US Can Company v. NLRB ( 2001 )


Menu:
  • In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    Nos. 99-2828 & 99-3049
    United States Can Company,
    Petitioner, Cross-Respondent,
    v.
    National Labor Relations Board,
    Respondent, Cross-Petitioner,
    and
    United Steelworkers of America, afl-cio-clc,
    Intervening Respondent.
    Petition to Set Aside, and Cross-Petition to Enforce,
    an Order of the National Labor Relations Board.
    Argued September 20, 2000--Decided June 19, 2001
    Before Coffey, Easterbrook, and Evans,
    Circuit Judges.
    Easterbrook, Circuit Judge. A long time
    has passed since United States Can Co. v.
    NLRB, 
    984 F.2d 864
     (7th Cir. 1993),
    enforced the Labor Board’s substantive
    decision in this case, 
    305 N.L.R.B. 1127
    (1992). Now we’re at the remedy stage;
    the Board has ordered the employer to
    fork over about $1.5 million in back pay,
    plus pension credits and other fringe
    benefits, plus more than a decade’s worth
    of interest, to 28 employees who between
    1987 and 1989 were denied opportunities
    to transfer to other plants in lieu of
    layoffs. See 1999 NLRB Lexis 310, slightly
    modifying the ALJ’s decision at 1998 NLRB
    Lexis 268. We shall cut to the chase;
    exhaustive recitations of events may be
    found in the decisions just cited.
    The Board concluded in 1992 that, when
    United States Can Co. acquired four
    packaging plants, it also acquired a
    collective bargaining agreement governing
    labor relations at those plants. As a
    result, U.S. Can was obliged for the
    duration of the agreement (which expired
    early in 1989) to offer employees laid
    off as a result of a plant closing the
    opportunity to transfer to vacant
    positions at other plants under an Inter-
    Plant Job Opportunity Program (ipjo). The
    Board’s order left open the calculation
    of back pay for employees who could have
    used the ipjo (had U.S. Can honored its
    obligation) to remain on the payroll for
    a while. Because U.S. Can eventually
    closed all four acquired plants,
    transfers would have postponed but not
    prevented the employees’ need to find
    work elsewhere.
    U.S. Can’s principal contention in this
    court--that the 28 employees would not
    have transferred even if offered the
    chance--goes nowhere given the standard
    of review. We must enforce the Board’s
    decision if substantial evidence on the
    record as a whole supports it. Universal
    Camera Corp. v. NLRB, 
    340 U.S. 474
    (1951). This decision is supported by the
    employees’ testimony. Each was asked
    whether he or she would have transferred
    if given the opportunity; each answered
    yes; the Board believed these answers.
    Such a decision is all but invulnerable.
    Anderson v. Bessemer City, 
    470 U.S. 564
    ,
    570 (1985). U.S. Can grumbles that the
    Board shifted the burden of persuasion,
    forcing it to disprove the possibility
    that the employees would have
    transferred. That’s not what happened.
    Once the employees testified that they
    would have moved, U.S. Can had an
    opportunity to persuade the Board not to
    believe that testimony. Extending such an
    opportunity does not "shift the burden of
    proof"; the Board chose in the end to
    credit the employees because they are
    believable, not because U.S. Can failed
    to carry some burden.
    What U.S. Can did in an effort to
    undercut the employees’ position was
    offer the testimony of a labor economist,
    David S. Evans, that the employees did
    not have much to gain by transferring.
    Evans began with the salary each could
    have earned at a new plant following an
    ipjo transfer. He subtracted what the
    employee would give up: unemployment
    compensation, supplemental unemployment
    benefits (sub) under the collective
    bargaining agreement, and pension
    benefits for which many of the laid-off
    employees were eligible. (Access to ipjo
    transfers depended on seniority, and it
    is not surprising that the most senior
    employees in a closed plant were eligible
    for either early or regular retirement.)
    According to Evans, the difference
    between the wages (and increases in
    future pension benefits) these 28
    employees would have received and the
    benefits they would have surrendered was
    just about the minimum wage. What kind of
    person, U.S. Can asks, will move to
    another part of the country to take a
    minimum-wage job when low-paying work is
    available close to home? One answer might
    be "the kind who work in packaging
    plants"; after all, these 28 swore that
    they would do this. It is not as if Evans
    calculated that their returns from ipjo
    transfers would be negative, so that
    moving would be irrational.
