United Farmers Agents Ass'n v. Farmers Insurance Exchange , 89 F.3d 233 ( 1996 )


Menu:
  •                  United States Court of Appeals,
    Fifth Circuit.
    No. 95-50559.
    UNITED FARMERS AGENTS ASSOCIATION, INC.;    Thomas J. Vinson;
    Robert D. Moon, Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    FARMERS INSURANCE EXCHANGE, a California Reciprocal or Inter-
    Insurance Exchange;      Fire Insurance Exchange, a California
    Reciprocal or Inter-Insurance Exchange; Truck Insurance Exchange,
    a California Reciprocal or Inter-Insurance Exchange; Mid-Century
    Insurance Company;    Farmers New World Life Insurance Company,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    July 25, 1996.
    Appeal from the United States District Court for the Western
    District of Texas.
    Before GARWOOD, DAVIS and DeMOSS, Circuit Judges.
    W. EUGENE DAVIS, Circuit Judge.
    The United Farmers Agents Association (UFAA) and Farmers
    insurance agents Thomas J. Vinson and Robert D. Moon appeal the
    district court's order granting Farmers Insurance summary judgment
    and dismissing their antitrust class action.    We AFFIRM.
    I.
    Farmers Insurance is a group of five insurance companies with
    approximately 14,000 independent contractor agents in 29 states.
    Under the contract between Farmers and its agents, Farmers is
    obligated to provide policyholder information to the agents.       It
    has always provided this information through manual records in
    paper and book form.   In 1981, Farmers set up a computer system,
    the Farmers Agency Network System (FANS), to allow agents on-line
    access to this information in addition to the traditional manual
    1
    access.     Agents   who   wished   to   gain   electronic     access   to
    policyholder information through FANS were required to purchase a
    specially configured IBM computer from Farmers or to use another
    agent's IBM computer purchased from Farmers.
    The written agreement between Farmers and agents who purchased
    computers and gained access to FANS specifically stated that,
    absent written agreement from Farmers, only computers purchased
    through Farmers would be allowed to access FANS.        Farmers' policy
    was to never grant a written waiver of this provision.        This policy
    continued until 1993 when Farmers began allowing agents to use
    personal computers and computers purchased from third-party vendors
    to access FANS.
    UFAA, Vinson and Moon (plaintiffs) filed this action as an
    antitrust class action on behalf of all Farmers agents alleging
    that Farmers illegally tied electronic access to policy information
    to the purchase of computers from Farmers.          The district court
    certified the class for liability purposes under Federal Rule of
    Civil Procedure 23(b)(1) but deferred a ruling on certification of
    a damages class pending the outcome on liability.            The district
    court   referred   discovery   motions   and    other   dispositive     and
    non-dispositive motions to a magistrate judge who recommended that
    the district court grant summary judgment in favor of Farmers.           On
    April 19, 1995, the district court adopted the magistrate's Report
    and Recommendation in full and dismissed the plaintiffs' suit.           On
    appeal, plaintiffs argue that the district court erred by granting
    2
    Farmers' motion for summary judgment.1
    II.
    A.
    Plaintiffs argue that Farmers' policies regarding electronic
    access to FANS constitute a per se illegal tying arrangement2 and
    1
    Plaintiffs also assert that the district court erred by
    failing to review the summary judgment record de novo before
    adopting the magistrate judge's recommendation, using an improper
    standard in deciding whether summary judgment was appropriate and
    failing to certify plaintiffs as a damages class under Federal
    Rule of Civil Procedure 23(b)(3). Our de novo review of the
    record and use of the proper standard for granting summary
    judgment cure the first two of these asserted errors. Our
    affirmance of the district court's decision to grant summary
    judgment makes it unnecessary for us to consider the third.
    2
    Tying exists when "a seller refuses to sell one product,
    which a buyer desires, unless the buyer also agrees to purchase a
    second product, which is not otherwise desired from this seller
    on the offered terms.... The desired product is called the
    "tying' product; the other is the "tied' product." 9 Phillip E.
