TFWS, Inc. v. Schaefer , 325 F.3d 234 ( 2003 )


Menu:
  •                            PUBLISHED
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE FOURTH CIRCUIT
    TFWS, INCORPORATED, t/a Beltway         
    Fine Wine and Spirits,
    Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.
    WILLIAM DONALD SCHAEFER, in his
    official capacity as Comptroller of
    the Treasury of the State of                    No. 02-1199
    Maryland; CHARLES W. EHART, in
    his official capacity as
    Administrator of the Alcohol and
    Tobacco Tax Unit of the
    Comptroller of the State of
    Maryland,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the District of Maryland, at Baltimore.
    Frederic N. Smalkin, District Judge.
    (CA-99-2008-S)
    Argued: October 30, 2002
    Decided: March 31, 2003
    Before LUTTIG, MICHAEL, and TRAXLER, Circuit Judges.
    Vacated and remanded by published opinion. Judge Michael wrote
    the opinion, in which Judge Luttig and Judge Traxler joined.
    2                      TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER
    COUNSEL
    ARGUED: William James Murphy, MURPHY & SHAFFER, Balti-
    more, Maryland, for Appellant. Steven Marshall Sullivan, Assistant
    Attorney General, Baltimore, Maryland, for Appellees. ON BRIEF:
    John J. Connolly, MURPHY & SHAFFER, Baltimore, Maryland, for
    Appellant. J. Joseph Curran, Jr., Attorney General of Maryland,
    Andrew H. Baida, Solicitor General, Meredyth Smith Andrus, Assis-
    tant Attorney General, Baltimore, Maryland, for Appellees.
    OPINION
    MICHAEL, Circuit Judge:
    This case is on its second trip to this court. TFWS, Inc., a large
    liquor retailer in Maryland, is suing the State Comptroller to obtain
    a declaration that certain Maryland regulations governing the whole-
    sale pricing of liquor and wine violate the Sherman Act. When the
    case was before us the first time, we affirmed the district court’s
    determination that the regulations violate the Sherman Act, but we
    remanded for further consideration of the Comptroller’s Twenty-first
    Amendment defense. On remand the district court granted summary
    judgment to the Comptroller, ultimately concluding that Maryland’s
    interest in promoting temperance, which is protected by the Twenty-
    first Amendment, outweighs the federal interest in promoting compe-
    tition under the Sherman Act. However, one of the questions that was
    to be decided on remand — whether the regulations are effective in
    promoting temperance — involves disputed factual issues that cannot
    be resolved on summary judgment. We therefore vacate the award of
    summary judgment to the Comptroller and remand once again for fur-
    ther proceedings.
    I.
    The Maryland liquor regulations under challenge by TFWS are
    explained in some detail in our first opinion, see TFWS, Inc. v. Schae-
    fer, 
    242 F.3d 198
    , 202-03 (4th Cir. 2001), so we offer only a brief
    summary here. The first regulation, the post-and-hold pricing system,
    TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER                           3
    prescribes how and when liquor wholesalers may change their prices.
    See Md. Ann. Code art. 2B, § 12-103(c) (Lexis 2001). By the fifth of
    each month, wholesalers must post a schedule of prices with the
    Comptroller. Md. Regs. Code tit. 03, § 02.01.05B(2) (2003). These
    prices are locked in for the following month. Id. § .05B(3)(a). The
    Comptroller makes each wholesaler’s monthly posting available to all
    other wholesalers. Id. § .05D. The second regulation is known as the
    volume discount ban or the antidiscrimination rule. It requires a
    wholesaler to offer every retailer the same price for a given product.
    See Md. Ann. Code art. 2B, § 12-102(a) (Lexis 2001); Md. Regs.
    Code tit. 03, § 02.01.05B(3)(c) (2003). Wholesalers cannot cut prices
    to large retailers because discounts "of any nature" are prohibited. See
    Md. Regs. Code tit. 03, § 02.01.05B(3)(c) (2003).