    And the employees may have been better
    economists than Evans, for their net
    wages would have been well above the
    minimum. Evans assumed that if the
    employees moved then sub and unemployment
    benefits would vanish. Not so. These
    payments would be deferred until the next
    layoff, when employees would enjoy them
    (less the time value of the delay) even
    if they took ipjo transfers. Although
    afuture layoff was not certain, the
    probability was high given the ongoing
    consolidation in the industry. Evans,
    however, implicitly assumed that the
    probability was zero and that
    transferring employees never would
    receive unemployment or sub payments to
    make up for what they would lose by
    transferring. Employees themselves would
    not have made that error. Similarly with
    pension payments, which not only would be
    deferred but also would increase as the
    employees made additional contributions
    to their pension accounts. For an
    employee eligible to retire, the decision
    to work another year at a distant plant
    is no different from the decision to work
    another year locally. The employee gives
    up the pension benefit that could have
    been received immediately, getting in
    return a salary plus pension
    contributions that increase the monthly
    benefit later; delay in retirement
    increases the monthly benefit for the
    further reason that actuarial tables
    predict that the pension will be paid out
    for fewer months. Whether the exchange is
    sensible depends on what the person will
    earn in the interim, on the rate of
    interest implicit in the pension plan
    (that is, how fast do monthly benefits
    increase if the employee postpones their
    commencement?), and on how long the
    employee expects to live after
    retirement. U.S. Can did not demonstrate
    that none of these 28 employees could
    have deemed it sensible to work another
    year.
    U.S. Can would have done better to
    examine its predecessor’s experience in
    operating the ipjo program. When
    Continental Can, whose business U.S. Can
    acquired, closed a plant and offered
    transfers, what happened? If no one
    accepted, then U.S. Can would have had
    powerful support for the proposition that
    the testimony of these 28 employees
    should not be believed. The Board should
    place what people do above what they say,
    for talk is cheap (and employees who know
    that a "yes" answer to the question
    "would you have moved?" will bring a
    large financial reward, without any risk,
    will find that this sways their beliefs
    about what they would have done a decade
    earlier, even if they are trying to be
    candid). Whether these 28 would have
    declined transfers is not dispositive; if
    they had said no, then the opportunity
    would have fallen through the seniority
    table until all eligible employees had
    been offered the chance to transfer. Only
    if vacancies would have remained at open
    plants after all eligible employees at
    the closed plants had a chance to move
    would U.S. Can be off the hook. A look at
    Continental Can’s experience would have
    revealed whether that happened. But at
    oral argument counsel for U.S. Can
    replied that it had not examined
    Continental Can’s experience (or at least
    had not put this experience in the
    record). What is in the record, Evans’
    flawed calculation, fell well short of
    the evidence needed to disable the Board
    from crediting the employees’ testimony.
    On to the calculation of back pay.
    According to U.S. Can, the back-pay
    period should not start until the union
    filed its unfair-labor-practice charge,
    or perhaps until the General Counsel of
    the Board commenced the unfair labor
    practice proceeding. U.S. Can concedes
    that both the union’s charge and the
    General Counsel’s complaint were timely
    but contends that it is inequitable to
    require it to afford back pay for earlier
    conduct. The idea that judicial notions
    of equity trump the statutory timeliness
    rules in cases commenced by the United
    States (or one of its agencies) runs
    headlong into Occidental Life Insurance
    Co. v. EEOC, 
    432 U.S. 355
     (1977), and
    Costello v. United States, 
    365 U.S. 265
    ,
    281 (1961), which hold that equitable
    principles such as laches play little if
    any role in the federal government’s
    litigation. See also NLRB v. P*I*E
    Nationwide, Inc., 
    894 F.2d 887
    , 893 (7th
    Cir. 1990). Cf. NLRB v. Ironworkers, 
    466 U.S. 720
     (1984) (long administrative
    delay, while back pay accumulates, does
    not prevent enforcement of the Board’s
    award); NLRB v. J.H. Rutter-Rex
    Manufacturing Co., 
    396 U.S. 258
     (1969)
    (same); Reich v. Sea Sprite Boat Co., 
    50 F.3d 413
     (7th Cir. 1995) (reserving
    question whether laches ever applies to
    the federal government’s cases). There’s
    an additional problem here: U.S. Can did
    not establish prejudice from the delay.
