White, William v. Sundstrand Corp ( 2001 )


Menu:
  • In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    Nos. 00-2613, 00-4075 & 01-1126
    William R. White, et al., on behalf
    of themselves and a class of others
    similarly situated,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    Sundstrand Corporation, et al.,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    Appeals from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of Illinois, Western Division.
    No. 98 C 50070--Philip G. Reinhard, Judge.
    Argued May 18, 2001--Decided July 3, 2001
    Before Easterbrook, Manion, and Evans,
    Circuit Judges.
    Easterbrook, Circuit Judge. Until it
    became a subsidiary of Sundstrand in
    1984, Sullair Corporation had a floor-
    offset pension plan. Distinctive features
    of that plan still apply to persons who
    worked at Sullair before the acquisition.
    A floor-offset plan uses a defined-
    benefit structure (with pension payments
    linked to years of work and high salary)
    to buffer the uncertainty of a defined-
    contribution system (where pension
    payments depend on the performance of
    investments in each employee’s account).
    See Brengettsy v. LTV Steel (Republic)
    Hourly Pension Plan, 
    241 F.3d 609
     (7th
    Cir. 2001); Regina T. Jefferson,
    Rethinking the Risk of Defined
    Contribution Plans, 
    4 Fla. Tax Rev. 607
    ,
    668-71 (2000). Sullair’s pre-acquisition
    defined-contribution plan was an Employee
    Stock Ownership Plan. Employees were
    entitled to buy Sullair stock, which the
    esop would hold for their account. An esop
    is a high-risk investment: employees’
    retirement wealth is undiversified, so if
    something happens to the firm a retiree
    can end up with little beyond Social
    Security benefits, while if the firm
    prospers he may live in the lap of
    luxury. A defined-benefit component
    ensures that retirees have some
    supplement to Social Security even if the
    employer (or the stock market) goes
    south. The principal question in this
    class action is how the plans interact
    when an employee quits Sullair after
    pension benefits have vested, but before
    retirement age.
    Sullair’s floor-offset plan gives
    retirees the greater of the defined-
    benefit amount and the value of an
    annuity that could be purchased with the
    stock held for the retiree’s benefit by
    the esop. If the annuity that could be
    purchased with the esop stock is less than
    the defined-benefit amount, then the
    defined-benefit plan pays the difference,
    topping up the employee’s pension. Two
    aspects of this arrangement give rise to
    the question at hand. First, the employee
    does not surrender the esop units in order
    to receive a supplemental payment from
    the defined-benefit plan; the employee is
    free to cash out the esop and buy an
    annuity but also is free to keep the
    stock and continue to bear the risk. Sec
    ond, and essential in light of the first,
    the coordination between plans is done
    with a hypothetical annuity, which
    presents the question how the monthly
    annuity benefit will be calculated.
    An example shows how the floor-offset
    arrangement works. Suppose that a given
    employee who retires at age 65 would be
    entitled to a $2,000 monthly pension from
    the defined-benefit plan. This serves as
    the floor. If this employee has a
    $100,000 balance in the esop, the plan
    administrator determines how large an
    annuity the $100,000 could purchase. That
    would be about $900 per month (assuming
    7% annual interest and a 15-year life
    expectancy). Sundstrand then would offset
    the $900 hypothetical annuity and pay the
    retiree $1,100 per month; the esop balance
    is the retiree’s to annuitize, hold, or
    invest as he pleases. If, however, the
    employee has a $300,000 esop balance on
    retirement, an amount that could purchase
    an annuity of about $2,700 monthly, then
    the payment from the defined-benefit plan
    would be zero. Again the retiree retains
    the ability to draw down or invest the
    esop balance. Everything works smoothly
    when the employee starts receiving
    pension benefits immediately on leaving
    Sullair.
    What happens when there is a gap between
    leaving Sullair and retiring? The plan’s
    administrative committee calculates the
    monthly defined-benefit amount based on
    the employee’s length of service and
    terminal salary. That much is
    uncontroversial. What about the defined-
    contribution offset? The plan takes the
    value of the employee’s esop account on
    the day he left Sullair’s employ and
    places that amount in a hypothetical
    savings account, at the same interest
    rate used in the annuity calculations,
    until the day the employee becomes
    eligible for retirement; at that point
    the balance is annuitized, and the
    resulting monthly benefit subtracted from
    the defined-benefit amount. So if an
    employee quits at age 45, with $100,000
    in the esop account, and plans to retire
    at age 65, the plan assumes that this
    balance will compound for 20 years at the
    going rate (7% in our example), producing
    a kitty of almost $390,000 by retirement.
