FTC v. Hackensack Meridian Health Inc ( 2022 )


Menu:
  •                                         PRECEDENTIAL
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    ______
    No. 21-2603
    ______
    FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
    v.
    HACKENSACK MERIDIAN HEALTH, INC.;
    ENGLEWOOD HEALTHCARE FOUNDATION,
    Appellants
    ______
    On Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the District of New Jersey
    (D. C. No. 2-20-cv-18140)
    District Judge: Honorable John M. Vazquez
    ______
    Argued December 7, 2021
    Before: SHWARTZ, PORTER and FISHER, Circuit Judges.
    (Filed: March 22, 2022)
    Alison M. Agnew
    John L. Roach, IV
    Jonathan Todt
    Kenneth M. Vorrasi
    Faegre Drinker Biddle & Reath
    1500 K Street, N.W., Suite 1100
    Washington, DC 20005
    Daniel J. Delaney
    Faegre Drinker Biddle & Reath
    191 North Wacker Drive, Suite 3700
    Chicago, IL 60606
    Paul H. Saint-Antoine
    John S. Yi
    Faegre Drinker Biddle & Reath
    One Logan Square, Suite 2000
    Philadelphia, PA 19103
    Aaron D. Van Oort [ARGUED]
    Faegre Drinker Biddle & Reath
    90 South Seventh Street
    2200 Wells Fargo Center
    Minneapolis, MN 55402
    Counsel for Appellant Hackensack Meridian Health,
    Inc.
    Neely B. Agin
    Heather P. Lamberg
    Andrew Tauber
    Winston & Strawn
    1901 L Street, N.W.
    Washington, DC 20036
    Jeffrey J. Amato
    Johanna Hudgens
    2
    Jeffrey L. Kessler
    Winston & Strawn
    200 Park Avenue
    New York, NY 10166
    David E. Dahlquist
    Kevin B. Goldstein
    Winston & Strawn
    35 West Wacker Drive, 46th Floor
    Chicago, IL 60601
    Counsel for Appellant Englewood           Healthcare
    Foundation
    David R. Fine
    K&L Gates
    17 North Second Street, 18th Floor
    Harrisburg, PA 17101
    Counsel for Amicus Appellants Michael R. Baye,
    Kenneth G. Elzinga, Gregory K. Leonard, Janusz A.
    Ordover, Robert D. Willig
    Paul Harold
    Steffen N. Johnson
    Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati
    1700 K Street, N.W., 5th Floor
    Washington, DC 20006
    Jonathan M. Jacobson
    Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati
    1301 Avenue of the Americas, 40th Floor
    New York, NY 10019
    Counsel for Amicus Appellants American Hospital
    Association, Association of American Medical Colleges
    3
    Jennifer A. Hradil
    Gibbons
    One Gateway Center
    Newark, NJ 07102
    Counsel for Amicus Appellant African American
    Chamber of Commerce of New Jersey
    Richard Hernandez
    McCarter & English
    100 Mulberry Street
    Four Gateway Center, 14th Floor
    Newark, NJ 07102
    Ashley L. Turner
    McCarter & English
    1600 Market Street, Suite 3900
    Philadelphia, PA 19103
    Counsel for Amicus Appellant New Jersey Hospital
    Association
    Mariel Goetz [ARGUED]
    Jonathan H. Lasken
    Federal Trade Commission
    600 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W.
    Washington, DC 20580
    Counsel for Appellee Federal Trade Commission
    Jamie Crooks
    Fairmark Partners
    1499 Massachusetts Avenue, Suite 113a
    Washington, DC 20005
    4
    Counsel for Amicus Appellees Professors, Economists
    and Scholars
    Douglas F. Johnson
    Earp Cohn
    20 Brace Road, 4th Floor
    Cherry Hill, NJ 08034
    Counsel for Amicus Professors of Law and Economics,
    Economists and Health Policy Researchers, Thomas L.
    Greaney, Alexandra D. Montague, Jaime S. King,
    Richard M. Scheffler, Katherine M. Gudiksen, Brent D.
    Fulton, Daniel R. Arnold
    Tracy W. Wertz
    Office of Attorney General of Pennsylvania
    Strawberry Square
    Harrisburg, PA 17120
    Counsel for Amicus Appellee Commonwealth of
    Pennsylvania
    ______
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    ______
    FISHER, Circuit Judge
    Englewood Healthcare Foundation, a local New Jersey
    hospital, and Hackensack Meridian Health, Inc., New Jersey’s
    largest healthcare system, agreed to a multi-million-dollar
    merger. The Federal Trade Commission opposes their merger
    and filed an administrative complaint alleging it violates
    Section 7 of the Clayton Act because it is likely to substantially
    5
    lessen competition. To prevent the parties from merging before
    the administrative adjudication could occur, the FTC filed suit
    in the District of New Jersey under Section 13(b) of the Federal
    Trade Commission Act, requesting a preliminary injunction
    pending the outcome of the administrative adjudication. The
    District Court granted the preliminary injunction, holding that
    the FTC established that there is a reasonable probability that
    the merger will substantially impair competition. For the
    reasons that follow, we will affirm.
    Englewood Healthcare Foundation is a non-profit
    corporation that operates a single community hospital in
    Bergen County, New Jersey. It provides primary, secondary,
    and some non-complex tertiary services to patients. It does not
    provide more complex tertiary and quaternary services. It
    currently lacks the expertise, regulatory approvals, and
    facilities to perform those services.1 Englewood is licensed for
    531 beds, although it currently operates around 350 beds.
    Hackensack Meridian Health is the largest hospital
    system in New Jersey. It is a sixteen-hospital health system
    with multiple academic medical centers, community hospitals,
    specialty hospitals, a medical school, and a research institution.
    Hackensack has two hospitals in Bergen County: Hackensack
    University Medical Center (“HUMC”), the busiest hospital in
    New Jersey, and Pascack Valley Medical Center, a small, acute
    care community hospital. HUMC offers all levels of care, but
    1
    Hospital services range from primary care—the least
    complex, such as routine delivery of a baby—to quaternary
    care—the most complex, such as an organ transplant or
    experimental treatment.
    6
    it is Hackensack’s only hospital that performs complex tertiary
    and quaternary services. HUMC is licensed for 781 beds, 711
    of which are operational. In recent years, Hackensack has
    acquired other health providers, each time raising prices at the
    acquired facility.
    Bergen County is part of a densely populated region of
    Northern New Jersey that borders New York City. Bergen
    County is home to three other hospitals affiliated with neither
    Englewood nor Hackensack. Some Bergen County residents
    seek care in nearby Northern New Jersey counties—e.g.,
    Hudson, Essex, and Passaic Counties—and New York.