    In our first opinion we affirmed the district court’s determination
    (1) that the post-and-hold regulation is a hybrid restraint that is illegal
    per se under § 1 of the Sherman Act, (2) that the volume discount ban
    is a per se violation of § 1, and (3) that Maryland cannot claim "state
    action" immunity from the Sherman Act because the regulatory
    scheme is not actively supervised by the state. See TFWS, 
    242 F.3d at 208-11
    ; see also 
    id. at 213-15
     (Luttig, J., concurring). We held,
    however, that the district court’s dismissal of TFWS’s complaint on
    Twenty-first Amendment grounds was premature. In the first round
    the district court concluded on its own motion that "despite their anti-
    competitive effect," the regulations "should be upheld under the
    [liquor control] powers reserved to the states under the Twenty-first
    Amendment." TFWS, Inc. v. Schaefer, Civ. No. S99-2008, slip op. at
    16-17 (D. Md. Sept. 1, 1999). We held that it was too early for the
    district court to reach that conclusion because "neither side had a
    chance to make its case on the Twenty-first Amendment issue."
    TFWS, 
    242 F.3d at 211
    . As a result, we vacated the order of dismissal
    and remanded the case with the following instructions:
    On remand Maryland should be given the opportunity to
    assert and substantiate its Twenty-first Amendment defense,
    and TFWS should be permitted to respond. The analysis the
    district court should undertake in analyzing Maryland’s
    interest and then balancing it against the federal interest is
    straightforward. First, the court should examine the
    expressed state interest and the closeness of that interest to
    4                      TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER
    those protected by the Twenty-first Amendment. We
    acknowledge that little analysis is needed on this point.
    Temperance is the avowed goal of the Maryland regulatory
    scheme, and the Twenty-first Amendment definitely allows
    a state to promote temperance. Second, the court should
    examine whether, and to what extent, the regulatory scheme
    serves its stated purpose in promoting temperance. Simply
    put, is the scheme effective? Again, the answer to this ques-
    tion may ultimately rest upon findings and conclusions hav-
    ing a large factual component. Finally, the court should
    balance the state’s interest in temperance (to the extent that
    interest is actually furthered by the regulatory scheme)
    against the federal interest in promoting competition under
    the Sherman Act.
    
    Id. at 213
     (quotation marks and citation omitted).
    On remand the parties conducted discovery, which included the
    exchange of reports from expert witnesses, who were also deposed.
    In due course the parties filed cross-motions for summary judgment.
    The district court granted summary judgment for the Comptroller, (1)
    finding that the Maryland regulations achieved their stated purpose of
    promoting temperance and (2) concluding that Maryland’s interest in
    promoting temperance outweighed the federal interest in preserving
    free competition. TFWS appeals. We conduct a de novo review of the
    grant of summary judgment. Bond v. Blum, 
    317 F.3d 385
    , 394 (4th
    Cir. 2003).
    II.
    TFWS’s appeal boils down to the argument that the district court
    relied on disputed evidence to grant summary judgment to the Comp-
    troller on his Twenty-first Amendment defense. We will look at key
    issues considered on remand to see whether they could be decided on
    summary judgment.
    A.
    The district court’s first job in deciding whether the Comptroller
    had established his Twenty-first Amendment defense was to "exam-
    TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER                         5
    ine the expressed state interest [in establishing the regulatory scheme]
    and the closeness of that interest to those protected by the Twenty-
    first Amendment." TFWS, 
    242 F.3d at 213
     (emphasis added). The
    Maryland legislature authorized the regulations for the express pur-
    pose of "fostering and promoting temperance" and "eliminat[ing] the
    undue stimulation of the sale of alcoholic beverages." Md. Ann. Code
    art. 2B §§ 12-102(a), -103(a) (Lexis 2001). See also id. at § 1-101(a).
    The district court therefore concluded that Maryland established its
    post-and-hold liquor pricing system and its volume discount ban with
    the "avowed goal of promoting temperance," which "is a proper
    objective under the Twenty-first Amendment." TFWS, 183 F. Supp.
    2d at 791. This conclusion cannot be disputed, so we agree.
    B.
    1.