    If it had allowed the employees to make
    ipjo transfers as soon as the union
    complained, then it might have had a good
    claim that delay in making the complaint
    caused injury by requiring it to pay
    twice for the same work (one payment to
    the person actually hired to do the job,
    the other in back pay to the employee who
    might have transferred). But U.S. Can dug
    in its heels and refused to transfer the
    employees. Its back-pay obligation
    therefore would have been the same had
    the union and the General Counsel acted
    immediately.
    The Board awarded as back pay the gross
    wages the 28 employees would have earned
    at other plants, had they transferred and
    worked until those plants too were
    closed. It refused to give U.S. Can
    credit against this award for
    supplemental unemployment benefits and
    pension benefits that the employees
    received in lieu of wages. Whether to net
    out sub and pension benefits divided the
    Board: Chairman Truesdale and Member Fox
    were the majority; Member (now Chairman)
    Hurtgen dissented. Member Hurtgen
    concluded that sub and pension benefits,
    unlike unemployment benefits, see NLRB v.
    Gullett Gin Co., 
    340 U.S. 361
     (1951),
    fall outside the collateral-source
    doctrine because they are provided by the
    employer rather than a third party.
    (These are noncontributory, defined-
    benefit pension plans.) He concluded:
    [The] benefits at issue are not part of a
    governmental program that is broadly
    applicable to employees generally and
    aimed at addressing a general "policy of
    social betterment." [Language quoted from
    Gullet Gin.] Rather, the pension and sub
    payments came from employer-sponsored
    private benefit programs. These benefit
    programs, which inure solely to the
    benefit of [U.S. Can’s] employees, are
    sponsored and funded by [U.S. Can], and
    [U.S. Can] is responsible for
    administering the payments to its
    employees. Thus, there are no overriding
    social policy considerations that support
    the discriminatees’ retention of these
    payments. To the contrary, the relevant
    "policy" consideration is that the
    discriminatees should not receive a
    double-recovery windfall. [A footnote
    here continues: "In F&W Oldsmobile, [
    272 N.L.R.B. 1150
     (1984)], the judge,
    affirmed by the Board, spoke, generically
    of benefits, without distinguishing
    between governmental and private
    benefits. Indeed, it does not appear from
    the decision in that case that the
    distinction was even argued. Since the
    distinction is made by the Supreme Court
    in Gullett, I shall follow the Court’s
    teaching and not that of F&W."]
    Faced with this challenge based on the
    Supreme Court’s reasoning in Gullett Gin,
    the majority of the Board did not respond
    in the text of its opinion but did drop
    this footnote:
    In accord with Board and judicial
    precedent cited and fully discussed in
    the judge’s decision, we affirm the
    judge’s conclusion that [U.S. Can] is not
    entitled to an offset for retirement
    benefits and supplemental unemployment
    benefits paid to discriminatees during
    the backpay period. Although funded as
    part of the benefits earned by employees,
    the trusts are, as the judge correctly
    found, separate and distinct entities
    from [U.S. Can]. The dissent would
    effectively overrule the precedent cited
    by the judge. We decline to do so.
    That the majority relegated to a
    footnote the only significant issue in
    the case is bad; that it gave no reasons
    is worse. Member Hurtgen made a serious
    argument; the majority did not give a
    serious answer. Nor did the ALJ’s opinion
    tackle this subject, except to claim that
    cases such as F&W Oldsmobile support the
    outcome. We have no idea why the majority
    thought it important that the payments
    come from "separate and distinct
    entities" that are funded 100% by the
    employer. If an employer arranged for
    wages to be paid by a parent, subsidiary,
    or corporate affiliate-- "separate and
    distinct entities" all--would the Board
    conclude that these payments should be
    ignored when computing back pay? Surely
    not. Why, then, does it matter that
    fringe benefits such as sub and pension
    payments are funneled through separate
    entities? Why not treat wages and fringe
    benefits identically for this purpose
    (especially when the employer is liable
    if the "separate and distinct entity"
    does not pay in full)? The Board did not
    say.
