Olsen, Joseph D. v. Floit, Gary A. ( 2000 )


Menu:
  • In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    No. 00-1107
    Joseph D. Olsen, Trustee
    of Huntley Ready Mix, Inc.,
    Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.
    Gary A. Floit,
    Defendant-Appellee.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of Illinois, Western Division.
    No. 99 C 50203--Philip G. Reinhard, Judge.
    Argued June 1, 2000--Decided July 14, 2000
    Before Bauer, Easterbrook, and Manion, Circuit Judges.
    Easterbrook, Circuit Judge. In May 1993 Huntley
    Ready Mix sold all of its operating assets for
    $151,000 to Harvard Ready Mix. This plus cash on
    hand was just enough to pay off Huntley’s secured
    debt, which had been guaranteed by Gary Floit,
    Huntley’s founder, president, and principal
    shareholder. Huntley retained its accounts
    receivable, eventually collecting and
    distributing about $100,000 to its general
    creditors, but another $200,000 or so remained.
    When Huntley filed a petition under Chapter 7 of
    the Bankruptcy Code of 1978 its only asset was
    some $125,000 owed by deadbeats. As part of the
    transaction, Harvard hired Floit as its plant
    manager under a three-year employment contract
    (at approximately the salary he drew from
    Huntley) and paid $249,000 for a five-year
    covenant not to compete in the concrete business.
    Huntley’s trustee believes that Huntley’s assets
    were worth at least $400,000, more than enough to
    pay off its debts, and that Floit diverted to
    himself under cover of the no-compete agreement
    the value of the unsecured creditors’ interests.
    If so, then Huntley "received less than a
    reasonably equivalent value in exchange for [the]
    transfer". 11 U.S.C. sec.548(a)(1)(B)(i). As
    events revealed that Huntley either was insolvent
    when the sale occurred or became insolvent as a
    result, the transaction may have been a
    fraudulent conveyance, and the estate might have
    recovered from Floit as "the entity for whose
    benefit such transfer was made". 11 U.S.C.
    sec.550(a)(1). But Huntley entered bankruptcy 15
    months after the sale, and sec.548(a)(1) reaches
    back just one year.
    Instead of giving up or arguing that Floit is
    equitably estopped to take advantage of the time
    limit in sec.548(a)(1), Huntley’s trustee in
    bankruptcy tried a novel approach: he sued Floit
    (in an adversary proceeding) under state
    corporate law on the theory that Floit violated
    his fiduciary duty to Huntley as one of its
    directors. The theory is akin to that of a
    fraudulent-conveyance action--that Floit obtained
    too little for Huntley and too much for himself--
    without the need to show that Huntley was
    insolvent, and with the benefit of a longer
    period of limitations under Illinois law. We call
    this "novel" because the state-law claim is
    designed to protect shareholders rather than
    creditors, and the Floit family held all the
    shares. Under 805 ILCS 5/8.60, the statute in
    question, a director who receives a personal
    benefit from a transaction with or by the
    corporation must demonstrate that the arrangement
    was "fair" to the corporation, unless either
    disinterested directors or disinterested
    shareholders approved the transaction with
    knowledge of all material facts. This statute--
    similar to the 1984 version of the ABA’s Model
    Business Corporation Act sec.8.31--provides that
    directors and shareholders who do not participate
    in the transaction are free to approve it, which
    they will do when it benefits them (or at least
    does not harm them) as equity holders. Because
    shareholders acting in their own interests are
    entitled to approve, 805 ILCS 5/8.60 cannot be a
    creditor-protection rule. It is passing strange
    to say that a single minority shareholder with a
    trivial stake could have approved the sale to
    Harvard and thus insulated it from any later
    attack (other than a fraudulent-conveyance
    action), but that, because there were no minority
    shareholders in Huntley, approval was impossible.