    Areeda, Antitrust Law, ¶ 1700a (Little, Brown & Co., 1991). See
    also Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, 
    504 U.S. 451
    ,
    461-62, 
    112 S. Ct. 2072
    , 2079-80, 
    119 L. Ed. 2d 265
    (1992).
    A tying arrangement is per se illegal when it has the
    following characteristics: (1) Two separate products (as
    opposed to components of a single product), (2) The two
    products are tied together or customers are coerced, (3) The
    supplier possesses substantial economic power over the tying
    product, (4) The tie has an anticompetitive effect on the
    tied market, and (5) The tie affects a not insubstantial
    volume of commerce. 9 Areeda, Areeda at ¶ 1702. See also
    
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 461-62
    , 112 S.Ct. at 2079-80; Jefferson
    Parish Hospital Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    , 11-28, 
    104 S. Ct. 1551
    , 1558-66, 
    80 L. Ed. 2d 2
    (1984).
    Tying arrangements and other restraints of trade that
    do not fit the criteria for per se illegality are evaluated
    under the Rule of Reason. Jefferson Parish Hospital 
    Dist., 466 U.S. at 29
    , 104 S.Ct. at 1567 (1984). Under the Rule of
    Reason, the plaintiff has the burden of proving that the
    tying arrangement "unreasonably restrained competition."
    
    Id. This burden
    requires an inquiry into the actual effect
    of the tying arrangement on competition in the tied market.
    
    Id. 3 allege
    that the relevant market3 in which Farmers is illegally
    exercising market power is the market for electronic access to
    Farmers policy information.        Farmers responds by arguing that the
    relevant market should be insurance sales and even if the court
    accepts the plaintiffs' argument that a separate market exists for
    electronic access to Farmers policy information, Farmers' has no
    power in     the   market   for   electronic       access    to     Farmers    policy
    information because of intense competition in the insurance sales
    market.    We find that Farmers has no market power in the relevant
    market    (insurance    sales)    and       no   market     power    even     in   the
    plaintiffs' alleged relevant market (electronic access to policy
    information).      Market power is a necessary prerequisite to an
    illegal tie so we need not make any further inquiry into whether
    Farmers' policies constitute an illegal tie.
    Under the undisputed facts of this case, we agree with Farmers
    that the relevant market is the market for insurance sales.                        The
    only product that Farmers markets to consumers is insurance.                        We
    agree with the magistrate that the summary judgment record is
    "replete with evidence that Farmers Insurance sells insurance, not
    electronic    access,   not   computers."           (emphasis       in   original).
    3
    The relevant market in an antitrust inquiry is defined by
    the cross-elasticity of demand between a given product and its
    substitutes. 2 Phillip E. Areeda & Donald F. Turner, Antitrust
    at ¶ 519a. The cross-elasticity of demand for substitutes
    measures consumers' propensity to switch from one product to
    another, similar product when relative prices change. See
    William J. Baumol & Alan S. Blinder, Economics: Principles and
    Policy at 343 (Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, Inc., 1979). Products
    similar enough that a small relative price change causes
    consumers to substitute one for another are in the same market.
    2 Areeda & Turner, Antitrust at ¶ 525a.
    4
    Plaintiffs' alleged market consists of a single brand (Farmers) and
    a tying product (electronic access to policy information) that has
    never been available to anyone other than Farmers agents.                    The
    information that the alleged tying product allows agents to access
    has   always   been    available   to   agents    in   book   form   for   free.
    Additionally, plaintiffs' own attorney could offer no justification
    at oral argument for choosing electronic access to Farmers policy
    information as the relevant market other than that he was trying to
    define the market as narrowly as possible (in order to make it look
    as if Farmers had market power).            Plaintiffs have not alleged that
    Farmers has a superior or unique insurance product that allows it
    to charge consumers more for policies or pay agents less for
    selling them and they have shown no evidence that new Farmers
    agents would face significant information or switching costs4 in
    deciding whether to sell Farmers insurance or the insurance of
    another company.      The agents have failed to give us any reason to
    view the market for electronic access to Farmers policy information
    as the relevant market.