    In April 2018, Englewood hired a strategic planning
    consultant to explore ways to meet its capital needs and use its
    excess bed capacity. The consultant advised Englewood to
    consider searching for partnership opportunities. Shortly
    thereafter, the Englewood board of directors voted to pursue a
    merger. Englewood considered various merger partners and
    ultimately selected Hackensack.
    Englewood and Hackensack signed a merger
    agreement, which took effect in September 2019. As part of the
    agreement, Hackensack committed $439.5 million in capital
    investments over eight years. Hackensack also agreed to make
    other clinical, operational, and financial investments, such as
    transferring patients from its hospitals to Englewood and
    developing Englewood into a “tertiary hub.” FTC v.
    Hackensack Meridian Health, Inc., No. 20-18140, 
    2021 WL 4145062
    , at *10 (D.N.J. Aug. 4, 2021).
    After the signing of the agreement, the FTC filed an
    administrative complaint against the Hospitals alleging that the
    proposed merger would violate Section 7 of the Clayton Act,
    
    15 U.S.C. § 18
    . In December 2020, the FTC filed suit in the
    7
    District of New Jersey, seeking a temporary restraining order
    and a preliminary injunction to enjoin the merger. The parties
    stipulated that the Hospitals would not effectuate the proposed
    merger until after the District Court ruled on the FTC’s motion
    for a preliminary injunction.
    The District Court conducted a seven-day evidentiary
    hearing on the preliminary injunction motion. During the
    hearing, the Court admitted over 500 exhibits into evidence
    and heard testimony from fifteen fact witnesses and seven
    expert witnesses. The District Court held that the FTC was
    likely to succeed on the merits and the equities weighed in
    favor of issuing the injunction. It concluded that the FTC had
    established a prima facie case by proposing properly defined
    product and geographic markets and showing that the merger
    would likely have anticompetitive effects. Because the
    Hospitals failed to rebut the FTC’s prima facie case, the
    District Court granted the FTC’s request for a preliminary
    injunction.
    The Hospitals timely appealed.
    2
    Section 13(b) of the FTC Act empowers the FTC to ask
    a federal court to preliminarily enjoin a violation of § 7 “[u]pon
    2
    The District Court had jurisdiction under 15 U.S.C §
    53(b) (FTC injunction request) and 
    28 U.S.C. § 1331
     (federal
    question). This Court has jurisdiction under 
    28 U.S.C. § 1291
    (final decision) and 
    28 U.S.C. § 1292
    (a)(1) (order granting
    injunctive relief). The adjudicatory function of determining
    whether the FTC Act has been violated is vested in the FTC in
    the first instance. 
    15 U.S.C. § 45
    . The only purpose of a
    proceeding in federal court under § 13(b) of the Act is to obtain
    a preliminary injunction and preserve the status quo until the
    FTC can perform its adjudicatory function. Thus, the District
    8
    a proper showing that, weighing the equities and considering
    the Commission’s likelihood of ultimate success, such action
    would be in the public interest.” 
    15 U.S.C. § 53
    (b). The
    Hospitals challenge the preliminary injunction on one basis:
    that the District Court incorrectly concluded that the FTC is
    likely to succeed on the merits in the administrative
    proceeding.
    Section 7 of the Clayton Act bars mergers whose effect
    “may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create
    a monopoly.” 
    15 U.S.C. § 18
    . “Congress used the words ‘may
    be substantially to lessen competition’ . . . to indicate that its
    concern was with probabilities, not certainties.” Brown Shoe
    Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 323 (1962). Federal courts
    assess § 7 claims under a three-part, burden-shifting
    framework. FTC v. Penn State Hershey Med. Ctr. (“Hershey”),
    
    838 F.3d 327
    , 337 (3d Cir. 2016). First, the FTC must establish
    a prima facie case that the merger is anticompetitive. 
    Id.
     If the
    FTC establishes a prima facie case, the burden then shifts to
    the Hospitals to rebut it. 
    Id.
     If the Hospitals succeed on rebuttal,
    the burden of production shifts back to the FTC “and merges
    with the ultimate burden of persuasion, which is incumbent on
    the [FTC] at all times.” 
    Id.
     (quoting St. Alphonsus Med. Ctr.-
    Nampa Inc. v. St. Luke’s Health Sys., Ltd., 
    778 F.3d 775
    , 783
    (9th Cir. 2015)). “To establish a prima facie case, the [FTC]
    must (1) propose the proper relevant market and (2) show that
    Court’s grant of an injunction “effectively terminated the
    litigation and constituted a final order which is appealable
    under 
    28 U.S.C. § 1291
    .” FTC v. Food Town Stores, Inc., 
    539 F.2d 1339
    , 1342 (4th Cir. 1976).
    9
    the effect of the merger in that market is likely to be
    anticompetitive.” 
    Id.
     at 337–38. The relevant market includes
    both a product market and a geographic market. Id. at 338. The
    Hospitals challenge the District Court’s evaluation of the
    FTC’s likelihood of success on three grounds: the Court’s
    adoption of the FTC’s geographic market definition; its use of
    the efficiencies defense standard for evaluating the Hospitals’
    claims of procompetitive benefits; and its holding that the FTC
    carried its ultimate burden of persuasion.
    1. Product Market
    “Determination of the relevant product and geographic
    markets is a necessary predicate to deciding whether a merger
    contravenes the Clayton Act.” United States v. Marine
    Bancorporation, Inc., 
    418 U.S. 602
    , 618 (1974) (internal
    quotation marks omitted). The District Court found the
    relevant product market to be the “cluster of inpatient [general
    acute care] services” offered by Englewood and Hackensack’s
    Bergen County hospitals and sold to commercial insurers.
    Hackensack, 
    2021 WL 4145062
    , at *15. The parties do not
    dispute the relevant product market, but their agreement ends
    here.
    2. Geographic Market
    “The relevant geographic market ‘is that area in which
    a potential buyer may rationally look for the goods or services
    he seeks.’” Hershey, 838 F.3d at 338 (quoting Gordon v.
    Lewistown Hosp., 
    423 F.3d 184
    , 212 (3d Cir. 2005)). The
    relevant market’s geographic scope must be “[d]etermined
    within the specific context of each case,” “correspond to the
    commercial realities of the industry,” and “be economically
    significant.” 
    Id.
     (second and third phrases quoting Brown Shoe,
    
    370 U.S. at
    336–37). The plaintiff—here, the FTC—bears the
    burden of establishing the relevant geographic market. 
    Id.
