Club Misty, Inc v. Laski, James ( 2000 )


Menu:
  • In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    Nos. 99-1597 and 99-1628
    Club Misty, Inc., doing business as
    Tequila Roadhouse, et al.,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    James Laski, Clerk of the City of Chicago, et al.,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    Appeals from the United States District Court for the
    Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division.
    Nos. 98 C 7831 & 98 C 8054--Charles R. Norgle, Sr., Judge.
    Argued February 18, 2000--Decided April 3, 2000
    Before Posner, Chief Judge, and Bauer and Manion,
    Circuit Judges.
    Posner, Chief Judge. Two licensed taverns in
    Chicago appeal from the district court’s
    dismissal of their suit to enjoin an Illinois
    state statute pursuant to which the plaintiffs
    would have lost their licenses had they not been
    granted preliminary relief that continues on
    appeal. The statute, 235 ILCS 5/9-1 et seq., is
    challenged both as depriving the plaintiffs of
    their property without due process of law and as
    a bill of attainder.
    Illinois liquor licenses are revocable only for
    good cause during the one-year term of the
    license and renewable as a matter of right when
    the term expires unless the licensee is
    unqualified or his premises unsuitable. 235 ILCS
    5/3-14, 5/5-2, 5/6-1, 5/7-5. (A tavern must have
    a local license as well, see 235 ILCS 5/3-14,
    5/7-6; Chi. Munic. Code sec.sec. 4-60-20(a),
    60(a), but the parties make nothing of this, so
    we won’t either.) There is no suggestion that
    either plaintiff gave cause to have its license
    revoked or not renewed. Each simply lost a vote
    by the residents of the precinct in which its
    tavern is located. The vote was authorized by 235
    ILCS 5/9-2, which provides that if 40 percent of
    the registered voters in a precinct petition the
    board of elections for a vote on whether to
    prohibit the sale of liquor at a particular
    street address, the question shall be put to the
    precinct electorate at the next election and if a
    majority votes in favor of the prohibition the
    license of the establishment located at that
    address shall become void thirty days after the
    election. 235 ILCS 5/9-3. The record is silent on
    why these particular taverns incurred the voters’
    wrath; neither the petitioners nor the voters are
    required to give reasons. All we know, besides
    that the plaintiffs’ taverns were duly licensed,
    is that in each precinct there are other liquor
    licensees who have not been voted out.
    On the view we take of the case, we shall not
    have to decide whether the statute is a bill of
    attainder, U.S. Const., art. I, sec. 10, cl. 1;
    but we shall not conceal our skepticism that it
    is. A bill of attainder is a legislative
    punishment, and we may assume without having to
    decide both that a legislative delegation to the
    electorate of a standardless authority to punish
    would fall afoul of the prohibition of bills of
    attainder by constituting the electorate a
    surrogate legislature engaged in administering
    punishment, see Joint Anti-Fascist Refugee
    Committee v. McGrath, 
    341 U.S. 123
    , 144 (1951)
    (concurring opinion); Dehainaut v. Pena, 
    32 F.3d 1066
    , 1070-71 (7th Cir. 1994); Laurence H. Tribe,
    American Constitutional Law sec. 10-6, pp. 660-61
    (2d ed. 1988); cf. Citizens Against Rent
    Control/Coalition for Fair Housing v. City of
    Berkeley, 
    454 U.S. 290
    , 295 (1981), and that
    corporations as well as individuals are protected
    by the constitutional prohibition. See Plaut v.
    Spendthrift Farm, Inc., 
    514 U.S. 211
    , 239 n. 9
    (1995); BellSouth Corporation v. FCC, 
    144 F.3d 58
    , 63 (D.C. Cir. 1998); BellSouth Corporation v.
    FCC, 
    162 F.3d 678
    , 684 (D.C. Cir. 1998); SBC
    Communications, Inc. v. FCC, 
    154 F.3d 226
    , 234
    and n. 11 (5th Cir. 1998). Even so, it is
    doubtful that what the voters have voted to do to
    the plaintiffs can be regarded as punishment.
    The requirement of punishment is most clearly
    satisfied when a punitive purpose is conjoined
    with a characteristically punitive sanction, such
    as a fine. See generally Nixon v. Administrator
    of General Services, 
    433 U.S. 425
    (1977). (During
    the impeachment of President Clinton, there was
    much discussion of whether a congressional
    resolution censuring him would have been a bill
    of attainder.) We may assume, again without
    having to decide still another unsettled issue,
    that either a punitive purpose or a
    characteristically punitive sanction would
    suffice to make legislation directed against a
    particular individual or firm (of which a given
    street address is a transparent proxy) a bill of
    attainder. Selective Service System v. Minnesota
    Public Interest Research Group, 
    468 U.S. 841
    ,
    852-54 (1984); Nixon v. Administrator of General
    
    Services, supra
    , 433 U.S. at 473-84; De Veau v.
    Braisted, 
    363 U.S. 144
    , 160 (1960); Dehainaut v.
    