    Our second question for the district court on remand was "whether,
    and to what extent, the regulatory scheme serves its stated purpose in
    promoting temperance." TFWS, 
    242 F.3d at 213
    . This inquiry, we
    said, should focus on a basic question, "[I]s the scheme effective?" 
    Id.
    Whether the regulatory scheme actually serves its stated purpose is
    essentially a question of fact. In the summary judgment proceedings
    on remand, each side presented its case on this question largely
    through experts, who offered two types of evidence, theoretical and
    empirical. The theoretical evidence applies general principles of eco-
    nomics to Maryland’s regulatory scheme. Each side’s theoretical evi-
    dence predicts the consumption results that it claims should follow
    from Maryland’s scheme. The empirical evidence includes actual data
    about alcohol prices and consumption in Maryland and other states or
    localities.
    The Comptroller’s evidence showed the various ways that the regu-
    lations could, according to economic principles, promote temperance.
    The Comptroller’s first expert was Dr. Frank J. Chaloupka, a profes-
    sor of economics at the University of Illinois. Dr. Chaloupka offered
    the opinion, based on his review of published studies, that (in general)
    alcohol consumption falls as prices rise. This, he said, is in line with
    "one of the fundamental laws of economics — that of the downward
    sloping demand curve, which states that as the price of a product
    6                       TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER
    rises, the quantity demanded of that product falls." The Comptroller’s
    second expert was Dr. David T. Levy, a professor of economics at the
    University of Baltimore. Dr. Levy suggested ways in which the Mary-
    land scheme could, as a theoretical matter, reduce price competition
    and lead to higher liquor prices. Dr. Levy talked first about the vol-
    ume discount ban. The discount ban prevents a wholesaler from offer-
    ing its customers (liquor retailers) price discounts. If wholesale price
    discounts were legal, the lower prices would likely be passed on to
    consumers with a resulting increase in demand. Further, because
    wholesalers cannot provide discounts as a reward to retailers who
    increase sales of a given product, the retailers have less incentive to
    offer price promotions or sales on that product. Dr. Levy also
    explained why the post-and-hold regulation should have an anticom-
    petitive effect. This regulation, he said, reduces price competition
    because a wholesaler’s prices are locked in and may not be reduced
    for thirty days after they are posted with the Comptroller. Further-
    more, even when prices are reduced in a new filing, the cuts will be
    less effective because of the regulation. The price posting requirement
    means that a price cutter’s action is immediately known to his com-
    petitors. According to Dr. Levy, when there is no price posting and
    a seller reduces prices, he should gain sales until his competitors grad-
    ually learn of his reductions and match them. Under Maryland’s price
    posting scheme, this period of advantage is limited to a single month,
    making price cuts less worthwhile and thus less likely.
    Dr. Levy also presented some empirical evidence suggesting that
    alcohol prices in Maryland are "generally higher" than in other states.
    His figures were drawn from data gathered by the American Chamber
    of Commerce Research Association (ACCRA). Every quarter
    ACCRA samples prices of consumer goods, including beer, wine, and
    spirits, in cities around the country. Dr. Levy calculated the average
    price of these beverages for each state for the years 1996 through
    1999. After adjusting the averages for cost-of-living differences in the
    various locales, he concluded that Maryland’s 1999 average wine
    price exceeded the average in other states by more than a dollar.
    Maryland prices for spirits, according to Dr. Levy, were about five
    percent lower than the average in other states. He attributed this result
    to higher taxes or (sometimes) to state monopolies in the other juris-
    dictions. Dr. Levy’s report singles out Delaware, a Maryland neighbor
    with higher taxes on liquor, for comparison. He concluded that Dela-
    TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER                        7
    ware’s prices for spirits are about fifteen percent lower than Mary-
    land’s after adjustment for differences in the cost-of-living. He noted
    that wine and beer prices are also lower in Delaware, but declined to
    put a figure on the difference.
