Pilgrim's Pride Corporation v. Gary Agerton ( 2013 )


Menu:
  •       Case: 12-40085          Document: 00512355307            Page: 1   Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE FIFTH CIRCUIT  United States Court of Appeals
    Fifth Circuit
    FILED
    August 27, 2013
    No. 12-40085                   Lyle W. Cayce
    Clerk
    In the Matter of: PILGRIM’S PRIDE CORPORATION,
    Debtor
    ---------------------------------------------
    GARY HEATH AGERTON; JACOB WILSON AGERTON; JERRY
    AGERTON; SANDRA AGERTON; DANIEL ALBRITTON, ET AL.,
    Appellees
    v.
    PILGRIM’S PRIDE CORPORATION,
    Appellant
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Eastern District of Texas
    Before DAVIS and SMITH, Circuit Judges.*
    PER CURIAM:
    Appellant Pilgrim’s Pride Corporation (“PPC”), a large producer of
    processed chicken, idled a number of its chicken processing facilities with the
    alleged goal of reducing the excess chicken supply and increasing prices.
    Appellee chicken growers filed suit and obtained a money judgment against PPC
    *
    This matter is being decided by a quorum. 
    28 U.S.C. § 46
    (d).
    Case: 12-40085     Document: 00512355307     Page: 2    Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    No. 12-40085
    for damages the district court found arose from PPC’s unlawful attempt to
    manipulate or control poultry prices. Because PPC’s unilateral decision to reduce
    production was neither illegitimate nor anti-competitive, we REVERSE and
    RENDER judgment in favor of PPC.
    I.
    PPC, a Delaware corporation, is one of the world’s largest suppliers of
    chicken and processed chicken products. The heart of PPC’s operations is its
    network of chicken processing facilities located in the Southeast United States,
    from which it produces chicken for four primary product markets: (1) prepared
    chicken foods, (2) fresh food service, (3) retail or case-ready chicken, and (4)
    commodity chicken. PPC does not actually raise the chickens processed by these
    facilities, instead relying upon the husbandry services of dozens of local chicken
    growers. Under its Poultry Grower Agreements with chicken growers, PPC
    provides the chicks, feed, and other supplies, and the chicken growers provide
    the facilities and labor necessary to raise the chickens.
    Facing severe economic difficulties in 2008, PPC ceased profitability and
    began losing substantial amounts of money. The primary reason for PPC’s
    mounting financial problems appeared to be the company’s over-extension into
    the commodity chicken market, of which PPC held an estimated 50% market
    share. When PPC evaluated its operations, it concluded that it was
    unnecessarily producing a surplus of commodity chicken at great cost to itself.
    In an effort to stem its losses and streamline operations, PPC closed or idled
    several processing and distribution facilities, divested assets, restructured
    supply contracts, and laid off a number of employees. However, these measures
    proved ineffective and PPC ultimately filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy relief in
    December 2008.
    One of the PPC facilities most affected by the company’s financial
    challenges was its El Dorado, Arkansas, processing complex. Identified as a
    2
    Case: 12-40085       Document: 00512355307     Page: 3   Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    No. 12-40085
    potential candidate for strategic decommission, the El Dorado facility struggled
    with high operating costs, poor performance, and low-margin operations focused
    on commodity chicken. PPC hoped that by divesting itself of underperforming
    and unprofitable assets producing commodity chicken, it could increase
    profitability while de-emphasizing its position in a riskier market. By reducing
    PPC’s output and the surplus supply of commodity chicken, it is also alleged that
    PPC hoped commodity chicken prices would stabilize at a higher equilibrium
    price.
    After PPC filed for bankruptcy, it received approval from both the
    bankruptcy court and the unsecured creditors committee to idle or sell three of
    its processing complexes, including the El Dorado facility. PPC was unable to
    solicit an offer that even approached the El Dorado facility’s appraised value,
    and the facility was officially idled in May 2009. As a result of the facility’s
    closure, the husbandry services of some 163 contract chicken growers were no
    longer needed, and PPC rejected all related Poultry Grower Agreements.
    In response to the termination of their growing agreements, a group of the
    affected chicken growers filed suit under the Packers and Stockyards Act of 1921
    (“PSA”). 