    Yet Floit has not picked up on this logical
    problem in the trustee’s invocation of 805 ILCS
    5/8.60, forfeiting whatever arguments might be
    available to terminate the claim on strictly
    legal grounds. His sole response is that the
    transaction was indeed "fair" to Huntley. The
    bankruptcy judge held a trial and agreed with
    Floit; the district judge affirmed; the trustee
    now contends that the critical findings were
    clearly erroneous, an uphill battle. See Anderson
    v. Bessemer City, 
    470 U.S. 564
    (1985).
    Illinois defines "fair" as market value. A
    transaction is "fair" to a corporation when it
    receives at least what it would have obtained
    following arms’ length bargaining in competitive
    markets. Shlensky v. South Parkway Building
    Corp., 
    19 Ill. 2d 268
    , 283, 
    166 N.E.2d 793
    , 801
    (1960) (discussing common-law requirement of
    fairness preceding enactment of 805 ILCS 5/8.60);
    cf. BFP v. Resolution Trust Corp., 
    511 U.S. 531
    (1994) (a foreclosure sale produces "reasonably
    equivalent value" for purposes of bankruptcy
    law). Floit and the trustee produced expert
    witnesses who estimated the price that Huntley’s
    assets would have fetched in a competitive sale.
    Floit’s expert valued the business (including
    Floit’s services) at approximately $440,000, and
    the trustee’s at $380,000 to $410,000. Floit’s
    expert differed from the trustee’s by opining
    that most of this value was contributed by Floit
    personally and that the corporation assets were
    worth $151,000 or less. Floit also offered his
    own testimony and that of Jay Nolan, Harvard’s
    president, in support of the lower valuation. The
    bankruptcy judge accepted this view.
    Both sides also looked through the other end of
    the telescope, asking whether the covenant not to
    compete would have been worth $249,000 in a
    competitive market--on the sensible theory that
    if the covenant had been overvalued, then it must
    have represented a disguised portion of the
    purchase price for Huntley’s assets.
    Unsurprisingly Floit, Nolan, and Floit’s expert
    all testified that the covenant was worth at
    least $50,000 per year, for a total of $250,000.
    This testimony received some support from a
    disinterested source: when Harvard Ready Mix was
    itself sold in mid-1996, the buyer paid $200,000
    for the two remaining years of Floit’s
    abnegation. Perhaps conditions changed in the
    cement industry, making the threat of his
    competition more serious; the question in this
    litigation is what the covenant was worth in
    1993, not what it was worth in 1996; but a
    $100,000-per-year valuation in 1996 lends
    verisimilitude to the assertion that in 1993 the
    covenant was worth at least $50,000 per year. The
    trustee’s expert disagreed, stating that a
    covenant not to compete in the cement business
    should be valued at between 0.7 and 1.5 times the
    promisor’s annual earnings, which implies that
    the value of Floit’s covenant could not exceed
    $93,000 (given his salary of $62,000 during the
    year preceding sale). The expert conceded that
    covenants sometimes represent a percentage of a
    closely held corporation’s sales, and that in one
    case of which he was aware the owner-principal of
    a closely held firm had received 16% of its
    annual sales. Applied to Huntley’s sales (about
    $1.5 million in 1992, its last full year of
    operation), this implied a value of $240,000 for
    the covenant not to compete, but the trustee’s
    expert rejected this conclusion as unrealistic
    for Huntley and Floit. The bankruptcy judge,
    however, thought it entirely realistic given
    Nolan’s testimony and the $200,000 value later
    placed on two years of Floit’s covenant by
    parties who had no stake in the outcome of this
    litigation. That buyer also paid Nolan and his
    brother (Harvard’s two principals) $1.5 million
    apiece for their covenants not to compete for
    five years.
    Valuation of closely held businesses is
    something of a black art. Experts try to project
    the firm’s net cash flow into the future, then
    discount that stream to present value. This
    process is difficult for public companies, see
    Metlyn Realty Corp. v. Esmark, Inc., 
    763 F.2d 826
    (7th Cir. 1985); Richard A. Brealey, Stewart C.
