Chamber of Com of the USA v. SEC ( 2023 )


Menu:
  • Case: 23-60255     Document: 00516951547         Page: 1     Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    United States Court of Appeals
    for the Fifth Circuit
    United States Court of Appeals
    Fifth Circuit
    FILED
    ____________
    October 31, 2023
    No. 23-60255                       Lyle W. Cayce
    ____________                              Clerk
    Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America;
    Longview Chamber of Commerce;
    Texas Association of Business,
    Petitioners,
    versus
    United States Securities and Exchange Commission,
    Respondent.
    ______________________________
    Appeal from an Order of
    the Securities and Exchange Commission
    Agency Nos. 34-97424,
    
    88 Fed. Reg. 36002
    , IC-34906
    ______________________________
    Before Smith, Southwick, and Higginson, Circuit Judges.
    Jerry E. Smith, Circuit Judge:
    The Securities and Exchange Commission (“SEC”) adopted a rule
    requiring issuers to report day-to-day share repurchase data once a quarter
    and to disclose the reason why the issuer repurchased shares of its own stock.
    We consider a challenge to that rule by petitioners Chamber of Commerce of
    the United States, Longview Chamber of Commerce, and Texas Association
    of Business (“petitioners”).
    Case: 23-60255      Document: 00516951547          Page: 2   Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    I.
    Publicly traded companies have a responsibility to their shareholders
    to allocate capital in the most efficient way possible. One way in which com-
    panies fulfill this responsibility is by reinvesting capital in themselves by
    repurchasing their own shares. Such repurchases are common and occur
    whenever an issuer of securities (“issuer”) purchases its own stock.
    There are many different reasons why a company might repurchase
    its shares. Some of those reasons are for the benefit of shareholders, as when
    a company repurchases its own shares because it believes they are under-
    valued. Others could make investors less likely to buy or retain shares, as
    where a repurchase is motivated by a desire to achieve accounting metrics or
    to impact executive compensation.
    In response to increasing public skepticism of share repurchases, the
    SEC conducted a study on buybacks and why issuers repurchase their own
    shares. The study concluded that repurchasing shares can be an efficient use
    of capital and may indicate that an issuer’s shares are undervalued.
    The SEC, however, still believed investors could benefit from en-
    hanced repurchase disclosures designed to address supposed information
    asymmetries between investors and issuers as to why an issuer was repur-
    chasing its shares. The SEC’s rationale was that, because a share repurchase
    could signal either that the issuer’s shares were undervalued (and hence an
    attractive investment) or that the company was attempting to boost its met-
    rics (and hence a poor investment), shareholders, in order to make fully
    informed investment decisions, needed to know why a company was repur-
    chasing its shares.
    2
    Case: 23-60255       Document: 00516951547             Page: 3      Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    The SEC proposed a rule to address that concern. 1 The proposed rule
    required issuers to report certain repurchase data within one business day of
    the repurchase and to disclose the reason why the issuer was repurchasing its
    shares. The proposed rule stated that the SEC was unable to quantify most
    of the economic effects of the proposed amendments. Thus, the SEC relied
    primarily on a qualitative assessment of the rule’s potential effects, while
    encouraging commenters to provide information that could help quantify the
    costs and benefits of the proposed rule. The SEC solicited comments on the
    proposed rule during a 45-day comment period, which was reopened briefly
    to account for a technical difficulty in submitting comments. 2 The comment
    period was again reopened, this time for 30 days, to allow for new comments
    regarding the impact of an excise tax imposed by the Inflation Reduction
    Act. 3
    During the comment period, petitioners submitted guidance explain-
    ing how the SEC could quantify the proposed rule’s effects. Specifically,
    petitioners alerted the SEC to empirical data from academic sources and
    information available in existing SEC disclosures that could be used to quan-
    tify the economic effects of the proposed rule.
    The SEC adopted the final rule on May 3, 2023. As with the proposed
    _____________________
    1
    The SEC issued this rule under the Exchange Act of 1934, 
    Pub. L. No. 73-291, 48
     Stat. 881 (1934) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 78a et seq.), and the Investment
    Company Act of 1940, 
    Pub. L. No. 76-768, 54
     Stat. 789 (1940) (codified as amended at
    15 U.S.C. § 80a-1 et seq). No party disputes the SEC’s statutory authority to promulgate
    the final rule.
    2
    Resubmission of Comments and Reopening of Comment Periods for Several
    Rulemaking Releases due to a Technological Error in Receiving Certain Comments,
    
    87 Fed. Reg. 63016
    , 63016–17 (Oct. 18, 2022).
    3
    Reopening of Comment Period for Share Repurchase Disclosure Modernization,
    
    87 Fed. Reg. 75975
    , 75975–77 (Dec. 12, 2022).
    3
    Case: 23-60255      Document: 00516951547           Page: 4    Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    rule, the final rule requires issuers to disclose their reasons for repurchasing
    shares (“the rationale-disclosure requirement”). The final rule also requires
    issuers to collect repurchase data on a day-to-day basis, but in contrast to the
    proposed rule, issuers need file this day-to-day data only once per quarter
    (“the daily-disclosure requirement”).
    Despite petitioners’ comments, however, the SEC maintained that
    many of the effects of the daily-disclosure requirement could not be quan-
    tified. The SEC did, however, perform a cost-benefit analysis for both the
    rationale-disclosure requirement and the daily-disclosure requirement. The
    agency continued to believe that the final rule would help investors evaluate
    whether a share repurchase was intended to increase the value of the issuer’s
    shares or, instead, was undertaken for a purpose unrelated to the market
    value of the issuer’s shares.
    On May 12, 2023, petitioners filed a petition for review of the final rule
    with this court. See 15 U.S.C. § 80a-42(a). They assert that (1) the rationale-
    disclosure requirement violates the First Amendment by impermissibly com-
    pelling their speech; (2) the SEC acted arbitrarily and capriciously in adopt-
    ing the final rule by not considering their comments or conducting a proper
    cost benefit analysis; and (3) the SEC did not provide the public with a mean-
    ingful opportunity to comment.
    II.
    We review the SEC’s answers to purely legal questions de novo. Tex.
    Clinical Labs, Inc. v. Sebelius, 
    612 F.3d 771
    , 775 (5th Cir. 2010). Factual find-
    ings the SEC has “identified . . . as the basis, in whole or part, of the rule”
    are “conclusive” if “supported by substantial evidence.”             15 U.S.C.