    7 U.S.C. §§ 181
     et seq. Specifically, the growers alleged that PPC had
    engaged in a course of business for the purpose of “manipulating or controlling
    prices” in violation of PSA § 192(e). The growers originally filed suit in
    bankruptcy court in the Northern District of Texas. A district judge then
    withdrew the reference to bankruptcy court and transferred the case to the
    Eastern District of Texas, where it was referred by consent to a magistrate judge
    under 
    28 U.S.C. § 636
    (c). At a trial before a magistrate judge, the judge found
    that one of PPC’s goals in the idling of the El Dorado facility was to reduce the
    supply of commodity chicken and thereby pressure prices upward. Reasoning
    that the magnitude of PPC’s operations and actions was likely to lead to a
    competitive injury, the magistrate judge concluded that PPC’s actions violated
    3
    Case: 12-40085         Document: 00512355307      Page: 4   Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    No. 12-40085
    PSA § 192(e). To remedy PPC’s violation, the magistrate judge awarded over $25
    million to the chicken growers as part of the final judgment. The magistrate
    judge resigned soon after issuing the judgment, and a district judge ruled on the
    post-judgment motions. PPC now appeals.
    II.
    We review a district court’s findings of fact for clear error and its
    conclusions   of     law    de   novo.   City    of   New   Orleans    v.   BellSouth
    Telecommunications, Inc., 
    690 F.3d 312
    , 322 (5th Cir. 2012).
    III.
    PPC first argues that the district court erred in its conclusion that PPC’s
    deliberate reduction in commodity chicken output constitutes an illegal
    manipulation of poultry prices under the PSA.
    Under the relevant provision of the PSA,
    It shall be unlawful for . . . any live poultry dealer with respect to
    live poultry, to:
    ....
    (e) Engage in any course of business or do any act for the purpose or
    with the effect of manipulating or controlling prices . . . .
    
    7 U.S.C. § 192
    (e). In finding a violation of § 192(e), the district court’s analysis
    was simple: If PPC hoped to increase chicken prices by reducing the quantity of
    chicken offered on the market, then it had attempted to manipulate chicken
    prices and thereby violated the PSA. However, PPC contends that the district
    court’s simplistic interpretation of § 192(e) is flawed. Specifically, PPC argues
    that § 192(e) is an antitrust statute, and therefore is only violated by attempts
    to affect market prices which are anti-competitive, or “injurious to competition.”
    Because its output reductions were not anti-competitive, PPC asserts, it has not
    violated § 192(e).
    4
    Case: 12-40085       Document: 00512355307         Page: 5     Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    No. 12-40085
    In response, the growers emphasize that violations of the PSA are not
    strictly limited to the traditional antitrust realms of price-fixing conspiracies and
    monopolization. Rather, the history of the PSA supports a “wider power to
    prohibit unfair methods of competition than did antecedent anti-trust
    legislation.” Wheeler v. Pilgrim’s Pride Corp., 
    591 F.3d 355
    , 357 (5th Cir. 2009)
    (en banc).
    In Wheeler v. Pilgrim’s Pride, the en banc court considered whether PPC
    had violated PSA §§ 192(a) or (b) by providing preferential terms of dealing to
    certain chicken growers. Id. Of particular concern to the Wheeler court was the
    broad prohibition of § 192(a), which makes it unlawful to “[e]ngage in or use any
    unfair . . . or deceptive practice.” We first observed that “the object of the PSA
    was to secure the flow of livestock from the farms and ranges to the slaughtering
    center and into meat products unburdened by collusion that unduly lowered the
    prices to the shipper and unduly increased the price to the consumer.” Id. at 358
    (emphasis added). We next reviewed the decisions of our sister circuits, which
    unanimously agreed that the PSA’s proscription of unfair practices is aimed only
    at anti-competitive conduct. See id. at 358–60.1 Despite the lack of any explicit
    language in § 192(a) requiring an anti-competitive effect, we concluded that “an
    anti-competitive effect is necessary for an actionable claim under the PSA in
    light of the Act’s history in Congress and its consistent interpretation by the
    other circuits.” Id. at 362.
    Our decision in Wheeler leaves little doubt that § 192(e) proscribes only
    anti-competitive conduct. Moreover, unlike the broad language of § 192(a), §
    192(e) explicitly requires a purpose or effect of “manipulating or controlling
    1
    See also Terry v. Tyson Farms, Inc., 
    604 F.3d 272
    , 277 (6th Cir. 2010) (“The tide has
    now become a tidal wave . . . . All told, seven circuits—the Fourth, Fifth, Seventh, Eighth,
    Ninth, Tenth, and Eleventh Circuits—have now weighed in on this issue, with unanimous
    results.”) (citing cases).