    Pena, supra
    , 32 F.3d at 1071-73; Planned
    Parenthood of Mid-Missouri and Eastern Kansas,
    Inc. v. Dempsey, 
    167 F.3d 458
    , 465 (8th Cir.
    1999); SBC Communications, Inc. v. 
    FCC, supra
    ,
    154 F.3d at 241; Tribe, supra, sec. 10-5, p. 655.
    The problem here is that we have no information
    about the purpose that actuated the petitions and
    the votes against these licensees; nor is the
    revocation of a license a characteristically
    punitive sanction, Brookpark Entertainment, Inc.
    v. Taft, 
    951 F.2d 710
    , 717 (6th Cir. 1991); cf.
    Rivera v. Pugh, 
    194 F.3d 1064
    , 1068 (9th Cir.
    1999); United States v. Emerson, 
    107 F.3d 77
    , 81-
    83 (1st Cir. 1997), though it can inflict great
    hardship.
    We need not pursue the issue further, as we
    think the statute is unconstitutional as a denial
    of due process of law even if it is not a bill of
    attainder. We reach this conclusion on the basis
    of two previous decisions of this court, Reed v.
    Village of Shorewood, 
    704 F.2d 943
    (7th Cir.
    1983), and Philly’s v. Byrne, 
    732 F.2d 87
    (7th
    Cir. 1984). Neither side in the present
    litigation challenges the soundness of either
    decision. They differ as to the decisions’
    correct interpretation but they do not ask us to
    overrule either one in whole or in part. And so
    those decisions provide the framework for our
    analysis.
    Reed holds that an Illinois liquor license is a
    property right within the meaning of the due
    process clause of the Fourteenth 
    Amendment. 704 F.2d at 948-49
    . The license is revocable during
    its term only for cause, just like a public
    school teacher’s tenure contract--a familiar
    example of "property" as the Supreme Court has
    defined the term in the due process clauses of
    the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments. E.g., Perry
    v. Sindermann, 
    408 U.S. 593
    , 601 (1972). Were
    renewal a matter of administrative grace, the
    challenged statute would be vulnerable only in
    cases in which the license was voided before the
    expiration of its current term. E.g., Movers
    Warehouse, Inc. v. City of Little Canada, 
    71 F.3d 716
    , 718-19 (8th Cir. 1995); Kraft v. Jacka, 
    872 F.2d 862
    , 866-68 (9th Cir. 1989), overruled on
    other grounds by Dennis v. Higgins, 
    498 U.S. 439
    (1991). But we held in Reed, relying on the
    Illinois Appellate Court’s decision in City of
    Wyoming v. Liquor Control Comm’n, 
    362 N.E.2d 1080
    , 1084 (Ill. App. 1977), that Illinois law
    treats a refusal to renew a liquor license as
    equivalent to revocation, entitling the licensee
    "to all the protections, procedural and
    substantive, of the revocation process, [and]
    thus making [the licensee’s] interest in renewal
    a property right for purposes of the Fourteenth
    
    Amendment." 704 F.2d at 949
    . We followed Reed in
    Kelly v. City of Chicago, 
    4 F.3d 509
    , 511 (7th
    Cir. 1993), as well as in Philly’s v. 
    Byrne, supra
    , 732 F.2d at 90, as did the Sixth Circuit
    in Brookpark Entertainment, Inc. v. 
    Taft, supra
    ,
    951 F.2d at 714-15; see also Easter House v.
    Felder, 
    910 F.2d 1387
    , 1395 (7th Cir. 1990) (en
    banc); compare Herz v. Degnan, 
    648 F.2d 201
    , 208
    (3d Cir. 1981).
    The City of Chicago (the principal defendant)
    does not challenge any of these cases though it
    tweaks us a bit by remarking in a footnote that
    our holding that a liquor license is property has
    been rejected by the Illinois Appellate Court in
    decisions rendered after Reed. See Blue Cat
    Lounge, Inc. v. License Appeal Comm’n, 
    667 N.E.2d 554
    , 557 (Ill. App. 1996); Ole, Ole, Inc. v.
    Kozubowski, 
    543 N.E.2d 178
    , 181-82 (Ill. App.
    1989); Ross v. Kozubowski, 
    538 N.E.2d 623
    , 626
    (Ill. App. 1989); Black Knight Restaurant, Inc.
    v. City of Oak Forest, 
    513 N.E.2d 109
    , 111 (Ill.
    App. 1987). These cases rely on a provision of
    the Illinois Liquor Control Act which states that
    a liquor license is not property, 235 ILCS 5/6-1,
    and on "the wooden distinction between ’rights’
    and ’privileges’" that the Supreme Court has
    "fully and finally rejected." Board of Regents v.
    Roth, 
    408 U.S. 564
    , 571 (1972). As we explained
    in Reed, such a declaration and such a
    distinction cannot conclude the constitutional
    issue of whether the license is property, and
    indeed has very little relevance to it. Memphis
    Light, Gas & Water Division v. Craft, 
    436 U.S. 1
    ,
    9 (1978); Brookpark Entertainment, Inc. v. 
    Taft, supra
    , 951 F.2d at 714; Sea Girt Restaurant &
    Tavern Owners Ass’n, Inc. v. Borough of Sea Girt,
    