    10
    Courts and the FTC frequently use the hypothetical
    monopolist test to determine the relevant geographic market.
    A proposed market is properly defined, under this test, if a
    hypothetical monopolist who owns all the firms in the
    proposed market could profitably impose a small but
    significant non-transitory increase in price (“SSNIP”) on
    buyers in that market. U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Fed. Trade
    Comm’n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines, § 4.1.1, at 8–9
    (2010).3 Both parties here agree that this test is the proper one
    to apply.
    The FTC proposed a relevant geographic market
    defined by all hospitals used by commercially insured patients
    who reside in Bergen County. This means that any hospital that
    serves a resident of Bergen County is included as a market
    participant even if that hospital is not in Bergen County. The
    FTC’s proposed geographic market is thus patient-based, i.e.,
    it is defined by the location of patients rather than the location
    of hospitals. The FTC’s expert, Dr. Leemore Dafny, chose
    Bergen County as the proposed market for three reasons: (1)
    Englewood and HUMC are in Bergen County; (2) the majority
    of Bergen County residents receive care in Bergen County; and
    (3) Bergen County is an economically significant area for
    insurers. Recognizing the unique commercial realities of the
    healthcare market and relying heavily on insurer testimony, the
    District Court accepted the FTC’s proposed geographic
    market.
    The Hospitals argue that the District Court erred in its
    formulation of the relevant geographic market. First, they
    3
    The Merger Guidelines are not binding on the courts.
    However, “they are often used as persuasive authority.”
    Hershey, 838 F.3d at 338 n.2 (quoting St. Alphonsus,778 at 784
    n.9).
    11
    argue, the FTC did not prove the feasibility of price
    discrimination in the market. Second, they contend that even if
    a showing of price discrimination was not required, the
    proposed market does not pass the hypothetical monopolist
    test.
    “[D]efinition of the relevant [geographic] market is a
    factual question dependent upon the special characteristics of
    the industry involved,” so we review for clear error. Hershey,
    838 F.3d at 335 (quoting St. Alphonsus, 778 F.3d at 783
    (internal marks omitted)). However, “where a district court
    applies an incomplete economic analysis or an erroneous
    economic theory to [the] facts . . . , it has committed legal error
    subject to plenary review” and we will reverse. Id. at 336.
    a. Price discrimination is not a prerequisite for a patient-based
    market
    As a preliminary matter, we must address whether a
    showing of price discrimination is required for a patient-based
    geographic market. The Hospitals argue that a showing of price
    discrimination—specifically, that patients in the FTC’s
    proposed market could be charged higher prices for inpatient
    general acute care services than patients living outside the
    proposed market—is required under the Merger Guidelines,
    case law, and economic literature. Thus, the Hospitals argue,
    when the District Court accepted the FTC’s proposed market
    without this showing, it erred as a matter of law. We disagree.
    We begin our analysis with the Merger Guidelines. The
    Guidelines themselves caution that they “should be read with
    the awareness that merger analysis does not consist of uniform
    application of a single methodology. Rather, it is a fact-specific
    process through which the [FTC] . . . appl[ies] a range of
    analytical tools to the reasonably available and reliable
    evidence . . . .” Merger Guidelines, § 1, at 1. This initial call
    12
    for flexibility is bolstered throughout the Guidelines by the use
    of permissive language such as “normally,” “may,” and
    “usually.” See e.g., §§ 4, 5. The Hospitals argue that § 4.2 of
    the Guidelines outlines the only allowable methods for
    establishing a customer-based geographic market. They take
    too restrictive a view of § 4.2. Using price discrimination is but
    one way the Guidelines say the FTC may define a customer-
    based geographic market. Id. § 4.2, at 14. The Guidelines even
    recognize that these types of geographic markets apply most
    often when traditional buyers and sellers are involved. Id. But
    nothing in the Guidelines states that a customer-based
    geographic market may be defined only through price
    discrimination.
    The Hospitals next cite a slew of cases to argue
    customer-based geographic markets require a showing of price
    discrimination. But case law likewise provides us with no such
    mandate. Several of the Hospitals’ cases involve markets
    starkly different from the healthcare market here. See FTC v.
    Staples, Inc., 
    190 F. Supp. 3d 100
    , 112, 117–18 (D.D.C. 2016)
    (office supply companies); FTC v. Wilh. Wilhelmsen Holding
    ASA, 
    341 F. Supp. 3d 27
    , 47 (D.D.C. 2018) (marine water
    treatment providers). These markets, which involve traditional
    sellers and buyers, are not analogous to a complex healthcare
    market. The healthcare industry involves a two-stage model of
    competition. Hershey, 838 F.3d at 342. In the first stage,
    “insurers and hospitals negotiate to determine whether the
    hospitals will be in the insurers’ networks and how much the
    insurers will pay them.” FTC v. Advocate Health Care
    Network, 
    841 F.3d 460
    , 465 (7th Cir. 2016). In the second
    stage, “hospitals compete to attract patients, based primarily on
    non-price factors like convenience and reputation for
    quality.” 
    Id.
     Thus, unlike a traditional seller and buyer
    industry, healthcare involves different payors with different
    13
    incentives and competitive constraints. We must always
    consider the commercial realities of the industry involved. See
    Brown Shoe, 
    370 U.S. at
    336–37.
    In the other cases the Hospitals cite, courts mandated
    price discrimination because the FTC asked the court to impose
    a price discrimination requirement. For example, in United
    States v. Eastman Kodak Co., the Second Circuit rejected the
    FTC’s proposed customer-based market because the FTC
    failed to prove “systematic price discrimination.” 
    63 F.3d 95
    ,
    107 (2d Cir. 1995). But the government there “chose[] to rebut
    Kodak’s proposed market definition” and proposed its own
    geographic market “by relying on [a] theory of price
    discrimination.” 
    Id.
     The government did not argue, and the
    Second Circuit did not hold, that price discrimination was the
    only basis on which to define a customer-based market. The
    Second Circuit assumed without deciding that if it accepted the
    government’s theory of price discrimination, the government
    would still lose because it did not proffer evidence to support
    its theory. 
    Id.
     Here, by contrast, the FTC chose Bergen County
    as its geographic market based on a theory of economic
    significance—Englewood and HUMC are both located there,
    the vast majority of Bergen County residents receive care
    there, and insurers think Bergen County is economically
    significant. The FTC here, unlike in Kodak, provided evidence
    to support its theory.
    St. Alphonsus provides a better example of defining a
    geographic market in the complex healthcare industry. St.
    Alphonsus Med. Ctr.-Nampa, Inc. v. St. Luke’s Health Sys., No.
