Steves and Sons, Inc. v. Jeld-Wen, Inc. ( 2021 )


Menu:
  •                                     PUBLISHED
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE FOURTH CIRCUIT
    No. 19-1397
    STEVES AND SONS, INC.,
    Plaintiff − Appellee,
    and
    SAMUEL STEVES; EDWARD STEVES; JOHN G. PIERCE,
    Counter Defendants – Appellees,
    v.
    JELD-WEN, INC.,
    Defendant – Appellant,
    and
    UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
    Amicus Supporting Appellee.
    Appeal from the United States District Court for the Eastern District of Virginia, at
    Richmond. Robert E. Payne, Senior District Judge. (3:16-cv-00545-REP)
    Argued: May 29, 2020                                     Decided: February 18, 2021
    Before DIAZ, FLOYD, and RUSHING, Circuit Judges.
    Affirmed in part, vacated in part, and remanded by published opinion. Judge Diaz wrote
    the opinion, in which Judge Floyd and Judge Rushing joined. Judge Rushing wrote a
    concurring opinion.
    ARGUED: Paul D. Clement, KIRKLAND & ELLIS, Washington, D.C., for Appellant.
    Taylor Mayly Owings, UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE, Washington,
    D.C., for Amicus United States of America. Benjamin Joseph Horwich, MUNGER,
    TOLLES & OLSON, LLP, San Francisco, California, for Appellees. ON BRIEF: Erin
    E. Murphy, C. Harker Rhodes IV, Erin E. Cady, KIRKLAND & ELLIS LLP, Washington,
    D.C., for Appellant. Lewis F. Powell III, John S. Martin, Maya M. Eckstein, R. Dennis
    Fairbanks, HUNTON ANDREWS KURTH LLP, Richmond, Virginia; Marvin G. Pipkin,
    PIPKIN LAW LLP, San Antonio, Texas; Kyle W. Mach, Emily C. Curran-Huberty, San
    Francisco, California, Glenn D. Pomerantz, Ted Dane, Kuruvilla J. Olasa, MUNGER,
    TOLLES & OLSON LLP, Los Angeles, California, for Appellees. Makan Delrahim,
    Assistant Attorney General, Andrew C. Finch, Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney
    General, Michael F. Murray, Deputy Assistant Attorney General, Kristen C. Limarzi,
    Kathleen Simpson Kiernan, Antitrust Department, UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF
    JUSTICE, Washington, D.C., for Amicus United States of America.
    2
    DIAZ, Circuit Judge:
    This case arises from JELD-WEN, Inc.’s acquisition of a competitor, CMI, in 2012.
    Four years later, one of JELD-WEN’s customers, Steves and Sons, Inc., filed this suit
    challenging the merger. After a trial, a jury found that the merger violated the Clayton
    Antitrust Act and that Steves was entitled to treble damages. The district court then granted
    Steves’s request to unwind the merger, and plans to hold an auction for the merged assets
    after this appeal.
    The district court held another trial before a different jury on JELD-WEN’s
    countersuit against Steves for trade secret misappropriation. The court allowed the three
    individuals at the center of JELD-WEN’s allegations—Steves’s two owners and one of its
    employees—to intervene in the case. After the jury ruled for Steves on most of JELD-
    WEN’s claims, the court entered judgment for the intervenors, even though JELD-WEN
    had brought no claims against them.
    JELD-WEN now appeals various aspects of the district court’s rulings, the bulk of
    which we affirm. On the one hand, the court properly declined to grant JELD-WEN
    judgment as a matter of law on whether Steves demonstrated antitrust injury. The court
    also acted within its discretion by excluding certain evidence from the antitrust trial and by
    ordering JELD-WEN to unwind the merger, rejecting JELD-WEN’s laches defense in the
    process. The court properly found that equitable relief under the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 26
    , was appropriate because the merger created a significant threat that Steves will go out
    of business in 2021. And JELD-WEN hasn’t shown that the court’s jury instructions in the
    trade-secrets trial were improper.
    3
    On the other hand, we vacate the jury’s award of future lost profits to Steves in the
    antitrust trial (which was meant to be a backup remedy in case divestiture doesn’t pan out)
    because that issue isn’t ripe. The injury on which the future lost profits award was premised
    can’t occur until September 2021, and the Clayton Act requires a plaintiff seeking
    damages—as opposed to equitable relief—to “show actual injury,” Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort
    of Colo., Inc., 
    479 U.S. 104
    , 111 (1986) (contrasting 
    15 U.S.C. § 15
     with 
    15 U.S.C. § 26
    ).
    We also vacate the district court’s entry of judgment for the intervenors in the trade-secrets
    case because JELD-WEN brought no claims against them.
    I.
    This case concerns the American “doorskin” market and events that took place
    between 2012 and 2016. But we must first explore the pre-2012 doorskin market.
    A.
    Most doors used in homes in the United States are “molded doors,” which are made
    by placing a wood frame and a solid or hollow core between two “doorskins” that make up
    the front and back of the finished door. Doorskins are made from fibrous materials (such
    as wood chips or sawdust) that are combined with wax or resin and then molded by a metal
    die into paneled designs and textures.
    Steves and JELD-WEN sell molded doors. JELD-WEN also makes doorskins,
    some of which it uses in its own doors, and some of which it sells to other door
    manufacturers (the “Independents”), including Steves. Since the Independents don’t make
    4
    their own doorskins, they must buy them from doorskin suppliers. As of 2015, there were
    six Independents in this country, of which Steves was the largest.
    From 2001 through 2012, there were three doorskin manufacturers in the United
    States: JELD-WEN, Masonite, and CMI. In 2012, Masonite had 46% market share, JELD-
    WEN had 38%, and CMI had 16%. All three were vertically integrated, meaning that each
    made their own molded doors and also sold doorskins to the Independents.
    To make doors, Steves must either buy its doorskins on the “spot market” (i.e., the
    market for one-off purchases) or enter a long-term supply contract with a manufacturer.
    From 2003–2010, Steves and JELD-WEN had a long-term agreement that covered 90% of
    Steves’s doorskin purchases. This deal fell apart in 2010, after JELD-WEN raised its prices
    in response to regulatory changes. For the next two years or so, Steves bought doorskins
    on the spot market from Masonite and CMI, who offered Steves low prices to try to woo it
    into entering a long-term supply agreement.
    Instead, Steves signed another long-term agreement with JELD-WEN in May 2012
    (the “Supply Agreement”). In this deal, Steves committed to purchasing at least 80% of
    its doorskins from JELD-WEN, with one exception: if another supplier offered a price at
    least 3% below JELD-WEN’s, and JELD-WEN refused to match, Steves could purchase
    any quantity of doorskins from that supplier. Important here, prices under the Supply
    Agreement varied annually based on JELD-WEN’s costs. The agreement also contained
    quality assurances, which required JELD-WEN to reimburse Steves for damages resulting
    from defective doorskins, and provided for alternative dispute resolution procedures before
    either party could sue the other.
    5
    The Supply Agreement expired in December 2019, but would automatically renew
    for successive seven-year terms unless either party terminated it. Steves could terminate it
    for any reason upon two years’ notice, and JELD-WEN could do so upon seven years’
    notice. Steves could also end it immediately if JELD-WEN gave notice of termination.
    JELD-WEN’s then-CEO told Steves that the company viewed this as a “life time [sic]
    deal.” J.A. 1594.
    Immediately after Steves entered into the Supply Agreement, Masonite stopped
    selling Steves any doorskins and cancelled existing orders.
    B.
    Meanwhile, JELD-WEN set its sights on acquiring CMI. CMI produced doorskins
    and “trim board” products at a plant in Towanda, Pennsylvania. CMI’s business was
    profitable until 2007, and trial evidence showed that the Independents benefited from the
    competition between the three American doorskin manufacturers.            But CMI began
    struggling once the housing bubble burst. After pouring their own money into the company
    in 2011 to keep it afloat, CMI’s owners decided to sell the business.
    Many bidders showed interest, including JELD-WEN, Masonite, and Steves.
    Among these, CMI identified four or five “serious prospective buyers” (which didn’t
    include Steves), J.A. 3447; narrowed its consideration to JELD-WEN and Masonite; and
    chose JELD-WEN in early 2012. Steves learned of the merger in April 2012, just before
    it signed the Supply Agreement.
    The CMI merger reduced the number of American doorskin manufacturers from
    three to two. Recognizing that this could present antitrust issues, JELD-WEN didn’t notify
    6
    the Department of Justice’s Antitrust Division of the merger until July 2012, after it entered
    into long-term supply contracts with Steves and two other large Independents. JELD-WEN
    hoped that these contracts, by appearing to protect the Independents from price increases
    or refusals to sell, would allay concerns about the merger’s potential anticompetitive
    effects.
    When it learned of the merger, the Justice Department quickly opened an
    investigation and reached out to Steves, who responded that it didn’t oppose the merger.
    The Department closed its investigation in September 2012, and JELD-WEN and CMI
    consummated the merger in October 2012.           JELD-WEN spent significant time and
    resources integrating the Towanda plant’s doorskin and trim-board manufacturing
    processes over the next few years.
    C.
    Steves had issues with JELD-WEN almost immediately after signing the Supply
    Agreement.    Starting in mid-2012, Steves noticed quality issues with JELD-WEN’s
    doorskins. Internal JELD-WEN documents from this time suggest that other Independents
    were complaining about its doorskins, too.
    JELD-WEN nonetheless increased the prices that it charged Steves in 2013, 2014,
    and 2015. Trial evidence showed that JELD-WEN’s costs declined in each of those years,
    which meant that it should have reduced Steves’s prices (per the Supply Agreement), not
    raised them. According to Steves’s expert, JELD-WEN charged Steves almost eight
    percent more than what the Supply Agreement allowed in these years. Other JELD-WEN
    customers without a supply agreement endured even greater price increases. Additionally,
    7
    JELD-WEN released two new doorskin styles (the “Madison” and “Monroe” styles) in late
    2012 and charged Steves more for them than the contract allowed, asserting that they were
    outside the scope of the agreement. Steves protested these maneuvers, but continued
    buying doorskins from JELD-WEN and ultimately agreed to pay more for the new styles.
    Internal documents from 2013 suggest that JELD-WEN understood that the merger
    gave it added leverage in contract negotiations with the Independents. Specifically, a
    December 2013 email reflects JELD-WEN’s belief that the CMI merger left the
    Independents with “few options” for doorskin suppliers, J.A. 1647, and a memorandum
    drafted by one of JELD-WEN’s investors states that the merger “made us and Masonite
    the only two manufacturers of facings [i.e., doorskins] in North America, which over time
    will improve our pricing power,” J.A. 1644.
    The parties’ relationship deteriorated further after JELD-WEN hired a new CEO,
    Kirk Hachigian, in early 2014. That April, Hachigian told Steves that, in his view, the
    Supply Agreement didn’t adequately compensate JELD-WEN for its capital improvements
    to its doorskin facilities. He suggested that JELD-WEN might exercise its seven-year
    termination option.    Meanwhile, JELD-WEN’s quality issues persisted, and it also
    tightened its policy for reimbursements for defective doorskins. 1 Hachigian insisted that
    1
    JELD-WEN made two specific changes to its reimbursement policy. First, it
    stopped reflexively satisfying Steves’s reimbursement requests, instead scrutinizing them
    closely to ensure that a refund was warranted. And second, it stopped reimbursing Steves
    for the cost of doors that couldn’t be sold because of defective doorskins, instead refunding
    only the cost of the doorskin.
    8
    he wanted to reach a new agreement with Steves, though, so the two sides continued to
    negotiate through 2014 and early 2015.
    In May 2014, Masonite announced that it would stop selling doorskins to the
    Independents. At a public presentation, a Masonite executive explained that this was “the
    right strategic call” and would “make sure that there are some effective barriers to entry
    within the [molded-door] space.” J.A. 1657. He also opined that Masonite and JELD-
    WEN would maintain their doorskin duopoly because of such barriers to entry, and that
    the continued survival of the Independents was “less likely going forward.” 
    Id.
    That August, the Steves co-owners began exchanging emails about how they should
    explore an antitrust claim if JELD-WEN terminated the Supply Agreement. The month
    after that, Hachigian gave notice of termination, effective September 2021. JELD-WEN
    continued to supply Steves with doorskins under the agreement in the meantime, and still
    does so today.
    Steves then reached out to Masonite, who refused to negotiate a long-term contract,
    instead offering to sell on the spot market at much higher prices than it had before 2012.
    Steves rejected that offer. Steves also reached out to foreign suppliers, but they offered
    only a fraction of the designs and sizes that Steves needed and had quality and reliability
    issues. According to Steves, it had no choice but to keep buying doorskins from JELD-
    WEN.
    In January 2015, JELD-WEN again increased prices for the upcoming year. JELD-
    WEN and Steves then had a contentious meeting, which ended with each of them
    threatening to make the other’s lives miserable until their contract expired.
    9
    JELD-WEN internal documents from 2015 and 2016 suggest that it planned to
    increase its doorskin prices, end contracts with customers, and ultimately stop selling to
    the Independents altogether over the next few years. JELD-WEN hoped that this would
    “kill off a few” of the Independents, J.A. 1803, and allow it to “[i]ncrease [its molded] door
    market share,” J.A. 1834. Another email from Hachigian indicated that JELD-WEN would
    “exit all the Steves business” in 2021, when the Supply Agreement would be terminated.
    J.A. 1857.
    D.
    Meanwhile, Steves considered whether it could build its own doorskin-
    manufacturing plant. In March 2015, it hired a former JELD-WEN executive, John Pierce,
    as a consultant.    Pierce gave Steves information about JELD-WEN’s finances and
    manufacturing processes, which JELD-WEN alleges were trade secrets.
    Steves ultimately concluded that building a plant likely wasn’t feasible. But Steves
    didn’t abandon its interest in building one, and it was continuing to explore the possibility
    when the trial in this case began.
    E.
    In March 2015, Steves triggered the dispute resolution procedures built into the
    Supply Agreement. But face-to-face conferences and mediation with JELD-WEN failed
    to produce a settlement. At the second conference, Steves raised antitrust concerns to
    JELD-WEN for the first time. That September, Steves presented JELD-WEN with a draft
    complaint raising contract and antitrust claims. Over the next nine months, the parties
    10
    signed a series of agreements that recited their desire to resolve their dispute without
    litigating.
    In December 2015, Steves asked the Justice Department to reexamine whether the
    CMI merger had been anticompetitive. The Department did so, but closed its investigation
    in April 2016 without acting. After JELD-WEN refused to sign another agreement not to
    litigate, Steves filed this action in June 2016.
    II.
    This litigation has unfolded in many stages, which we summarize below.
    A.
    Steves brought breach-of-contract claims and an antitrust claim under § 7 of the
    Clayton Act. The Act forbids mergers whose effect “may be substantially to lessen
    competition,” 
    15 U.S.C. § 18
    , and authorizes treble damages for private plaintiffs who are
    injured by such mergers, 
    id.
     § 15(a).
    To support its contract claims, Steves alleged that JELD-WEN breached the Supply
    Agreement by overcharging Steves for doorskins of poor quality. And the basis of Steves’s
    antitrust claim was that the merger gave JELD-WEN too much power in the doorskin
    market, which emboldened it to charge higher prices, offer inferior products and customer
    service, and eventually try to “kill off” Steves by refusing to sell it doorskins. Steves sought
    (1) past damages for JELD-WEN’s alleged breaches and (2) future damages on the theory
    that Steves would lose access to doorskins and go out of business after September 2021,
    when the Supply Agreement ended.
    11
    In addition to damages, Steves sought to force JELD-WEN to unwind the merger
    and divest the Towanda plant. Divestiture is the customary form of relief in Clayton Act
    § 7 cases because (among other reasons) it’s “simple, relatively easy to administer, and
    sure.” California v. Am. Stores Co., 
    495 U.S. 271
    , 281 (1990) (cleaned up).
    Courts have often ordered divestiture in suits brought by the government. See, e.g.,
    Saint Alphonsus Med. Ctr.-Nampa Inc. v. St. Luke’s Health Sys., Ltd., 
    778 F.3d 775
    , 792–
    93 (9th Cir. 2015). The Clayton Act also authorizes divestiture in private suits when it’s
    “appropriate in light of equitable principles,” Am. Stores, 
    495 U.S. at 285
    , to protect
    plaintiffs from “threatened loss or damage by a violation of the antitrust laws,” 
    id. at 280
    (quoting 
    15 U.S.C. § 26
    ). But private suits seeking divestiture are rare and, to our
    knowledge, no court had ever ordered divestiture in a private suit before this case.
    JELD-WEN moved to dismiss Steves’s antitrust claim, arguing that Steves had not
    plausibly alleged any antitrust injury and that its claim for injunctive relief was barred by
    laches. The district court denied the motion and JELD-WEN’s subsequent summary
    judgment motion repeating those arguments.
    After learning in discovery that Steves had hired Pierce as a consultant, JELD-WEN
    filed trade-secrets misappropriation counterclaims against Steves.       The district court
    severed these counterclaims for a separate trial before another jury, over JELD-WEN’s
    objection.
    12
    B.
    The district court held a jury trial as to Steves’s damages claims first, with the
    understanding that, if the jury found that the merger was anticompetitive, the court would
    then hold separate proceedings on the equitable claims. 2 To prevail on its antitrust claim,
    Steves had to prove that the merger’s effect “may be substantially to lessen competition,”
    