    625 F. Supp. 1482
    , 1486-88 (D. N.J.), aff’d
    without opinion, 
    802 F.2d 448
    (3d Cir. 1986).
    Think back to the classic case of constitutional
    property--a teacher’s tenure contract. Obviously
    such a contract would not be classified as
    "property" or a "property right" under state law,
    a classification that would weirdly imply that a
    teacher could sue his employer for trespass if he
    were fired in breach of the contract. For most
    purposes, perhaps for all but one purpose, an
    Illinois liquor license is not property; but
    insofar as it is revocable (or nonrenewable) only
    for cause, it is property for purposes of
    determining whether the state can deprive the
    licensee of it without according him due process
    of law. Baer v. City of Wauwatosa, 
    716 F.2d 1117
    ,
    1122 (7th Cir. 1983); see also Perry v.
    
    Sindermann, supra
    , 408 U.S. at 601.
    The City denies that a liquor license is
    property for a reason unrelated to Reed--that the
    challenged statute so eviscerates the rights of
    liquor licensees as to destroy their status as
    owners of constitutional property. We left this
    issue open in 
    Philly’s. 732 F.2d at 90-91
    . That
    case arose under the provision, codified in the
    same section of the Illinois Liquor Control Act
    as the provision challenged in this case, that
    allows the voters in a precinct to vote the
    entire precinct dry, as distinct from prohibiting
    the sale of liquor at a particular address. We
    held that there was no denial of due process (see
    also Sam & Ali, Inc. v. Ohio Dept. of Liquor
    Control, 
    158 F.3d 397
    , 398-99 (6th Cir. 1998);
    37712, Inc. v. Ohio Dept. of Liquor Control, 
    113 F.3d 614
    , 619 (6th Cir. 1997)) and so we didn’t
    have to decide whether there was a deprivation of
    property. We did a little dance around the issue.
    On the one hand we pointed out that the power to
    vote a precinct dry could conceivably be thought
    an implicit term of every liquor license, in
    which event such a license could no longer be
    thought revocable or nonrenewable for cause and
    so it would lose the defining characteristic of
    constitutional property. On the other hand we
    pointed out that such an analysis, implying as it
    does that by repealing procedural protections a
    state could demote property to nonproperty, would
    leave very little standing of the constitutional
    protection of property, since the essential
    protection is precisely the guarantee of the
    procedural safeguards (basically notice and an
    opportunity to be heard) that constitute the core
    of the concept of due process of law as it is
    understood in the modern decisions.
    Today we have to bite the bullet. In conformity
    with the case law that has accreted since
    Philly’s was decided, see Cleveland Board of
    Education v. Loudermill, 
    470 U.S. 532
    , 541
    (1985); Youakim v. McDonald, 
    71 F.3d 1274
    , 1289
    (7th Cir. 1995); Listenbee v. City of Milwaukee,
    