    1:12-cv-00560, 
    2014 WL 407446
     (D. Idaho Jan. 24, 2014),
    aff’d 778 F.3d at 775. In St. Alphonsus, the FTC argued for,
    and the District Court found, a market based both on patient
    location and physician group location. Id. at *7–8. The FTC’s
    argument in this case is remarkably similar. The commercial
    14
    realities here are that most Bergen County residents receive
    their inpatient general acute care services in Bergen County
    and thus insurers feel they cannot offer a plan that does not
    include any Bergen County hospital options. Therefore, just as
    the court in St. Alphonsus defined the market based on both
    patient and supplier location considerations, so too did the
    District Court here.
    Finally, we see nothing in the economic literature to
    convince us that price discrimination is a prerequisite for a
    patient-based market. Far from “unambiguously stat[ing] that
    price discrimination is a prerequisite to defining a relevant
    customer-based geographic market,” Hospitals’ Br. at 26, the
    economic literature explains how a price discrimination theory
    applies to the definition of a relevant market when a price
    discrimination theory is used. See Jerry Hausman et al., Market
    Definition Under Price Discrimination, 64 Antitrust L.J. 367,
    369 (1996); Phillip Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, An
    Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application, ¶ 534d
    (4th and 5th Eds., 2021). The Hospitals point to one article that
    supports their reading of the Merger Guidelines. See Gregory
    Werden, Why (Ever) Define Markets? An Answer to Professor
    Kaplow, 78 Antitrust L.J. 729, 743 (2012). However, as
    discussed above, the Guidelines are flexible.
    Thus, we are not willing to adopt a rigid requirement
    that price discrimination must be feasible in every customer-
    based geographic market. Instead, we hew to the fundamental
    antitrust principle that courts must consider the commercial
    realities of the industry involved when defining the relevant
    market. The District Court did not err.4
    4
    Because we hold that the District Court correctly did
    not require a showing of price discrimination for the FTC’s
    proposed patient-based market, we do not address the parties’
    15
    b. The FTC verified the patient-based market with the
    hypothetical monopolist test
    To confirm the feasibility of a geographic market,
    courts often employ the hypothetical monopolist test. As
    already explained, the market is properly defined under this
    test if a hypothetical monopolist could impose a SSNIP,
    typically about five percent, in the proposed market. Hershey,
    838 F.3d at 338 & n.1 (citing Merger Guidelines, § 4.1.2, at
    10). “If, however, consumers would respond to a SSNIP by
    purchasing the product from outside the proposed market,
    thereby making the SSNIP unprofitable, the proposed market
    definition is too narrow.” Id.
    The FTC, through its expert Dr. Dafny, opined that the
    hypothetical monopolist test in this case is whether “a
    hypothetical monopolist of . . . all the hospitals supplying the
    cluster of inpatient [general acute care] services to residents of
    Bergen County [could] profitably impose a SSNIP.” Hr’g Tr.
    vol. 3, 562:18–21, ECF No. 356. Insurers testified that Bergen
    County is economically significant to them and they cannot
    market a plan to Bergen County residents that does not include
    a Bergen County hospital. Thus, Dafny concluded that these
    insurers would be forced to accept a SSNIP from a hypothetical
    monopolist of all hospitals supplying the cluster of inpatient
    general acute care services to residents of Bergen County.
    To empirically test her conclusion that Bergen County
    satisfies the hypothetical monopolist test, Dafny conducted a
    willingness-to-pay analysis. This analysis measures the
    bargaining leverage of a hospital by estimating the value that
    patients place on having access to that hospital. Patient
    preferences may depend on a multitude of factors, such as drive
    arguments regarding whether the FTC showed that price
    discrimination is feasible in the proposed market.
    16
    time to the hospital, services offered at the hospital, and the
    reputation of the hospital. The more value patients assign to the
    hospital, the more desirable that hospital is to an insurer’s
    network, and the higher the price an insurer is willing to pay to
    include that hospital in its network. Insurers maintain
    bargaining leverage by having alternative hospitals that
    patients recognize as close substitutes to include in their
    networks. When individual hospitals merge, the merged entity
    may increase its collective bargaining leverage, as compared to
    the leverage each individual entity maintained on its own,
    because the merger limits insurers’ ability to provide
    alternative hospitals for its enrollees.
    Using patient discharge data from Bergen County
    residents from 2017 to 2019, Dafny used a statistical model to
    calculate the bargaining leverage of the six hospitals in Bergen
    County—i.e., a subset of all hospitals that serve Bergen County
    residents. She calculated their leverage individually and as one
    entity owned by a hypothetical monopolist. Her calculations
    revealed that the merged hospitals’ bargaining leverage
    increased by sixty-five percent as compared to each hospital’s
    leverage if each negotiated independently. Dafny opined that,
    according to academic research, a change in leverage of this
    magnitude corresponds to a thirty-seven percent price increase,
    well above the five percent SSNIP threshold. Dafny reasoned
    that if a hypothetical monopolist of just this subset of hospitals
    could profitably impose a SSNIP on insurers, then a
    hypothetical monopolist of all hospitals serving Bergen County
    could likewise impose a SSNIP. The FTC argues that Dafny’s
    extrapolation was proper because the insurers testified that
    Bergen County is economically significant and that they could
    not market a plan to Bergen County residents that did not
    include a Bergen County hospital.
    17
    The Hospitals argue that Dafny’s proposed market and
    the methodology she applied do not match. They assert that
    Dafny envisioned a hypothetical monopolist that controlled
    only the six hospitals located in Bergen County—a market
    defined by the hospitals’ location, rather than patients’
    location. Because she used the wrong market definition, they
    claim she only tested a subset of the FTC’s proposed patient-
    based market. Thus, they argue, the District Court erred as a
    matter of law in finding the hypothetical monopolist test
    supported the FTC’s proposed geographic market.
    Hershey supports Dafny’s methodology. There, we
    concluded that insurers would accept a price increase from the
    two merging hospitals rather than excluding them from their
    networks due to the economically significant nature of those
    hospitals. 838 F.3d at 346. While the hypothetical monopolist
    test required the government to show only that insurers would
    “accept a price increase rather than exclude all of the hospitals”
    in the geographic market, the government had actually
    answered a narrower question—whether insurers would accept
    a price increase rather than exclude the two particular hospitals
    that planned to merge. Id. Thus, by determining that insurers
    would accept a SSNIP rather than exclude even two hospitals
    from its network, we could easily conclude that insurers would
    accept a SSNIP rather than exclude all the hospitals in the
    county. Id.