    15 U.S.C. § 18
    , and that the merger inflicted upon Steves a loss that “reflect[s] the
    anticompetitive effect” of the merger, Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 489 (1977).
    “A burden-shifting analysis applies to consider the merger’s effect on competition.”
    United States v. Anthem, Inc., 
    855 F.3d 345
    , 349 (D.C. Cir. 2017). First, Steves had to
    “establish a presumption of anticompetitive effect by showing that the transaction [led] to
    undue concentration” in the American doorskin market, which is typically done by
    comparing the market’s concentration before and after the merger. See 
    id.
     (cleaned up).
    JELD-WEN could then rebut that presumption either by (1) discrediting Steves’s market-
    concentration evidence (i.e., showing that it doesn’t reflect the true level of concentration)
    or (2) showing that, even if Steves’s market-concentration evidence is credible, it
    inaccurately predicts the merger’s probable effect on competition. See 
    id.
     One way to do
    the latter is via the “weakened-competitor” defense: that is, by showing that the acquired
    2
    Where a case involves legal and equitable claims that share common factual issues,
    the Seventh Amendment requires a jury trial on the legal claims first, with the jury’s factual
    findings binding the court as to the equitable claims. See Dairy Queen, Inc. v. Wood, 
    369 U.S. 469
    , 479 (1962).
    13
    company (here, CMI) would have been too weak to affect competition and that there were
    no competitively preferable alternatives to a merger with the acquiring company (here,
    JELD-WEN). See FTC v. Univ. Health, Inc., 
    938 F.2d 1206
    , 1221 (11th Cir. 1991).
    The jury heard testimony from several lay witnesses, including executives for both
    parties, CMI’s former CEO, Masonite’s CEO, and executives from a private equity firm
    invested in JELD-WEN. The jury also heard from four expert witnesses, including
    Steves’s expert economist, who opined that the high concentration in the doorskin market
    made the merger presumptively anticompetitive.
    The expert based this opinion not only on his belief that that JELD-WEN’s enhanced
    market power enabled it to raise prices after 2012, but also on the merger’s placement on
    the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, a common measure of market concentration that is
    calculated by summing the squares of each firm’s share of the relevant market, Anthem,
    855 F.3d at 349. According to guidelines issued by the Justice Department and the Federal
    Trade Commission, a market with an Index above 2,500 is highly concentrated, and a
    merger that increases such a market’s Index by more than 200 points is presumptively
    anticompetitive. Id.; see Dept. of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm’n, Horizontal Merger
    Guidelines § 5.3 (Aug. 19, 2010) (the “Guidelines”). While courts aren’t bound by the
    Guidelines, they’re “a helpful tool, in view of the many years of thoughtful analysis they
    represent, for analyzing . . . mergers.” Anthem, 855 F.3d at 349.
    Here, the doorskin market’s Index was 3,820 before the merger and about 5,000
    after the merger, a roughly 1,200-point increase—six times the threshold for presumed
    illegality. Cf. FTC v. H.J. Heinz Co., 
    246 F.3d 708
    , 716 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (noting that a
    14
    510-point increase “create[d], by a wide margin, a presumption that the merger w[ould]
    lessen competition”).
    Over the course of the trial, the district court made several evidentiary rulings
    against JELD-WEN under Federal Rule of Evidence 403. First, it excluded evidence that
    the Justice Department had investigated the CMI merger in 2012 and late 2015 without
    acting, reasoning that such evidence might mislead the jury. Relatedly, while the court
    admitted Steves’s 2012 statement that it didn’t object to the merger and 2015 statement
    that the prices Steves was paying JELD-WEN had been flat, it excluded evidence that
    Steves made the statements to the Justice Department. Second, the court excluded evidence
    of CMI’s pre-merger financial distress. In the court’s view, this evidence couldn’t support
    a weakened-competitor defense because CMI’s doorskin business had done well before the
    merger and CMI had competitively preferable alternatives to merging with JELD-WEN
    (e.g., a sale to another bidder or a financial restructuring). Letting such weak evidence in
    would distract the jury, the court reasoned. And third, the court admitted evidence that
    Steves possessed information about how to build a doorskin plant, but forbade evidence
    that Steves may have acquired it by allegedly misappropriating JELD-WEN’s trade secrets.
    The jury ruled for Steves on all claims. On the contract claims, the jury found that
    JELD-WEN had breached the Supply Agreement by overcharging Steves for doorskins.
    The jury awarded Steves $9.9 million in damages, in line with Steves’s expert’s
    computations. Additionally, the jury awarded Steves $2.2 million on its claim that JELD-
    WEN had breached the Supply Agreement by changing its reimbursement policies, but the
    15
    court later vacated that award and granted JELD-WEN judgment as a matter of law on that
    claim.
    On the antitrust claim, the jury found that the merger violated § 7 of the Clayton
    Act; that this violation caused Steves to suffer an antitrust injury; and that Steves proved
    both past damages and future lost profits. With respect to past damages, the jury awarded
    Steves about $12.1 million, the same amount that it had awarded for the contract claims. 3
    The jury also awarded Steves $46.4 million in future lost profits on the theory that Steves
    would lose access to doorskins and thereby collapse after the Supply Agreement terminates
    in September 2021. The jury appeared to arrive at the amount of $46.4 million by relying
    on one of Steves’s expert witnesses, who calculated the lost profits by extrapolating
    Steves’s recent annual profits over the eight-year period from September 2021 to
    September 2029. After trebling these awards, the court awarded Steves $36.4 million in
    past damages, plus $139.4 million for future lost profits, on its antitrust claim.
    The court thereafter denied JELD-WEN’s motion for judgment as a matter of law
    on the antitrust claim and rejected its argument that Steves’s future damages were too
    speculative to award.
    3
    The court didn’t reduce the antitrust award by $2.2 million, as it had done with the
    contractual-damages award, because sufficient evidence supported the jury’s finding that
    JELD-WEN wouldn’t have tightened its reimbursement policies absent the merger.
    16
    C.
    Next, the district court considered Steves’s claims for equitable relief. Steves’s
    primary request was that the court compel JELD-WEN to divest the Towanda plant. Steves
    also asked the court to impose several “conduct remedies” to complement divestiture. 4
    To obtain equitable relief, Steves had to demonstrate:
    (1) that it had suffered an irreparable injury; (2) that remedies available at
    law, such as monetary damages, were inadequate to compensate for that
    injury; (3) that, considering the balance of hardships between the plaintiff
    and defendant, a remedy in equity was warranted; and (4) that the public
    interest would not be disserved by a permanent injunction.
    See eBay Inc. v. MercExchange, LLC, 
    547 U.S. 388
    , 391 (2006) (applying these “well-
    established principles” of equitable relief to the Patent Act). The Clayton Act tweaks the
    first factor by authorizing equitable relief where a plaintiff shows “a significant threat” of
    irreparable antitrust injury, even if the injury hasn’t happened yet. Zenith Radio Corp. v.
    Hazeltine Rsch., Inc., 
    395 U.S. 100
    , 130 (1969); cf. Cargill, 
    479 U.S. at 122
     (clarifying that
    the threat must be one of antitrust injury).
    1.
    The court heard three days of testimony and two days of argument on the equitable
    claims. On the issue of irreparable injury, Steves presented evidence of the company’s
    4
    These conduct remedies included: requiring JELD-WEN to transfer the equipment
    and intellectual property used at Towanda to its buyer; enabling the buyer to retain
    Towanda’s current employees; ordering the buyer to offer Steves an eight-year supply
    agreement at prices based on the current Supply Agreement; allowing other Independents
    to terminate their supply agreements with JELD-WEN without penalty; and permitting
    JELD-WEN to purchase as many doorskins as it needed from the divested entity for two
    years before capping the number that JELD-WEN could buy annually thereafter.
    17
    importance to the Steves family, who had owned it for 150 years, and to its over 1,000
    employees. As to the balance of hardships, the parties disputed the extent to which
    divestiture would harm JELD-WEN. And as to the public-interest factor, the parties
    disputed whether Towanda would be viable after divestiture. JELD-WEN also argued that
    Steves’s four-year delay in challenging the merger precluded it from relief under the laches
    defense.
    The Justice Department also filed a statement of interest in the equitable
    proceedings. It asserted that divestiture is generally, but not always, the best remedy for
    an anticompetitive merger. The Department said that it considers five factors when
    evaluating whether a divestiture would be proper:
    (1) whether the divestiture assets are sufficient to create a business that will
    replace lost competition; (2) whether the divestiture buyer has the incentive
    to compete in the relevant market; (3) whether the divestiture buyer has the
    business acumen, experience, and financial ability to compete in the relevant
    market in the future; (4) whether the divestiture itself is likely to cause
    competitive harm; and (5) whether the asset sale is structured to enable the
    buyer to emerge as a viable competitor.
    J.A. 970.
    In the Justice Department’s view, it was difficult to assess the final four factors
    without knowing who would buy Towanda. Further, letting Steves (who had expressed its
    intent to bid for Towanda) purchase the plant might not maximize competition. Doing so,
    the Department maintained, would create another vertically integrated doorskin supplier,
    rather than an independent one, and might disadvantage Steves’s competitors in the
    molded-door market. Relying on the Department’s statement, JELD-WEN contended that
    it would be improper for the court to order divestiture without first identifying a buyer.
    18
    2.
    The district court granted the request for divestiture. It analyzed Steves’s request as
    follows, relying heavily on precedent from our sister circuits because we haven’t had
    occasion to speak on many of these issues.
    First, the court determined that “divestiture should be ordered when it is the most
    effective way of restoring the substantially lessened competition brought about by the
    merger at issue and where its collateral consequences can be mitigated.” Steves & Sons,
    Inc. v. JELD-WEN, Inc., 
    345 F. Supp. 3d 614
    , 650 (E.D. Va. 2018). With those principles
    in mind, the court proceeded to apply the four-factor test set forth in eBay.
    In the district court’s view, Steves satisfied the first two factors because its 150-
    year-old family-owned business would likely collapse after September 2021 without
    equitable relief, and such a loss can’t be measured purely in monetary terms. At factor
    three, the court found that the threat to Steves’s survival outweighed JELD-WEN’s
    hardships, which—while significant—could be mitigated by ordering the divested entity
    to sell JELD-WEN as many doorskins as it needed for two years. And at factor four, the
    court found divestiture to be in the public interest because it would restore competition to
    the doorskin market by creating a third supplier. Alternative equitable remedies wouldn’t
    do, the court reasoned, because:
    Divestiture would once again place three domestic doorskin suppliers in the
    doorskin market. Nothing in the record points to how that could be
    accomplished short of divestiture. Neither party has posited an alternative.
    Although the Court could solve Steves’ supply problem by ordering JELD-
    WEN to supply Steves’ requirements for a long term, that alternate remedy
    would not restore competition in the industry as a whole. And, the record
    19
    proves that the lessened competition has adversely affected the Independents
    other than Steves. So simply securing a long-term supply for Steves would
    not aid those manufacturers.
    Even if the Court could order JELD-WEN to sell, for a period of time, to
    Steves and the other Independents at the prices that prevailed before JELD-
    WEN secured new prices in 2014 and 2015, there still would be only one
    domestic supplier willing to sell to the Independents other than on a spot
    basis. And, there would be no structure in place to foster competition after
    the Court-ordered prices expired.
    Steves & Sons, 345 F. Supp. 3d at 668.
    The district court further rejected JELD-WEN’s argument that it should identify and
    vet a proposed buyer before ordering divestiture. Instead, the court fixed on a two-step
    process: order divestiture first, and then—if affirmed on appeal—arrange an auction with
    the help of a special master. The court reasoned that the Supreme Court had approved of
    such a process in Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 309–10 (1962); that the
    uncertainty of a pending appeal might chill prospective buyers; that Towanda was likely to
    attract many bidders because it had done so in 2012 and had more value now; and that
    JELD-WEN may challenge the details of the divestiture process in a later appeal. 5
    Finally, the district court rejected JELD-WEN’s laches defense. Laches required
    JELD-WEN to show both (1) that Steves unreasonably delayed in bringing suit and (2) that
    its delay prejudiced JELD-WEN. See PBM Prods., LLC v. Mead Johnson & Co., 
    639 F.3d 111
    , 121 (4th Cir. 2011). JELD-WEN showed neither, in the court’s view.
    5
    The court also granted most of the conduct remedies that Steves requested. JELD-
    WEN’s briefs don’t address the propriety of these remedies.
    20
    As to delay, the district court found that Steves’s nearly four-year lag in bringing
    suit after the merger was reasonable because: (1) Steves couldn’t reasonably have been
    aware that it had suffered antitrust injury until August or September 2014, once Hachigian
    demanded an increase in prices and terminated the Supply Agreement; and (2) from then
    until 2016, Steves diligently exhausted alternative remedies—i.e., other supply sources and
    alternative dispute resolution—before suing JELD-WEN.
    The court noted that JELD-WEN’s prior CEO had told Steves in 2012 that they had
    a “life time [sic]” deal, J.A. 1594, and that JELD-WEN didn’t back off from that sentiment
    until 2014. And, said the court, Steves’s pursuit of alternative solutions before suing
    shouldn’t be held against it because public policy supports such efforts. Further, it noted
    that courts often use the Clayton Act’s four-year statute of limitations for damages claims
    as a guideline for analyzing laches defenses to injunctive claims. See, e.g., Oliver v. SD-
    3C LLC, 
    751 F.3d 1081
    , 1085–86 (9th Cir. 2014).             That cut against a finding of
    unreasonable delay, the court explained, as Steves sued less than four years after the merger
    and less than two years after it became aware of its antitrust injury.
    As to prejudice, the court found that JELD-WEN kept investing heavily in Towanda
    even after Steves presented its draft complaint (which included an antitrust claim) in
    September 2015. In the court’s view, this undercut JELD-WEN’s position that Steves’s
    delay had affected JELD-WEN’s behavior. Further, the court observed that JELD-WEN
    had already recovered its investment in Towanda and made a considerable profit, so it
    hadn’t suffered any economic harm from Steves’s (reasonable) delay.
    21
    D.
    There was no rest for these weary litigants, as the district court also held parallel
    proceedings on JELD-WEN’s counterclaims, brought under the federal Defend Trade
    Secrets Act, 
    18 U.S.C. § 1836
    (b), and the Texas Uniform Trade Secrets Act, Tex. Civ.
    Prac. & Rem. Code Ch. 134A.
    While the trade-secrets trial was pending, JELD-WEN sued Pierce and the two
    Steves co-owners (collectively, the “Intervenors”) in Texas state court on essentially the
    same allegations that supported its counterclaims. In response, the Intervenors moved to
    intervene as counter-defendants in this case under Fed. R. Civ. P. 24(b)(1)(B), which
    permits intervention by anyone with “a claim or defense that shares with the main action a
    common question of law or fact.”
    The district court granted their motion in order to “bring all implicated parties
    together in one forum and help avoid inconsistent rulings between [the district court] and
    the court presiding over the Texas case.” Steves & Sons, Inc. v. JELD-WEN, Inc., 
    323 F.R.D. 553
    , 562 (E.D. Va. 2018). The issues in this case “might well have preclusive effect
    in the Texas case,” the court reasoned. J.A. 439. Despite the intervention, JELD-WEN
    didn’t amend its counterclaims to seek relief against the Intervenors, and it agreed to a
    Final Pretrial Order, jury instructions, and a verdict form that omitted any mention of
    triable issues involving the Intervenors.
    The trial followed. JELD-WEN argued that Steves willfully and maliciously
    misappropriated sixty-seven of its trade secrets. Two of the court’s jury instructions are at
    issue in this appeal. The first related to trade secret 23, which “sets out a variety of factors
    22
    that must be monitored together to mitigate a condition [in doorskins] known as pre-cure,” 6
    J.A. 1934, and is the only “combination” trade secret that JELD-WEN asserted. 7 The court
    instructed the jury that
    as to trade secret 23, and only trade secret 23, I would like to point out that a
    trade secret . . . may be comprised of several elements. And a trade secret
    may exist if some, or even all, of its individual elements are public, provided
    that the trade secret as a whole remains confidential . . . .
    But that applies only to trade secret 23. That does not apply to any of these
    other trade secrets.
    J.A. 2991 (emphasis added). In the second instruction at issue, the court advised the jury
    that in order for a misappropriation to be “willful and malicious” under both federal and
    Texas law, the defendant must have an “intent . . . to cause injury or harm” to the plaintiff.
    J.A. 2992–93.
    The jury determined that only eight of JELD-WEN’s alleged trade secrets (including
    trade secret 23) were protectable and misappropriated, and that Steves’s appropriation
    wasn’t willful and malicious (which would have yielded exemplary damages and attorney’s
    fees). Consequently, the jury awarded JELD-WEN $1.2 million in compensatory damages.
    6
    Pre-cure occurs when the surface of a doorskin isn’t consolidated with the rest of
    the skin before the doorskin is cured (i.e., air-dried). This may lead the surface to separate
    from the rest of the doorskin, causing problems in the finished door.
    7
    As its name implies, a “combination” trade secret consists of “a combination of
    characteristics and components, each of which, by itself, is in the public domain, but the
    unified process, design, and operation of which, in unique combination, affords a
    competitive advantage and is a protectable secret.” AirFacts, Inc. v. de Amezaga, 
    909 F.3d 84
    , 96 (4th Cir. 2018) (cleaned up).
    23
    E.
    In March 2019, after all proceedings were over, the district court entered a final
    judgment meant to give Steves its preferred remedies while avoiding inconsistent or double
    recovery. As relevant here, the court:
    1. Awarded Steves $36.4 million in trebled past damages on its antitrust
    claim, in lieu of contract damages for the same injury;
    2. Ordered divestiture of Towanda, but provided that if the divestiture didn’t
    go through for any reason, JELD-WEN should pay Steves $139.4 million
    in treble antitrust damages for future lost profits; and that if those
    damages were set aside on appeal, JELD-WEN should pay Steves $9.9
    million on its contractual claims;
    3. Ordered Steves to pay JELD-WEN $1.2 million on the trade-secrets
    counterclaims, and also entered judgment as a matter of law for the
    Intervenors on those claims.
    4. Ordered JELD-WEN to continue operating Towanda under a special
    master’s supervision pending appeal of the divestiture order.
    This appeal followed. The Justice Department filed an amicus brief, arguing that
    (1) laches doesn’t categorically bar divestiture in a private suit filed after a merger is
    consummated, particularly where (as here) the plaintiff cooperated with the Department’s
    review before suing; and (2) there’s no evidentiary significance to the Department’s choice
    not to challenge the underlying merger, as there are many reasons why the Department
    might make that choice.
    III.
    JELD-WEN raises eight issues on appeal: (1) whether Steves suffered antitrust
    injury; (2) whether it was required to show “antitrust impact”; (3) whether the district court
    24
    erred in excluding evidence under Rule 403; (4) whether divestiture was the proper remedy;
    (5) whether Steves’s claim for future lost profits was ripe; (6) whether certain jury
    instructions in the trade-secrets trial were proper; (7) whether the court’s entry of judgment
    for the Intervenors was appropriate; and (8) whether we should reassign this case on
    remand. We address each of these in turn.
    A.
    First, JELD-WEN argues that the district court erred in denying it judgment as a
    matter of law on Steves’s antitrust claim for past damages because Steves didn’t prove an
    antitrust injury, a necessary element of standing in the antitrust context. According to
    JELD-WEN, Steves’s injury was a purely contractual one: It paid more and got less than
    the Supply Agreement called for.
    Whether antitrust injury occurred is a question for the jury to decide, Int’l Wood
    Processors v. Power Dry, Inc., 
    792 F.2d 416
    , 431 (4th Cir. 1986), and we must uphold the
    jury’s finding unless no reasonable jury could have reached that conclusion, see Int’l
    Ground Transp. v. Mayor of Ocean City, 
    475 F.3d 214
    , 218 (4th Cir. 2007). 8
    8
    If we were to find that Steves has yet to suffer an antitrust injury, we would vacate
    the jury’s past-damages award, but not the district court’s divestiture order. This is because
    the divestiture order is premised on a threatened injury: Steves’s potential loss of access to
    doorskins in September 2021, which would drive it out of business. Such a loss would
    undoubtedly be an antitrust injury, as “competitors suffer antitrust injury when they are
    forced from the market by exclusionary conduct” like a refusal to sell. See Viamedia, Inc.
    v. Comcast Co., 
    951 F.3d 429
    , 482 (7th Cir. 2020).
    25
    1.
    To bring a private antitrust suit, a plaintiff must have antitrust standing. Novell, Inc.
    v. Microsoft Corp., 
    505 F.3d 302
    , 310 (4th Cir. 2007). One component of antitrust standing
    is “antitrust injury,” 
    id. at 311
    , which requires that the plaintiff’s loss “reflect the
    anticompetitive effect” of the defendant’s conduct, Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at 489
    . Antitrust
    injury encompasses two concepts: (1) the “causal connection” between the plaintiff’s injury
    and an antitrust violation, and (2) whether the plaintiff’s injury “was of a type that Congress
    sought to redress in providing a private remedy for violations of the antitrust laws.” Novell,
    