    976 F.2d 348
    , 352 (7th Cir. 1992); Campbell v.
    Miller, 
    787 F.2d 217
    , 223 (7th Cir. 1986);
    Furlong v. Shalala, 
    156 F.3d 384
    , 395 (2d Cir.
    1998); Frazier v. Garrison I.S.D., 
    980 F.2d 1514
    ,
    1528-29 (5th Cir. 1993); Brookpark Entertainment,
    Inc. v. 
    Taft, supra
    , 951 F.2d at 716-17, we hold
    that the two-step process for eliminating due
    process rights that we have just described, of
    which the first is to authorize a procedure for
    extinguishing property rights that does not
    conform to the requirements of due process and
    the second is to invoke that process to
    extinguish a particular person’s property right,
    is ineffectual to destroy constitutional
    property.
    We are mindful that the Twenty-First Amendment
    to the Constitution gives the states very broad
    power over the sale of alcoholic beverages.
    Illinois could if it wanted forbid such sale
    altogether; it certainly is not required to give
    liquor licensees the attributes of constitutional
    property. But it has given them those attributes,
    as we have seen, and the challenged statute does
    not purport to remove them. It creates no new
    substantive criteria for the grant or withdrawal
    of Illinois liquor licenses. Nothing in it
    purports to alter the "for cause" condition that
    makes those licenses property within the meaning
    of the due process clause. It does not refer to
    the provisions of Illinois law that we have held
    make liquor licenses "property" for purposes of
    the clause, or to the Twenty-First Amendment. All
    the referendum statute does is provide an
    alternative procedure for revocation of liquor
    licenses. This is apparent from the legislative
    history, as we are about to see. The supporters
    of the statute believed that it would provide a
    swifter alternative to administrative procedures
    for revoking the licenses of "bad apples," which
    is to say licensees who had given cause for
    revocation.
    The plaintiffs thus have a property right of
    which the voters in their precincts deprived
    them, and the remaining question is whether the
    deprivation was brought about by a method that
    denied the plaintiffs due process of law. The
    City argues "no," relying on Philly’s, where we
    held that while an election is not an
    adjudicative procedure that comports with due
    process, the fact that the voters of a precinct
    could get rid of a liquor licensee whom they
    didn’t like (for whatever reason) only by voting
    the entire precinct dry provided the disfavored
    licensee with protection and marked the vote as a
    legislative rather than an adjudicative act. It
    is the same kind of protection that is provided
    by the equal protection clause, see Railway
    Express Agency v. New York, 
    336 U.S. 106
    , 112-13
    (1949) (Jackson, J., concurring), and by the
    principle, which is the very foundation of the
    concept of the rule of law (as well as of the
    prohibition of bills of attainder), that a
    legislature can prohibit private conduct only
    through general rules. Chicago precincts are
    small (each is supposed to have 400 registered
    voters, 10 ILCS 5/11-3, 11-5), which reduces the
    protection conferred by requiring the precinct to
    vote itself dry rather than picking on a
    particular licensee--many precincts have only one
    liquor licensee. But we emphasized that "the
    Illinois act does not permit the precinct’s
    voters to single out a particular liquor seller
    to shut down. . . . This means not only that the
    licensee who is disliked is protected to some
    extent by the licensee who is liked [if there is
    one] but also that the voters cannot impose costs
    on liquor sellers without imposing costs on
    themselves--the costs of not being able to buy
    liquor in the 
    precinct." 732 F.2d at 92
    .
    Philly’s was decided in 1984. Five years later
    the Illinois legislature added to the Liquor
    Control Act the provision challenged in this
    case. Why? The only reason that is suggested in
    the legislative history, and anyway the only
    reason that is remotely plausible, is that the
    legislature wanted the residents of a precinct to
    be able to get rid of a particular licensee of
    whom they disapproved. See, e.g., Statement of
    Rep. McGann, in Transcript of General Assembly,
    June 27, 1989, at 138-39 ("But say you have one
    [tavern] that is causing real problems, causing
    problems for the neighbors around them and so
    forth that they cannot affectively [sic] by the
    law presently of the police administration deal
    with these situations and the community neighbors
    are having problems. This will not penalize the
    good licensees in these areas, but will only
    target that bad operator"). The reason for
    targeting a particular licensee could be a good
    one, as this quotation from the legislative
    history suggests--that the licensee was selling
    liquor to minors, or serving drunks, or
    attracting a rowdy lot from other neighborhoods,
    or disturbing the neighbors with loud music. Any
    of these could be a solid ground for revocation;
    and although if there is such a ground the
    authorities presumably will revoke the license--
    eventually--the procedures for revocation that
    comport with due process often take a long time
    to complete. Their length is a practical reason
    for wanting to have a substitute mode of
    revocation that is not encumbered by procedural
    safeguards. See Statement of Sen. Marovitz, in
    Transcript of General Assembly, July 1, 1989, at
    3 ("you may have a particular bar, a particular
    tavern that’s causing a tremendous problem. I
    have a lot of them in my district, where you have
    drug dealers, where you have prostitution, where
    you have knifings and shootings. We have tried
    and tried and tried before the Liquor Commission
    of the City of Chicago to close those taverns.
    We’ve been turned away every time"). But the
    guarantee of due process would mean little if it
    could be dispensed with upon a showing, which
    could be made in every case, that a remedy that
    provides no procedural safeguards at all will be
    faster and cheaper than one that provides some.
    The costs of procedural safeguards are only half
    the formula that the Supreme Court set forth in
    Mathews v. Eldridge, 
    424 U.S. 319
    , 334-35 (1976),
    for determining the minimum requirements of due
    process. The other half is the benefits in
    preventing error. The challenged statute contains
    no safeguards against error.
    A vote by neighbors to decide whether a
    particular person or firm is a bad apple
    exemplifies "popular justice," the mode by which
    an Athenian jury, without deliberation, without
    instruction or control by professional judges,
    without possibility of correction on appeal, and
    without the assistance of lawyers, condemned
    Socrates. The revocation of the liquor license of
    the Tequila Roadhouse is not to be compared with
    the death sentence imposed on Socrates. Yet
    Socrates received more due process than the
    Tequila Roadhouse, since he had an opportunity to
    argue his innocence to the jury and the jury
    convicted him of a crime, albeit a vague one
    (corrupting the morals of the young men of Athens
    by questioning pious certitudes). There is no
    standard to guide voters in deciding whether to
    void a liquor license. We need not attribute
    frivolous motives to them. Yet just as we do not
    trust jurors to deliberate without instructions,
    so we should be concerned that an electoral free-
    for-all might result in serious errors that a due
    process hearing would avert. The voters might be
    stirred to action by an influential resident of
    the precinct who was angry about being refused
    service because he was inebriated. They might be
    outraged because one of the taverns in the
    precinct had topless waitresses--or refused to
    have them. They might be victims of a campaign of
    disinformation by a competing tavern--a
    possibility that concerned Representative
    Matijevich, who in Transcript of General
    Assembly, June 27, 1989, at 137-38, observed:
    "let’s say that in a precinct there are two
    establishments, only two establishments. And one
    establishment may have some political pull. . . .
    [Y]ou may have that establishment lobbying in an
    election to get the other competition out of
    business for no other reason than he likes to get
    all the business for himself"). They might be
    induced to vote against a tavern by a precinct
    captain who was on the outs with the tavern’s
    owner. The possibilities are myriad and some of
    them are unsavory, and against them the procedure
    established by the challenged statute offers no
    protection at all.
    This will not bother anyone who believes that
    the democratic process should be left completely
    unhindered by law. But that is not the theory of
    the Constitution. An individual’s life, liberty,
    and property are not held or enjoyed at the
    sufferance of the electorate. When the Illinois
    legislature stepped from allowing a precinct’s
    voters to vote the precinct dry to allowing the
    voters to expel a particular disfavored licensee,
    it crossed the line that protects property
    holders from being deprived of their property
    without due process of law. Although taverns are
    not the most popular businesses in some quarters,
    no principle is suggested that would limit the
    power claimed by the City to the sale of
    alcoholic beverages. Its position casts a long
    shadow over all property rights. We pointed out
    earlier that the state has not attempted to exert
    its plenary powers under the Twenty-First
    Amendment to curtail the abuses to which the sale
    of alcoholic beverages may give rise.
    Nothing that we have said is intended to suggest
    that referenda are unconstitutional. The
    Constitution does not forbid direct democracy.
    City of Eastlake v. Forest City Enterprises,
    Inc., 
    426 U.S. 668
    (1976), holds that voters can
    be empowered to act as legislators--but that is
    provided that the action they are empowered to
    take is legislative. City of Eastlake was a
    zoning case, and zoning is on the legislative
    side of the legislative/judicial divide. River
    Park, Inc. v. City of Highland Park, 
    23 F.3d 164
    ,
    166-67 (7th Cir. 1994); Coniston Corp. v. Village
    of Hoffman Estates, 
    844 F.2d 461
    , 468-69 (7th
    Cir. 1988). This is not only because "the
    decision whether and what kind of land uses to
    permit does not have the form of a judicial
    decision. The potential criteria and
    considerations are too open-ended and ill-
    defined." 
    Id. at 468.
    It is also because zoning,
    like ordinary legislation, operates
    prospectively. The lawful destruction of existing
    property is the domain of nuisance law, a branch
    of tort law that is applied by courts to specific
    offending properties. As Justice Holmes, writing
    for the Court in Prentis v. Atlantic Coast Line
    Co., 
    211 U.S. 210
    , 226-27 (1908) (citations
    omitted), pointed out, "A judicial inquiry
    investigates, declares, and enforces liabilities
    as they stand on present or past facts and under
    laws supposed already to exist. That is its
    purpose and end. Legislation, on the other hand,
    looks to the future and changes existing
    conditions by making a new rule, to be applied
    thereafter to all or some part of those subject
    to its power. . . . Proceedings legislative in
    nature are not proceedings in a court, . . . , no
    matter what may be the general or dominant
    character of the body in which they may take
    place. That question depends not upon the
    character of the body, but upon the character of
    the proceedings." See also New Orleans Public
    Service, Inc. v. Council of City of New Orleans,
    