    As we did in Hershey, the District Court here found the
    extrapolation to be reasonable. The Court concluded that if a
    hypothetical monopolist owned all of the hospitals in Bergen
    County, “then insurers could attempt to redirect their
    customers to nearby hospitals outside of the county.”
    Hackensack, 
    2021 WL 4145062
    , at *20. However, if the
    hypothetical monopolist also owned other nearby hospitals that
    serve Bergen County residents—i.e., hospitals in Essex,
    18
    Hudson, and Passaic Counties—the monopolist’s bargaining
    leverage would increase even more. The District Court
    accepted Dafny’s extrapolation that the more hospitals the
    monopolist owned in the area, the greater leverage the
    monopolist would have over insurers because insurers would
    no longer have the option to redirect their Bergen County
    customers to nearby, non-county hospitals.
    The Hospitals first challenge this extrapolation by
    arguing that Dafny did not consider how individuals from other
    counties—a large portion of the patients for hospitals outside
    Bergen County—would affect her analysis. They argue that
    “[t]o determine whether the hospitals located outside Bergen
    County could profitably raise their prices across the board,
    Dafny would have had to examine how insurers and competing
    hospitals would react to such a price increase, which would
    affect the prices charged to patients across the region.” Reply
    Br. 13 (emphasis omitted). Not so. The District Court found
    the insurer testimony and supporting data that Bergen County
    is important to insurers credible and compelling. It was not
    clear error for the District Court to find that insurers’ desire to
    offer plans that include hospitals in Bergen County outweighs
    any possible reaction competing hospitals further outside of
    Bergen County and neighboring counties would have to a price
    increase.
    The Hospitals next argue that Dafny only considered the
    bargaining leverage of insurers, not patients. They point to
    Dafny’s alleged concession in her deposition testimony that
    she applied the hypothetical monopolist test to a market “based
    on the location of facilities” and to the District Court’s apparent
    acknowledgment that Dafny’s willingness-to-pay analysis
    “examines the leverage that a hypothetical monopolist of
    Bergen County hospitals would have as to insurers.” Hospitals’
    Br. 33–34 (emphasis omitted). But as Dafny explained in that
    19
    deposition and at the preliminary injunction hearing, she
    evaluated only hospitals located in Bergen County to predict
    what a hypothetical monopolist of all hospitals serving Bergen
    County residents—including those hospitals located in Bergen
    County—would do. Her hospital-based approach was but a
    first step to her patient-based analysis. The District Court
    recognized as much, noting that in the healthcare industry
    patient preferences and insurer preferences “cannot be viewed
    in separate, isolated spheres.” Hackensack, 
    2021 WL 4145062
    ,
    at *20. Again, the Hospitals take too rigid a view of the
    healthcare market. We therefore conclude that the District
    Court did not clearly err in its application of the hypothetical
    monopolist test.5
    ***
    For the reasons stated above, the District Court did not
    clearly err in finding the FTC demonstrated that Bergen
    County, including all hospitals that serve its residents, is a
    relevant geographic market.
    3. The merger will lead to anticompetitive effects
    After the relevant product and geographic markets are
    determined, “a prima facie case is established if the plaintiff
    proves that the merger will probably lead to anticompetitive
    effects in that market.” Hershey, 838 F.3d at 346 (quoting St.
    5
    The FTC alternatively alleged that Bergen County is a
    properly defined geographic market supported by the
    hypothetical monopolist test if a hospital-based approach is
    used. The Hospitals argue that the FTC forfeited this argument
    when its expert did not propose a hospital-based geographic
    market. Because we hold that the District Court did not err in
    defining a patient-based market, we need not address either
    argument.
    20
    Alphonsus, 778 F.3d at 785). Anticompetitive effects can
    include price increases and reduced product quality, product
    variety, service, or innovation. See Merger Guidelines, § 1, at
    2. The record thoroughly supports the District Court’s
    conclusion that the FTC established a prima facie case.
    a. Market Concentration
    One useful indicator of the competitive effects of a
    merger is market concentration. Id. § 5.3, at 18. Market
    concentration is measured by the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index
    (“HHI”). Id. A merger’s HHI is calculated by summing the
    squares of the market shares of each market participant.
    Squaring the shares “gives proportionately greater weight to
    the larger market shares,” id., and economists consider the HHI
    to be “superior to such cruder measures” such as summing up
    the largest firms’ market shares, FTC v. H.J. Heinz Co., 
    246 F.3d 708
    , 716 n.9 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (citation omitted). A pure
    monopoly would have an HHI of 10,000 (the square of a single
    business’s 100 percent market share), while a market with
    many players would have an HHI near zero. Merger
    Guidelines, § 5.3, at 18. A post-merger market with an HHI
    below 1,500 is considered unconcentrated, a market between
    1,500 and 2,500 is considered moderately concentrated, and a
    market with an HHI above 2,500 is considered highly
    concentrated. Id. § 5.3, at 19.
    In addition to the post-merger HHI number, we also
    consider the increase in the HHI resulting from the merger. Id.
    § 5.3, at 18–19. A merger that increases the HHI by more than
    200 points and results in a highly concentrated market, as
    described above, is “presumed to be likely to enhance market
    power.” Id. § 5.3, at 19. The FTC may establish a prima facie
    case by showing a high market concentration based on HHI
    numbers alone. See, e.g., Hershey, 838 F.3d at 347.
    21
    Using the methods described above, the FTC
    demonstrated that the post-merger HHI would be 2,835—a
    number that crosses the highly concentrated market threshold.
    The merger would increase the HHI by 841 points—over four
    times the 200-point benchmark that creates a presumption of
    enhanced market power if the merger results in a highly
    concentrated market. The FTC alleges that the post-merger
    combined Englewood/Hackensack Hospitals would command
    forty-seven percent of the market, with the next two closest
    competitors commanding only twenty-one percent and nine
    percent. The Hospitals do not dispute these numbers. Instead,
    they argue that the total HHI “barely exceed[s] the minimum
    2,500 threshold” to trigger a presumption of anticompetitive
    effects. Hospitals’ Br. 38. The Hospitals highlight that these
    numbers—an increase of 841 to an HHI of 2,835—are the
    “lowest [HHI numbers] that the FTC has relied on in any recent
    hospital-merger case involving [general acute care] services.”
    Id. at 38–39. But the FTC is not required to show extraordinary
    numbers to make out a prima facie case that the merger would
    have anticompetitive effects. Anticompetitive effects can occur
    at even lower thresholds, as evidenced by the Guidelines.
    Merger Guidelines, § 5.3, at 19. For instance, a moderately
    concentrated market (with a total HHI below 2,500) involving
    only more than a hundred-point increase “potentially raise[s]
    significant competitive concerns and [may] warrant scrutiny.”