    § 78y(b)(4). “We review constitutional issues de novo.” Huawei Techs. USA,
    Inc. v. FCC, 
    2 F.4th 421
    , 434 (5th Cir. 2021).
    The Administrative Procedure Act (“APA”) requires us to “set
    4
    Case: 23-60255      Document: 00516951547          Page: 5    Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    aside” agency actions found to be “arbitrary [or] capricious,” “contrary to
    constitutional right,” or “without observance of procedure required by law.”
    
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A)–(B), (D); see also 15 U.S.C. § 78y(b)(4). Arbitrary-and-
    capricious review requires this court to scrutinize the record to determine
    whether the agency has “examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a
    satisfactory explanation for its action including a rational connection between
    the facts found and the choice made.” Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n of U.S., Inc.
    v. State Farm Mut. Auto Ins. Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 43 (1983) (cleaned up). We
    “may not supply a reasoned basis for the agency’s decision that the agency
    itself has not given.” 
    Id.
     Finally, we “must set aside any action premised on
    reasoning that fails to account for relevant factors or evinces a clear error of
    judgment.” Univ. of Tex. M.D. Anderson Cancer Ctr. v. U.S. Dep’t of Health
    & Hum. Servs., 
    985 F.3d 472
    , 475 (5th Cir. 2021) (cleaned up).
    III.
    We turn first to petitioners’ claim that the rationale-disclosure
    requirement violates the First Amendment by impermissibly compelling
    their speech. The First Amendment “includes both the right to speak freely
    and the right to refrain from speaking.” Wooley v. Maynard, 
    430 U.S. 705
    ,
    714 (1977). Thus, laws compelling speech normally trigger strict scrutiny and
    “may be justified only if the government proves that they are narrowly tai-
    lored to serve compelling state interests.” Nat’l Inst. Fam. & Life Advocs. v.
    Becerra (“NIFLA”), 
    138 S. Ct. 2361
    , 2371 (2018) (cleaned up). But lesser
    scrutiny applies when the government compels disclosures in the context of
    commercial speech because “the extension of First Amendment protection
    to commercial speech is justified principally by the value to consumers of the
    information such speech provides.” See Zauderer v. Off. Disciplinary Couns.
    Sup. Ct. Ohio, 
    471 U.S. 626
    , 651 (1985).
    This means that “[s]tates may require commercial enterprises to dis-
    5
    Case: 23-60255        Document: 00516951547              Page: 6      Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    close ‘purely factual and uncontroversial information’ about their services”
    so long as those disclosures are “reasonably related to a legitimate state
    interest” and not “unjustified or unduly burdensome.” 4 The SEC’s primary
    defense to petitioner’s constitutional challenge is that the rationale-
    disclosure requirement is governed by Zauderer and that it can survive the
    lower level of scrutiny. Therefore, we must determine whether Zauderer
    applies because the rationale-disclosure requirement compels issuers to
    disclose “purely factual and uncontroversial information” in the context of
    commercial speech. See Zauderer, 471 U.S. at 651. 5 If so, the rationale-
    disclosure requirement is constitutionally permissible so long as it “reasona-
    bly relate[s] to a legitimate state interest” and is not “‘unjustified or unduly
    burdensome.’” See NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 585 (quoting Zauderer, 471 U.S.
    at 651).
    1. Zauderer applies because the rationale-disclosure requirement compels
    the disclosure of factual and uncontroversial information in the context of
    commercial speech.
    First, Zauderer’s lower level of scrutiny applies only to compelled dis-
    closures that are “purely factual.” See 471 U.S. at 651. Petitioners assert that
    the rationale-disclosure requirement compels issuers to disclose their rea-
    sons for repurchasing stock and that by its very nature, an issuer’s subjective
    _____________________
    4
    See NetChoice, L.L.C. v. Paxton, 
    49 F.4th 439
    , 485 (5th Cir. 2022) (quoting
    Zauderer, 471 U.S. at 651), cert. granted, 
    2023 WL 6319650
     (Sept. 29, 2023). The grant of
    certiorari does not change the fact that NetChoice remains binding precedent unless and
    until the Supreme Court says otherwise. See Wicker v. McCotter, 
    798 F.2d 155
    , 157–58 (5th
    Cir. 1986).
    5 The parties do not dispute that the rationale-disclosure requirement compels dis-
    closures only where issuers engage in commercial speech, so we need only determine
    whether the rationale-disclosure requirement compels purely factual, uncontroversial
    speech.
    6
    Case: 23-60255        Document: 00516951547             Page: 7      Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    opinion about the business benefits of its actions cannot be a purely factual
    disclosure. Essentially, petitioners urge that any compelled disclosure that
    requires an issuer to explain why it is repurchasing stock cannot be a purely
    factual disclosure. That contention, however, is foreclosed by NetChoice.
    NetChoice dealt with a First Amendment challenge to Texas Business
    & Commerce Code § 120.103(a)(1), which regulates large social media plat-
    forms. That provision “obligate[d] the Platforms to explain their content
    removal decisions.” 6        NetChoice analyzed the constitutionality of Sec-
    tion 120.103(a)(1) under Zauderer and held that forcing social media
    platforms to explain their reasons for removing content compelled “disclos-
    ures that consist of purely factual and uncontroversial information.” See
    NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 485–88 (cleaned up).
    NetChoice stands for the proposition that forcing a company to
    “explain the reason” for its actions is a purely factual disclosure. See id.
    at 446, 485. If forcing a social media company to explain why it removed
    posts compels a purely factual disclosure, it follows that forcing issuers to
    explain why they are repurchasing their shares also compels a purely factual
    disclosure.
    Although petitioners’ reply brief all but concedes that NetChoice
    applies, they instead attempt to minimize the opinion’s impact. They assert
    that this part of NetChoice was dictum because NetChoice supposedly did not
    dispute that its reasons for removing content constituted purely factual infor-
    mation. But that is not so: Though NetChoice’s brief could have done a
    better job at articulating Zauderer’s standard, it did repeatedly contend that
    _____________________
    6
    NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 485; Tex. Bus. & Com. Code § 120.103(a)(1) (“[T]he
    social medial platform shall . . . notify the user who provided the content of the removal
    and explain the reason the content was removed.”).
    7
    Case: 23-60255         Document: 00516951547                Page: 8       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    Zauderer did not apply because the Texas statute compelled disclosures that
    were not purely factual, uncontroversial information. 7 Therefore, determin-
    ing that Zauderer applied was “necessary to the holding of the case” and thus
    was not dictum. Cf. FDIC v. Enventure V, 
    77 F.3d 123
    , 125 (5th Cir. 1996).