    491 U.S. 350
    , 370-71 (1989).
    The statute that is challenged in this case does
    not authorize the voters to determine, in the
    manner of zoning, where liquor may be sold (a
    possible interpretation of Philly’s); it
    authorizes them to evict a particular seller, as
    if they were the judges of a housing court or a
    judge asked to abate a nuisance. Cf. Nasierowski
    Bros. Investment Co. v. City of Sterling Heights,
    
    949 F.2d 890
    , 895-96 (6th Cir. 1991); Harris v.
    County of Riverside, 
    904 F.2d 497
    , 501-04 (9th
    Cir. 1990). The vote is limited to a specific
    street address currently occupied by a licensee,
    235 ILCS 5/9-2; it does not prevent the sale of
    liquor next door. In the typical zoning case
    prospective uses of property are in issue, and
    decision making is likely to be based on general,
    legislative grounds. Voters are likely to
    consider whether they want a building "like that"
    in their neighborhood. The primary factor in a
    targeted liquor referendum is bound to be, in
    contrast, the past behavior of the tavern, for
    the voters have already decided to permit
    businesses "like that" in the neighborhood.
    (Remember that they could vote the precinct dry
    if they wanted.) Something has forced them to
    change their minds about this tavern, and the
    only plausible explanation is the tavern’s
    behavior, but the evaluation of past behavior for
    conformity to norms of proper conduct is the
    domain of adjudication.
    So the issue "is not too much delegation, but
    delegation to the wrong body: delegation of
    judicial decision-making, for example, to people
    who are not judges." United Beverage Co. of South
    Bend, Inc. v. Indiana Alcoholic Beverage Comm’n,
    