    5
    Case: 12-40085        Document: 00512355307           Page: 6      Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    No. 12-40085
    prices.” Because the protection of natural price levels is the object of prohibitions
    against anti-competitive conduct, § 192(e) is clearly directed at conduct that is
    anti-competitive.2 See United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 
    310 U.S. 150
    , 223
    (1940).
    The express wording of § 192(e) bolsters this conclusion. Section 192(e)
    does not forbid all conduct which might affect prices, but only conduct that is
    designed to manipulate or control prices. In the absence of statutory definitions,
    “manipulation” ordinarily requires the use of deceptive or unfair means to
    accomplish something;3 “control” connotes the exercise of power or force to
    accomplish something that would not happen in the absence of interference.4 By
    using the words “manipulate” and “control” in § 192(e), Congress thus prohibited
    2
    Even the dissent in Wheeler conceded a requirement of anti-competitive effect in §
    192(e): “Subsections (c)–(e) [of § 192], unlike subsections (a) and (b), prohibit only those acts[]
    which have the effect of ‘restraining commerce’ or which produce another common antitrust
    injury, such as ‘creating a monopoly.’” See Wheeler, 
    591 F.3d at 374
     (Garza, J., dissenting).
    Although divided as to the meaning of § 192 (a)–(b), the Wheeler en banc court was thus
    unanimous that § 192(e) is not violated absent a showing of anti-competitive conduct.
    3
    See, e.g., Schreiber v. Burlington Northern, Inc., 
    472 U.S. 1
    , 12 (1985) (“We hold that
    the term ‘manipulative’ as used in [Securities Exchange Act] § 14(e) requires
    misrepresentation or nondisclosure. It connotes ‘conduct designed to deceive or defraud
    investors by controlling or artificially affecting the price of securities.’” (citation omitted));
    Ernst & Ernst v. Hochfelder, 
    425 U.S. 185
    , 199 (1976) (“[‘Manipulative’] connotes intentional
    or willful conduct designed to deceive or defraud investors by controlling or artificially
    affecting the price of securities.”); OXFORD ENGLISH DICTIONARY (defining “manipulate” to
    mean “to manage, control, or influence in a subtle, devious, or underhand manner;” “to cause
    (stocks, currency, a commodity, etc.) to rise or fall in value by affecting the market illicitly,
    improperly, or by contrived methods”).
    4
    See, e.g., In re ATM Fee Antitrust Litig., 
    686 F.3d 741
    , 757 (9th Cir. 2012) (“Control
    means ‘to exercise restraint or direction over; dominate, regulate, or command.’” (citation
    omitted)), petition for cert. Filed (July 11, 2013) (No. 13-63); Marcus & Millichap Inv. Servs.
    of Chicago, Inc., v. Sekulovski, 
    639 F.3d 301
     (7th Cir. 2011) (“‘[C]ontrol means that the
    employer has the right to control and direct the worker . . .’” (citation omitted)); OXFORD
    ENGLISH DICTIONARY (defining “control” to mean “to exercise restraint or direction upon the
    free action of; to hold sway over, exercise power or authority over; to dominate, command”).
    6
    Case: 12-40085       Document: 00512355307         Page: 7    Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    No. 12-40085
    only deceptive, illegitimate, or unnatural—i.e., anti-competitive—attempts to
    influence prices.
    The relevant question thus becomes whether PPC’s decision to reduce its
    chicken output was improper and anti-competitive. When evaluating competitive
    injury, we ordinarily rely upon a “rule of reason” analysis: in light of all the
    relevant facts, an action is unlawful only if it is likely to suppress or destroy
    competition. See Am. Needle, Inc. v. NFL, 
    130 S.Ct. 2201
    , 2216–17 (2010).5
    The growers’ alleged injury to competition stems entirely from PPC’s
    alleged intent to influence prices. However, we remain conscious of the fact that
    laws against anti-competitive conduct seek to protect competition, not low prices.
    Competition, of course, is merely the existence of genuine commercial rivalry.
    While we agree that a goal of competition is lower price levels, a unilateral
    attempt to raise prices, without more, is not inherently illicit or anti-
    competitive.6 As the Supreme Court explained in Spectrum Sports, Inc. v.