    And since NetChoice could not determine whether Zauderer applied without
    deciding whether § 120.103(a)(1) compelled purely factual and uncontrover-
    sial information, its holding in this respect was also authoritative. See
    NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 485–88.
    In sum, petitioners do not try to distinguish this matter from Net-
    Choice. Nor can they, for we held there that a law requiring companies to
    explain the reasons behind their actions compelled the disclosure of purely
    factual information. Here too, the rationale-disclosure requirement compels
    issuers to explain their reasons for repurchasing shares. That is a purely fac-
    tual disclosure under NetChoice.
    Second, even if a compelled disclosure is purely factual, Zauderer’s
    lower level of scrutiny applies only to compelled disclosures concerning
    “uncontroversial information.” See Zauderer, 471 U.S. at 651. Petitioners
    contend that Zauderer cannot apply because the rationale-disclosure require-
    ment forces the issuers to opine on share repurchases, a topic they consider
    to be one of the most controversial corporate decisions an issuer can make.
    _____________________
    7
    See, e.g., Brief of Appellees, at 16, NetChoice, L.L.C. v. Paxton, 
    49 F.4th 439
    , 485–
    87 (5th Cir. 2022) (No. 21-51178) (“Nor can [the Texas law] be saved under the (in-
    apposite) commercial-speech doctrine or the limited Zauderer doctrine, which applies only
    to non-burdensome, purely factual commercial disclosure requirements.”); id. at 52
    (“This case, therefore, is not governed by the Zauderer test for compelled speech in com-
    mercial advertising.”). NetChoice also recognized that the platforms disputed whether
    Zauderer applied. See NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 487 (“[T]he platforms claim the Zauderer
    standard does not apply to disclosure laws that implicate the editorial process—that is, laws
    requiring publishers to disclose their editorial policies or explain how they exercise editorial
    discretion.”).
    8
    Case: 23-60255      Document: 00516951547           Page: 9    Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    That contention is also foreclosed by NetChoice.
    As explained above, NetChoice held that forcing social media plat-
    forms to explain their reasons for removing content compelled “disclosures
    that consist of purely factual and uncontroversial information.” See 49 F.4th
    at 485 (cleaned up). It is hard to think of a more controversial topic in current
    public discourse than content moderation and social media censorship. If a
    social media company’s reason for removing user content was uncontro-
    versial in NetChoice, then an issuer’s reason for repurchasing its own shares
    is uncontroversial here.
    Petitions rely on NIFLA to contend that the rationale-disclosure
    requirement is controversial. Their reliance is misplaced. NIFLA held that
    Zauderer was inapplicable to clinics that were forced to disclose information
    about state-sponsored abortion services, a topic that the Supreme Court
    described as “anything but . . . uncontroversial.” NIFLA, 
    138 S. Ct. at 2372
    (cleaned up). All NIFLA says is that abortion is too controversial a topic for
    Zauderer to govern compelled speech relating to it. See 
    id.
     The case is consis-
    tent with NetChoice’s determination that a social media company’s reasons
    for removing content are uncontroversial. Petitioners, in essence, invite us
    to hold that the reasons behind a share repurchase are so much more contro-
    versial than the reasons behind social media censorship that they engender a
    similar level of controversy as does abortion. We decline that invitation.
    NetChoice governs and requires us to hold that the rationale-disclosure
    requirement compels only uncontroversial information.
    In summary, then, the rationale-disclosure requirement compels
    issuers to disclose “purely factual and uncontroversial information” in the
    context of commercial speech, and its constitutionality is governed by
    Zauderer.
    9
    Case: 23-60255        Document: 00516951547               Page: 10        Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    2. The rationale-disclosure requirement satisfies Zauderer because the rule
    is justified, is reasonably related to a legitimate state interest, and does not burden
    petitioners’ protected speech.
    Zauderer allows “[s]tates [to] require commercial enterprises to dis-
    close ‘purely factual and uncontroversial information’ about their services”
    so long as those disclosures are not “‘unjustified or unduly burdensome’”
    and are “reasonably related to a legitimate state interest.” NetChoice,
    49 F.4th at 485 (quoting Zauderer, 471 U.S. at 651). The SEC bears the bur-
    den of showing that the rationale-disclosure requirement is neither unjusti-
    fied nor unduly burdensome. NIFLA, 
    138 S. Ct. at 2377
    . 8 The SEC has sat-
    isfied that burden.
    First, a compelled disclosure cannot be permitted if it is “unjusti-
    fied.” Zauderer, 471 U.S. at 651. That means the disclosure must be “rea-
    sonably related to a legitimate state interest” such that it “remed[ies] a harm
    that is potentially real not purely hypothetical.” NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 485;
    NIFLA, 
    138 S. Ct. at 2377
     (internal quotation marks omitted). A compelled
    disclosure is reasonably related to a legitimate state interest when it is “no
    broader than reasonably necessary” to further that interest. See NIFLA,
    
    138 S. Ct. at 2377
     (internal quotation marks omitted).
    In contrast, a compelled disclosure has purely hypothetical benefits
    when the government “points to nothing” supporting its interest. See 
    id.
    _____________________
    8
    Despite language in NetChoice that could be read as describing the reasonable-
    relation requirement as a separate prong of Zauderer, the opinion makes clear that assessing
    whether a compelled disclosure is reasonably related to a legitimate state interest is how we
    determine whether a compelled disclosure is justified. See NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 485
    (“Texas argues—and the Platforms do not dispute —that Section 2 advances the State’s
    interest . . . Therefore, the only question is whether the State has carried its burden to show
    that the three categories of disclosures required by Section 2 are not unduly
    burdensome.”).
    10
    Case: 23-60255     Document: 00516951547           Page: 11    Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    Any assumptions the government makes in justifying the compelled disclo-
    sure must be more than “speculative.” Zauderer, 471 U.S. at 652.
    The SEC has a legitimate interest in promoting the free flow of com-
    mercial information. See Lamar Outdoor Adver. Inc., v. Miss. State Tax
    Comm’n, 
    701 F.2d 314
    , 323 (5th Cir. 1983). The rationale-disclosure require-
    ment is reasonably related to that interest. The SEC adopted the require-
    ment because of a supposed asymmetry in information surrounding the rea-
    sons issuers repurchase their shares. The SEC cited empirical evidence dem-
    onstrating that issuers could have many different reasons for repurchasing
    shares. Some, such as increasing the value of the shares, are beneficial to
    investors. Others, such as a desire to achieve accounting metrics or impact
    executive compensation, could make purchasers less inclined to invest.