    760 F.2d 155
    , 159 (7th Cir. 1985); see also City
    of Eastlake v. Forest City Enterprises, 
    Inc., supra
    , 426 U.S. at 678; Seattle Title Trust Co.
    v. Roberge, 
    278 U.S. 116
    , 121-22 (1928); Eubank
    v. City of Richmond, 
    226 U.S. 137
    (1912); Jones
    v. Bates, 
    127 F.3d 839
    , 858 n. 25 (9th Cir.
    1997); General Elec. Co. v. New York State Dept.
    of Labor, 
    936 F.2d 1448
    , 1454-55 (2d Cir. 1991);
    Scott v. Greenville County, 
    716 F.2d 1409
    , 1420
    n. 16 (4th Cir. 1983). That is what Illinois has
    done and what the due process clause prohibits.
    Reversed.
    BAUER, Circuit Judge, dissenting. In order to
    better understand the ramifications of the
    majority opinion, a bit of urban reality is, I
    believe, in order.
    The residents of the City of Chicago, 2,700,000
    or more, live in neighborhoods characterized by
    their homogeneity. The residents share, in
    general, the same socio-economic status, the
    homes are strikingly similar in configuration and
    costs, and the blue-collar/white-collar
    employment of the workers are usually the same.
    Racial and/or ethnic backgrounds tend to be
    similar. Although neighborhoods have no
    recognized political existence, they are there,
    with or without political acknowledgment, and it
    is there that Chicagoans live, marry, raise
    families, socialize and die. Most of the
    residents lack real mobility of choice;
    affordable housing near or convenient to
    employment or transportation is what they must
    settle for. Stability of neighborhood and safety
    are their primary objectives. Many have no choice
    at all; public housing or subsidized housing
    dictates where they live.
    What businesses are in or around these
    neighborhoods are there because the zoning laws
    and licensing regulations, planned on a city-wide
    basis, permit their existence. (Of course, the
    business investors look for areas of opportunity
    and that plays a major role in what businesses
    exist side by side with the residential
    buildings.)
    Barber shops, grocery stores, convenience
    markets, drugstores, restaurants, tailor shops,
    all these exist in the neighborhoods and add to
    the livability of the area. One business,
    however, is acknowledged to have a greater impact
    on the tone of a neighborhood than any other--the
    liquor business.
    For purposes of this case, we need not think in
    terms of liquor stores but only those licensed
    premises which purvey drinks by the glass. They
    include most fine restaurants, many family or
    ethnic restaurants, and neighborhood saloons;
    those places that Chicago historians called the
    working man’s social clubs. It is here that the
    people meet, not just to drink, but to eat, to
    celebrate birthdays, anniversaries and other
    special occasions and to socialize with people of
    the neighborhood.
    When Illinois exercised its right to control (or
    ban altogether) the sale of liquor, it opted to
    create a system of local-option rules. The
    decision as to whether to permit liquor sales, to
    define how many and where such emporiums could
    exist was left to cities and villages and even
    counties for the unincorporated areas. Moreover,
    the towns and villages, many with a smaller total
    population than a Chicago precinct, can determine
    the character of the liquor emporium. They can,
    for instance, regulate the type of entertainment
    a licensee can offer the public, the hours and
    days of purveying, or even restrict the sale of
    liquor to hotels or places that serve food.
    Because of its size, however, Chicago
    (technically, cities of a certain size that only
    Chicago meets) is treated differently.
    Recognizing that neighborhoods most closely
    resemble small towns, the legislature sought to
    give some local control.
    There is, however, as we have said, no political
    entity called a "neighborhood"; its closest
    parallel is the precinct. A "precinct" is not a
    definable graphic area; it is an entity that
    exists only to facilitate voting. It is created
    by the city in its establishment of places to
    vote; ideally, each precinct will contain 400
    registered voters. When the number of registered
    voters goes much above or below that figure, the
    precinct boundaries must, by law, be redrawn.
    This to ensure a conveniently close place for
    voters to exercise their franchise and to reduce
    the possibility of long lines of voters waiting
    for a vacant polling booth.
    Of course, in addition to the 400 registered
    voters, the precinct will contain many more
    people: those ineligible to vote because of their
    minority, non-citizens, those who have not
    established sufficient length of residency and
    (if voter registration proponents are to be
    believed) a large number of people, otherwise
    eligible, who have not bothered to register to
    vote. In short, a "precinct" is close to being a
    neighborhood or a small town and it has a
    political existence. And local option of sort is
    granted to these entities.
    As I said, it is usually to the economic self-
    interest of a license holder to maintain cordial
    and friendly relations with the people of the
    area where his establishment is located; they are
    a source of business to him. There are some
    establishments that attract patrons from areas
    distant from the precinct, either because of a
    particular form of entertainment, glowing
    restaurant reviews, proximity to sports arenas,
    etc. (The people living near sports arenas show
    an extraordinary patience with absurd activities
    of the fans, but it is also true that the sports
    bars make extraordinary efforts to keep the
    locals happy. Properly speaking, the two groups
    establish a mutually advantageous economic truce.
    The saloons and restaurants are sources of
    employment--as in the area itself--and the locals
    provide some patronage during off-season months).
    As to the premises that cater to different
    clientele, striptease fans, loud music fans,
    youth groups, bikers--not to mention premises
    that cater to the drug culture or other illegal
    activities--these groups try to keep the
    irritation level of the activity to a minimum
    because they know about the local-option laws.
    And if enough of their neighbors get pushed hard
    enough, they can respond by eliminating the
    problem through the ballot box.
    To suggest, as the majority opinion does, that
    a voter who is disgruntled by the refusal of a
    bartender to serve him while inebriated can
    eliminate a license, is to ridicule the
    intelligence of the voters. To imagine that such
    a malcontent could convince a majority of the
    voters in a precinct (or even the smaller number