    The idea behind the collateral-benefits
    doctrine, which originated in tort law,
    is that damages measured by the injury
    are essential to deterrence. See Steven
    Shavell, Economic Analysis of Accident
    Law sec.sec. 6.6.7, 10.3 (1987). Suppose
    A negligently trips B, who incurs $10,000
    in medical expenses. Suppose further that
    B had medical insurance covering these
    costs. To deduct the insurance proceeds
    from A’s damages not only would give the
    tortfeasor the benefit of the victim’s
    expense on insurance but also would
    curtail deterrence. Why should A take
    care in the future if his victims bear
    their own loss? If the government rather
    than B supplies the insurance, the
    analysis is the same. B paid for the
    coverage through taxes, and giving A the
    benefit would reduce if not eliminate A’s
    incentive to take care. That’s a central
    point of Gullett Gin, which held that
    unemployment insurance benefits are
    within the scope of the collateral-source
    doctrine. Although employers pay a tax
    that funds some of these benefits, some
    come from general revenues and all are
    portable; it would be a mistake to say
    that the employer that laid off a worker
    fully pays for the resulting benefits and
    therefore takes the employee’s whole loss
    into account when deciding what to do.
    Contrast unemployment benefits, whose
    level and eligibility criteria are out of
    the employer’s hands, with severance
    benefits. Think of an employer that
    promises its workers that, if they are
    discharged, it will pay six months’ wages
    in a lump sum. An employer discharges a
    worker and pays the promised benefit. Six
    months later the Labor Board concludes
    that the discharge was unlawful and
    orders the worker reinstated. How much
    back pay should the employer be required
    to tender to make the employee whole?--
    for make-whole remedies are the NLRB’s
    financial tool. 29 U.S.C. sec.160(c);
    Sure-Tan, Inc. v. NLRB, 
    467 U.S. 883
    ,
    900-01 (1984); NLRB v. Strong, 
    393 U.S. 357
    , 359 (1969). The answer is zero. The
    employer already has paid six months’
    wages, and once restored to the payroll
    the employee will not have missed a dime.
    The employee loses nothing tomorrow
    either, because the employer’s promise to
    pay severance benefits remains; if the
    employer makes a lawful discharge in the
    future, the employee gets another check
    for six months’ wages. (This restoration
    proviso is important, lest the employer
    be able to appropriate the value of a
    fringe benefit promised to its workers.
    We return to this subject toward the end
    of the opinion.)
    Now suppose that instead of paying six
    months’ wages as a flat benefit, the
    employer coordinates severance benefits
    with unemployment compensation (as many
    pensions are coordinated with Social
    Security retirement benefits) and pays
    only the difference between six months’
    wages and any unemployment benefit the
    former employee receives. Per Gullett
    Gin, the unemployment benefits--which
    come from the public fisc--are not
    deducted from a back-pay award. But the
    severance benefit surely would be
    deducted. And that still would be true if
    the employer’s severance package lasted
    not a flat six months, but until the
    employee found a new job. The amount of
    back pay the employee would receive would
    remain the wages lost, less other
    payments (including the severance benefit
    from the employer).
    One more step and the hypothetical
    becomes the actual case. Suppose that
    instead of paying the severance benefit
    from general corporate funds, the
    employer sets up a second entity--call it
    the Severance Benefits Administrator--
    that disburses the money. Instead of
    making an unfunded severance-benefit
    promise, the employer writes a check to
    the Administrator every month to cover
    the actuarial cost of its severance
    promises. Advance funding of promises
    reduces the cash-flow drain if the
    employer should decide to close a plant
    or lay off many employees at once. But
    from the employee’s perspective it is a
    detail whether a promise is funded in
    advance or met on a pay-as-you-go basis,
    and whether the Administrator is
    incorporated separately from the
    employer. It is all the same--the same
    benefits, the same source, and, one would
    suppose, the same legal consequences. Yet
    we have now described the sub program,
    which is a severance benefit, coordinated
    with the unemployment insurance system
    and administered through a separate
    entity.
    If ordinary severance benefits are
    offset against back-pay obligations--
    something that the Board concedes is
    proper-- then sub payments also must be
    offset. Pension promises are
    fundamentally the same; severance
    benefits with a longer payout. It is
    impossible to see why unfunded benefits
    would be offset, while funded benefits
    administered by a separate entity would
    not be offset. This distinction is the
    nub of the Board’s decision, yet the
    Board offered no logical support. The
    make-whole goal of putting the employees
    in the position they would have occupied,
    but for the employer’s unfair labor
    practice, is unaffected by whether the
    benefits are funded or unfunded, paid
    directly from the employer’s treasury or
    disbursed by an intermediary.
    The Board’s majority did refer to
    "judicial precedent cited and fully
    discussed in the [ALJ’s] decision". Here
    is what the ALJ had to say about pension
    benefits (adding later that sub payments
    are identical in principle):
    [I]t is well-settled that "application of
    the collateral source rule depends less
    upon the source of funds than upon the
    character of the benefits received."