    This sum, when annuitized, is about
    $3,500 per month, so the monthly defined-
    benefit is zero (but, as always, the
    employee can do what he pleases with the
    esop balance from age 45 onward). This
    process is equivalent to asking what
    monthly annuity an employee could buy
    with $100,000 today, when payments on the
    annuity would be deferred for 20 years.
    The parties call this approach the
    "deferred rate" calculation. The other
    approach, which the plaintiffs favor and
    call the "immediate rate" calculation,
    asks how large an annuity a 45-year-old
    could buy with $100,000 for immediate
    commencement. That would be about $640
    monthly--less than the $900 calculated in
    our first example because payments would
    be expected to last 35 years instead of
    15. Under the immediate-rate calculation,
    then, the retiree’s benefit from the
    pension plan would be $1,360 monthly,
    starting at age 65. Meanwhile the esop
    balance is likely to grow to $390,000 by
    age 65, so this person’s total monthly
    benefit will be about $4,900 (the $1,360
    from the plan, plus the $3,500 monthly
    that could be obtained by using the esop
    balance at age 65 to purchase an
    annuity). The difference between deferred
    and immediate calculation can be
    substantial (though there will be no
    difference if even the immediate-rate
    calculation exceeds the monthly pension
    generated by the defined-benefit
    component). The functional question is:
    Who gets the benefit of interest between
    quitting and retirement age, the employee
    or the plan?
    Any pension plan giving retirees the
    greater of two amounts, as opposed to the
    sum of these amounts, can be described as
    confiscating the difference. That’s the
    nature of a floor-offset plan: the
    retiree always "loses" the defined-
    contribution balance (principal and
    interest) up to the floor in the defined-
    benefit plan. What the employee loses,
    the plan receives. Using the esop to fund
    part of the defined-benefit promise makes
    any given level of promised benefits
    cheaper to the employer and so may
    increase the fallback pension. But under
    erisa that is neither here nor there. The
    Employee Retirement Income Security Act
    does not require employers to establish
    plans that are particularly favorable to
    employees. There is no fiduciary duty to
    employees when establishing plans’
    provisions. See Hughes Aircraft Co. v.
    Jacobson, 
    525 U.S. 432
     (1999); Lockheed
    Corp. v. Spink, 
    517 U.S. 882
     (1996). The
    employer’s fiduciary duty, as plan
    administrator, is to implement faithfully
    the provisions of the plan as written.
    Thus we arrive at the critical language
    of the Sullair plan (we quote the 1981
    version, which has not been altered
    substantively):
    The amount of monthly pension which
    could be provided on a straight life
    annuity basis by application of an
    amount equal to the fair market
    value as of such specified date of
    the Participant’s vested interest in
    the balance credited to his account
    under the Sullair Corporation
    Employee Stock Ownership Plan, and,
    for this purpose, such amount of
    monthly pension shall be determined
    on the basis of the annuity purchase
    rates in effect as of such specified
    date under and as set forth in the
    Group Contract.
    So the hypothetical calculation uses the
    "annuity purchase rates"--whatever they
    are. In 1981 and for many subsequent
    years they were set by Bankers Life (now
    Principal Mutual Life Insurance Co.),
    which underwrote the plan with a group
    annuity contract. The first time the
    issue came up, Bankers Life used an
    immediate-rate approach, but it reversed
    itself before any benefits were paid and
    told the Plan Benefit Committee in May
    1985 that a deferred-rate approach should
    be used. The Committee agreed, and a
    deferred-rate approach has been in force
    ever since.
    Plaintiffs observe that immediate-rate
    calculations are used for persons still
    on Sullair’s payroll at retirement, and
    they demand the same for themselves.
    Moreover, when the plan uses a deferred-
    rate calculation for persons who leave
    Sullair before retirement age, the floor-
    offset system loses some or all of its
    risk-buffering function. The deferred-
    rate calculation assumes that the balance
    in the esop will grow at some steady rate
    to retirement age. If it grows less (or
    even shrinks), the employee bears the
    whole loss, without any assistance from
    the defined-benefit component, although
    an employee who works at Sullair through
    retirement receives the assurance that if
    the esop’s value collapses at the last
    moment, the defined-benefit floor still
    is there. (A person who leaves Sullair
    before retirement does have the option,
    however, of rolling the esop balance over
    into a more diversified fund, thus
    protecting against firm-specific risks.)