    called for to place the issue on the ballot) to
    take up the cudgel of the ballot on such a silly
    crusade is, itself, ridiculous.
    The fact is the motivation behind such a
    difficult task as securing signatures on a
    petition and votes in the ballot box is one the
    majority should well understand: cost-benefit.
    The term may not be used but, as we know, it is
    the real motivation behind most human activity. I
    should think that this constitutionally permitted
    reason should be both understood and applauded.
    As we have seen, most liquor license holders are
    benign influences in the areas around them, even
    serving to enhance the livability and property
    values of the neighborhood. Nevertheless, under
    the original rule of local option, the precinct
    had only one choice: vote entirely dry or put up
    with the one or more festering sores.
    The right of the precincts to vote entirely dry
    was endorsed by this court (indeed, by the author
    of the majority opinion in the instant case). And
    if there is only one such establishment in the
    precinct and only one possible target of the
    vote-to-go-dry, it still passes constitutional
    muster. Apparently, the constitutional rights of
    an individual liquor license holder increase with
    the number of licenses in a precinct; they can
    take shelter in the acceptance of their good
    brothers-in-business and thumb their noses at the
    legitimate wishes of the residents of the
    neighborhood.
    The legislature recognized the unfairness of
    this all-or-nothing approach to the wet/dry
    dilemma when they amended the local-option law to
    permit a referendum on the issue of whether a
    single (or, I assume, more than one) liquor
    establishment shall continue to be licensed in
    the precinct. This is so that the businesses
    which have decent regard for the preservation of
    the community standards can remain and their
    property rights not scuttled by a bad apple in
    the liquor dispensing barrel.
    The majority opinion agrees with the Supreme
    Court that the Constitution does not forbid
    direct democracy. What seems to be the theme of
    the opinion is that, under the local-option rule,
    voters can exercise their franchise without
    "standards to guide the voters in deciding
    whether to void a liquor license." One assumes by
    this, "judicial guides". And, of course, such is
    the price of democracy; the voters may make a
    choice that their betters may not approve.
    The majority opinion points to the use of
    judicial instructions in jury trials and
    describes the referendum (or election) process as
    an "electoral free-for-all" that might result "in
    serious error". Just so. The process of
    democratic government does not rely on stern
    lectures from the highly educated. The least of
    us has the right to express himself or herself in
    the ballot box without deference to the ruling
    classes. It is also of interest to note that a
    precinct, if so inclined, can, as this court (and
    the author of the instant majority opinion) has
    ruled, snuff out the license rights of one, or
    any number of, licensees in the precinct without
    the splendid guidance of court or city fathers,
    providing that all the licensees in the precinct
    are eliminated. Why is the same use of the ballot
    box constitutionally infirm if the licensees
    affected are fewer than all of those in the
    precinct? If "guidance" is required to make the
    decision of the voters constitutionally kosher,
    why not require that such guidance (whatever that
    might be!) be required for all referenda that
    affect a property right (bond issues, annexation,
    establishment of school districts and mosquito
    abatement districts, etc.)?
    It is not accurate to say, as the majority
    opinion does, that, before a referendum is
    undertaken "the voters have already decided to
    permit businesses" like that "in the
    neighborhood" because they could vote the
    precinct dry if they wanted to. What is more
    accurate is that they made no decision at all;
    the city makes it for them. It is probably also
    safe to say that not one voter in fifty even
    knows about the local-option rule and only a
    crisis in the neighborhood eventually may serve
    to enlighten them--and then after every other
    avenue to correct a problem involving a liquor
    licensee (petitioning the city liquor commission,
    calling the police, calling the alderman, etc.)
    has failed.
    The deprivation of property, discussed by the
    majority, occurs in exactly the same way whether
    the voters wipe out all of the liquor vendors in
    a precinct or a single vendor. I fail to see how
    a total deprivation of "property rights" that
    affects two or more owners is more constitutional
    than the same action which affects only one
    liquor emporium.
    It is worthwhile considering how much trouble
    such a referendum is to the people of the
    precinct. First, to focus the residents on the
    way to solve the problem (I’m willing to assume
    the existence of the problem and knowledge of its
    existence among the neighbors), then to secure
    sufficient signatures to get the matter placed on
    the ballot, and then to campaign successfully
    enough to get a majority of the voters to vote
    against an existing business. The effort involved
    and the work entailed should at least indicate to
    us the incredible problem the licensee must be
    causing. And it is a fact that, like Socrates,
    the liquor dispenser has an opportunity to
    present his defense to the jury (i.e., the
    voters); he can campaign as hard against the
    referendum as his opponents argue for it; it
    might even convince him to reform before the vote
    and become a good neighbor.
    I believe that the legislature of Illinois and
    its court system can protect the rights of its
    citizens in the field of liquor control and
    neighborhood safety. If it is constitutionally
    proper for the voters of a precinct to ban the
    only bar in the area, or all the bars in the
    neighborhood, I cannot believe that it is
    constitutionally improper for the legislature to
    authorize, and the voters to exercise, a right to
    prohibit the operation of a particular liquor
    license. There is no constitutional right to be
    in the liquor business and I cannot believe that
    the authorization of a referendum as to whether a
    particular saloon shall be permitted in a
    neighborhood is an invasion of a constitutional
    right. I suspect it depends on whose
    constitutional property rights should concern us.
    I think the rights of the people who live in the
    area should have our deepest concern.
    I would affirm the dismissal of the case.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 99-1597