    This suit is essentially an intracompany dispute over how to
    run a computer system, not a valid claim under antitrust laws.
    Economic   power      derived   from    contractual     agreements    such    as
    franchises or in this case, the agents' contract with Farmers, "has
    4
    Information costs in this case are the costs incurred by
    new agents in finding out how much Farmers will charge for
    electronic access to policy information and other services after
    they begin selling Farmers policies. Switching costs are the
    costs incurred in switching from selling Farmers insurance to
    selling the policies of another company. Compare 
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 473-77
    , 112 S.Ct. at 2083-88.
    5
    nothing to do with market power, ultimate consumers' welfare, or
    antitrust."   Benjamin Klein & Lester F. Saft, The Law and Economics
    of Franchise Tying Contracts, 28 J.Law & Econ. 345, 356 (1985).                We
    agree with    the   magistrate    judge      and   the   district    court    that
    plaintiffs fail to raise a question of material fact as to whether
    electronic access to Farmers policy information is the relevant
    market for our inquiry.
    The relevant market for an inquiry into market power in this
    case is the market for insurance sales and the agents do not
    contend that Farmers could exercise (or has exercised) market power
    in that market.      The agents' claim is not, therefore, cognizable
    under antitrust laws and the magistrate judge and the district
    court correctly determined that Farmers was entitled to summary
    judgment.
    B.
    Even    if    we   accept   the    plaintiffs'     alleged     market   for
    electronic access to policy information as the relevant market, the
    plaintiffs have failed to prove that Farmers had or exercised
    market power.      Farmers has 100% of the market share in the tying
    product (electronic access to policy information).                 However, this
    does not mean that Farmers has market power in the tying market.
    In fact, undisputed evidence showing that the markets for insurance
    sales and agents are highly competitive makes plaintiffs' argument
    that Farmers has market power in the market for its policy holder
    information     highly    unlikely      in   the   absence    of    prohibitive
    6
    information costs or the ability to price discriminate5 between
    agents with high switching costs and those with low or no switching
    costs. See Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, 
    504 U.S. 451
    ,       475,    
    112 S. Ct. 2072
    ,   2086-87,     
    119 L. Ed. 2d 265
      (1992).
    Plaintiffs have cited no evidence that information or switching
    costs were high for most agents and offer no evidence that Farmers
    attempted to engage in price discrimination.
    The plaintiffs argue that Kodak compels us to deny Farmers
    motion for summary judgment.              However, their reliance on Kodak is
    misplaced.          The Supreme Court's decision in Kodak was a rejection
    of Kodak's assertion that market power could never exist over
    repair parts in any case where the defendant did not have market
    power over the earlier-purchased machines needing those parts.
    Critically, the plaintiffs in Kodak produced evidence that Kodak
    was charging above market prices for its service and was engaged in
    price discrimination in favor of the knowledgeable customers who
    could most easily obtain information or switch companies.                        
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 465
    , 
    476, 112 S. Ct. at 2081
    , 2087.                    By contrast, the
    plaintiffs         in    this   case   have   failed   to    proffer    any    specific
    evidence          that   the    computers     sold   by   Farmers      were    sold   at
    5
    Price discrimination is charging different buyers different
    prices for the same item. A price-discriminating monopolist
    charges each consumer as much as the consumer is willing to pay
    for an item. Consumers who desperately need a particular product
    are charged a high price for it while those who do not really
    need the product and will refuse to buy it rather than pay a high
    price are charged a relatively low price. A price-discriminating
    monopolist makes as much money as possible on its product because
    it charges high prices to the people who are willing to pay high
    prices without losing sales to people willing to pay only a low
    price. See 2 Areeda & Turner Antitrust, ¶ 514a.