    505 F.3d at 311
    .
    The Supreme Court’s decision in Brunswick illustrates the concept of antitrust
    injury. There, three bowling centers claimed that a bowling-equipment manufacturer had
    violated § 7 of the Clayton Act by buying and operating over 200 bowling centers around
    the country that otherwise would have defaulted, including ones in the same markets as the
    plaintiffs, making the defendant the nation’s largest operator of bowling centers by far. Id.
    at 480–81. The plaintiffs sought damages, arguing that they would have realized more
    profit had the manufacturer not acquired the defaulting centers. Id. at 481.
    The Court held that the plaintiffs hadn’t proved an antitrust injury for two reasons.
    See id. at 488–89. First and foremost, they were complaining that the acquisitions
    “preserved competition, thereby depriving [the plaintiffs] of the benefits of increased
    [market] concentration.” Id. at 488. And second, the plaintiffs would’ve suffered “the
    identical loss[,] but no compensable injury[,]” if the acquired centers had stayed in business
    26
    without being bought by the defendant. Id. at 487. Thus, the plaintiffs’ injury didn’t
    “reflect” any “anticompetitive effect” of the challenged acquisitions. Id. at 489.
    Cases that involve both contractual and antitrust claims present a unique challenge.
    While a single act can both breach a contract and cause antitrust injury, we must ensure
    that Steves’s antitrust claim isn’t “simply a contract claim masquerading as a candidate for
    treble damages.” SAS of P.R., Inc. v. P.R. Tel. Co., 
    48 F.3d 39
    , 44 (1st Cir. 1995). We do
    this primarily by considering whether Steves would have suffered “an identical loss” if
    JELD-WEN had breached the Supply Agreement absent the merger. See Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at 487
    ; see also Valley Prods. Co. v. Landmark, 
    128 F.3d 398
    , 404 (6th Cir. 1997)
    (finding no antitrust injury because “the alleged antitrust violation was simply not a
    necessary predicate to the plaintiff’s injury”); SAS, 
    48 F.3d at 45
     (finding no antitrust injury
    because the plaintiff “would have been no less damaged” if the defendant had breached the
    contract without committing an antitrust violation). We also consider whether competition
    remained “a factor in determining” how JELD-WEN treated Steves, even after they entered
    into their contract. See Orion Pictures Distrib. Corp. v. Syufy Enters., 
    829 F.2d 946
    , 949
    (9th Cir. 1987).
    2.
    We agree with the district court that a reasonable jury could have found that Steves
    suffered antitrust injury.
    27
    For starters, the CMI merger hindered Steves’s access to other doorskin suppliers,
    which the Supply Agreement would have otherwise protected. 9 Had JELD-WEN breached
    the contract without merging with CMI, Steves could obviously have bought doorskins
    from CMI. And, viewing the evidence in Steves’s favor (as we must), it could’ve also
    bought from Masonite.
    Specifically, a reasonable jury could have found that, if not for the merger, Masonite
    would’ve taken up Steves’s invitation to negotiate a contract in 2014, when Steves wanted
    to end its agreement with JELD-WEN. Indeed, Masonite had actively sought such a
    contract before the merger and stopped selling to Steves in 2012 only because of Steves’s
    long-term agreement with JELD-WEN. It was only after the merger, once the two doorskin
    suppliers shared an incentive to kill off the Independents, that Masonite stopped selling to
    the Independents altogether for the express purpose of killing them off and forming a
    duopoly with JELD-WEN.
    The ability to buy from either CMI or Masonite would have mitigated Steves’s
    damages from JELD-WEN’s breaches. But the merger foreclosed that option. So, the loss
    that Steves suffered is greater than—not “identical” to, see Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at
    487—
    what it would have suffered from breaches of the Supply Agreement absent the merger.
    9
    The Supply Agreement was designed to protect that ability by allowing Steves to
    do three things: purchase up to 20% of its doorskins from other suppliers for any reason;
    buy any amount from other suppliers if they beat JELD-WEN’s pricing by at least 3%; and
    terminate the contract immediately once JELD-WEN gave notice of termination.
    28
    The merger also weakened the competitive pressures on JELD-WEN to provide
    good customer service beyond its contractual duties. For example, the contract didn’t
    require JELD-WEN to supply high-quality products, maintain a liberal reimbursement
    policy, or come within 3% of other suppliers’ prices. Competition incentivized JELD-
    WEN to do those things, and the merger reduced that incentive. Indeed, after the merger,
    JELD-WEN’s product quality declined, it became stingier with reimbursements, and it
    raised its prices without fear of being undercut by another supplier. Thus, competition
    remained “a factor in determining” how JELD-WEN treated Steves, such that JELD-
    WEN’s worsened products and service do “reflect the anticompetitive effect” of the
    merger. See Orion, 
    829 F.2d at 949
     (cleaned up).
    We also note that JELD-WEN intended to harm Steves in a way that “the antitrust
    laws were intended to prevent.” Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at 489
    . Specifically, JELD-WEN
    sought to leverage its enhanced market power to hurt its customers, including Steves. And
    that intent is relevant to our antitrust-injury analysis. Novell, 
    505 F.3d at 316
    . JELD-
    WEN’s contractual breach should not shield it from liability for the very injury that it meant
    to inflict.
    JELD-WEN protests that the district court didn’t rely on these rationales in
    affirming the jury’s finding of antitrust injury. But that doesn’t matter. “[W]e may affirm
    on any ground revealed in the record,” Strawser v. Atkins, 
    290 F.3d 720
    , 728 n.4 (4th Cir.
    2002), and Steves presented its evidence for these theories to the jury, showing that the
    merger blocked its access to other suppliers and caused a decline in JELD-WEN’s product
    quality and customer service.
    29
    Further, Steves directed us to this basis for affirming in its brief, allowing JELD-
    WEN to respond in its reply brief and at oral argument. In doing so, JELD-WEN also
    complains that the theories of antitrust injury that we now rely on to affirm the jury’s
    verdict don’t align with how the antitrust damages award was calculated. Specifically, the
    antitrust damages are calculated in the same way as the contract damages, but under
    Steves’s theories of antitrust injury, the two should have been calculated differently.
    JELD-WEN believes that this mismatch indicates that Steves didn’t suffer an antitrust
    injury.
    Not so. At most, the alleged mismatch means that Steves’s damages award was too
    large. But JELD-WEN doesn’t appeal the jury’s calculation of past damages. Instead, it
    argues that Steves didn’t demonstrate antitrust injury, an issue that “must be distinguished
    from calculation of damages,” Newton v. Merrill Lynch, Pierce, Fenner & Smith, Inc., 
    259 F.3d 154
    , 188 (3d Cir. 2001), as amended (Oct. 16, 2001). We decline to consider sua
    sponte whether Steves’s damages award should be amended to correlate with its antitrust
    injuries. See United States v. Sineneng-Smith, 
    140 S. Ct. 1575
    , 1579 (2020) (explaining
    that courts should “decide only questions presented by the parties”).
    B.
    JELD-WEN also contends that, in addition to antitrust injury, Steves had to prove
    “antitrust impact.” Appellant’s Br. at 28. To do so, according to JELD-WEN, Steves had
    to construct a hypothetical market in which the merger never happened and show how it
    would have been better off therein. And Steves failed to do that, JELD-WEN insists,
    because it didn’t try to quantify the price of doorskins in this hypothetical market. Rather,
    30
    Steves showed only that JELD-WEN’s profit margins would be smaller, i.e., that its prices
    would be closer to its costs (whatever those costs might be).
    This argument fails on several levels. First and foremost, “antitrust impact” is
    merely a synonym for “injury” that courts use in the class-action context. Comcast Corp.
    v. Behrend, 
    569 U.S. 27
    , 30 (2013) (stating that “the existence of individual injury resulting
    from the alleged antitrust violation” is “referred to as ‘antitrust impact’”); accord In re
    Hydrogen Peroxide Antitrust Litig., 
    552 F.3d 305
    , 311 (3d Cir. 2008), as amended (Jan.
    16, 2009). It’s not a requirement distinct from antitrust injury, as JELD-WEN suggests.
    See Novell, 
    505 F.3d at 310
     (listing the factors that determine whether a plaintiff has
    antitrust standing, which include antitrust injury but not “antitrust impact”).
    Further, JELD-WEN doesn’t appear to have asked for a jury instruction or a
    question on the verdict form regarding antitrust impact. And it doesn’t challenge any of
    the jury instructions in the antitrust trial on appeal. So, it waived this issue.
    The real thrust of JELD-WEN’s argument is that, without the merger, the market
    price for doorskins would have been higher than what Steves actually paid—leaving Steves
    worse off—because the merger cut JELD-WEN’s costs. Read liberally, this argument
    speaks to whether the merger caused Steves’s injuries, which is a component of antitrust
    injury. But Steves’s theories of antitrust injury aren’t based on the market price of
    doorskins, but rather on its contractual damages being exacerbated and on JELD-WEN’s
    inferior customer service. So, it wasn’t required to prove what that price would be had the
    merger never happened.        That distinguishes this case from Concord Boat Corp. v.
    Brunswick Corp., the primary case cited by JELD-WEN, where the plaintiffs’ expert
    31
    sought to quantify their damages via a pricing comparison to a hypothetical market. See
    