    The stated purpose of the rationale-disclosure requirement is to allow
    investors to separate out and assess the different motivations behind, and
    impacts of, share repurchases. In the SEC’s view, when investors know why
    a company is repurchasing its shares, they can better evaluate whether a share
    repurchase was intended to increase the value of the issuer or, instead, rep-
    resented an inefficient deployment of capital. Contra NIFLA, 
    138 S. Ct. at 2377
     (“California points to nothing” supporting its interest).
    These rationales may not be enough to survive APA review—see infra
    part IV—but they are more than enough to satisfy this prong of Zauderer.
    The SEC has demonstrated that the information asymmetry surrounding
    share repurchases is a “potentially real not purely hypothetical” harm to
    investors. See NIFLA, 
    138 S. Ct. at 2377
     (internal quotation marks omitted).
    The rationale-disclosure rule reaches no broader than necessary to address
    this harm because the only speech it compels relates directly to alleviating the
    information asymmetry.
    We need not be persuaded by the SEC’s reasoning to hold that the
    11
    Case: 23-60255     Document: 00516951547           Page: 12    Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    benefits of the rationale-disclosure rule are more than purely hypothetical.
    Therefore, the rationale-disclosure rule is justified as that word is used in
    Zauderer.
    Second, even if a compelled commercial disclosure is justified, it still
    violates the constitution if it “unduly burden[s]” a speaker’s “protected
    commercial speech.” NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 486 (cleaned up). In NIFLA,
    the Court held that a California statue compelling a provider of pregnancy-
    related services to include a government-sponsored message in promotional
    materials was unduly burdensome. See 
    138 S. Ct. at
    2377–78. The statute
    required the inclusion of a lengthy message emphasized “by some method
    such as larger text or contrasting type or color.” 
    Id. at 2378
    . That was unduly
    burdensome because it “drown[ed] out the facility’s own message.” 
    Id.
    Here, in contrast, the rationale-disclosure requirement neither bur-
    dens issuers’ protected speech nor drowns out their message. The issuer is
    free to speak (or not) however and whenever it wishes apart from a privately
    crafted explanation of its reasons for repurchasing shares. That is a far lesser
    burden than was the California law the Court found unduly burdensome in
    NIFLA, which mandated a “29-word statement from the government, in as
    many as 13 different languages.” See 
    id.
     A requirement that compels speech
    solely within the narrow confines of SEC filings is not the type of forced dis-
    closure that would meaningfully “chill protected commercial speech.”
    NetChoice, 49 F.4th at 486 (cleaned up).
    In sum, the rationale-disclosure requirement is not unduly burden-
    some, and because both elements of the Zauderer test are met, the require-
    ment passes constitutional muster.
    IV.
    Petitioners claim that the final rule violates the APA. They aver the
    SEC acted arbitrarily and capriciously when it failed to (1) quantitatively
    12
    Case: 23-60255         Document: 00516951547                 Page: 13        Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    analyze the economic implications of its proposed rule whenever feasible,
    (2) respond to petitioners’ comments about the agency’s economic implica-
    tions analysis adequately, and (3) substantiate the proposed rule’s benefits
    adequately. 9
    1. The SEC is not required to quantify economic implications generally.
    The Exchange Act and the Investment Companies Act (“ICA”)
    require the SEC to consider “whether [an] action will promote efficiency,
    competition, and capital formation” whenever it engages in rulemaking and
    is “required to consider or determine whether an action is “necessary or
    appropriate in the public interest,” 15 U.S.C. § 78c(f), or “consistent with
    the public interest,” id. § 80a-2(c). Those two statutory commands, peti-
    tioners urge, require the SEC to “determine as best it can the economic
    implications of the rule it has proposed.” Chamber of Com. of U.S. v. SEC,
    
    412 F.3d 133
    , 143 (D.C. Cir. 2005). According to petitioners, quantitative
    data is the “best” data, so they adduce the SEC cannot rely merely on quali-
    tative analyses without first explaining why a rule’s costs and benefits “could
    not be quantified.” In other words, petitioners contend that a qualitative
    economic impact analysis will satisfy SEC’s statutory obligation only where
    it is unable feasibly to conduct any quantitative analysis.
    The SEC disagrees, positing that it is duty-bound only to conduct a
    “reasonable and reasonably explained” analysis. Huawei, 2 F.4th at 452
    _____________________
    9
    Petitioners raise three additional reasons the rule is arbitrary and capricious. Spe-
    cifically, they contend the SEC (1) failed to consider adequately whether the additional dis-
    closures would overwhelm retail investors and disincentivize information collection
    efforts; (2) ignored fixed costs in its analysis of the share repurchase excise tax; and (3) did
    not consider all costs and benefits it identified in its analysis of the rule’s overall effect. But
    as we explain in the main text, each of petitioners’ primary contentions justifies granting
    the petition for review. It is therefore unnecessary for us to resolve petitioners’ additional
    theories.
    13
    Case: 23-60255          Document: 00516951547             Page: 14    Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    (internal quotation marks omitted). The agency states that it “need not base
    its every action upon empirical data and may reasonably conduct a general
    analysis based on informed conjecture.” Nasdaq Stock Mkt. L.L.C. v. SEC,
    
    34 F.4th 1105
    , 1111 (D.C. Cir. 2022) (cleaned up).
    We agree with the SEC that, as a general matter, it is not required to
    undertake a quantitative analysis to determine a proposed rule’s economic
    implications. The relevant statutory provisions providing the SEC with rule-
    making authority do not stipulate such a requirement—they merely com-
    mand the SEC to “consider . . . whether the action will promote efficiency,
    competition, and capital formation.” 15 U.S.C. §§ 78c(f), 80a-2(c). Per the
    text, the agency is only told to “consider,” and that term—shorn of modifiers
    or limiters—does not restrict the universe of otherwise permissible methods
    by which the SEC can analyze the economic implications of a proposed rule.
    Nor do the statutorily stipulated objects of consideration lend any sup-
    port to petitioners’ position. A rigorous quantitative cost-benefit analysis is
    one way—but not the only way—to determine whether a proposed rule “pro-
    mote[s] efficiency, competition, and capital formation.” Id. Accordingly,
    there is no textual basis to conclude that the SEC must analyze economic
    impacts using quantitative methods whenever it is feasible. 10
    Petitioners, citing Business Roundtable v. SEC 11 and Chamber of Com-
    merce, maintain the D.C. Circuit has concluded to the contrary. Not so.