    7
    above-market prices or that other equipment of comparable quality
    was available    for      less.     The    only   summary   judgment   evidence
    plaintiffs submitted was general testimony that third party vendors
    of used IBM system 36 computers were selling them for less than
    Farmers and in larger quantities. They offer no evidence regarding
    price, quality, reliability or the expense necessary to configure
    these   computers    to     FANS.     Except      for   general   disclaimers,
    plaintiffs offered no assurance that these used computers would
    maintain the security of Farmer's policy information and would not
    introduce viruses into the system.            Additionally, plaintiffs offer
    no evidence of an appropriate market price for electronic access to
    policy information and have failed to even allege that the tied
    bundle of electronic access and computers cost more than the sum of
    their market prices.        See Will v. Comprehensive Accounting Corp.,
    
    776 F.2d 665
    , 672-73 (7th Cir.1985) cert. denied 
    475 U.S. 1129
    , 
    106 S. Ct. 1659
    , 
    90 L. Ed. 2d 201
    (1986) ("unless plaintiff shows that the
    package price was elevated, the suit must be dismissed without
    further ado");      Kypta v. McDonald's Corp., 
    671 F.2d 1282
    (11th
    Cir.) cert. denied, 
    459 U.S. 857
    , 
    103 S. Ct. 127
    , 
    74 L. Ed. 2d 109
    (1982) (same).      In sharp contrast to Kodak where the plaintiffs
    supported their claims of market power with evidence that Kodak
    charged above-market prices and engaged in price discrimination,
    the plaintiffs here simply allege that Farmers charged prices above
    the market price for computers without offering any evidence of
    what the market price for reliable computers was or alleging that
    the bundle of products, taken together, was sold at an above-market
    8
    price.
    The plaintiffs have failed to raise a question of material
    fact as to whether Farmers has sufficient market power in the
    market for electronic access to Farmers policy information to force
    agents to buy computers at higher than market prices.               The fact
    that Farmers required agents to purchase a computer from it in
    order to obtain electronic access to policy information does not
    prove that Farmers had market power.        See Breaux Bros. Farms, Inc.
    v. Teche Sugar Co., 
    21 F.3d 83
    , 86-87 (5th Cir.) cert. denied ---
    U.S. ----, 
    115 S. Ct. 425
    , 
    130 L. Ed. 2d 339
    (1994).          As noted above,
    the summary judgment record contains no evidence that the computers
    were sold at a premium price or that acceptable alternatives were
    available   for   less.     It   also    contains   no   evidence   of   what
    electronic access to policy information should cost.          In fact, the
    summary judgment record strongly supports Farmers' argument that it
    had no power in the electronic-access-to-policy-information market.
    Plaintiffs do not dispute that the insurance sales market is
    highly competitive.       Absent high information or switching costs,
    intense competition in the market for insurance agents will force
    Farmers to pay competitive wages and preclude it from imposing
    above-market prices on its agents for the services it provides
    them.    Additionally, availability of manual access to policy
    information was a good substitute for electronic access.                 This
    seriously limited Farmers' ability to charge more than the market
    9
    price for electronic access to the same information.6          The summary
    judgment record here contains no evidence that information or
    switching costs were high enough to produce any substantial market
    power for Farmers and no evidence that manual access to policy
    information   was   so   seriously    inadequate   as   a   substitute   for
    electronic access as to allow Farmers to exercise market power over
    electronic access.
    Information and switching costs for Farmers agents hired after
    1981 when FANS was implemented were virtually nonexistent.               The
    summary judgment record shows that Farmers openly required agents
    wishing to access FANS to do so only with computers purchased from
    Farmers.   Any agent hired would have known of the two ways to
    obtain policy information and could have easily inquired about the
    cost of electronic access.           The computer installment contract
    clearly states that no non-Farmers computer will be allowed to
    access FANS without the written consent of Farmers.               Division
    manager Bob Akers testified that he regularly told his agents that
    Farmers' policy was to not allow any computers purchased from
    third-party vendors to access FANS.       Internal correspondence shows
    that a corporate officer who led an agent to believe that he could
    hook up his computer to FANS even though it was purchased from a
    6
    Substitutes limit market power by giving consumers an
    alternative to paying an above-market price for a product. The
    existence of a good substitute at a competitive price (in this
    case manual access to policy information for free) prevents a
    producer from selling its product at an above-market price. An
    attempt to raise price of the product above a competitive level
    will be met with a shift in demand from the product to its
    substitute. See 2 Areeda & Turner, Antitrust at ¶ 525a.