    21 F. Supp. 2d 923
    , 926 (E.D. Ark. 1998) (“Dr. Hall testified that in order to quantify
    damages, he had to consider what the market would have looked like without the conduct.”
    (cleaned up)), rev’d, 
    207 F.3d 1039
     (8th Cir. 2000). 10
    Instead, Steves could prove causation by demonstrating that the merger (1) kept it
    from buying from other suppliers, thereby exacerbating its contract damages, and (2)
    disincentivized JELD-WEN from offering quality products and customer service. A
    reasonable jury could find that Steves succeeded in its proof.
    Of course, the hypothetical-market inquiry is relevant to whether the merger was
    anticompetitive. JELD-WEN could have rebutted Steves’s prima facie case by convincing
    the jury that the merger didn’t harm pricing competition. But the jury found that the merger
    was anticompetitive, and JELD-WEN doesn’t dispute the reasonableness of that finding.
    C.
    JELD-WEN also challenges three of the district court’s decisions to exclude
    evidence from the antitrust trial under Rule 403. JELD-WEN insists that these errors merit
    vacatur of the jury’s verdicts on the antitrust claims.
    Exclusion under Rule 403 is only proper when the probative value of evidence “is
    substantially outweighed by a danger of . . . unfair prejudice, confusing the issues,
    10
    Indeed, the opinions in Concord Boat Corp. don’t use the term “antitrust impact”
    or suggest that it’s a standing requirement, as JELD-WEN asserts. Rather, they discuss
    whether the defendant’s conduct was anticompetitive and whether the plaintiffs’ expert’s
    testimony about his pricing comparison was properly admitted at trial. See Concord Boat
    Corp., 
    207 F.3d at
    1055–57; Concord Boat Corp., 
    21 F. Supp. 2d at
    925–28, 934.
    32
    misleading the jury, undue delay, wasting time, or needlessly presenting cumulative
    evidence.” Fed. R. Evid. 403. Nonetheless, district courts have “broad discretion” in
    making such determinations, which we may overturn only “under the most extraordinary
    circumstances, where that discretion has been plainly abused.” United States v. Udeozor,
    