    _____________________
    10
    Nor could such a quantitative analysis requirement be read into the relevant
    statutory provisions. “Where Congress has required ‘rigorous, quantitative economic
    analysis,’ it has made that requirement clear in the agency’s statute.” Inv. Co. Inst. v.
    CFTC, 
    720 F.3d 370
    , 379 (D.C. Cir. 2013) (quoting Am. Fin. Servs. Ass’n v. FTC, 
    767 F.2d 957
    , 986 (D.C. Cir. 1985)); see, e.g., 
    2 U.S.C. § 1532
    (a)(2) (mandating “a qualitative and
    quantitative assessment of the anticipated costs and benefits” (emphasis added)). No such
    statutory requirement is imposed here.
    11
    
    647 F.3d 1144
     (D.C. Cir. 2011).
    14
    Case: 23-60255       Document: 00516951547              Page: 15       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    Neither lends support to their theory that the Exchange Act and ICA require
    the SEC to conduct a quantitative economic analysis whenever feasible.
    In Chamber of Commerce, the D.C. Circuit held that difficulties in
    determining a rule’s precise costs “d[id] not excuse the [SEC] from its
    statutory obligation” because the agency could still have provided a “range
    within which [the] cost . . . will fall.” 412 F.3d at 143. And Business Round-
    table held that SEC’s failure adequately to “quantify the certain costs or to
    explain why those costs could not be quantified” was one basis justifying
    vacatur. 
    647 F.3d at 1149
    . But in Chamber of Commerce, SEC “stopped” its
    cost analysis after asserting “it had no ‘reliable basis for estimating those
    costs.’” 12 Similarly, in Business Roundtable, SEC’s prediction “had no basis
    beyond mere speculation” and was functionally equivalent to no economic
    impact analysis at all. 
    647 F.3d at 1150
    .
    Neither case restricts the SEC’s ability to rely on a qualitative analysis
    for its determination of economic impact. 13 Neither Chamber of Commerce
    nor Business Roundtable supports petitioners’ reasoning. It is within the
    agency’s discretion 14 to determine the mode of analysis that most allows it
    “to determine as best it can the economic implications of the rule it has
    _____________________
    12
    412 F.3d at 144 (quoting Investment Company Governance, 
    69 Fed. Reg. 46378
    ,
    46387 n.81 (Aug. 2, 2004)).
    13
    See Nasdaq, 34 F.4th at 1113 (distinguishing Business Roundtable since SEC
    “explained in detail why [the rule’s effect on] competition would ultimately benefit
    investors”).
    14
    Such discretion is still bounded by default APA requirements. First, the SEC
    cannot act arbitrarily and capriciously in choosing the mode of analysis that it uses to
    analyze the economic implications of its proposed rule. Second, regardless of the mode of
    analysis chosen, the agency “must cogently explain why it has exercised its discretion in a
    given manner and must offer a rational connection between the facts found and the choice
    made.” Corrosion Proof Fittings v. EPA, 
    947 F.2d 1201
    , 1214 (5th Cir. 1991) (cleaned up)
    (quoting Chem. Mfrs. Ass’n v. EPA, 
    899 F.2d 344
    , 359 (5th Cir. 1990).
    15
    Case: 23-60255       Document: 00516951547              Page: 16       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    proposed.” Chamber of Commerce, 412 F.3d at 143.
    2. The SEC failed to respond to petitioners’ comments.
    Petitioners contend that the SEC failed to respond to their comments
    about the proposed rules’ economic implications. Under the arbitrary-and-
    capricious standard, the SEC must show that it has “reasonably considered
    the relevant issues and reasonably explained the decision.” FCC v. Prome-
    theus Radio Project, 
    141 S. Ct. 1150
    , 1158 (2021). That requires the agency to
    consider all relevant factors raised by the public comments and provide a
    response to significant points within. See Huawei, 2 F.4th at 449. Comments
    the agency must respond to include those that “can be thought to challenge
    a fundamental premise underlying the proposed agency decision” 15 or
    include points that “if true and adopted would require a change in an
    agency’s proposed rule.” 16
    The SEC, in its proposed rule, stated that “[m]any of the [economic]
    effects . . . cannot be quantified.” Share Repurchase Disclosure Moderniza-
    tion, 
    87 Fed. Reg. 8443
    , 8451 (Feb. 15, 2022). That prompted the agency to
    do two things: First, it “encourage[d] commenters to provide data and
    information that would help quantify the benefits, costs, and the potential
    impacts of the proposed amendments on efficiency, competition, and capital
    formation.” 
    Id.
     Second, for the economic effects the SEC asserted it was
    “unable to quantify,” the agency “provide[d] a qualitative assessment.” 
    Id.
    Indeed, in both the proposed and final rule, the SEC claimed that it provided
    quantified economic effects “wherever possible.” Id.; Share Repurchase
    _____________________
    15
    Carlson v. Postal Regul. Comm’n, 
    938 F.3d 337
    , 344 (D.C. Cir. 2019) (cleaned up)
    (quoting MCI WorldCom, Inc. v. FCC, 
    209 F.3d 760
    , 765 (D.C. Cir. 2000)).
    16
    Mexican Gulf Fishing Co. v. U.S. Dep’t of Com., 
    60 F.4th 956
    , 971 (5th Cir. 2023)
    (cleaned up) (quoting Huawei, 2 F.4th at 449).
    16
    Case: 23-60255        Document: 00516951547               Page: 17       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    Disclosure Modernization, 
    88 Fed. Reg. 36002
    , 36029 (June 1, 2023).
    Petitioners maintain—and we agree—that is not so.
    Petitioners point to three suggestions they submitted to the SEC that
    explained how the agency could quantify the proposed rule’s effects. They
    suggested the SEC should quantify
    1. “the percentage of issuers’ annual and long-term incentive plans that is
    tied to [earnings per share] and how it correlates with buybacks” based
    on readily available “academic databases” that “provide detailed data on
    executive compensation”;
    2. “how many issuers used share repurchases to trigger an executive bonus
    that would not have been earned without repurchasing shares” and “the
    total executive compensation awarded from potentially opportunistic
    buybacks.” They note a British study had conducted such an estimate for
    U.K. issuers, and the SEC could just “replicate the threshold analysis”
    of that study using preexisting U.S. data;
    3. “the incremental benefits of potential reductions in asymmetric infor-
    mation stemming from the proposed amendments” by (i) “examin[ing]
    how investors react to more frequent repurchase disclosure” in other
    jurisdictions; (ii) using existing studies to “compare liquidity measures of
    similarly sized issuers operating in the same industry that conduct buy-
    backs across countries” with different disclosure frequencies; or
    (iii) examining the movement of stock prices on days that repurchases are
    disclosed in jurisdictions with daily reporting.