Judges: Per Curiam

Filed Date: 4/3/2000

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/24/2015

Authorities (52)

United States v. Emerson , 107 F.3d 77 ( 1997 )

general-electric-company-v-new-york-state-department-of-labor-thomas-f , 936 F.2d 1448 ( 1991 )

1998-2-trade-cases-p-72256-13-communications-reg-pf-458-sbc , 154 F.3d 226 ( 1998 )

herz-sylvia-v-john-j-degnan-morris-goodman-adella-c-youtz-and , 648 F.2d 201 ( 1981 )

gt-scott-v-greenville-county-c-daniel-riddle-ih-gibson-mike-fair , 716 F.2d 1409 ( 1983 )

monica-furlong-lawrence-schwartz-robert-sloan-and-kenneth-y-sunew , 156 F.3d 384 ( 1998 )

37712, Inc. v. Ohio Department of Liquor Control and ... , 113 F.3d 614 ( 1997 )

John A. Reed, Gerald G. Kaluzny, and Rbk, Ltd. v. Village ... , 704 F.2d 943 ( 1983 )

River Park, Inc., and Country Club Estates, Ltd. v. City of ... , 23 F.3d 164 ( 1994 )

Coniston Corporation v. Village of Hoffman Estates , 844 F.2d 461 ( 1988 )

Dorothy J. Listenbee v. City of Milwaukee and Milwaukee ... , 976 F.2d 348 ( 1992 )

Sam & Ali, Inc. Aleb, Inc. Mallough, Inc. And Murib, Inc. v.... , 158 F.3d 397 ( 1998 )

david-frazier-hattie-bradley-bonnie-alexander-and-juanita-griffin , 980 F.2d 1514 ( 1993 )

Nasierowski Brothers Investment Company v. City of Sterling ... , 949 F.2d 890 ( 1991 )

Quentin Kelly, Jerry Smith, Ray B. Hill v. City of Chicago, ... , 4 F.3d 509 ( 1993 )

John H. Baer, Individually and D/B/A Liberty Guns v. The ... , 716 F.2d 1117 ( 1983 )

United Beverage Company of South Bend, Inc. And National ... , 760 F.2d 155 ( 1985 )

John Stanley Campbell v. H.G. Miller , 787 F.2d 217 ( 1986 )

Jean Dehainaut v. Federico Pena , 32 F.3d 1066 ( 1994 )

Easter House, an Illinois Not-For-Profit Corporation v. ... , 910 F.2d 1387 ( 1990 )

View All Authorities »