    Haughton v. Blackships, Inc., 
    462 F.2d 788
    , 790 (5th Cir. 1972). Thus, the mere
    fact that an employer contributes money,
    either by paying premiums, making
    contributions, etc., to the fund from
    which benefits are derived does not
    establish that the fund is not a
    collateral source. 
    Id.
     Also, Blake v.
    Delaware and Hudson Railway Company, 
    484 F.2d 204
    , 206 (2nd Cir. 1973); Phillips
    v. Western Company of North America, 
    953 F. 2d 929
    , 929 (5th Cir. 1992); Molzof v.
    United States, 
    6 F.3d 461
    , 465 (7th Cir.
    1993); Russo v. Matson Navigation
    Company, 
    486 F.2d 1018
    , 1020 (9th Cir.
    1993). As was more succinctly stated in
    Folkestad v. Burlington Northern, Inc.,
    
    813 F.2d 1377
    , 1381 (9th Cir. 1987),
    "courts have been virtually unanimous in
    their refusal to make the source of the
    premiums the determinative factor in
    deciding whether thebenefits should be
    regarded as emanating from the employer
    or from a ’collateral source.’"
    Respondent’s assertion, therefore, that
    the benefits should be found not to be
    collateral because it alone funds the
    pension trust account is without merit.
    Further, while Respondent may fund the
    pension trust, under ERISA the trust
    remains a separate and distinct entity
    independent from Respondent. See, NLRB v.
    Amax Coal Co., 
    453 U.S. 322
    , 332-333
    (1981); Doyne v. Union Electric Company,
    
    953 F.2d 447
    , 451 (8th Cir. 1992);
    Garland-Sherman Masonry, 
    305 NLRB 511
    ,
    513 (1991). As the source of pension
    benefits received by the discriminatees
    was the trust fund and not the
    Respondent, said payments were clearly
    from a collateral source and not
    deductible from backpay.
    1998 NLRB Lexis 268 at *36-37. Most of
    these cases concern insurance. It is
    economically irrelevant whether the
    employer pays an employee $1 per hour
    extra, and the employee uses the money to
    buy health insurance, or whether instead
    the employer offers health insurance as a
    fringe benefit. (The difference may be
    vital for tax purposes, but these do not
    concern us here.) The insurance, like the
    wages, becomes the employee’s asset.
    Severance benefits cannot be conceived
    that way. It is therefore not surprising
    that, whatever may be the rule in the
    ninth circuit (the source of the lengthy
    quotation from Folkestad), this circuit
    has concluded that severance benefits and
    their economic equivalents in pension
    packages must be offset when calculating
    make-whole awards. See, e.g., Orzel v.
    Wauwatosa Fire Department, 
    697 F.2d 743
    ,
    756 (7th Cir. 1983) (dictum); Kossman v.
    Calumet County, 
    849 F.2d 1027
    , 1032 (7th
    Cir. 1988). Although, as the Board’s
    appellate brief (though not the Board’s
    or ALJ’s opinion) notes, we held in EEOC
    v. O’Grady, 
    857 F.2d 383
    , 389-91 (7th
    Cir. 1988), that particular pension
    benefits should not be deducted from a
    make-whole award of back pay, we
    emphasized in O’Grady that the benefits
    in question came from a state agency
    other than the employer, making them more
    like Social Security retirement benefits.
    The benefits in this case, by contrast,
    come ultimately from the employer’s
    resources.
    What is economically important for
    deterrence is not whether benefits pass
    through an intermediary but how the
    wrongdoer’s actions affect the victim’s
    well-being, and whether those costs are
    brought home fully to the wrongdoer. What
    is important for compensation is not
    whether benefits pass through a financial
    intermediary, but whether the victim is
    put in the same position he would have
    occupied had his rights been respected.
    So we set the financing arrangements
    aside and ask the important questions
    directly. The employer would indeed gain
    from its wrong--and the employee would
    lose out--if the employer were allowed to
    subtract, from the back-pay obligation,
    pension and welfare benefits that serve
    as deferred compensation for work
    performed. See Hunter v. Allis-Chalmers
    Corp., 
    797 F.2d 1417
    , 1428-29 (7th Cir.