    Id. The District Court correctly concluded that these numbers
    demonstrate the merger is presumptively anticompetitive.
    b. Direct Evidence
    Although the District Court needed no further evidence
    to find the FTC had established its prima facie case, the Court
    evaluated other evidence of anticompetitive effects presented
    by the FTC. This direct evidence strengthens the probability
    22
    that the merger will likely lead to anticompetitive effects and,
    thus, the FTC’s prima facie case. See St. Alphonsus, 778 F.3d
    at 788 (relying on HHI numbers and direct evidence of
    anticompetitive effects to confirm the prima facie case); Chi.
    Bridge & Iron Co. N.V. v. FTC, 
    534 F.3d 410
    , 431–32 (5th Cir.
    2008) (same); Heinz, 
    246 F.3d at 717
     (same). As the District
    Court explained, the Hospitals, a consultant hired by
    Englewood, and insurance companies all indicated that the
    merger would lead to anticompetitive effects or, at the very
    least, recognized the Hospitals as competitors.
    First, the Hospitals view each other as competitors.
    During Englewood’s partner search, Englewood’s president
    expressed hesitation about sharing information with
    Hackensack should the deal not go forward. Englewood
    representatives also speculated that Hackensack’s motivation
    for merging might stem from its competition with Englewood.
    Hackensack’s president similarly recognized Englewood as a
    competitor. The District Court also found that the Hospitals
    monitored each other’s offerings and technology innovations
    and made decisions about their own businesses as a result.
    Englewood’s merger consultant likewise concluded that
    Hackensack was Englewood’s main competitor. First, the
    consultant identified that Englewood and Hackensack draw
    their patients from a similar area in northern New Jersey. The
    District Court logically concluded that if the Hospitals merged,
    a competitor would be lost from that area. When evaluating
    merger offers, the consultant advised Englewood that
    accepting Hackensack’s offer would slow down competition
    between the hospitals, but accepting another northern New
    Jersey health system’s offer would intensify competition with
    Hackensack.
    Finally, insurers that do business with the Hospitals
    recognized that the merger would have anticompetitive effects.
    23
    For example, one insurer testified that under its modeling and
    projections, were HUMC to leave its coverage network, fifty
    percent of the patients who would have gone there would
    choose to go to Englewood. Another insurer provided an
    internal analysis that showed that after the merger Englewood,
    HUMC, and Pascack Valley would account for sixty-two
    percent of the insurer’s inpatient spending.
    The District Court interpreted all of these statements—
    from the Hospitals’ representatives, Englewood’s consultant,
    and insurers—as evidence that the Hospitals are competitors
    and, should they merge, a competitor would be eliminated. The
    District Court’s reasoning is sound.
    Dafny also presented the District Court with various
    calculations that bolstered the FTC’s prima facie case. First,
    she calculated diversion ratios of the hospitals in the market. A
    diversion ratio assesses the share of patients that would go to a
    certain hospital if their chosen hospital were not available to
    them. The higher the diversion ratio, the closer the competition
    between the named hospitals. Dafny calculated that nearly
    forty percent of Englewood’s patients would choose a
    Hackensack hospital if Englewood were not available. Its next
    closest Bergen County competitor was at twelve percent.
    Dafny concluded that Hackensack places a strong competitive
    constraint on Englewood, which affects Englewood’s pricing
    and quality. The District Court credited this analysis,
    unpersuaded again by the Hospitals’ rigid argument that
    diversion ratios should focus only on insurer preferences.
    Dafny also calculated the price impact of the merger and
    estimated the Hospitals would be able to increase prices by $31
    million after the merger. Dafny used both her patient-based
    willingness-to-pay model and information from a peer-
    reviewed paper to generate her calculations. The Hospitals
    argue that Dafny’s analysis is unreliable because it rests on
    24
    estimates of patient preferences rather than insurer preferences,
    and New Jersey claims data shows that there is no statistically
    significant correlation between the two. The Hospitals made
    the same argument before the District Court, which found the
    FTC’s explanation more persuasive.
    We see no clear error in the District Court’s reasoning.
    The study Dafny used evaluated twenty-eight hospital mergers
    and examined whether there was a statistically significant
    correlation between a change in patient preferences and a
    change in price. Dafny testified that substantial literature
    supports the general proposition that hospitals that perform
    more strongly in the willingness-to-pay analysis command
    higher negotiated prices in the marketplace. In addition to this
    general principle, she explained that she was selective when
    using the study to make her calculations. She included only the
    mergers without variable cost savings because she had
    accounted for any cost savings from this merger as part of her
    efficiencies analysis. If she had not eliminated those cost-
    saving mergers from her calculations, she would be “double
    counting” the savings. Hackensack, 
    2021 WL 4145062
    , at *22.
    Through this analysis, she found a statistically significant
    correlation between changes in patient preferences and
    changes in price.
    The Hospitals’ sole argument against Dafny’s
    methodology is that she did not use the best data available,
    which they say is New Jersey claims data. Their expert used
    that data and found no statistically significant correlation
    between patient preferences and hospital prices in New Jersey.
    Dafny addressed this criticism in the District Court, explaining
    that the Hospitals’ expert’s methodology using this data was
    “inferior” because it looked at only one point in time, omitted
    important variables, and included irrelevant factors that could
    lead to misleading estimates. Hr’g Tr. vol. 3, 578:22, ECF No.
    25
    356. Nonetheless, Dafny did an analysis using this data to
    refute the Hospitals’ expert’s results, but she adjusted for the
    supposed flaws in the other expert’s methodology.6 Her results
    using this data showed a statistically significant relationship
    between patient preferences and price, and ultimately resulted
    in price increase estimates that were higher than those using
    her original methodology. Thus, the FTC introduced evidence
    showing that the merger would lead to anticompetitive price
    increases using Dafny’s preferred data or the Hospitals’
    preferred data.
    Outside of the expert analyses, the District Court relied
    on previous Hackensack merger contracts to conclude the
    merger would lead to anticompetitive price increases.
    Contracts between Hackensack and facilities it had merged
    with in the past show Hackensack’s ability to raise rates. The
    Hospitals challenge the District Court’s reliance on the
    contracts, arguing they only reflect past, pre-merger power and
    have no bearing on this merger. But the Hospitals miss the
    6
    According to Dafny, the methodology used by the
    Hospitals’ expert suffered from several flaws: he used
    willingness-to-pay and price measurements that were out of
    sync with the standards in the economic literature; although he
    controlled for observable factors present in rate negotiations
    between hospitals and insurers, such as insurer identity and
    system costs, he did not control for unobservable factors, such
    as the bargaining skills of the negotiators, that may
    independently affect prices; and he used all of northern New
    Jersey—an area consisting of fourteen counties—instead of the
    four-county area as his baseline, which further exacerbated
    problems associated with not controlling for unobservable
    factors because competitive conditions are more likely to differ
    as the geographic area expands.
