve as a full employment program for bankruptcy lawyers
    of companies unable to make prescribed payments. Sadly,
    I do not believe that this statement is an argumentum ad
    terrorem.
    I join in the judgment of the court.
    A True Copy:
    Teste:
    Clerk of the United States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    59