    515 F.3d 260
    , 265 (4th Cir. 2008) (cleaned up). We find that no such abuse occurred here.
    1.
    First, JELD-WEN criticizes the exclusion of evidence related to the Justice
    Department’s investigations of the merger. Specifically, the district court forbade evidence
    that the Department had twice investigated the merger without challenging it. The court
    also permitted evidence that Steves had stated (in 2012) that it didn’t object to the merger
    and (in 2015) that the prices that it was paying JELD-WEN had been flat, while barring
    evidence that these statements were made to the Justice Department. The court limited
    JELD-WEN to asking Steves’s witnesses whether Steves had made “official statement[s]”
    to that effect. J.A. 1881.
    We conclude that the district court acted within its discretion. The Department’s
    decision not to pursue the matter isn’t probative as to the merger’s legality because many
    factors may motivate such a decision, including the Department’s limited resources. See
    In re High Fructose Corn Syrup Antitrust Litig., 
    295 F.3d 651
    , 664 (7th Cir. 2002) (Posner,
    J.) (explaining that, for this reason, defendants couldn’t use the Department’s decision not
    to bring an enforcement action “to show that, because the Justice Department has not
    moved against the alleged . . . price-fixing conspiracy, there must not have been one”); In
    re Carbon Black Antitrust Litig., No. 03-CV-10191-D, 
    2005 WL 2323184
    , at *1 (D. Mass.
    33
    Sept. 8, 2005) (“Needless to say, the defendants will not be permitted to introduce evidence
    on the merits that the closing of the [Department’s] investigations is somehow evidence
    that no [price-fixing] conspiracy exists.”).
    And in general, a defendant may not use an enforcement authority’s “decision not
    to take action as a sword because inaction on the part of the government cannot be used to
    prove innocence.” Static Control Components, Inc. v. Lexmark Int’l, Inc., 749 F. Supp. 2d.
    542, 556 (E.D. Ky. 2010). In short, evidence of the Department’s decision could have
    misled the jury into thinking that the Department deemed the merger to be legal “when no
    such determination ha[d] been made.” See United States v. Candelaria-Silva, 
    166 F.3d 19
    ,
    35 (1st Cir. 1999) (affirming the exclusion of evidence of a prosecutor’s dismissal of a
    prior criminal case, which the defendants wanted to introduce to show that their conduct
    was legal).
    Similarly, the jury didn’t need to know to whom Steves’s made its statements.
    Indeed, admitting that evidence might have misled the jury by calling attention to the
    Department’s decision not to challenge the merger.
    2.
    JELD-WEN also protests the exclusion of evidence regarding CMI’s pre-merger
    financial distress, which JELD-WEN claimed was central to its weakened-competitor
    defense. Specifically, JELD-WEN wanted to show that CMI lost money each year from
    2008 to 2011; that its owners loaned it $36 million to keep it afloat; that it owed an
    additional $16.7 million to third-party lenders; and that it lost two of its largest customers
    in 2010, when Masonite bought them. This evidence was meant to demonstrate that, if
    34
    CMI hadn’t merged with JELD-WEN, CMI would’ve been a “price taker” unable to charge
    less than the other two suppliers, meaning that the merger didn’t impede competition.
    Appellant’s Br. at 67.
    The district court excluded the evidence because, in the court’s estimation, it
    couldn’t support the weakened-competitor defense as a matter of law and thus was
    irrelevant. That defense requires a showing that “the acquired firm’s weakness[] . . . cannot
    be resolved by any competitive means” and “would cause that firm’s market share to reduce
    to a level that would undermine the [plaintiff’s] prima facie case.” Univ. Health, 
    938 F.2d at 1221
    . A defendant can show this “only in rare cases,” 
    id.,
     which is why the weakened-
    competitor defense has been described as “the Hail-Mary pass of presumptively doomed
    mergers,” ProMedica Health Sys., Inc. v. FTC, 
    749 F.3d 559
    , 572 (6th Cir. 2014); cf. FTC
    v. Arch Coal, Inc., 
    329 F. Supp. 2d 109
    , 153–57 (D.D.C. 2004) (one of the rare cases in
    which the weakened-competitor defense succeeded).
    The defense has been attempted many times (usually without success) in the context
    of motions for injunctions or appeals of Federal Trade Commission orders, where Rule 403
    doesn’t apply. See, e.g., ProMedica, 749 F.3d at 571–72. Before this case, however, the
    defense had never been asserted in a jury trial, so the district court made its evidentiary
    ruling in uncharted waters.
    We conclude that the district court’s ruling was, at worst, harmless error. JELD-
    WEN’s weakened-competitor defense would have failed, for two reasons. First, CMI had
    options besides merging with JELD-WEN that would have preserved competition in the
    doorskin market. In particular, it could have sold itself to one of the two or three other
    35
    bidders who made serious offers (not including JELD-WEN and Masonite). This would
    have kept a third competitor in the doorskin market. So, CMI’s issues could have been
    “resolved by” means that would’ve preserved competition, Univ. Health, 
    938 F.2d at 1221
    ,
    precluding the defense.
    Second, CMI’s market share wouldn’t have fallen to a level that could have
    undermined Steves’s prima facie case. As explained above, the merger caused a 1,200-
    point increase in the doorskin market’s Herfindahl-Hirschman Index, where an increase of
    over 200 points (in an already highly concentrated market) triggers a presumption of
    illegality. To rebut that overwhelming presumption via the weakened-competitor defense,
    JELD-WEN had to show that CMI’s market share would have dropped from 16% down to
    about 3% absent the merger, such that the Index would have remained within 200 points
    of its current score. 11 See FTC v. ProMedica Health Sys., Inc., No. 3:11-CV-47, 
    2011 WL 1219281
    , at *58 (N.D. Ohio Mar. 29, 2011) (explaining that the defendant had to show “an
    imminent, steep plummet in [the acquired company’s] market share . . . such that market
    concentration falls below levels that trigger the presumption of anticompetitive harm”).
    11
    To arrive at the 3% figure, we assume that Masonite (who had 46% market share
    in 2012) and JELD-WEN (who had 38%) would capture equal amounts of the market share
    that CMI lost. Based on that assumption, if CMI’s share had dropped from 16% to 3%,
    then Masonite and JELD-WEN would have each captured an additional 6.5%, giving them
    52.5% and 44.5%, respectively. 52.52 + 44.52 + 32 = 4,745.50, which is about 250 points
    less than the doorskin market’s current Index. Under that same assumption, if CMI’s share
    had dropped to 2%, the market’s Index would’ve been 4,838 (within about 160 points of
    its current score). So, to prove the weakened-competitor defense, JELD-WEN had to show
    that CMI’s market share would have fallen to between 2% and 3%.
    36
    JELD-WEN’s evidence falls far short of proving that. CMI’s doorskin business
    remained profitable until the merger, and the housing market vastly improved between the
    merger and the time of trial. 12 So, unlike in cases where the weakened-competitor defense
    has succeeded, CMI had “convincing prospects for improvement.” Arch Coal, 
    329 F. Supp. 2d at 157
    . And, while CMI had lost major customers before the merger, there’s no
    indication that its market share was dropping precipitously, let alone that it could have
    fallen to 2%.
    Of course, in assessing the merger’s effect on competition, the jury wasn’t obliged
    to credit the Index. See Anthem, 855 F.3d at 349. There are many ways by which JELD-
    WEN could have tried to rebut the Index’s presumption of illegality—for example, by
    arguing that the merger’s real-world effects were benign. But “[t]he weakness of the
    acquired firm is only relevant if the defendant demonstrates that this weakness undermines
    the predictive value of the [plaintiff’s] market share statistics.” Univ. Health, 
    938 F.2d at 1221
    . Because no reasonable jury could find that the proof of CMI’s weakness did that,
    the evidence was irrelevant.
    JELD-WEN complains that the jury should have been allowed to weigh this
    evidence, and that Steves could have pointed out its flaws to the jury. But the district court
    had a duty—which was especially salient in a long and complex trial like this one—to keep
    12
    The district court, of course, was considering a different economic climate than
    the one we face now in light of COVID-19. Throughout this opinion, we review the district
    court’s analysis based on the facts that were before it, without considering how the housing
    market has changed in the meantime.
    37
    out weak evidence that carried a substantial risk of undue delay, confusing the issues, and
    misleading the jury. By determining that CMI’s financial distress fit that description, the
    court acted within its discretion, as admitting the evidence could have prompted a “trial
    within a trial” about CMI’s prospects in 2012. See Fry v. Rand Constr. Corp., 
    964 F.3d 239
    , 249 (4th Cir. 2020) (finding that a trial court properly excluded evidence under Rule
    403). And, in any event, the court’s ruling was harmless because the evidence was legally
    insufficient to support the weakened-competitor defense. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 61.
    3.
    Finally, JELD-WEN asserts that it should have been permitted to tell the jury (at the
    antitrust trial) about Steves’s alleged trade-secrets misappropriation. According to JELD-
    WEN, the steps Steves took to get these trade secrets showed how serious it was about
    building a doorskin plant, which was allegedly relevant to whether Steves could solve its
    supply issues by 2021 and thus avoid the injury on which its claim for future lost profits is
    based.
    We think that the district court acted properly in letting the jury hear about the
    information Steves obtained, but excluding evidence of how Steves obtained it. This
    allowed the jury to make an informed judgment as to Steves’s ability (or lack thereof) to
    construct its own doorskin plant. Alerting the jury to the trade-secret allegations would
    have risked confusion and unfair prejudice to Steves.
    ***
    In short, none of the Rule 403 rulings that JELD-WEN challenges merit vacatur of
    the antitrust verdict.
    38
    D.
    Next, JELD-WEN attacks the divestiture order on the grounds that the district court
    improperly denied its laches defense and misapplied the factors governing equitable relief.
    We address laches first.
    1.
    Laches is a defense to a divestiture request. See Am. Stores, 
    495 U.S. at 296
    . For
    the defense to succeed, JELD-WEN must prove both (1) that Steves unreasonably delayed
    in bringing suit and (2) that Steves’s unreasonable delay prejudiced JELD-WEN. See PBM
    Prods., 
    639 F.3d at 121
    . The district court found that JELD-WEN satisfied neither element,
    and we review that finding for abuse of discretion. 
    Id. at 120
    .
    As to unreasonable delay, JELD-WEN makes three points. None is persuasive.
    a.
    First, JELD-WEN contends that a nearly four-year delay after a merger’s
    consummation is presumptively unreasonable.          We disagree.     Laches turns on “the
    particular circumstances of the case,” White v. Daniel, 
    909 F.2d 99
    , 102 (4th Cir. 1990),
    militating against a singular focus on a merger’s closing date. And we measure delay not
    from the date of the challenged action, but from when the plaintiff “discovers or with
    reasonable diligence could have discovered the facts giving rise to his cause of action,” 
    id.,
    39
    and was “able to pursue a claim,” Ray Commc’ns, Inc. v. Clear Channel Commc’ns, Inc.,
    
    673 F.3d 294
    , 301 (4th Cir. 2012). 13
    Some courts have relied on laches to dismiss post-consummation challenges to
    mergers. See Midwestern Mach. Co. v. Northwest Airlines, Inc., 
    392 F.3d 265
    , 277 (8th
    Cir. 2004); Fed. Home Loan Bank Bd. v. Elliott, 
    386 F.2d 42
    , 54 (9th Cir. 1967); Antoine
    L. Garabet, M.D., Inc. v. Antomonous Techs. Corp., 
    116 F. Supp. 2d 1159
    , 1171–73 (C.D.
    Cal. 2000). None of the plaintiffs in those cases, however, offered a good excuse for their
    delay. See Midwestern Mach. Co., 
    392 F.3d at 277
     (“Midwestern produced no reasonable
    justification for the eleven-year delay in filing suit.”); Elliott, 386 F.2d at 54 (stating that
    the plaintiffs “were on notice of all material facts” three months before they filed suit, yet
    “they deliberately chose to wait until the merger had been effectuated”); Garabet, 
    116 F. Supp. 2d at
    1172–73 (explaining that the plaintiffs “failed to exercise proper diligence in
    the pursuit of their claim(s)”). So, those cases don’t support a singular focus on the date
    that a merger is consummated.
    Nor is such a focus warranted by the hardships of unwinding a completed merger.
    While those hardships factor into the prejudice stage of the laches analysis, they don’t
    obviate our need to consider whether the plaintiff’s delay was unreasonable. And even if
    a defendant’s laches defense fails, it can still prevent divestiture by showing that the
    13
    If there is a presumptive deadline for Clayton Act injunctive claims, it’s four years
    after the challenged action, tracking that statute’s limitations period for damages claims.
    See, e.g., Oliver, 751 F.3d at 1085–86. This is because, in applying laches, courts of equity
    “usually act or refuse to act in analogy to[] the statute of limitations relating to actions at
    law of like character.” See King v. Richardson, 
    136 F.2d 849
    , 862 (4th Cir. 1943) (cleaned
    up). And here, Steves filed suit less than four years after the merger closed.
    40
    balance of hardships (one of the four equitable factors) tips in its favor. See Ginsburg v.
    InBev NV/SA, 
    623 F.3d 1229
    , 1235–36 (8th Cir. 2010) (dismissing a divestiture claim
    because of the effect of the plaintiff’s delay on the balance of hardships); Taleff v. Sw.
    Airlines Co., 
    828 F. Supp. 2d 1118
    , 1123–24 (N.D. Cal. 2011) (same). Thus, there’s no
    need for the hardships of unwinding a merger to bleed into our review of whether Steves’s
    delay was reasonable.
    b.
    JELD-WEN’s second argument is that Steves had notice of its injury right after the
    merger was announced and thus shouldn’t have waited until fall 2014 to pursue relief.
    Specifically, Steves knew that the merger, by removing a competitor from the market,
    would hinder it from buying doorskins from other suppliers and weaken JELD-WEN’s
    incentive to provide good service. Further, Masonite stopped selling Steves any doorskins
    in 2012, so for those next two years, Steves knew that its only option was to buy from
    JELD-WEN—yet Steves didn’t seek relief.
    Again, we disagree with JELD-WEN. It’s true that Steves knew about the two
    injuries that support its past-damages claim in 2012. But Steves lacked notice of the
    threatened injury on which its divestiture claim is based—its potential loss of access to
    doorskins in 2021—until 2014, when JELD-WEN indicated that it was terminating the
    Supply Agreement and Masonite announced that it would stop selling to the Independents
    entirely. Before then, Steves’s access to doorskins was contractually protected for the
    foreseeable future. The Supply Agreement was set to renew perpetually, and JELD-
    WEN’s CEO had referred to it as a “life time [sic]” deal, J.A. 1594.
    41
    Moreover, Masonite had previously sought a long-term agreement with Steves, so
    Steves had reason to believe that it had a fallback if its relationship with JELD-WEN
    soured. That fallback vanished in 2014, when Masonite announced its strategy to kill off
    the Independents. JELD-WEN’s notice of termination and Masonite’s announcement are
    key “facts giving rise to [Steves’s] cause of action,” which Steves couldn’t have discovered
    before 2014. See White, 
    909 F.2d at 102
    .
    The injuries that Steves suffered prior to 2014 wouldn’t have supported a divestiture
    claim. Absent the threat to its survival that emerged only then, Steves couldn’t have shown
    any of the first three eBay factors—a threatened irreparable injury, inadequacy of legal
    remedies, and that the balance of hardships tipped in its favor—because its earlier injuries
    were compensable by money damages (as evidenced by the award that Steves received in
    this case). Cf. Nat’l Viatical, Inc. v. Universal Settlements Int’l, Inc., 
    716 F.3d 952
    , 957
    (6th Cir. 2013) (“[T]he general rule is that a plaintiff’s harm is not irreparable if it is fully
    compensable by money damages.” (cleaned up)).
    “Logic dictates that ‘unreasonable delay’ does not include any period of time
    before” Steves was “able to pursue a claim.” Ray Commc’ns, 
    673 F.3d at 301
    . And, as the
    Supreme Court has explained, laches doesn’t require a plaintiff to “sue soon, or forever
    hold [their] peace.” Petrella v. Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer, Inc., 
    572 U.S. 663
    , 682 (2014)
    (cleaned up). In other words, a plaintiff need not challenge an illegal act immediately after
    it happens; it may wait until it “can estimate whether” the act threatens it with irreparable
    harm. See 
    id.
     at 682–83. Thus, it was reasonable for Steves to wait to pursue relief until
    42
    2014, when it learned that the merger threatened its access to doorskins (and thus its
    survival) after September 2021.
    c.
    JELD-WEN’s last argument about delay is that Steves lacks a good excuse for not
    seeking divestiture between 2014 and 2016. But evidence supports the district court’s
    finding that Steves spent that time diligently exhausting its alternative remedies.
    Specifically, Steves reached out to Masonite and foreign suppliers, explored building its
    own doorskin plant, engaged in settlement talks and mediation with JELD-WEN, and asked
    for (and cooperated with) a Justice Department investigation.           Moreover, between
    September 2015 and June 2016, JELD-WEN signed a series of agreements with Steves
    reciting their mutual desire to settle their dispute. “It would disserve the strong policy in
    favor of nonjudicial dispute resolution if [a] defendant successfully could assert that [a]
    . . . period of settlement attempts”—i.e., efforts to find nonjudicial remedies—“contributes
    to the establishment of laches,” particularly when the defendant has expressed a desire to
    settle. Piper Aircraft Corp. v. Wag-Aero, Inc., 
    741 F.2d 925
    , 932 (7th Cir. 1984).
    In short, the district court didn’t abuse its discretion in finding that Steves’s delay
    was reasonable, and thus properly denied JELD-WEN’s laches defense. As JELD-WEN
    didn’t prove unreasonable delay, we need not address whether the delay prejudiced JELD-
    WEN.
    2.
    JELD-WEN also contends that the district court misapplied each of the four
    equitable factors, which are as follows (as applied to a Clayton Act suit):
    43
    A plaintiff must demonstrate: (1) that it [faces a significant threat of]
    irreparable [antitrust] injury; (2) that remedies available at law, such as
    monetary damages, are inadequate to compensate for that injury; (3) that,
    considering the balance of hardships between the plaintiff and defendant, a
    remedy in equity is warranted; and (4) that the public interest would not be
    disserved by a permanent injunction.
    See eBay, 
    547 U.S. at 391
    ; see also Cargill, 
    479 U.S. at 122
     (holding that a Clayton Act
    plaintiff “must show a threat of antitrust injury” to warrant injunctive relief); Zenith, 
    395 U.S. at 130
     (indicating that the threat of antitrust injury must be “significant”). Steves had
    the burden of proving all four factors, and JELD-WEN insists that it proved none.
    We review an “award of equitable relief for abuse of discretion,” Solis v. Malkani,
    