    The SEC admits it never considered any of petitioners’ suggestions. 17
    _____________________
    17
    Oral argument was the first time the SEC attempted to engage with the substance
    of petitioners’ suggestions. That’s too late. We don’t evaluate post-hoc justifications, given
    that “an agency’s action must be upheld, if at all, on the basis articulated by the agency
    itself.” BNSF Ry. Co. v. Fed. R.R. Admin., 
    62 F.4th 905
    , 910–11 (5th Cir. 2023) (cleaned
    17
    Case: 23-60255     Document: 00516951547             Page: 18   Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    On appeal, it instead blames petitioners for failing to (1) “identify any
    specific [data] already available that the Commission should have used,” and
    (2) raise points which, if true and adopted, would require a change in an
    agency’s proposed rule. See Huawei, 2 F.4th at 449, 453. There is no merit
    to either of the SEC’s post-hoc justifications:
    The first justification—that the suggestions did not identify data—is
    demonstrably false. Petitioners’ first suggestion flagged academic databases
    containing datasets from the Incentive Lab by Institutional Shareholder Ser-
    vices. The second suggestion points to existing SEC disclosures. And the
    last expressly references existing academic studies with similar empirical
    analyses. Such datasets and academic studies are a far cry from the com-
    ments at issue in Huawei that failed to “identify relevant cost data the agency
    ignored.” 2 F.4th at 453 (emphasis removed). The Huawei comments were
    “asserted without evidence,” “speculative,” and devoid of any “factual
    basis.” Id. at 453–54. Petitioners’ suggestions, in contrast, include specific
    references to readily available data as well as explanations on “how the SEC
    could use these data to quantify the [r]ule’s effects.”
    The agency’s second justification—that petitioners’ suggestions did
    not raise points that, if true and adopted, would require a change in the pro-
    posed rule—is also meritless. The SEC, relying on Prometheus, avers that
    “[t]he APA imposes no general obligation on agencies to conduct or com-
    mission their own empirical or statistical studies.” 141 S. Ct. at 1160.
    The SEC’s reliance on Prometheus is misplaced. There, the FCC had
    “repeatedly asked for data” but “received no data” other than the materially
    incomplete dataset it already possessed and ultimately relied upon. 141 S. Ct.
    at 1159 (cleaned up). That is not so with the rulemaking at issue in this case:
    _____________________
    up).
    18
    Case: 23-60255     Document: 00516951547           Page: 19   Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    The SEC did receive new data in response to its solicitation. Indeed, in the
    proposed rule, the SEC expressly asked for and “encourage[d]” commenta-
    tors to provide “data and information that would help quantify the benefits,
    costs, and the potential impacts of the proposed rule on efficiency, com-
    petition, and capital formation.” 87 Fed. Reg. at 8451. And that’s exactly
    what petitioners did—provide data that was either readily accessible to, or
    already in the possession of, the SEC.
    It is hard to fault petitioners for giving the SEC exactly what it had
    asked for. And that factual distinction makes all the difference: Critical to
    the holding in Prometheus was the FCC’s reliance on both “the data it had”
    and “the absence of any countervailing evidence.” 141 S. Ct. at 1159. Prome-
    theus thus stands for the proposition that an agency need not create data that
    doesn’t already exist. It offers no support for the SEC’s decision to ask for—
    and then ignore—already-existing data it did not want to consider.
    Undeterred, the SEC then characterizes petitioners’ comments as
    mere “recommendation[s] to conduct new studies that [they] contend might
    produce useful data.” That is incorrect. All three suggestions address costs
    and benefits the SEC identified in the proposed rule, such as the loss of
    economically efficient buybacks and increased litigation costs for issuers.
    The first suggestion is relevant because it addresses the prevalence of
    improperly motivated buybacks—the very concern motivating the SEC’s
    instant rulemaking. Two of the “incentives for value-destroying or oppor-
    tunistic repurchases” the agency identified in the proposed rule were
    “[s]hare price- or EPS-tied compensation arrangements [which] can . . .
    incentivize executives to undertake repurchases, in an attempt to maximize
    their compensation, even if such repurchases are not optimal from the share-
    holder value maximization perspective,” 87 Fed. Reg. at 8457, 8454–55.
    Similarly, the second suggestion sheds light on the strength of the incentives
    19
    Case: 23-60255          Document: 00516951547              Page: 20       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    underlying such opportunistic repurchases. And the third suggestion strikes
    at the heart of the proposed rule’s purported benefit by examining the mar-
    ginal effect of additional disclosures on regulated entities’ behaviors. 18
    All three suggestions provide quantification of the rule’s expected
    costs and benefits—the very same costs and benefits the SEC asserts “can-
    not be quantified.” 19 That destroys the only basis the agency supplied in sup-
    port of its decision to conduct a qualitative analysis. 20 The SEC—by con-
    tinuing to insist that the rule’s economic effects are unquantifiable in spite of
    petitioners’ suggestions to the contrary—has failed to demonstrate that its
    conclusion that the proposed rule “promote[s] efficiency, competition, and
    capital formation” 21 is “the product of reasoned decisionmaking.” 22
    3. The SEC failed adequately to substantiate the rule’s benefits and costs.
    “[A] regulation is arbitrary and capricious if the agency ‘failed to
    consider an important aspect of the problem.’” Mexican Gulf Fishing,
    60 F.4th at 973 (quoting State Farm, 463 U.S. at 43). That “includes, of
    _____________________
    18
    More disclosure isn’t always better. See, e.g., Eugene G. Chewning, Jr. & Adrian
    M. Harrell, The Effect of Information Load on Decision Makers’ Cue Utilization Levels and
    Decision Quality in a Financial Distress Decision Task, 15 Acct. Org. & Soc’y 527, 539–
    40 (1990); Kevin Lane Keller & Richard Staelin, Effects of Quality and Quantity of
    Information on Decision Effectiveness, 14 J. Consumer Res. 200, 211–12 (1987).