    TFWS offered a single expert, Dr. Thomas R. Overstreet, Jr., who
    is an economist. Dr. Overstreet advanced both theoretical evidence
    and empirical data. On the theoretical side, he offered several reasons
    why the Maryland regulations might fail to reduce liquor consump-
    tion despite increased prices. First, consumers might respond to
    higher prices by buying less expensive brands or types of alcoholic
    beverages. Spending the same amount of money, they could consume
    just as much as they did before the price increase. On the other hand,
    they might allocate more money to alcohol purchases. Second,
    increased prices will expand wholesalers’ profit margins, leaving
    them extra money to invest in marketing, which might increase con-
    sumption or at least counteract the effect of higher prices. Third, by
    reducing competition between large and small liquor retailers, the reg-
    ulations may increase the number of small retailers across the state,
    and this could increase consumption.
    Although Dr. Overstreet, like the Comptroller’s experts, did not
    gather any data of his own, he used available data to run a series of
    empirical comparisons. First, he compared Maryland’s per capita con-
    sumption of wine, spirits, and beer with that of the other forty-nine
    states. He found that while Maryland was in the top half of all states
    in the consumption of wine and spirits between 1980 and 1997, its
    consumption of beer has been falling relative to other states. Mary-
    land beer prices are not regulated by the challenged scheme. Dr.
    Overstreet suggested that if the one beverage not subject to the regu-
    lations is also the one beverage with declining consumption, the regu-
    lations may not be effective in reducing consumption. Second, Dr.
    Overstreet compared the changes in Maryland’s per capita consump-
    tion of the three categories of alcoholic beverages with the trends for
    the United States as a whole. He found a very tight correlation
    between Maryland and the country for wine and spirits consumption.
    With respect to these two beverages, Maryland’s consumption pat-
    terns and trends were very similar to the country as a whole. In the
    1970-97 period evaluated by Dr. Overstreet, Maryland beer consump-
    tion was considerably below the national average. Indeed, beer con-
    8                      TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER
    sumption in Maryland fell faster and further than the national average.
    According to Dr. Overstreet, this suggests "that the absence of [post-
    and-hold] regulations do[es] not prevent other factors [such as culture
    or demographics] from tempering consumption." Finally, Dr. Over-
    street examined alcohol consumption patterns in California and
    Nebraska, two states where post-and-hold regulations had been struck
    down by courts. (California’s regulations were invalidated by Califor-
    nia Retail Liquor Dealers Ass’n v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 
    445 U.S. 97
     (1980), and Nebraska’s by Finocchiaro v. Liquor Control Com-
    mission, 
    351 N.W.2d 701
     (Neb. 1984).) Specifically, Dr. Overstreet
    looked at whether consumption rates changed after the regulations
    were invalidated. In California consumption did not change very
    much for the seven years immediately after the regulations ended, but
    then it tailed off sharply. In Nebraska consumption did not change
    significantly in the period after invalidation.
    In addition to Dr. Overstreet’s expert evidence, TFWS offered the
    deposition testimony of David J. Trone, the president of TFWS.
    Trone or members of his family own companies that run liquor stores
    in the Mid-Atlantic region. Trone, based on what he said was first-
    hand information, testified that liquor and wine prices are lower in
    Maryland than in Delaware, New Jersey, Pennsylvania, and Virginia.
    TFWS also attacked the weight of Dr. Levy’s evidence. Dr. Levy’s
    figures, TFWS argued, are based on inappropriate data and do not
    support his conclusions. The ACCRA quarterly price samples upon
    which he depends consist of the price of a single brand and size of
    wine, a single brand and size of liquor, and six-packs of two brands
    of beer, each taken from a single liquor store in each of two to four
    Maryland cities, depending on the year. The sampled stores were not
    randomly selected within the cities, nor is there any showing that
    alcohol prices in these cities are representative of prices across the
    state. The Comptroller responded by noting that ACCRA data are
    widely used and are the most accurate available for tracking alcohol
    prices.