    26
    District Court’s point: past behavior is often indicative of
    future behavior. Furthermore, according to the Hospitals’
    expert and Hackensack’s president, Hackensack has always
    been able to negotiate higher rate increases than Englewood.
    As the District Court put it, “the reasonable inference” is that
    Hackensack will continue to be able to do so after the merger,
    having added another Bergen County hospital to its portfolio.
    Hackensack, 
    2021 WL 4145062
    , at *24. Thus, regardless of
    whether the impact is $31 million, as Dafny estimated, or some
    lower figure, the District Court did not err in finding that, as a
    matter of common sense, there would be a significant price
    impact.
    ***
    The District Court did not clearly err in making these
    factual findings. This direct evidence, in addition to the HHI
    numbers, establishes a strong prima facie case of
    anticompetitive effects.
    Once the FTC establishes a prima facie case that a
    merger may substantially lessen competition, the burden shifts
    to the Hospitals to rebut the FTC’s case. “[T]he Hospitals must
    show either that the combination would not have
    anticompetitive effects or that the anticompetitive effects of the
    merger will be offset by extraordinary efficiencies resulting
    from the merger.” Hershey, 838 F.3d at 347. The “linchpin of
    any efficiencies defense” is the language of the Clayton Act,
    which “speaks in terms of ‘competition.’” Id. at 349 (quoting
    St. Alphonsus, 778 F.3d at 790). The defense “requires proof
    that a merger is not, despite the existence of a prima facie case,
    anticompetitive” because “the prima facie case portrays
    inaccurately the merger’s probable effects on competition.” Id.
    (quoting St. Alphonsus, 778 F.3d at 790). This defense
    27
    recognizes that efficiencies created by a merger can “enhance
    the merged firm’s ability and incentive to compete, which may
    result in lower prices, improved quality, enhanced service, or
    new products.” Merger Guidelines, § 10, at 29.
    To combat the likely anticompetitive harms the FTC
    established, the Hospitals offer a panoply of procompetitive
    benefits that may be reaped from the merger: upgrades and
    increased capacity limits at Englewood, the expansion of
    complex tertiary and quaternary care at HUMC, cost-savings
    that will result from service optimization between the
    Hospitals, and quality improvements at both Hospitals. They
    argue that these benefits, which the District Court recognized,
    show that the FTC did not establish a likelihood that the merger
    would substantially lessen competition. They claim they are
    not making an efficiencies defense, thus the stringent standard
    developed in other circuits need not apply. They say, instead,
    that procompetitive effects must simply be weighed in the
    balance together with anticompetitive effects when
    considering whether they have rebutted the FTC’s prima facie
    case.
    The existence of procompetitive benefits does not mean
    the absence of anticompetitive harms. The Hospitals’ argument
    that there “would not likely be a substantial lessening of
    competition when both pro- and anti-competitive effects were
    duly considered,” Reply Br. 26, is merely a different way of
    saying there would not likely be a substantial lessening of
    competition because the procompetitive effects offset the
    anticompetitive effects of the merger. Thus, the Hospitals’
    procompetitive benefits argument is an efficiencies defense.
    Neither this Court nor the Supreme Court has formally
    adopted the efficiencies defense. See Hershey, 838 F.3d at 347.
    Other Circuits have at least been tentatively willing to
    recognize the defense, though none have held that it was
    28
    successfully invoked. See ProMedica Health Sys., Inc. v. FTC,
    
    749 F.3d 559
    , 571 (6th Cir. 2014); St. Alphonsus, 778 F.3d at
    788–92; Heinz, 
    246 F.3d at 720
    ; FTC v. Univ. Health, Inc., 
    938 F.2d 1206
    , 1222 (11th Cir. 1991). In Hershey, we explained
    that we were skeptical such a defense exists. 838 F.3d at 348.
    Although we have yet to see an efficiency so great as to justify
    a presumptively anticompetitive merger, we do not rule out
    that the efficiencies defense may be viable. But as in Hershey,
    we are not forced to confront that possibility. Id. Although this
    case is much closer than Hershey, the efficiencies defense, as
    adopted by other Circuits, is clearly not met here. Nonetheless,
    we address the defense and each of the Hospitals’ claimed
    procompetitive benefits to clarify any ambiguity in Hershey.
    For the efficiencies defense to be cognizable, the
    efficiencies must (1) “offset the anticompetitive concerns in
    highly concentrated markets”; (2) “be merger-specific” (i.e.,
    the efficiencies cannot be achieved by either party alone); (3)
    “be verifiable, not speculative”; and (4) “not arise from
    anticompetitive reductions in output or service.” Hershey, 838
    F.3d at 348–49 (internal quotation marks and citations
    omitted).
    In Hershey, we expounded on the first element—
    whether efficiencies offset anticompetitive concerns—in the
    context of HHI numbers. Id. at 350.We stated that even if the
    hospitals could show an efficiency was verified, was merger-
    specific, and did not arise from anticompetitive reduction in
    output, the HHI numbers were so great as to “eclipse any others
    we have identified in similar cases.” Id. Therefore, the merger
    was “so likely to be anticompetitive that ‘extraordinarily great
    . . . efficiencies [were] necessary to prevent the merger from
    being anticompetitive.’” Id. (quoting Merger Guidelines, § 10,
    at 31). The District Court seems to have interpreted Hershey to
    mean that “extraordinary” efficiencies must be found in every
    29
    case where a prima facie case is established, regardless of the
    HHI numbers. Hackensack, 
    2021 WL 4145062
    , at *26, *30.
    We now clarify our earlier statements.
    Efficiencies are best understood as a sliding scale. The
    magnitude of the efficiencies needed to overcome a prima facie
    case depends on the strength of the likely adverse competitive
    effects of a merger. At a minimum, the defendant must show
    that “the intended acquisition would result in significant
    economies and that [those] economies would ultimately benefit
    competition and, hence, consumers.” See Univ. Health, 
    938 F.2d at 1223
    . Hershey examined the high end of the spectrum.
    There, the market had an HHI of 5,984—more than twice the
    highly-concentrated-market threshold—and an increase in
    HHI of 2,582—more than twelve times the 200-point increase
    that triggers a presumption of anticompetitive harm when the
    resulting market is highly concentrated. Hershey, 838 F.3d at
    347. Recognizing that the HHI numbers were extraordinary,
    we declared that any efficiencies would have to be equally
    extraordinary to overcome the likely anticompetitive effects.