    19
    87 Fed. Reg. at 8451 (proposed rule); 88 Fed. Reg. at 36029 (final rule).
    20
    See 87 Fed. Reg. at 8451 (“[W]e have, wherever possible, attempted to quantify
    the economic effects expected from these amendments . . . . Where we are unable to
    quantify the economic effects of the final amendments, we provide a qualitative assess-
    ment.”); 88 Fed. Reg. at 36029 (same).
    21
    15 U.S.C. §§ 78c(f), 80a-2(c).
    22
    State Farm, 463 U.S. at 52; see also Huawei, 2 F.4th at 452 (“An agency’s decision
    to rely on a cost-benefit analysis as part of its rulemaking can ‘render the rule unreasonable’
    if the analysis rests on a ‘serious flaw.’” (quoting Nat’l Ass’n of Home Builders v. EPA,
    
    682 F.3d 1032
    , 1040 (D.C. Cir. 2012)).
    20
    Case: 23-60255       Document: 00516951547              Page: 21       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    course, considering the costs and benefits associated with the regulation.” 
    Id.
    And as part of that cost-benefit analysis, the agency must identify benefits
    that “bear a rational relationship to the . . . costs imposed.” 
    Id.
     (citing Pub.
    Citizen v. EPA, 
    343 F.3d 449
    , 455 (5th Cir. 2003)). 23
    The SEC contends the rule primarily helps investors “better evaluate
    whether a share repurchase was intended to increase the value of the firm”
    or for an improper purpose such as “providing additional compensation to
    management.” 
    88 Fed. Reg. 36008
    . The agency also avers that the rule
    promotes price discovery. 24 But while the rule’s purported benefits may be
    more than purely hypothetical, see supra part III.2, neither is adequately
    substantiated.
    Petitioners insist the first benefit is inadequately substantiated be-
    cause the agency “never substantiated the threshold proposition that im-
    properly motivated buybacks are actually a problem.” And while the SEC
    concedes it never substantiated that proposition in either the proposed or the
    final rule,25 the agency nevertheless maintains the rule’s first benefit is ade-
    _____________________
    23
    See R.J. Reynolds Vapor Co. v. FDA, 
    65 F.4th 182
    , 189 (5th Cir. 2023) (“At a bare
    minimum, ‘[w]hen an agency changes its existing position, it . . . must at least display
    awareness that it is changing position and show that there are good reasons for the new
    policy.’” (quoting Encino Motorcars LLC v. Navarro, 
    579 U.S. 211
    , 221 (2016))).
    24
    See 88 Fed. Reg. at 36033 (“The additional quantitative and qualitative disclos-
    ures we are adopting are further expected to enhance the information about share repur-
    chases, providing clearer insights into how and why the issuers undertake repurchases and
    the extent to which they are related to temporary undervaluation of issuer shares, tem-
    porary cash windfalls that cannot be deployed to positive-net present value (NPV) invest-
    ment projects, or other objectives.”).
    25
    Indeed, the SEC contends in its briefing that “the rule was explicitly not prem-
    ised on th[e] notion” that “‘improperly motivated buybacks regularly occur’ in ‘significant
    numbers.’” See 88 Fed. Reg. at 36007 (“[I]t is not necessary to find that opportunism
    drives the timing of most issuer share repurchases to conclude that it is appropriate for
    investors to have more useful information about such repurchases.”).
    21
    Case: 23-60255        Document: 00516951547               Page: 22        Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    quately substantiated. That’s because, according to the SEC, investors can
    be uncertain about the true motivations underlying a buyback so long as there
    exists an opportunity for—and thus possibility of—opportunistic or improp-
    erly motivated buybacks. 26
    We agree with petitioners. If opportunistic or improperly motivated
    buybacks are not genuine problems, then there is no rational basis for inves-
    tors to experience any of the uncertainty the SEC now claims warrants the
    rule. Concern about uncertainty positively scales with the magnitude and
    probability of the matter for which one is uncertain. A reasoned response to
    uncertainty about matters of low probability or low magnitude should be
    markedly different from those of high probability and magnitude. And that
    only makes common sense: Tolerance of uncertainty varies depending on
    considerations of likelihood and severity.
    It’s no different when it comes to the proposed rule. The rule’s bene-
    fit scales with the degree of investor uncertainty in the status quo, and that
    degree of uncertainty is tied to the magnitude and probability of opportunistic
    or improperly motivated buybacks. The SEC must therefore show that
    opportunistic or improperly motivated buybacks are a genuine problem even
    under its theory of investor uncertainty. Because the agency has not done so,
    the first benefit is inadequately substantiated.
    The rule’s second benefit—promoting price discovery—fares no
    better than the first. The SEC theorizes that “more comprehensive and dis-
    aggregated, granular information about recent repurchases and prices of such
    _____________________
    26
    See, e.g., id. (“[W]e believe all of the quantitative and qualitative disclosure
    requirements that we are adopting in this release together will serve to alert investors to the
    possibility of repurchases being motivated, at least in part, by goals unconnected to
    increasing shareholders value or signaling the issuer’s view that its stock is undervalued.”
    (emphasis added)).
    22
    Case: 23-60255        Document: 00516951547              Page: 23       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    repurchases should be useful to investors in inferring the management’s
    evolving beliefs about the company’s underlying value and, in conjunction
    with other disclosures, [thereby] improving price discovery.” 
    88 Fed. Reg. 36032
    –33.
    The SEC’s theory is internally contradictory and thus fails adequately
    to substantiate the rule’s price-discovery benefit. 27 That theory rests on the
    notion that the rule’s additional disclosure requirements will mitigate sub-
    optimal voluntary disclosure levels by providing investors with valuable new
    information. The SEC reasons that these voluntary disclosure levels are sub-
    optimal in the status quo because issuers currently withhold information from
    investors on account of the “the potential costs of leaking valuable private
    information to competitors.” 
    88 Fed. Reg. 36036
    . But the agency soon
    changes tack. In its discussion of the rule’s general costs, the SEC adopts the
    opposite—and contradictory—position: In concluding that costs of disclos-
    ing “significant proprietary information” would be “relatively modest for
    most issuers,” the SEC asserts the new disclosures would not contain valua-
    ble information. 
    88 Fed. Reg. 36040
    .