    In addition to questioning the quality of the underlying data used
    by Dr. Levy, TFWS argued that his calculations do not lead to mean-
    ingful results. Because the cities sampled by ACCRA are of widely
    varying populations, taking a straight average of their prices does not
    TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER                         9
    properly reflect the price paid by the average Marylander; Dr. Levy
    should have weighted the prices to reflect population differences,
    TFWS claimed. TFWS further questioned whether the cost-of-living
    adjustment was properly applied or even appropriate. And perhaps
    most important, TFWS suggested a flaw in the logic that leads from
    Dr. Levy’s averages to the conclusion that Maryland’s scheme is
    actually effective. Dr. Levy compares Maryland prices to the rest of
    the country and to Delaware and finds Maryland’s to be generally
    higher. Maryland’s regulatory scheme is just one way in which Mary-
    land is different from other states. Any number of other variables —
    for example, culture, economics, or demographics — could explain
    why Maryland’s prices are generally higher than the average in the
    rest of the country. Dr. Levy’s analysis does not come to grips with
    the effect of other variables on consumption in Maryland and else-
    where.
    In deciding whether Maryland’s scheme is effective, the district
    court discussed only the theoretical evidence offered by the three
    experts. In the end, the court credited Maryland’s experts. TFWS, Inc.
    v. Schaefer, 
    183 F. Supp. 2d 789
    , 793 (D. Md. 2002). The court
    rejected the theories advanced by TFWS’s expert, Dr. Overstreet, say-
    ing that his deposition testimony and report "lack[ed] the persuasive-
    ness of the evidence offered by the [Comptroller], in the form of the
    expert testimony of Drs. Chaloupka and Levy." 
    Id.
     The district court
    rebutted each of Dr. Overstreet’s attacks on the Comptroller’s basic
    argument that higher alcohol prices lead to lower demand. First, the
    district court rejected Dr. Overstreet’s contention that because the reg-
    ulations have the effect of protecting small retailers, the scheme
    increases the number of retail liquor outlets. The court said that the
    state could control the number of retailers through its licensing sys-
    tem. 
    Id.
     Second, the court rejected Dr. Overstreet’s contention that
    higher prices might trigger switches to cheaper brands by repeating
    the Comptroller’s theory that a drinker faced with higher prices
    "might prefer to [stick to his brand but] drink less." 
    Id. at 793-94
    .
    Finally, the court dealt with Dr. Overstreet’s point that Maryland’s
    scheme allows for wide profit margins for wholesalers, who can
    devote some of that money to marketing efforts and thereby maintain
    or increase consumption levels. "While this is a possibility," the court
    said, "it is a remote, speculative, and tolerable one, in light of the
    direct effect the scheme has on keeping prices high." 
    Id. at 794
    . The
    10                      TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER
    court did not address either side’s empirical evidence about alcohol
    prices or consumption trends. In crediting the reports and deposition
    testimony of the Comptroller’s experts, Dr. Chaloupka and Dr. Levy,
    the district court determined that their opinions supported the conclu-
    sion that Maryland’s scheme leads to higher alcohol prices and is
    effective in reducing alcohol use. The district court ultimately found
    that the Comptroller had "adequately substantiated [Maryland’s]
    avowed [temperance objective] of preventing undue stimulation of
    alcohol sales and consumption through regulation of price competi-
    tion." Id.
    2.
    We first consider TFWS’s evidentiary objection, which the district
    court rejected. TFWS argues that Dr. Levy’s empirical evidence on
    state-by-state liquor price comparisons is so unreliable as to be inad-
    missible under Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 
    509 U.S. 579
     (1993). See also Kumho Tire, Inc. v. Carmichael, 
    526 U.S. 137
     (1999) (extending Daubert to technical experts). We give "great
    deference" to a district court’s decision to admit or exclude expert tes-
    timony under Daubert. United States v. Barnette, 
    211 F.3d 803
    , 816
    (4th Cir. 2000); Talkington v. Atria Reclamelucifers Fabrieken BV,
    
    152 F.3d 254
    , 265 (4th Cir. 1998). In applying Daubert, a court eval-
    uates the methodology or reasoning that the proffered scientific or
    technical expert uses to reach his conclusion; the court does not eval-
    uate the conclusion itself. See Freeman v. Case Corp., 
    118 F.3d 1011
    ,
    1016 n.6 (4th Cir. 1997). Dr. Levy’s basic methodology was to use
    ACCRA pricing data for metropolitan areas (not states), calculate
    average prices, and apply cost-of-living adjustments. TFWS does not
    mount a true Daubert challenge, for it does not argue that these meth-
    ods have not been tested, have not withstood peer review and publica-
    tion, have excessive rates of error, have no standards for their
    application, or have not been accepted in their field. See Daubert, 
    509 U.S. at 593-95
    . Rather, TFWS basically argues that Dr. Levy’s calcu-
    lations do not support his conclusion that Maryland has higher alcohol
    beverage prices than most other states. This is a challenge to the
    proper weight to be given to Dr. Levy’s evidence, not to its admissi-
    bility. The district court did not abuse its discretion in ruling that Dr.