    Myers & Alan J. Marcus, Fundamentals of Corporate
    Finance 122-35 (2d ed. 1999); Lucian Arye Bebchuk
    & Marcel Kahan, Fairness Opinions: How Fair Are
    They and What Can Be Done About It?, 1989 Duke
    L.J. 27, 35-37, and almost impossible for private
    companies, for which uncertainties abound. What
    was apt to happen to Huntley? The trustee’s
    expert assumed that, if not sold, it would have
    remained in business and generated about the same
    cash flows as before; Floit and Nolan testified,
    however, that Huntley’s plant was decrepit and
    that the expense of renovation could not be
    justified. Nolan recounted that most of Huntley’s
    equipment had been "hauled off to the junkyard"
    soon after the acquisition. These two stories
    implied dramatically different futures for the
    firm and correspondingly large differences in the
    present value of its earnings and the price-
    earnings multiple on sale.
    Similarly unclear was how to calculate the
    firm’s real earnings. The trustee’s expert
    calculated that over the last few years before
    its sale Huntley generated a weighted annual
    average of $115,000 in "discretionary income,"
    with a high of $166,000 in 1992. "Discretionary
    income" in this formulation is whatever is left
    after the costs of paying for all materials and
    labor, other than Floit’s. But it is artificial
    to assume that the full cost of an entrepreneur’s
    labor is the nominal salary he pays to himself;
    the entrepreneur also benefits from perquisites
    of office and changes in the value of the firm’s
    stock. To determine how much Huntley’s assets
    could have fetched in an arms’ length sale, it
    would have been necessary to know the full cost
    of Floit’s services--which is to say his
    reservation wage, what he could earn in other
    employment--not just his nominal salary.
    Sometimes a court can pin down the entrepreneur’s
    entitlement by asking whether what remains
    adequately compensates minority investors for the
    risk they bear, see Exacto Spring Corp. v. CIR,
    
    196 F.3d 833
    , 838-39 (7th Cir. 1999), but Huntley
    did not have minority shareholders. Reservation
    wages, alas, are hard to pin down otherwise,
    unless perhaps by observing how much Harvard was
    willing to pay Floit. That answer turned out to
    be $115,000 per year ($65,000 in salary plus
    $50,000 as the annual portion of the covenant not
    to compete). Viewed this way, the numbers imply
    that Huntley didn’t have much if any value beyond
    its physical assets; its net cash flow was needed
    to retain Floit’s services. (That the
    "discretionary income" increased to $166,000 in
    1992 may do more to show that Huntley had
    deferred replacing its assets, and thus curtailed
    its out-of-pocket costs, than to show an
    improvement in its true economic position. Nor is
    it dispositive that Harvard paid Floit both for
    employment and for a covenant not to compete. The
    latter was independently valuable to Harvard in
    the event Floit should quit, be fired, or just
    leave at the expiration of the three-year
    employment contract.)
    When hard numbers are difficult to come by or
    evaluate, people often rely on reputations. The
    trustee insists that his expert had better
    academic credentials and more experience valuing
    closely held companies than did Floit’s, so that
    the bankruptcy judge should have adopted the
    estimates of the trustee’s expert. A reasonable
    trier of fact might have proceeded that way, but
    we cannot say that a contrary view was clearly
    erroneous. After all, the bankruptcy judge’s
    views do receive support from the $100,000-per-
    year valuation of Floit’s covenant as of 1996.
    Floit may have been well respected by others in
    the business, and thus able to attract a
    substantial package of compensation to deter him
    from starting a new firm or defecting to another
    producer. What is more, the trustee’s expert did
    not do all that would be expected of a specialist
    in valuing closely held firms. Why leap to a
    discounted cash flow analysis when other methods
    are available? Most trade associations maintain
    records of sale prices for firms in the business.
    What multiple of free cash flow did other small
    cement ready-mix producers sell for? See To-Am
    Equipment Co. v. Mitsubishi Caterpillar Forklift
    America, Inc., 
    953 F. Supp. 987
    , 996-97 (N.D.
    Ill. 1997), affirmed, 
    152 F.3d 658
    (7th Cir.