    Id. at 350. But not every invocation of the efficiencies defense
    will require that showing. Courts must take their cues from the
    HHI numbers and direct evidence presented by the government
    in each case.
    Here, the District Court analyzed the Hospitals’ claimed
    procompetitive benefits as efficiencies and concluded that they
    were insufficient to overcome the FTC’s prima facie case.
    Although we agree with that conclusion, to the extent the
    District Court required a showing of extraordinary
    procompetitive effects, it would have been incorrect. The
    presumption of anticompetitive effects established by the FTC
    here does not rise to the level seen in Hershey. Nonetheless, we
    review conclusions of law de novo, id. at 335, and our review
    leads us to the same conclusion. Some procompetitive benefits
    30
    may exist, but they are not significant enough to offset the
    likely anticompetitive effects of the merger. Most of the
    Hospitals’ claimed benefits were speculative or non-merger-
    specific. And the few procompetitive effects that the Hospitals
    did establish do not constitute significant economies that will
    ultimately benefit competition and, hence, the patients in
    Bergen County.
    The District Court found that most of the Hospitals’
    commitments to increase Englewood’s capacity and improve
    its clinical offerings were merely speculative. What the
    Hospitals called “hard commitments” were only commitments
    to “explore, assess, and collaborate.” Hackensack, 
    2021 WL 4145062
    , at *26. Furthermore, many of these commitments
    were not Englewood-specific or enforceable. On the other
    hand, the Court noted that Hackensack’s significant capital
    contribution could likely amount to a procompetitive benefit to
    Bergen County in a few ways, such as upgrading some physical
    facilities and providing Englewood with robotic technology,
    both of which would offer Bergen County patients more or
    upgraded services. But these modest upgrades alone are not
    significant enough to overcome the strong evidence of
    anticompetitive harms.
    The District Court held that cost savings due to post-
    merger service optimization were also too speculative to be
    meaningful. The Court found that the $38 million figure the
    Hospitals relied on failed to account for the $439 million
    capital contribution by Hackensack. Additionally, the Court
    found more persuasive the evidence, or rather lack of evidence,
    presented about cost savings in past Hackensack mergers.
    Hackensack has previously acquired other hospitals in New
    Jersey, yet the Hospitals provided no evidence that consumers
    benefitted from cost savings due to service optimization
    between the merging parties. Whatever savings the merging
    31
    entities may have cashed in on, there was no evidence the
    savings ever flowed through to patients.
    The District Court held that the benefit of expanded
    complex tertiary and quaternary care was both non-merger-
    specific and speculative. To embark on this expansion,
    Hackensack claims it must relieve capacity restraints at
    HUMC. But the District Court found that the only thing
    preventing HUMC from transferring patients to Englewood
    was financial or competitive motive. As the District Court
    stated, this motive may be legitimate, but it nonetheless
    undercuts the Hospitals’ argument that the expansion can only
    occur if the merger moves forward. The District Court also
    noted that HUMC is currently expanding capacity and
    quaternary services through an ongoing upgrade project.
    Finally, the District Court rightly pointed out that Hackensack
    has three hospitals near HUMC that are not at capacity and
    likely could help alleviate HUMC’s capacity restraints. The
    Hospitals have offered nothing to combat these findings.
    Furthermore, the District Court found that any
    procompetitive benefit gained by easing HUMC’s capacity
    restraints is speculative. First, the Hospitals provided no
    evidence that they have a plan to transfer patients from HUMC
    to Englewood. At best, the Hospitals have a sense of the
    number of patients they would like to transfer. Second, the
    Hospitals failed to account for the fact that many hospital
    referrals come from physicians not employed by HUMC and
    those physicians may not recommend their patients seek
    services at Englewood. Thus, even the Hospitals’ transfer goals
    are speculative. Finally, assuming the capacity restraint
    problems were confirmed, the expansion of quaternary
    services is speculative. State approval is required for any such
    expansion and the process to gain that approval is expensive
    and time-consuming. Thus, the District Court correctly found
    32
    that the expansion of services at HUMC is not a cognizable
    efficiency.
    As for the Hospitals’ claim that the merger will provide
    quality improvements to both Englewood and HUMC, the
    District Court found these too were not merger-specific.
    Although the Court did not doubt that Hackensack’s capital
    commitment would improve facilities and equipment at
    Englewood, it explained that such quality improvements were
    likely to happen regardless of a merger. Englewood is a high-
    quality hospital. It consistently performs well in multiple
    quality assessments and is motivated to maintain this quality of
    care because of its competition with HUMC. Therefore,
    Englewood would likely make similar quality improvements
    even if it did not merge with Hackensack. Furthermore,
    Englewood scores better than HUMC on multiple important
    performance measures, such as hospital safety, patient
    experience, timely and effective care, nursing recognition, and
    healthcare-associated infection rates. If the merger occurs,
    consumers would likely be disadvantaged because Englewood
    would no longer have an incentive to outperform HUMC and
    HUMC would have no reason to strive for improvement in
    those areas.
    The District Court did not directly address the New
    Jersey Attorney General’s finding that the merger is in the
    public interest under the New Jersey Community Health Care
    Assets Protection Act. Under the Act, the New Jersey Attorney
    General and the New Jersey Department of Health evaluate
    whether a nonprofit hospital transaction is in the public
    interest. Relevant to their inquiry, they evaluate whether the
    proposed transaction is “likely to result in the deterioration of
    quality, availability or accessibility of heath care services in the
    affected communities.” N.J.S.A. 26:2H-7.11(b). Here, New
    Jersey concluded that Hackensack made commitments to
    33
    enhance Englewood’s offerings to the community. Although
    that finding is independent of any antitrust analysis federal
    courts may perform, we would be remiss not to consider a
    state’s assessment of the effects of a merger within its borders.
    Therefore, the District Court should have included the interests
    of the community, as assessed by the New Jersey Attorney
    General, in analyzing the likely effects of the merger.
    Nonetheless, when we consider this assessment of the
    community’s interests along with the modest quality
    improvements and upgrades likely to occur because of this
    merger, they are not significant enough to overcome the FTC’s
    strong prima facie case. We thus conclude that the District
    Court did not err in holding that the Hospitals failed to rebut
    the prima facie case that the merger is likely to substantially
    lessen competition. Therefore, no additional evidence is
    necessary for the FTC to carry its ultimate burden of
    persuasion. See Hershey, 838 F.3d at 337.
    For these reasons, we will affirm the District Court’s
    grant of preliminary injunctive relief.
    34