    Levy’s evidence was admissible.
    TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER                          11
    3.
    TFWS’s essential argument is that the Comptroller did not present
    undisputed evidence that Maryland’s post-and-hold and volume dis-
    count ban regulations actually result in higher liquor prices and lower
    consumption, making summary judgment for the Comptroller inap-
    propriate. The district court credited the evidence advanced by the
    Comptroller’s experts, rejected the conflicting evidence offered by
    TFWS’s expert, and found that Maryland’s regulatory scheme pro-
    motes temperance. The district court justified its factfinding, which
    was based solely on the summary judgment record, as follows:
    [B]oth parties have submitted cross-motions for summary
    judgment . . . . Neither party has asserted that the factual
    issue now in dispute (whether Maryland’s statutory scheme
    promotes temperance) presents an issue that must be
    decided by a jury, by a bench trial, or otherwise by a viva
    voce proceeding. There is ample evidence accompanying
    both parties’ motions in this case, including the depositions
    and reports of both parties’ experts. Because both parties
    had a full and complete opportunity to cross-examine each
    other’s witnesses at deposition and to challenge their asser-
    tions in arguments supported by evidence, this Court finds
    itself in the position to make a factual determination without
    resort to further development of the evidentiary record.
    TFWS, 
    183 F. Supp. 2d at 791
    . On appeal TFWS argues that if it was
    not entitled to summary judgment, the district court was required to
    conduct an evidentiary hearing as a prerequisite to any factfinding.
    We agree that the district court had no warrant in this case to take the
    summary judgment record and engage in factfinding.
    A party is entitled to summary judgment only if it can "show that
    there is no genuine issue as to any material fact and that [it] is entitled
    to judgment as a matter of law." Fed. R. Civ. P. 56. That standard
    does not change when, as in this case, both parties move for summary
    judgment. "The fact that both parties simultaneously are arguing that
    there is no genuine issue of fact does not establish that a trial is
    unnecessary thereby empowering the court to enter judgment as it
    sees fit." Podberesky v. Kirwan, 
    38 F.3d 147
    , 156 (4th Cir. 1994)
    12                      TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER
    (brackets omitted) (quoting 10A Charles Alan Wright et al., Federal
    Practice and Procedure § 2720 (2nd ed. 1983)). In other words, "[a]
    district court may not resolve conflicts in the evidence on summary
    judgment motions." Id. at 157. Because much of the evidence in this
    case is expert opinion and statistics, we can appreciate why the dis-
    trict court believed that it was more efficient to go ahead and resolve
    the evidentiary conflicts in the summary judgment record. But that
    procedure was inappropriate here because the parties did not consent
    to it or waive their right to a trial if there turned out to be disputed
    issues of material fact. See Satellite Television & Associated Res., Inc.
    v. Cont’l Cable of Va., 
    714 F.2d 351
    , 354 (4th Cir. 1983); see also
    Garcia-Ayala v. Lederle Parenterals, Inc., 
    212 F.3d 638
    , 643-45 (1st
    Cir. 2000).