    If immediate-rate calculations are used,
    however, then employees who leave Sullair
    before retirement age obtain a big
    advantage over those who stay--for the
    floor-offset plan assuredly deprives
    lifetime employees of some or all value
    of growth in the esop account. Think again
    about our hypothetical employee, who
    accumulates a value of $100,000 in the
    esop by age 45. If the employee quits and
    retires 20 years later, an immediate-rate
    calculation provides that person with the
    full value of the esop plus $1,360 per
    month at age 65. Now suppose that the
    person decides to stay at Sullair through
    retirement and does not make further
    investments in the esop. If the value of
    the esop account grows at the assumed 7%
    rate, it will be worth $390,000 at age
    65, and the monthly kicker from the
    defined-benefit component of the plan
    will be zero. Exactly the same investment
    strategy--accumulate $100,000 by age 45,
    invest nothing for the next 20 years--has
    substantially different effects, under
    plaintiffs’ preferred approach, depending
    on whether the person leaves Sullair or
    stays to retirement. What sense does that
    make? Perhaps more to the point, unless
    it is trying to encourage early
    retirement (which it isn’t) why would
    Sullair want a pension plan that rewards
    employees for quitting? Cf. McNab v.
    General Motors Corp., 
    162 F.3d 959
     (7th
    Cir. 1998). Employers can structure their
    plans to make it worthwhile for employees
    to leave, but firms usually want to
    encourage employees who have developed
    valuable skills and knowledge to remain--
    and, not incidentally, encourage them to
    develop such firm-specific skills in the
    first place. Back-loading of compensation
    (through salary that generally increases
    with age as well as through defined-
    benefit pension plans) is a principal way
    to do this. See Edward P. Lazear & Robert
    Moore, Pensions and Turnover, in Pensions
    in the U.S. Economy 163-87 (Zvi Brodie,
    et al., eds. 1988); Edward P. Lazear &
    Sherwin Rosen, Pension Inequality, in
    Issues in Pension Economics 341 (Zvi
    Brodie, et al., eds. 1987). Plaintiffs’
    approach, by contrast, would produce a
    plan that treated workers staying through
    retirement age as suckers.
    The need to use a different calculation
    strategy (immediate-rate for those who
    retire immediately, deferred-rate for
    those who retire later) in order to
    achieve an economically identical outcome
    offers very strong support for the plan’s
    decision. Any remaining doubt is resolved
    by the fact that the plan contains a
    strong grant of discretion--in both
    interpretation and application. Section
    8.01 of the 1981 plan provides:
    The Plan Administrator will have
    complete control of the
    administration of the Plan, subject
    to the provisions hereof, with all
    powers necessary to enable it
    properly to carry out its duties in
    that respect. Not in limitation, but
    in amplification of the foregoing,
    it will have the power to construe
    the Plan and to determine all
    questions that may arise hereunder,
    including all questions relating to
    the eligibility of Employees to
    participate in the Plan and the
    amount of benefit to which any
    Participant, Beneficiary, spouse or
    Contingent Annuitant may become
    entitled hereunder. Its decisions
    upon all matters within the scope of
    its authority will be final.
    This meets the requirements of
    Herzberger v. Standard Insurance Co., 
    205 F.3d 327
    , 331 (7th Cir. 2000), for
    discretion in the plan’s interpretation.
    It was on the basis of the
    administrator’s discretion that the
    district judge granted summary judgment
    on defendants’ favor. 2000 U.S. Dist.
    Lexis 7273 (N.D. Ill. May 23, 2000). We
    agree with the district court’s
    conclusion that the Committee’s decision
    was not arbitrary or capricious (the
    right standard when the administrator has
    interpretive discretion)--and we would
    have reached the same construction as an
    independent matter if review were
    plenary.
    Plaintiffs protest that deference is due
    to one of their number, rather than to
    the plan’s administrator. According to
    plaintiffs, William R. White, the lead
    plaintiff, drafted the plan. Surely he is
    best suited to interpret it, plaintiffs
    insist. Not so. Self-interest would be
    disqualifying (White can’t demand a right
    to calculate his own benefits), but we do
    not get that far. Section 8.01 gives
    interpretive discretion to the Plan
    Administrator, not to William R. White.
    The power goes with the office. A
    Secretary of Labor who drafts and
    promulgates a rule will have leeway to
    interpret its language only as long as
    she remains in office; when a new
    Secretary is confirmed, interpretive
    discretion comes with the job. The ex-
    Secretary may write op-ed pieces trying
    to influence the rule’s application, but
    the elbow room that goes with delegated
    authority belongs to the incumbent, not
    to the author. Senator Wagner may have
    written the National Labor Relations Act,
    but the current members of the National
    Labor Relations Board (and sitting
    federal judges) hold the power of
    interpretation. For the same reason, it
    matters not whether the interpretation
    changed in 1985, after Sundstrand
    acquired Sullair. Whoever sits on the
    Plan Committee today may change matters
    yet again; the discretion created by
    sec.8.01 was not abolished in 1984 but
    passed to new holders.