    The SEC cannot have it both ways. It is illogical for the rule simul-
    taneously to accept and to reject the reasoning underlying the price discovery
    benefit. The rule’s price discovery benefit is therefore unsubstantiated. 28
    The price-discovery benefit would still be inadequately substantiated
    even if we were to disregard the fact that the SEC’s theory is internally
    contradictory. First, the agency fails to demonstrate that it considered rele-
    _____________________
    27
    See Sw. Elec. Power Co. v. EPA, 
    920 F.3d 999
    , 1021 (5th Cir. 2019) (“[A]n
    agency’s action is arbitrary and capricious if illogical on its own terms.” (cleaned up)).
    28
    See R.J. Reynolds Vapor Co., 65 F.4th at 189 (“[W]hen an agency changes its
    existing position, it . . . must . . . show that there are good reasons for the new policy.”
    (quoting Encino, 579 U.S. at 222) (cleaned up)).
    23
    Case: 23-60255        Document: 00516951547              Page: 24       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    vant factors in concluding the rule’s additional disclosures would impose
    “relatively modest [costs] for most issuers.” 
    88 Fed. Reg. 36040
    . Looking
    at the rule’s disclosure requirements explains why that is the case. Plainly
    put: The rule’s requirements are clear as mud. Issuers are instructed not to
    “rely[] on boilerplate language” but are offered no guidance except a non-
    exclusive and non-exhaustive list compiling myriad suggestions from com-
    mentators. 29 Worse still, there is no safe harbor even for issuers whose dis-
    closures discuss all the rule’s suggestions. And even when pressed at oral
    argument, counsel for the SEC offered little in the way of clarifying what
    disclosures the rule actually mandated. The price-discovery benefit is not the
    product of reasoned decisionmaking.
    Regardless, the rule cannot be sustained on the price-discovery ration-
    ale even if we were to assume that the price-discovery benefit is adequately
    substantiated. Under the harmless-error doctrine, a challenged rule survives
    judicial review notwithstanding error only if such error “clearly had no bear-
    ing on the procedure used or the substance of the decision reached.” 30
    As explained above, the rule’s primary benefit—decreasing investor
    uncertainty about motivations underlying buybacks—is inadequately sub-
    _____________________
    29
    These suggestions direct issuers to discuss: (1) “other possible ways to use the
    funds allocated for the repurchase and [to] compar[e] the repurchase with other investment
    opportunities that would ordinarily be considered by the issuer, such as capital expendi-
    tures and other uses of capital”; (2) “the expected impact of the repurchases on the value
    of remaining shares”; (3) “factors driving the repurchase, including whether their stock is
    undervalued, prospective internal growth opportunities are economically viable, or the
    valuation for potential targets is attractive”; and (4) “the sources of funding for the
    repurchase, where material, such as, for example, in the case where the source of funding
    results in tax advantages that would not otherwise be available for a repurchase.” 88 Fed.
    Reg. at 36024.
    30
    Sierra Club v. U.S. Fish & Wildlife Serv., 
    245 F.3d 434
    , 444 (5th Cir. 2001)
    (quoting U.S. Steel Corp. v. EPA, 
    595 F.2d 207
    , 215 (5th Cir. 1979); see 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
     (“due
    account shall be taken of the rule of prejudicial error”).
    24
    Case: 23-60255        Document: 00516951547              Page: 25       Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    stantiated. Almost every part of the SEC’s justification and explanation of
    the rule reflects the agency’s concern about opportunistic or improperly
    motivated buybacks. That error permeates—and therefore infects—the
    entire rule. Consequently, we cannot conclude that error in the SEC’s sub-
    stantiation of the first benefit clearly had no bearing on the remainder of the
    rule.
    Because the SEC acted arbitrarily and capriciously in failing ade-
    quately to (1) respond to petitioners’ comments and (2) substantiate the
    rule’s benefits, we grant the petition for review.
    V.
    Petitioners contend the SEC did not provide adequate opportunity for
    notice and comment. Under the APA, agencies must “give interested per-
    sons an opportunity to participate in the rule making through submission of
    written data, views, or arguments.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 553
    (c).
    We disagree with petitioners. They aver the SEC’s initial forty-five-
    day comment period should “raise red flags” because it was shorter than
    sixty days. But the APA generally requires only a minimum thirty-day com-
    ment period. 31 And “while interested parties should be able to participate
    meaningfully in the rulemaking process, the public ‘need not have an oppor-
    tunity to comment on every bit of information influencing an agency’s deci-
    sion.’” Tex. Off. of Pub. Util. Couns. v. FCC, 
    265 F.3d 313
    , 326 (5th Cir. 2001)
    (quoting Texas v. Lyng, 
    868 F.2d 795
    , 800 (5th Cir. 1989)). We cannot con-
    clude that the initial comment period was so short as to deprive petitioners
    _____________________
    31
    Chem. Mfrs. Ass’n, 899 F.2d at 347. See also Nat’l Lifeline Ass’n v. FCC, 
    921 F.3d 1102
    , 1117 (D.C. Cir. 2019) (“[A] 30-day comment period is generally the shortest time
    period sufficient for interested persons to meaningfully review a proposed rule and provide
    informed comment.” (internal citations omitted)).
    25
    Case: 23-60255     Document: 00516951547           Page: 26   Date Filed: 10/31/2023
    No. 23-60255
    of a meaningful opportunity to comment on the proposed rulemaking. Peti-
    tioners may have hoped for more time, but it is not for us to decide whether
    an agency has chosen a maximally net beneficial comment period.
    Accordingly, the SEC’s notice and comment period satisfies the
    APA’s requirements.
    VI.
    The SEC acted arbitrarily and capriciously, in violation of the APA,
    when it failed to respond to petitioners’ comments and failed to conduct a
    proper cost-benefit analysis. We recognize that “there is at least a serious
    possibility that the agency will be able to substantiate its decision given an
    opportunity to do so.” Texas v. United States, 
    50 F.4th 498
    , 529 (5th Cir.
    2022) (quoting Texas Ass’n of Mfrs. v. US. Consumer Prod. Safety Comm’n,
    
    989 F.3d 368
    , 389–90 (5th Cir. 2021)). Short of vacating the rule, we there-
    fore afford the agency limited time to remedy the deficiencies in the rule.
    Because, for the reasons explained, the SEC’s adoption of the Share
    Repurchase Disclosure Modernization Rule is arbitrary and capricious, the
    petition for review is GRANTED, and this matter is REMANDED with
    direction to the SEC to correct the defects in the rule within 30 days of this
    opinion. This is a limited remand. This panel retains jurisdiction to consider
    the decision that is made on remand.
    26
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 23-60255

Filed Date: 10/31/2023

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 11/1/2023