    638 F.3d 269
    , 274 (4th Cir. 2011) (cleaned up), including a decision to enjoin a merger
    under the Clayton Act, Anthem, 855 F.3d at 352–53. “A district court abuses its discretion
    when it relies on incorrect legal conclusions or clearly erroneous findings of fact, or
    otherwise acts arbitrarily or irrationally in its ruling.”       SAS Inst., Inc. v. World
    Programming Ltd., 
    874 F.3d 370
    , 385 (4th Cir. 2017) (cleaned up).
    a.
    We address the first two eBay factors together, as the district court did. They
    required Steves to “demonstrate a significant threat,” Zenith, 
    395 U.S. at 130
    , of an
    irreparable antitrust injury that damages couldn’t cure, see eBay, 
    547 U.S. at 391
    ; Cargill,
    
    479 U.S. at 122
    . According to the district court, Steves’s potential collapse after September
    2021 was such an injury. JELD-WEN now asserts that this injury could be remedied by
    either monetary damages or equitable relief that is less drastic than divestiture.
    44
    We affirm the district court’s finding that Steves’s threatened collapse couldn’t be
    repaired by money damages. The permanent loss of a business, with its corresponding
    goodwill, is a well-recognized form of irreparable injury. See, e.g., Warren v. City of
    Athens, 
    411 F.3d 697
    , 711–12 (6th Cir. 2005). Of course, not every company’s failure will
    warrant equitable relief. For example, the dissolution of a new enterprise, or one that’s not
    very important to its owner (who may own many companies), may be reparable by
    damages. See, e.g., DFW Metro Line Servs. v. Sw. Bell Tel. Co., 
    901 F.2d 1267
    , 1269 (5th
    Cir. 1990) (“The lost goodwill of a business operated over a short period of time is usually
    compensable in money damages.”).
    But here, Steves has been family-owned for 150 years. The right to continue a
    multi-generational family business “is not measurable entirely in monetary terms; the
    [Steveses] want to sell [doors], not to live on the income from a damages award.” See
    Semmes Motors, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co., 
    429 F.2d 1197
    , 1205 (2d Cir. 1970) (Friendly, J.).
    Thus, the district court didn’t abuse its discretion in finding that damages couldn’t repair
    Steves’s threatened injury. 14
    A tougher question is whether the court should have chosen a different equitable
    remedy. As a “general rule,” “injunctive relief should be no more burdensome to the
    defendant than necessary to provide complete relief to the plaintiffs.” Madsen v. Women’s
    14
    The district court’s award of future damages as an alternative—which we vacate
    for unrelated reasons, as explained below—doesn’t undercut its irreparable-harm finding.
    As the district court recognized, while a damages award would be better than no relief at
    all, it wouldn’t fully repair Steves’s injury because it wouldn’t keep Steves in business.
    45
    Health Ctr., Inc., 
    512 U.S. 753
    , 765 (1994) (cleaned up). Here, the court acknowledged
    that it could protect Steves by ordering JELD-WEN to supply Steves’s requirements at fair
    prices going forward. But the court chose divestiture instead, reasoning that it was needed
    to restore competition in the doorskin market and that a conduct remedy would provide
    only temporary relief before eventually expiring. In JELD-WEN’s view, the availability
    of a less drastic remedy forecloses divestiture, and the court erred by considering what
    would best promote competition.
    We disagree with JELD-WEN for two independent reasons. First, the district court
    reasonably found that a conduct remedy would only protect Steves temporarily. After it
    expired, “there would be no structure in place to foster competition.” Steves and Sons, 345
    F. Supp. 3d at 668. The threat to Steves’s survival would persist, as there would be only
    two American doorskin manufacturers, each of whom would be vertically integrated.
    Without divestiture, “the threat to [Steves] inherent in the [merger] would [not] cease in
    the foreseeable future.” See Zenith, 
    395 U.S. at 131
    . Thus, a conduct remedy wouldn’t
    give Steves “complete relief,” Madsen, 
    512 U.S. at 765
     (cleaned up), against the
    “threatened loss or damage” for which it seeks divestiture, 
    15 U.S.C. § 26
    .
    Second, JELD-WEN’s argument conflicts with Clayton Act principles. The Act
    authorizes injunctive relief in private suits “not merely to provide private relief, but to serve
    as well the high purpose of enforcing the antitrust laws”—i.e., protecting competition. Am.
    Stores, 
    495 U.S. at 284
     (cleaned up). Indeed, private enforcement of antitrust laws is an
    “integral part of the congressional plan for protecting competition,” 
    id.,
     so courts may
    fashion equitable remedies with that broader purpose in mind. A remedy that helped only
    46
    Steves wouldn’t promote competition in the doorskin market, conflicting with the principle
    that antitrust law protects competition, not competitors, Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at 488
    .
    Further, if courts were required to choose the remedy least burdensome to the
    defendant—rather than the one that best promotes competition—conduct remedies would
    be the norm because they generally burden defendants less. But that would go against
    Congress’s policy judgment that divestiture is “the remedy best suited to redress the ills of
    an anticompetitive merger,” Am. Stores, 
    495 U.S. at 285
    , as well as the principle that
    conduct remedies are disfavored because they “risk excessive government entanglement in
    the market,” Saint Alphonsus, 778 F.3d at 793; accord ProMedica, 749 F.3d at 573.
    It’s telling that in American Stores—the seminal case finding that divestiture is
    authorized in private suits—the Supreme Court listed antitrust standing, laches, and
    unclean hands as the unique obstacles facing private plaintiffs. See 
    495 U.S. at 296
    .
    Conspicuous in its absence from that list is the equitable principle that JELD-WEN clings
    to now, which would be the greatest obstacle of all.
    In sum, the district court didn’t abuse its discretion by finding that Steves’s
    threatened injury was irreparable by money damages or conduct remedies, or by
    considering which equitable remedy would best promote competition.
    b.
    The third eBay factor required the district court to “balance the hardships” that
    divestiture would cause JELD-WEN against those which Steves would suffer in its
    absence. See 
    547 U.S. at 391
    . JELD-WEN maintains that the district court gave short
    shrift to its hardships, improperly faulted JELD-WEN for not quantifying them, and
    47
    assigned too much weight to Steves’s “speculative” claim that it won’t survive absent
    divestiture, Appellant’s Reply Br. at 15.
    Again, we conclude that the district court acted within its discretion. Record
    evidence supports the court’s finding that Steves faces collapse without injunctive relief.
    If neither JELD-WEN nor Masonite sell Steves doorskins, Steves will have no recourse.
    Such a “significant possibility” that a party “would be driven out of business” carries great
    weight when balancing hardships. See Buffalo Courier-Express, Inc. v. Buffalo Evening
    News, Inc., 
    601 F.2d 48
    , 58 (2d Cir. 1979) (Friendly, J.).
    The court also analyzed the evidence of JELD-WEN’s hardships thoroughly. It
    recognized that divestiture would cost JELD-WEN a great deal financially and would
    reduce its doorskin output. But JELD-WEN could weather these hardships, the court
    found, because it was much larger and more diversified than Steves. For instance, JELD-
    WEN had several other doorskin plants and had just opened a new one. None of them were
    running at full capacity, and one wasn’t being operated at all and could be reactivated
    within two years.     And the court could ease JELD-WEN’s transition by ordering
    Towanda’s new owner to supply JELD-WEN’s doorskin requirements for two years.
    JELD-WEN’s hardships, while significant, were outweighed by the “far more serious
    harm” facing Steves. Steves and Sons, 345 F. Supp. 3d at 662. We see no reversible error
    in this analysis.
    Additionally, the district court discounted some of JELD-WEN’s claimed hardships
    as too speculative. For example, JELD-WEN posited that divestiture could cause layoffs
    at Towanda and at its other plants. In the court’s view, this was both unsupported by the
    48
    record and illogical because Towanda’s new owner would want to retain its employees and
    JELD-WEN would have to shift more production to its remaining plants. JELD-WEN also
    surmised that it would have to pay contractual penalties for failing to meet other customers’
    supply needs, but the district court found this unlikely, noting that those contracts contained
    force majeure clauses that encompass the divestiture order.
    The court’s dismissal of such conjecture did not constitute impermissible burden-
    shifting. It was proper for JELD-WEN to bear the burden of proving its own hardships, as
    such facts were “peculiarly in [its] knowledge.” See Smith v. United States, 
    568 U.S. 106
    ,
    112 (2013) (cleaned up).
    c.
    The fourth factor required Steves to show “that the public interest would not be
    disserved by a permanent injunction.” eBay, 
    547 U.S. at 391
    . The district court found
    divestiture to be in the public interest because it would add a third supplier to the doorskin
    market, thereby promoting competition. JELD-WEN asserts (1) that the court wasn’t
    equipped to assess this factor without knowing who would buy Towanda (or at least
    knowing more about the likely bidders); (2) that Towanda won’t compete effectively after
    it’s divested, so the remedy will backfire; and (3) that letting Steves buy Towanda (which
    it has expressed interest in doing) won’t increase competition.
    JELD-WEN’s first argument requires some unpacking. In this case, the district
    court undertook a two-step process of ordering divestiture first, and then (if affirmed on
    appeal) holding an auction with a special master’s help. This approach is commonly taken
    in suits filed by the Federal Trade Commission. The Supreme Court recognized its virtues
    49
    in Brown Shoe, 
    370 U.S. at
    309–310, and since then, our sister circuits have often affirmed
    divestiture orders in government suits where important details—like who would buy the
    divested entity—had not been sorted out yet. See Saint Alphonsus Med. Ctr.-Nampa Inc.
    v. St. Luke’s Health Sys., Ltd., Nos. 1:12-CV-560 and 1:13-CV-116, 
    2014 WL 407446
     (D.
    Idaho Jan. 24, 2014), at *26 (ordering a company “to fully divest itself” of assets acquired
    in a merger and “take any further action needed to unwind the [a]cquisition,” without
    addressing who would buy the assets), aff’d, 778 F.3d at 792–793; In re ProMedica Health
    Sys., Inc., No. 9346, 
    2012 WL 2450574
    , at *6 (F.T.C. June 25, 2012) (ordering a company
    to fully divest merged assets “to an [a]cquirer that receives the prior approval of the
    [Federal Trade] Commission”), aff’d sub nom. ProMedica, 749 F.3d at 573.
    JELD-WEN contends that a two-step process is inappropriate in private suits like
    this one. We disagree. In both government and private suits, a court may order divestiture
    if it’s needed to “restore competition,” i.e., to “protect the public interest.” United States
    v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 
    366 U.S. 316
    , 326 (1961). If a court can properly assess
    the public interest in a government suit without having found a buyer, it can also do so in
    a private suit. Brown Shoe’s rationale for approving of a two-step process applies with
    equal force here: Potential buyers may hesitate to place bids while a lengthy appeal looms.
    See 
    370 U.S. at 309
    . Indeed, over two years have passed between the divestiture order and
    our decision, and more time will pass if JELD-WEN presses its appeal further. Delaying
    the auction until this appeal wraps up will attract more buyers and thus serve the public
    interest.
    50
    The facts of this case also support the use of a two-step process. The district court
    reasonably found that Towanda will likely attract a buyer capable of competing with JELD-
    WEN and Masonite. Several serious bidders emerged in 2012, when both CMI and the
    molded-door market as a whole were doing poorly. Since then, demand for doorskins has
    increased dramatically and the Towanda plant has undergone capital improvements,
    making it an even more appealing investment. In other cases, where a buyer is less likely
    to emerge, a two-step process may be inadvisable because the appeal is likely to be a waste
    of time that prejudices the defendant. But on this record, the district court acted within its
    discretion by ordering such a process.
    JELD-WEN also faults the district court for not requiring Steves to submit more
    proof of other bidders’ interest. There’s some merit to this critique. Perhaps there were
    ways, short of an auction, to confirm with greater certainty that multiple bidders would
    emerge. The court could have, for instance, sought input from the parties that placed bids
    for CMI in 2012, or asked the Justice Department (or another expert) to share its
    expectations of how the auction process might unfold. But the district court’s failure to
    take such steps here wasn’t an abuse of discretion, as no case law required them, and ample
    evidence supported a finding that buyers would likely emerge.
    We turn now to JELD-WEN’s second public-interest argument. As our sister
    circuits and the Justice Department have recognized, a key factor in divestiture analysis is
    whether the divested entity will be “a willing, independent competitor capable of effective
    production in the [relevant] market.” White Consol. Indus., Inc. v. Whirlpool Corp., 
    781 F.2d 1224
    , 1228 (6th Cir. 1986); see also J.A. 970 (listing the factors that the Justice
    51
    Department considers before pursuing divestiture). JELD-WEN disputes the district
    court’s finding that a divested Towanda can compete effectively. As this is a factual
    finding, we review it for clear error. See Equinor USA Onshore Props. Inc. v. Pine Res.,
    LLC, 
    917 F.3d 807
    , 813 (4th Cir. 2019).
    We conclude that the district court’s finding wasn’t clear error because substantial
    evidence supports it. Specifically, CMI had 16% market share before the merger, making
    it a significant player in the market. It thrived until the housing bubble burst, and even
    afterward, its doorskin business remained profitable until the merger. There was ample
    interest in buying CMI in 2012, suggesting that investors believed in its ability to compete
    even when the doorskin market wasn’t doing well. And since then, JELD-WEN has made
    capital improvements to Towanda, helping the plant generate substantial profits. Demand
    for doorskins has also increased, creating more room for a third supplier. Further, trial
    evidence showed that, since 2012, JELD-WEN and Masonite’s prices have increased,
    while their product quality has decreased. So, even if a divested Towanda’s market share
    doesn’t exceed the 16% enjoyed by CMI pre-merger, its presence should still stoke
    competition and thereby serve the public interest.
    JELD-WEN posits that Towanda won’t be profitable without relying on JELD-
    WEN’s sales, administration, and technology services. But the eventual buyer of Towanda
    may offer similar or better services. While this is a factor that the special master should
    consider when it holds an auction, it’s not a reason to reject divestiture outright.