    10
    third party was quickly reprimanded and informed that Farmers
    policy was to not allow FANS access to any computers purchased from
    third parties.   The plaintiffs produce no evidence that suggests
    that this information was difficult to obtain.        Agents would
    clearly have become aware of Farmers' policy long before they faced
    significant switching costs.
    If an agent, unhappy with Farmer's computer policy, wished to
    move to a new company, he was free to do so.   Switching costs for
    most agents were very low.   The only switching cost evident in the
    summary judgment record is the inability to continue earning
    commission from Farmers policies which agents have already sold.
    New agents have virtually no switching costs because they have sold
    no policies or only a few.     These agents can switch to selling
    insurance for another insurance company without incurring any
    significant cost.   The only group of agents that faced switching
    costs of any significance were Farmers agents hired before 1981
    when FANS was implemented.   Switching costs for these agents could
    have been high because the agents could not take their customers
    with them if they left. Policyholders are Farmers' customers under
    the terms of the agency agreement and departing agents would be
    forced to give up the income from the numerous policies they had
    sold in previous years.7
    7
    It is important to note that even agents who faced high
    switching costs in the decision to switch insurance companies
    could easily have continued selling policies with the manual
    system. Farmers clearly did not require agents to use FANS and
    continued to supply its agents with manual policy information for
    free. Even, if manual access to policy information was inferior
    to electronic access, it was a reasonably good substitute that
    11
    The absence of significant information costs to the agents and
    the existence of switching costs for some agents but not for others
    means that in order for Farmers to have exercised market power in
    the markets for electronic access and computers, it must have
    engaged in price discrimination.       Farmers could exercise market
    power and sell electronic access or computers at above-market
    prices only to those agents with high switching costs.   Agents with
    low switching costs would refuse to pay an above-market price for
    the bundled electronic access and computers.      Rather than pay a
    premium, these agents could simply leave Farmers and move to
    another insurance company.
    Plaintiffs submit no evidence that Farmers charged agents with
    many policies in force more than it charged new agents or those
    with few policies in force.    They do not even allege that Farmers
    attempted to engage in price discrimination. Without an allegation
    that price discrimination occurred or evidence that Farmers agents
    faced prohibitive costs in discovering Farmers' computer policy,
    the plaintiffs cannot seriously argue that Farmers had or exploited
    any market power.   Plaintiffs fail to raise a question of material
    fact as to whether Farmers had market power in the market for
    electronic access to policy information.
    Conclusion
    We agree with the district court and the magistrate judge that
    electronic access to policy information is merely a component of
    would have seriously limited Farmers' ability to charge
    above-market prices for electronic access and computers even to
    those agents with many policies in force.
    12
    Farmers' insurance product and that the relevant market for an
    antitrust inquiry is the insurance sales market. Farmers exercised
    no market power in this highly competitive market and plaintiffs'
    antitrust action fails for this reason alone.   Additionally, even
    if we accept plaintiffs' alleged markets as the relevant markets
    for our inquiry, plaintiffs still fail to raise a question of
    material fact on the issue of whether Farmers has market power.
    Plaintiffs fail to offer any evidence of above-market computer
    prices or high switching or information costs.    They present no
    evidence that Farmers engaged in price discrimination and they
    offer no plausible economic argument that would support market
    power.   For all of these reasons, we find that plaintiffs have
    failed to raise a question of material fact as to whether Farmers
    violated antitrust laws.   The judgment of the district court is,
    therefore, AFFIRMED.
    AFFIRMED.
    13