    1998). It would have been especially interesting
    to know the answer to this question for sales
    following the departure (or death) of the
    founding entrepreneur. For although Huntley owned
    its assets, Floit was not among these. He did not
    have a long-term contract with Huntley or a no-
    compete agreement and thus could leave and
    compete at will. E.J. McKernan Co. v. Gregory,
    
    252 Ill. App. 3d 514
    , 530-31, 
    623 N.E.2d 981
    , 994
    (2d Dist. 1993). Floit owned his human capital
    and was free to withdraw from Huntley and sell
    his services to a higher bidder without violating
    any fiduciary duty. For what price could
    Huntley’s plant, customer list, goodwill, and so
    on have been sold without assurance of Floit’s
    services? That’s where price-earnings ratios for
    firms sold after the death or departure of their
    founders would have come in handy. The trustee’s
    expert did not attempt to estimate this figure;
    instead he assumed that whatever value Floit’s
    services produced was "owned" by Huntley and
    would be capitalized in its sale price. When
    asked about this at oral argument, the trustee’s
    counsel conceded that his expert had valued
    Huntley as a going concern with Floit as its
    manager, adding that Floit’s expert had done the
    same thing and that Floit bears the risk of non-
    persuasion. But this case was not a tossup as the
    bankruptcy judge saw things, so allocation of the
    burden was not dispositive. A solid demonstration
    that Huntley was worth more than $150,000 even if
    Floit was planning to leave would have gone a
    long way toward establishing that the bankruptcy
    judge made a clear error. Without such evidence
    it is awfully hard to say that the bankruptcy
    judge’s findings are clearly erroneous.
    According to the trustee, however, valuation is
    a matter of law rather than fact, and the trustee
    contends that under In re Prince, 
    85 F.3d 314
    (7th Cir. 1996), corporate value includes the
    value of its entrepreneur’s services. If that is
    so, then even a penny for Floit’s covenant not to
    compete violates the duty he owed to the firm.
    But it is not so. Prince does not concern
    Illinois corporate law in general or 805 ILCS
    5/8.60 in particular. It is instead an
    application of contract law to a bankruptcy case.
    Prince, an orthodontist, promised his creditors
    as part of an agreed plan of reorganization that
    he would turn over the value of his stock in his
    professional corporation. He agreed to sell that
    practice to a Dr. Clare for $450,000 but proposed
    to turn over only $7,500 to his creditors,
    claiming that the rest of the value was
    attributable to a no-competition agreement. One
    difficulty with this contention is that the
    $450,000 was the price set on "the practice";
    unlike Harvard Ready Mix, Clare did not pay
    separately for physical assets and a covenant not
    to compete. What Prince had to sell was
    principally goodwill--that is, a client base,
    client records (exceptionally valuable in a
    dental practice), and a promise to continue
    working for six months to ensure that patients
    transferred their allegiance to Dr. Clare. Prince
    held that the agreement between Prince and his
    creditors included goodwill as part of the
    practice’s value. We did not hold that for this
    purpose "goodwill" included the value of Prince’s
    personal services for the indefinite future. Our
    understanding of the bargain between Prince and
    his creditors does not imply that Huntley owned
    the value of Floit’s services for the foreseeable
    future, despite the absence of an employment
    agreement between Huntley and Floit.
    Doubtless Huntley owned its goodwill--its
    customer lists, the value of repeat business, and
    so on. See Hagshenas v. Gaylord, 
    199 Ill. App. 3d 60
    , 
    557 N.E.2d 316
    (2d Dist. 1990). But the
    trustee does not accuse Floit of trying to make
    off with these assets, or of including their
    value in the $249,000 allocated to the covenant
    rather than the $151,000 allocated to assets.
    Even the trustee’s expert conceded that Huntley’s
    tangible assets were worth no more than $106,000;
    the rest was goodwill. Harvard did not assume
    Huntley’s name, and cement usually is sold by
    competitive bid, so Huntley did not have the sort
    of goodwill that is associated with a personal-
    services business such as a medical practice. In
    the end, the trustee’s position depends on
    allocating the value of Floit’s human capital to
    Huntley, and we do not think that the bankruptcy
    judge committed clear error in ruling otherwise.
    Affirmed