    Lastly, we consider the possibility that Steves may buy Towanda. So far, Steves is
    the only entity to have expressed interest in doing so. As JELD-WEN points out, there’s a
    52
    tension between Steves’s desire to pay as little as it can for Towanda and the public’s
    interest in finding the best purchaser. Indeed, Steves’s preference for divestiture in lieu of
    a $139.4 million damages award may signify that it hopes to buy Towanda at a bargain
    price. But Steves won’t run the auction process. The special master will be charged with
    soliciting bids. So, we need not worry about any conflict of interest.
    If Steves does buy Towanda, each of the three doorskin suppliers would be
    vertically integrated. That’s not ideal for promoting competition, as the three suppliers
    would share a collective incentive not to sell to the Independents. But three is better than
    two. And reducing market concentration generally promotes competition because, “where
    rivals are few, firms will be able to coordinate their behavior, either by overt collusion or
    implicit understanding, in order to restrict output and achieve profits above competitive
    levels.” Heinz, 
    246 F.3d at 715
     (cleaned up). Indeed, a “duopoly . . . is presumptively
    unlawful in and of itself.” ProMedica, No. 3:11-CV-47, 
    2011 WL 1219281
    , at *56.
    The facts of this case bear out those principles, as trial evidence shows that there
    was more competition in the doorskin market pre-merger, even though all three suppliers
    at the time were vertically integrated. Thus, the chance that Steves may buy Towanda
    doesn’t render the divestiture order an abuse of discretion.
    ***
    In sum, the record supports the district court’s findings as to each of the equitable
    factors. Of course, the divestiture process is far from over. If the special master can’t
    locate a satisfactory buyer, the district court may have to revisit its ruling. And, when a
    53
    buyer is selected, JELD-WEN may challenge whether a sale to that particular buyer will
    serve the public interest.
    But as it stands, this case is a poster child for divestiture. A merger has resulted in
    a duopoly. Each doorskin supplier is vertically integrated. Evidence indicates that they’ve
    used their market power to threaten the Independents’ survival. And it’s reasonable to
    expect that a third supplier—even one that’s vertically integrated—will promote
    competition, as CMI did before the 2012 merger. Thus, the district court acted within its
    discretion by ordering divestiture.
    E.
    JELD-WEN also challenges the $139.4 million damages award for future lost
    profits, which would only kick in if divestiture doesn’t occur. Unlike with its claim for
    equitable relief, Steves had to “show actual injury” to obtain damages, not merely
    threatened injury. See Cargill, 
    479 U.S. at 111
    . We conclude that, because Steves has not
    yet suffered the injury on which its claim for future lost profits rests, this claim wasn’t ripe
    for adjudication and thus should have been dismissed without prejudice.
    “The doctrine of ripeness,” which is rooted in both Article III and prudential
    doctrines, “prevents judicial consideration of issues until a controversy is presented in
    clean-cut and concrete form.” Lansdowne on the Potomac Homeowners Ass’n, Inc. v.
    OpenBand at Lansdowne, LLC, 
    713 F.3d 187
    , 198 (4th Cir. 2013) (cleaned up). As
    ripeness is a jurisdictional issue, Sansotta v. Town of Nags Head, 
    724 F.3d 533
    , 548 (4th
    Cir. 2013), we must consider it whenever it draws our attention, including after the plaintiff
    has been awarded judgment. See Lansdowne at 198–99 (reviewing ripeness argument after
    54
    the plaintiff had been granted summary judgment). “To determine if a case is ripe, we
    balance the fitness of the issues for judicial decision with the hardship to the parties of
    withholding court consideration.” 
    Id. at 198
     (cleaned up).
    We begin with fitness. As relevant here, a claim is fit for adjudication when it’s
    “not dependent on future uncertainties.” See id.; see also Thomas v. Union Carbide Agric.
    Prods. Co., 
    473 U.S. 568
    , 580–81 (1985) (indicating that a claim is unripe if it “involve[s]
    contingent future events that may not occur as anticipated, or indeed may not occur at all”
    (cleaned up)).
    Steves’s claim for future lost profits depends on a future uncertainty: whether it will
    have access to doorskins after September 2021.          And this uncertainty is especially
    problematic because it’s entirely within JELD-WEN’s control.             See SureShot Golf
    Ventures, Inc. v. Topgolf Int’l, Inc., 754 F. App’x 235, 240–41 (5th Cir. 2018) (dismissing
    an antitrust damages claim as unripe because it was based on an allegation that the
    defendant, who had just acquired the plaintiff’s supplier, would refuse to deal with the
    plaintiff in the future); Volvo N. Am. Corp. v. Men’s Int’l Prof’l Tennis Council, 
    857 F.2d 55
    , 64–65 (2d Cir. 1988) (holding that an antitrust challenge to rules that the defendant had
    proposed (but not yet adopted) was ripe only where the possibility of the rules’ adoption
    had “a present anti-competitive effect”); cf. Clapper v. Amnesty Int’l USA, 
    568 U.S. 398
    ,
    413 (2013) (stating that the Supreme Court is “reluctant to endorse standing theories that
    require guesswork as to how independent decisionmakers will exercise their judgment”).
    Specifically, JELD-WEN could offer to supply Steves after September 2021 on
    terms agreeable to Steves, which would prevent the injury on which this claim is premised.
    55
    If JELD-WEN were to take that route, the damages award would be superfluous. Of
    course, the jury found that JELD-WEN planned not to do that, but JELD-WEN might well
    change its tune if the alternative is to pay Steves almost $140 million. And Steves’s duty
    to mitigate damages may oblige it to accept a reasonable offer. Cf. Golf City, Inc. v. Wilson
    Sporting Goods, Co., Inc., 
    555 F.2d 426
    , 436 (5th Cir. 1977) (“An antitrust plaintiff has a
    duty to mitigate damages.”).
    It’s true that any future-lost-profits claim involves uncertainty as to the extent of
    those lost profits. But “[p]roof of injury (whether or not an injury occurred at all) must be
    distinguished from calculation of damages (which determines the actual value of the
    injury).” Newton, 259 F.3d at 188. The problem here is that Steves’s potential injury—its
    loss of access to doorskins after September 2021—hasn’t “occurred at all.” See id.
    In rejecting JELD-WEN’s ripeness argument, the district court found that Steves’s
    future damages will flow from JELD-WEN’s notice of termination in September 2014.
    But that’s beside the point. JELD-WEN had every right to give such notice; doing so didn’t
    inflict an actual injury (as opposed to a threat of future injury) upon Steves. Indeed, JELD-
    WEN and Steves terminated a previous contract in 2010 before negotiating the Supply
    Agreement. It will take an intervening event—JELD-WEN’s anticipated refusal to sell to
    Steves on any reasonable terms after September 2021—to block Steves’s access to
    doorskins, which is the injury on which its claim is premised. Whether that event will
    occur is uncertain and entirely up to JELD-WEN.
    Because of this uncertainty, Steves’s future-lost-profits claim wasn’t fit for judicial
    decision. And by the same token, withholding adjudication of this claim should not cause
    56
    Steves any hardship. For one thing, if divestiture occurs, Steves’s threatened injury will
    be avoided and it won’t get its future damages anyway. If divestiture doesn’t pan out, and
    JELD-WEN refuses to sell doorskins to Steves, Steves could then seek a conduct remedy
    or damages, as it would have suffered an actual injury by that point. And, of course, JELD-
    WEN would be estopped from relitigating issues that have already been decided, such as
    whether the merger was illegal.
    We therefore vacate that portion of the district court’s judgment awarding future
    lost profits as an alternative to divestiture. 15
    F.
    We turn now to the trade-secrets trial. JELD-WEN challenges two of the district
    court’s jury instructions, which we review for abuse of discretion, United States ex rel.
    Oberg v. Pa. Higher Educ. Assistance Agency, 
    912 F.3d 731
    , 736 (4th Cir. 2019).
    1.
    JELD-WEN first assails the court’s instruction that, “as to trade secret 23, and only
    trade secret 23[,] . . . . a trade secret may exist if some, or even all, of its individual elements
    are public, provided that the trade secret as a whole remains confidential,” J.A. 2991. We
    understand JELD-WEN to argue that, by limiting this instruction to trade secret 23 (the
    only combination trade secret in the case), the court suggested that the bar for proving the
    existence of a non-combination trade secret is higher than it really is. That is, this
    15
    As we conclude that Steves’s future-lost-profits claim wasn’t ripe, we need not
    address JELD-WEN’s alternative argument that the damages award didn’t account for
    benefits that Steves gained from the CMI merger.
    57
    instruction implied that JELD-WEN had to prove that its sixty-six other alleged trade
    secrets were wholly confidential, which (JELD-WEN claims) isn’t the right legal standard.
    This argument misses the mark. The court was right to limit its instruction to trade
    secret 23. By definition, a combination trade secret has multiple elements, not all of which
    must be confidential so long as the fact of their “unified process, design, and operation”
    are confidential. AirFacts, 909 F.3d at 96. In contrast, a non-combination trade secret by
    definition has only one element. That element “must be secret”; otherwise, it couldn’t be
    a trade secret. Hoechst Diafoil Co. v. Nan Ya Plastics Corp., 
    174 F.3d 411
    , 418 (4th Cir.
    1999) (quoting Kewanee Oil Co. v. Bicron Corp., 
    416 U.S. 470
    , 475 (1974)).
    JELD-WEN conflates two concepts: combination trade secrets and the level of
    secrecy required of trade secrets generally. While it’s true that an item can be a trade secret
    even if it’s publicly available—for instance, if it appears in an unsealed court filing, see
    id.—it still must be relatively secret, i.e., it “must not be of public knowledge or of a general
    knowledge in the trade or business,” 
    id.
     (quoting Kewanee, 
    416 U.S. at 475
    ). After all,
    that’s the point of a trade secret. JELD-WEN’s position—i.e., that a non-combination trade
    secret need not be secret—strains common sense.
    2.
    Next, JELD-WEN protests the district court’s instruction that malicious trade-secret
    appropriation, under federal and Texas law, requires an “intent to cause injury or harm” to
    the plaintiff. According to JELD-WEN, the proper standard is whether the defendant
    showed “conscious disregard for the rights of another.” Appellant’s Br. at 73. JELD-WEN
    58
    insists that this error requires a retrial as to the eight secrets that the jury deemed protectable
    and misappropriated.
    JELD-WEN’s federal and state claims warrant separate analysis.
    a.
    Congress enacted the Defend Trade Secrets Act to create a federal private cause of
    action for trade-secret misappropriation. See Defend Trade Secrets Act of 2016, Pub. L.
    114-153 § 2, 
    130 Stat. 376
    , 376–82 (May 11, 2016). The statute provides, inter alia, that
    plaintiffs are entitled to exemplary damages and attorney’s fees if a trade secret is “willfully
    and maliciously misappropriated.” 
    18 U.S.C. § 1836
    (b)(3)(C), (D). But it doesn’t define
    “malicious,” and we have found no cases that define that term in the context of this statute.
    Nor have we found a clear definition of the term in states’ versions of the Uniform
    Trade Secrets Act—on which the federal statute is modeled. See Kuryakyn Holdings, LLC
    v. Ciro, LLC, 
    242 F. Supp. 3d 789
    , 797 (W.D. Wis. 2017) (looking to state statutes with
    respect to another Defend Trade Secrets Act issue). To the contrary, cases interpreting
    those statutes show that they offer competing definitions, each based on how “malice” is
    defined in other contexts under the relevant state’s laws. In some of these cases, courts
    have adopted the “intent to cause injury or harm” standard that was used here (or something
    similar). See Contour Design, Inc. v. Chance Mold Steel Co., Ltd., No. 09-CV-451, 
    2011 WL 6300622
    , at *12 (D.N.H. Dec. 16, 2011) (looking to New Hampshire law), aff’d in
    part and rev’d in part, 
    693 F.3d 102
     (1st Cir. 2012); Wellogix, Inc. v. Accenture, LLP, 
    823 F. Supp. 2d 555
    , 570 (S.D. Tex. 2011) (looking to Texas law). The leading trade-secrets
    treatise also supports that approach. See 1 Milgrim on Trade Secrets § 1.01[2][c][iv][C],
    59
    [5][d][ii].   Other courts, however, have used JELD-WEN’s favored standard.              See
    Macquarie Bank Ltd. v. Knickel, 
    793 F.3d 926
    , 940 (8th Cir. 2015) (looking to North
    Dakota law); Learning Curve Toys, Inc. v. PlayWood Toys, Inc., 
    342 F.3d 714
    , 730 (7th
    Cir. 2003) (looking to Illinois law).
    Next, we consider legislative history and how Congress and courts have defined
    “malicious” in analogous contexts. But JELD-WEN offers no help on these points. It
    devotes less than a page of briefing to this issue, and the only authorities it cites involve
    the Illinois and North Carolina versions of the Uniform Trade Secrets Act. It fails to
    recognize that states have differing views on this issue, and that we must look to other
    evidence to assess what Congress intended.
    “[I]t is not the obligation of this court to research and construct legal arguments
    open to parties, especially when they are represented by counsel,” and “perfunctory and
    undeveloped arguments . . . are waived.” Judge v. Quinn, 
    612 F.3d 537
    , 557 (7th Cir.
    2010) (cleaned up).     Thus, in light of JELD-WEN’s perfunctory and undeveloped
    argument, we have no cause to reverse the district court on this issue.
    b.
    We turn now to the Texas-law claim. The current version of the Texas Uniform
    Trade Secrets Act includes JELD-WEN’s favored definition of “willful and malicious.”
    See Tex. Civ. Prac. & Rem. Code § 134A.002(7). But that’s due to a statutory amendment
    that took effect on September 1, 2017, and doesn’t apply to actions that commenced before
    that date. Texas Unif. Trade Secrets Act, 2017 Tex. Sess. Law Serv. Ch. 37, §§ 6, 7 (H.B.
    1995) (“Chapter 134A, Civil Practice and Remedies Code, as amended by this Act, applies
    60
    only to an action that commences on or after the effective date of this Act . . . . This Act
    takes effect September 1, 2017.”).            Thus, it doesn’t apply to JELD-WEN’s
    misappropriation claims, because JELD-WEN first sought leave to file these claims in
    March 2017 and the district court granted leave that May.
    JELD-WEN’s claims are instead governed by pre-September 2017 Texas law. See
    id. § 6 (“An action that commences before the effective date of this Act is governed by the
    law applicable to the action immediately before the effective date of this Act . . . .”). Before
    the 2017 amendment, Texas courts defined “malice” in misappropriation suits as “a
    specific intent by the defendant to cause substantial injury or harm to the claimant,” in
    accordance with the Texas civil code’s general definition of the term. Horizon Health
    Corp. v. Acadia Healthcare Co., Inc., 
    520 S.W.3d 848
    , 866 (Tex. 2017) (quoting Tex. Civ.
    Prac. & Rem. Code § 41.001(7)); accord Eagle Oil & Gas Co. v. Shale Exploration, LLC,
    