    The district court arrived at its conclusion that the Maryland regu-
    lations were effective in promoting temperance by weighing conflict-
    ing evidence. To obtain summary judgment, the Comptroller had to
    show by uncontested facts that alcohol consumption in Maryland is
    lower, or growing more slowly, than it would be without the regula-
    tions. To make this case, the Comptroller took Dr. Levy’s empirical
    evidence and combined it with Dr. Chaloupka’s application of general
    economic theory: Dr. Levy maintains that Maryland’s alcohol prices
    are generally higher, and Dr. Chaloupka claims that higher prices lead
    to lower consumption. To get from these propositions to the conclu-
    sion that the Comptroller has carried his burden, the court had to first
    find that Dr. Levy’s figures are reliable. Next, it had to find that the
    higher prices Dr. Levy shows are due at least in part to the regula-
    tions. The court then had to infer that higher prices have led to falling
    consumption.
    TFWS challenges the district court’s findings and conclusions in
    several ways. First, TFWS argues that Dr. Levy’s figures are not suf-
    ficiently representative or comprehensive to prove that alcohol prices
    in Maryland are higher than in the rest of the country. In addition,
    TFWS says that Dr. Levy’s figures are contradicted by David Trone,
    who testified that prices are lower in Maryland than in surrounding
    states. Second, TFWS points to Dr. Overstreet’s theoretical evidence
    suggesting that even if Maryland’s regulations do result in higher
    prices, reduced consumption does not necessarily follow. According
    to him, higher prices do not necessarily bring lower consumption
    TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER                         13
    because consumers might switch to cheaper brands or opt to pay the
    high prices. Moreover, reduced competition results in more retail
    stores. Third, TFWS attacks the final, crucial inference that the regu-
    lations reduce Maryland’s consumption. Even if Dr. Levy is right that
    Maryland’s prices are generally higher than the rest of the country’s,
    that does not show that the regulations are the reason. And Dr. Over-
    street’s empirical evidence suggests that Marylanders actually con-
    sume wine and spirits in about the same quantities as the rest of the
    United States, further calling into question whether the regulations
    affect consumption. Finally, Dr. Overstreet’s evidence shows that the
    elimination of post-and-hold rules in California and Nebraska had lit-
    tle effect on consumption. Contrary to the Comptroller’s argument,
    Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 242 (1993), does not prevent TFWS from using Dr. Overstreet’s
    theoretical evidence to challenge the Comptroller’s factual assertions.
    Brooke Group specifically allows TFWS to use Dr. Overstreet’s
    expert opinion — that high liquor prices do not necessarily reduce
    demand in this regulatory regime — "as a guide to interpreting [the
    Comptroller’s] market facts." 
    Id.
    Here, the Comptroller, in order to obtain summary judgment, had
    to show that there is no genuine issue of material fact about the effec-
    tiveness of the regulations. He failed to make this showing. To find
    that the Comptroller carried his burden, the district court had to
    choose the Comptroller’s version of the evidence over TFWS’s ver-
    sion. It had to find that TFWS’s challenges leave Dr. Levy’s evidence
    of high prices intact and reliable. It had to find that high prices lead
    to reduced consumption in Maryland, notwithstanding Dr. Over-
    street’s contentions to the contrary. It had to find either that Dr. Over-
    street’s figures about relatively high consumption in Maryland are
    wrong or that Maryland’s consumption would be even higher without
    the regulations. In making each of these findings, the district court
    had to decide which party’s evidence on economic theory was more
    persuasive and which party’s data were entitled to greater weight.
    These are not decisions that can be made on summary judgment. We
    see no alternative to a trial on the question of whether, and to what
    extent, Maryland’s regulatory scheme is effective in promoting tem-
    perance.
    14                      TFWS, INC. v. SCHAEFER
    C.
    Because the district court could not decide on summary judgment
    whether and to what extent Maryland’s regulations serve their stated
    purpose in promoting temperance, it could not perform its last task.
    Specifically, it was not in a position to "balance the state’s interest in
    temperance (to the extent that interest is actually furthered by the reg-
    ulatory scheme) against the federal interest in promoting competition
    under the Sherman Act." TFWS, 
    242 F.3d at 213
    . That balancing, of
    course, will determine whether the regulations may stand, even if they
    are anticompetitive.
    We vacate the order granting summary judgment to the Comptrol-
    ler and remand for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    VACATED AND REMANDED