    1986). That is why health insurance is
    treated as a collateral source even when
    the employer provides insurance as a
    fringe benefit. Likewise with sub and
    pension benefits. A direct offset would
    permit the employer to appropriate a
    portion of the employee’s own economic-
    benefits package. Deterrence would be
    reduced, and the employee would be worse
    off to boot. U.S. Can therefore is wrong
    to say that it is entitled to a dollar-
    for-dollar offset. That’s the same
    mistake David Evans made, a fallacy we
    discussed above. Think back to our first
    hypothetical, the lump sum severance
    payment. Allowing a simple offset would
    be equivalent to permitting the employer
    to treat the severance benefit as wages
    (canceling the back-pay obligation for
    the six months of unemployment), without
    restoring that benefit when the employee
    was lawfully let go. If the employer is
    to deduct the benefit from the back-pay
    obligation, it must restore the benefit
    for later use; otherwise the employee’s
    fringe benefit has vanished into the
    employer’s pocket.
    Here’s a concrete illustration. Suppose
    that Alex Baugh, one of the employees not
    offered the opportunity to transfer,
    would have moved to a new plant on
    January 1, 1988, and been laid off on
    January 1, 1990, if all of his
    entitlements under the collective
    bargaining agreement had been honored.
    Instead Baugh retired at the start of
    1988 and began collecting both sub and
    pension benefits. (These are not the
    actual details for Baugh; we are
    simplifying for illustrative purposes.)
    The Board held that Baugh is entitled to
    about $90,000, representing the wages he
    could have earned during 1988 and 1989,
    plus pension credits and interest, on top
    of the unemployment, SUB, and pension
    benefits that he actually received. U.S.
    Can wants to proceed as follows: deduct
    from the gross wages that Baugh would
    have received during these years the sub
    payments that effectively guaranteed him
    his full pay through July 1, 1988, and
    then subtract all of the pension benefits
    he received during those years, cutting
    the total to about a quarter of the
    Board’s actual award. Just as the Board
    erred in saying that sub and pension
    benefits must be ignored, so U.S. Can
    errs in saying that they must be deducted
    dollar for dollar. Suppose that Baugh had
    worked at another plant through the end
    of 1989 and then been laid off. He would
    have been entitled to sub payments for the
    first six months of 1990, plus higher
    monthly pension benefits (increased not
    only by the contributions made to his
    account during 1988 and 1989, but also
    because he would have been two years
    older on retirement). U.S. Can’s approach
    effectively strips Baugh of the sub
    payments--he does not keep what he
    received in 1988, and he does not get
    them in 1990 either. Moreover, U.S. Can’s
    calculation takes away the two years of
    pension benefits in 1988 and 1989 without
    higher monthly benefits in 1990, an
    increase that Baugh would have received
    had he worked through the end of 1989.
    (The Board’s position suffers from the
    same problem in reverse. Under the
    Board’s award Baugh is entitled to keep
    the pension benefits he received in 1988
    and 1989, plus receive pension credits as
    if he had worked in those years and thus
    could retire in 1990 with higher monthly
    benefits.)
    Pension and sub offsets are therefore
    considerably more complex than either the
    Board or U.S. Can supposes. Everyone’s
    rights are respected if, and only if, the
    offset puts each employee in the position
    he would have occupied had the collective
    bargaining agreement been respected--and
    that position is one in which the
    benefits are deferred but not
    obliterated. To make this concrete: U.S.
    Can is entitled to offset the sub payments
    from its back-pay obligation only if it
    also restores those benefits as of the
    time each employee finally would have
    left its employ. It is entitled, in other
    words, to the time value of the money: in
    Baugh’s (hypothetical) case it would make
    sub payments in 1990 rather than 1988, and
    thus would gain two years of interest on
    the obligation. With respect to pension
    benefits, the employer may deduct them
    from back-pay obligations during the time
    they were actually received, only if the
    employer also recalculates the payments
    for later months and increases them to
    the level they would have achieved had
    retirement been deferred. We suspect that
    U.S. Can would not reduce its net payouts
    all that much by these recalculations.
    Many employers therefore might be content
    to disregard sub and pension benefits,
    just as the Board did in this case. But
    the Board may not deprive an employer of
    its opportunity to make the more accurate
    calculation we have described, a
    calculation that fully respects the
    employer’s entitlements as well as each
    employee’s.
    The Board’s order is enforced, subject
    to the proviso that if within 30 days
    U.S. Can informs the Board that it wishes
    to offer actuarial calculations along the
    lines we have described, the Board must
    reopen the record and make new back-pay
    awards using the methods approved in this
    opinion.