    McQuillan,
    The purpose of [antitrust law] is not to protect businesses from the
    working of the market; it is to protect the public from the failure of
    the market. The law directs itself not against conduct which is
    competitive, even severely so, but against conduct which unfairly
    tends to destroy competition itself. It does so not out of solicitude for
    private concerns but out of concern for the public interest.
    
    506 U.S. 447
    , 458 (1993). Moreover, because healthy competition depends on
    individual firms aggressively pursuing their own interests, we are particularly
    5
    See Pickett v. Tyson Fresh Markets, Inc., 
    420 F.3d 1272
    , 1280–85 (11th Cir. 2005)
    (applying de facto rule of reason analysis in PSA case); IBP, Inc. v. Glickman, 
    187 F.3d 974
    ,
    977–78 (8th Cir. 1999) (same).
    6
    See OXFORD ENGLISH DICTIONARY (defining competition as “the action of endeavouring
    to gain what another endeavours to gain at the same time; the striving of two or more for the
    same object; rivalry”).
    7
    Case: 12-40085        Document: 00512355307           Page: 8     Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    No. 12-40085
    hesitant to condemn the unilateral act of a single firm.7 See also Armour & Co.
    v. United States, 
    402 F.2d 712
    , 717 (7th Cir. 1968) (finding that absent
    “predatory intent” or “the likelihood of injury to competition,” the PSA is not
    violated).
    In the instant case, PPC had overextended itself into the commodity
    chicken market, was producing more chicken than the market appeared to need,
    and was thereby driving the market price of chicken down at great cost to itself.
    Recognizing the damage inflicted by its own excess production, PPC wisely
    decided to stop flooding the market with unprofitable chicken.8 Not surprisingly,
    we have located no case finding such conduct to be unfair, illegal, or injurious to
    competition; in truth, PPC’s unilateral conduct had nothing to do with
    competition. Even if PPC hoped that chicken prices would respond to the output
    reduction by settling at a higher equilibrium price, that would not alter our
    conclusion.9 Far from being a nefarious goal, higher prices are the natural
    consequence of a reduction in supply.10 If it is lawful for a business to
    independently control its own output, then it is also lawful for the business to
    hope for the natural consequences of its actions.11
    7
    See Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 
    467 U.S. 752
    , 767–69 (1984).
    8
    This is not the type of pro-competitive business justification which arguably must be
    properly pled as an affirmative defense to a prima facie showing of anti-competitive conduct.
    See NCAA v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 
    468 U.S. 85
    , 113 (1984). This is merely evidence
    relevant to whether there was any underlying anti-competitive conduct to begin with. See
    American Needle, 
    130 S.Ct. at
    2216–17.
    9
    See American Needle, 
    130 S.Ct. at
    2216 n.10 (recognizing that even a devious
    intention will not necessarily de-legitimize an otherwise permissible act, “‘because knowledge
    of intent [is to] help the court to interpret facts and to predict consequences.’” (quoting Bd. of
    Trade of Chicago v. United States, 
    246 U.S. 231
    , 238 (1918)).
    10
    See PAUL A. SAMUELSON, ECONOMICS 56–60 (11th ed. 1980).
    11
    We separately note that the district court found that PPC did not violate PSA §
    192(a) because it did not engage in any “unfair” or “deceptive” practices. As some courts have
    described this provision as the PSA’s “catchall,” it would be anomalous to conclude that PPC
    8
    Case: 12-40085       Document: 00512355307          Page: 9     Date Filed: 08/27/2013
    No. 12-40085
    PPC’s conduct was merely the legitimate response of a rational market
    participant to changes in a dynamic market. If a firm inadvertently over-
    produces a good and drives down prices, it does not break the law by cutting
    production so that prices may recover. We therefore hold that PPC did not
    violate PSA § 192(e) by reducing its commodity chicken output.
    IV.
    For the reasons stated above, the judgment of the district court is
    REVERSED, and judgment is RENDERED in favor of PPC.
    REVERSED and RENDERED.
    did not do anything unfair or deceptive, but that it did illegitimately attempt to manipulate
    or control prices. See Been v. O.K. Indus., Inc., 
    495 F.3d 1217
    , 1229 (10th Cir. 2007).
    While a better argument could be made that PPC violated the PSA by intentionally
    creating a chicken supply shortage, nothing in the record supports that assertion. Moreover,
    in the months following the El Dorado facility’s idling, the total domestic supply of commodity
    chicken actually increased. Thus, the chicken processing industry either had enough new
    entrants or enough unused capacity to immediately compensate for any supply shortage
    created by PPC.
    9