    549 S.W.3d 256
    , 283 (Tex. Ct. App. 2018). The jury instruction in this case matches that
    standard, so no retrial is necessary.
    G.
    JELD-WEN also asserts that the district court lacked authority to enter judgment for
    the Intervenors in the trade-secrets case because JELD-WEN brought no claims against
    them. As this is an issue of law, we review it de novo. See Equinor, 917 F.3d at 813.
    We agree with JELD-WEN. Judgment as a matter of law may be granted only “on
    a claim or defense.” Fed. R. Civ. P. 50(a)(1)(B). To our knowledge, no federal court has
    ever recognized an exception to this principle. Nor would such an exception make sense,
    as the civil plaintiff is the “master of his complaint” and “determines the claims . . . to
    61
    bring.” See United States ex rel. Bunk v. Gosselin World Wide Moving, N.V., 
    741 F.3d 390
    , 405–06 (4th Cir. 2013) (cleaned up); see also Hudson v. Air Line Pilots Ass’n Int’l,
    
    415 B.R. 653
    , 660 (N.D. Ill. 2009) (denying summary judgment to an intervenor because
    the plaintiffs had not brought any claims against it).
    The district court nevertheless granted judgment to the Intervenors for two reasons:
    (1) the claims against Steves centered on the Intervenors’ conduct, and (2) by intervening,
    they gained the right to participate in the case and exposed themselves to potential liability
    if JELD-WEN pursued a claim against them. Neither reason passes muster. Suits against
    corporations often focus on certain individuals’ conduct; that doesn’t make such
    individuals defendants. And an intervenor’s right to participate in a case—by, e.g., filing
    motions, participating in discovery, and appealing judgments—doesn’t give them a right
    to judgment on claims that don’t exist. Further, the mere act of intervening didn’t expose
    the Intervenors to liability. That would have required JELD-WEN to pursue relief against
    them in this action, which it didn’t do.
    The cases cited by Steves and the district court are inapposite. For example, in
    Schneider v. Dumbarton Devs., Inc., the plaintiff successfully pursued a claim against the
    intervenor. See 
    767 F.2d 1007
    , 1017 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (stating that the plaintiff “asked for,”
    and the court granted after a bench trial, judgment specifically against the intervenor). And
    United States v. Oregon was about whether intervention constituted a waiver of tribal
    immunity. See 
    657 F.2d 1009
    , 1013–14 (9th Cir. 1981). As for Alvarado v. J.C. Penney
    Co., Inc., the intervenors in that case were granted judgment on their own claims. See 
    997 F.2d 803
    , 805 (10th Cir. 1993) (noting that the intervenors made “their claims known” by
    62
    “requesting a declaratory judgment of sorts” against the parties). None of these cases
    suggest that a party can be awarded judgment on a claim or defense that was never raised.
    H.
    Finally, JELD-WEN asks that we reassign this case on remand, alleging that the
    district judge “made repeated and critical errors that fundamentally skewed the proceedings
    against JELD-WEN.” Appellant’s Br. at 77. We decline to do so.
    “Absent a claim of bias,” which JELD-WEN doesn’t make here, “reassignment is
    appropriate in unusual circumstances where both for the judge’s sake and the appearance
    of justice an assignment to a different judge is salutary and in the public interest, especially
    as it minimizes even a suspicion of partiality.” United States v. North Carolina, 
    180 F.3d 574
    , 582–83 (4th Cir. 1999) (cleaned up). “In determining whether such circumstances
    exist, a court should consider:
    (1) whether the original judge would reasonably be expected upon remand to
    have substantial difficulty in putting out of his or her mind previously
    expressed views or findings determined to be erroneous or based on evidence
    that must be rejected,
    (2) whether reassignment is advisable to preserve the appearance of justice,
    and
    (3) whether reassignment would entail waste and duplication out of
    proportion to any gain in preserving the appearance of fairness.
    
    Id. at 583
    .
    Overall, the district judge presided admirably over this exceedingly complex case.
    While we disagree with some of the judge’s rulings, they nonetheless reflect thoughtful
    analysis, and we’re confident that the judge can put his previous rulings out of his mind.
    63
    “And, in light of the lengthy history of this case, reassignment would entail a waste of
    judicial resources.” 
    Id. at 583
    . We therefore decline to reassign this case.
    IV.
    For the reasons given, we vacate the district court’s judgment as to Steves’s future-
    lost-profits claim and the Intervenors. We otherwise affirm the district court’s judgment
    and remand for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    AFFIRMED IN PART, VACATED IN PART, AND REMANDED
    64
    RUSHING, Circuit Judge, concurring:
    I join the Court’s opinion in full. As the Court observes, we have not previously
    had occasion to speak on the issue of divestiture sought by a private plaintiff under
    Section 16 of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 26
    . Supra at 19. But other courts have
    considered such requests, and none has yet encountered a case in which divestiture was an
    appropriate award. In particular, courts have been reluctant to order divestiture at the
    behest of a private plaintiff after consummation of the allegedly anticompetitive merger.
    Divestiture is “simple, relatively easy to administer, and sure,” California v. Am.
    Stores Co., 
    495 U.S. 271
    , 281 (1990) (quoting United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours &
    Co., 
    366 U.S. 316
    , 331 (1961)), only “before the transaction is consummated, or if stock
    or discrete tangible assets are all that later need be divested,” Ginsburg v. InBev NV/SA,
    
    623 F.3d 1229
    , 1234 (8th Cir. 2010). After a merger closes and the two entities combine
    their assets and operations into a single corporate unit, divestiture becomes decidedly more
    complex. The passage of time exacerbates those complexities, not only for the combined
    entity but also for nonparties who will be affected by a court order dividing the company.
    See, e.g., 
    id.
     at 1235–1236 (noting “obvious hardship” divestiture would work on
    employees and distributors of the acquired company and potential damage to competition
    and consumers); Blue Cross & Blue Shield United of Wis. v. Marshfield Clinic, 
    883 F. Supp. 1247
    , 1264 (W.D. Wis. 1995) (observing that divestiture “would have a large impact
    on third parties . . . that have not been before this [c]ourt to protect their interests”), aff’d
    in part, rev’d in part on other grounds, 
    65 F.3d 1406
     (7th Cir. 1995).
    65
    Threatened antitrust injury is often foreseeable from the anticompetitive
    combination itself. Courts accordingly have measured the reasonableness of a private
    plaintiff’s delay in suing for divestiture relative to the announcement of the transaction and
    its subsequent consummation rather than analogizing to the four-year limitations period
    applicable to suits for damages. See, e.g., Ginsburg, 
    623 F.3d at 1235
     (finding delay
    “inexcusable” when plaintiffs “waited nearly two months” after the merger announcement
    to sue and moved for a preliminary injunction nine days before the contemplated closing
    date); Taleff v. Sw. Airlines Co., 
    828 F. Supp. 2d 1118
    , 1124 (N.D. Cal. 2011) (holding
    divestiture unavailable because plaintiffs “delayed in filing their suit until after
    [d]efendants’ merger had already been consummated”); Antoine L. Garabet, M.D., Inc. v.
    Autonomous Techs. Corp., 
    116 F. Supp. 2d 1159
    , 1173 (C.D. Cal. 2000) (concluding that
    divestiture was not an available remedy because plaintiffs waited until the day of the
    merger’s consummation to sue); see also Am. Stores, 
    495 U.S. at
    297–298 (Kennedy, J.,
    concurring) (reasoning that plaintiff’s delay in seeking divestiture for several months after
    notice of the intended merger and after completion of the stock sale but before the entities
    combined their business operations “should bear upon the ultimate disposition of the case,”
    including “the bar of laches”). But see supra at 40 n.13.
    Here, Steves alleged an antitrust injury that could not have been foreseen until two
    years after the merger closed, namely the loss of its doorskin supply and resulting threat to
    its survival. As the Court explains, it was reasonable for Steves to wait to pursue equitable
    relief until 2014, when it learned of this threat. Supra at 41–43. Although “problems of
    proof and causation” may attend claims alleging that a merger caused an antitrust injury to
    66
    occur years later, Midwestern Machinery, Inc. v. Nw. Airlines, Inc., 
    167 F.3d 439
    , 442 n.3
    (8th Cir. 1999), here the district court and jury found causation established. Steves was
    not on notice of the threatened injury that forms the basis for its divestiture claim until
    2014, therefore its delay in filing suit must be evaluated from that point rather than from
    the time the merger was announced or consummated, as might otherwise be the case.
    67
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 19-1397

Filed Date: 2/18/2021

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 2/18/2021

Authorities (51)

Smith v. United States , 133 S. Ct. 714 ( 2013 )

international-ground-transportation-incorporated-ta-whites-taxi , 475 F.3d 214 ( 2007 )

United States v. E. I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co. , 81 S. Ct. 1243 ( 1961 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Arch Coal, Inc. , 329 F. Supp. 2d 109 ( 2004 )

Wellogix, Inc. v. Accenture, LLP , 823 F. Supp. 2d 555 ( 2011 )

blue-cross-blue-shield-united-of-wisconsin-and-compcare-health-services , 65 F.3d 1406 ( 1995 )

United States v. Candelaria-Silva , 166 F.3d 19 ( 1999 )

Thomas v. Union Carbide Agricultural Products Co. , 105 S. Ct. 3325 ( 1985 )

Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp. , 505 F.3d 302 ( 2007 )

PBM PRODUCTS, LLC v. Mead Johnson & Co. , 639 F.3d 111 ( 2011 )

Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc. , 97 S. Ct. 690 ( 1977 )

Golf City, Inc., Cross v. Wilson Sporting Goods Co., Inc., ... , 555 F.2d 426 ( 1977 )

midwestern-machinery-co-inc-brian-f-gagan-sharon-tolbert-glover-charles , 392 F.3d 265 ( 2004 )

Eagle Oil & Gas Co. v. Shale Exploration, LLC , 549 S.W.3d 256 ( 2018 )

Hoechst Diafoil Company v. Nan Ya Plastics Corporation , 174 F.3d 411 ( 1999 )

federal-trade-commission-v-university-health-inc-university-health , 938 F.2d 1206 ( 1991 )

Buffalo Courier-Express, Inc. v. Buffalo Evening News, Inc. , 601 F.2d 48 ( 1979 )

Antoine L. Garabet, M.D., Inc. v. Autonomous Technologies ... , 116 F. Supp. 2d 1159 ( 2000 )

Valley Products Company, Inc. v. Landmark, a Division of ... , 128 F.3d 398 ( 1997 )

Sas of Puerto Rico, Inc. v. Puerto Rico Telephone Company , 48 F.3d 39 ( 1995 )

View All Authorities »