    Plaintiffs raised several arguments in
    addition to the immediate-rate claim, but
    several of these washed out before the
    suit began when the plan’s administrative
    committee took a fresh look at its
    calculations, agreed with the plaintiffs’
    position, and raised their retirement
    benefits (and those of other Sullair
    employees) accordingly. Other claims
    survived and became the subject of this
    suit, though it is hard to see why. For
    example, plaintiffs contend that the
    value of phantom stock benefits (bonuses
    calculated by changes in the value of
    Sullair’s stock) count as compensation
    for the purpose of calculating the
    defined-benefit component. Defendants
    responded that this may or may not be so,
    but that because none of the plaintiffs
    received phantom-stock compensation there
    was no reason to adjust their pensions.
    Plaintiffs ignore that problem on appeal.
    Plaintiffs did receive some profit-
    sharing payments and contend that these
    should be included in the base used to
    calculate the defined-benefit amount, but
    the plan documents explicitly exclude
    this possibility, as the district court
    correctly held. And the court was
    entirely right to deny plaintiffs’ post-
    judgment motion, under Fed. R. Civ. P.
    60(b)(3), accusing the defendants of
    fraud during discovery. Of this there is
    no evidence--and as this opinion
    demonstrates the outcome of the case
    depends on the plan’s terms and the
    administrator’s discretion, not on who
    said (or wrote) what to whom many years
    ago.
    After entering its judgment on the
    merits, the district court ordered
    plaintiffs to pay about $18,000 in costs
    under Fed. R. Civ. P. 54(d)(1). 2000 U.S.
    Dist. Lexis 15335 (N.D. Ill. Oct. 19,
    2000). The district court made the eight
    representatives jointly and severally
    liable for this amount. Plaintiffs do not
    contest the amount (a substantial
    reduction from the bill of costs
    defendants submitted) but say that
    liability should be individual rather
    than joint--and that the right
    denominator is the number of members in
    the class, rather than the number of
    representative plaintiffs. This class has
    a few more than 160 members, which
    implies a costs award of approximately
    $110 against each of the representatives.
    Any award against the absent class
    members would not be collectable--not
    only because the defendants have said
    that they would not try to do so, but
    also because execution would not be
    lawful. Class members were not given
    notice and an opportunity to opt out of
    the case, and it is impossible to see how
    conscripts who did not even know of the
    case’s existence, let alone have an
    opportunity to distance themselves from
    it, could be required to pony up. Neither
    the federal rules nor the due process
    clause of the fifth amendment would
    tolerate such a judicial order. So the
    upshot of plaintiffs’ rule would be that
    the defendants must bear most of their
    own costs: the larger the class, the
    greater the proportion of costs that
    prevailing defendants must bear.
    Yet Rule 54 says that the prevailing
    party recovers costs, and nothing in Rule
    23 suggests that cost-shifting is
    inapplicable to class actions. What
    justification could there be for leaving
    prevailing defendants out of pocket? Our
    eight representative plaintiffs observe
    that they do not want to bear the high
    expenses of litigation, and that
    protestation is easy to believe--but
    Sundstrand does not want to bear it
    either, and there is no justification for
    shifting the costs to the pension plan
    and forcing fellow retirees to bear the
    costs of the eight plaintiffs’ mistaken
    litigation choices. Eight persons caused
    this litigation to be brought, caused the
    costs to be incurred, and should make the
    prevailing party whole. Now it’s true, as
    the plaintiffs stress--and as we
    recognized in Rand v. Monsanto Co., 
    926 F.2d 596
     (7th Cir. 1991)--that class
    actions are designed to aggregate claims
    of many persons with small stakes, and
    that a representative who has himself
    only (say) $1,000 to gain from success
    will be unwilling to carry the load for
    the rest of the class. Even if the odds
    of winning are favorable, few people
    would start a case where their maximum
    gain is $1,000 yet they could be hit with
    a bill for $20,000 or $50,000 in costs if
    the defendants prevail. Demanding that
    representative plaintiffs personally
    cover all costs could be the demise of
    consumer class actions. The stakes in
    this case are considerably larger than
    $1,000 per person (indeed, each represen
    tative plaintiff had a stake exceeding
    the whole bill of costs), but the
    principle is general: The absent class
    members are free riders on the
    representative plaintiffs’ legwork, and
    making the representatives’ position
    financially risky would discourage class
    actions across the board.
    It does not follow from this, however,
    that the prevailing defendant must bear
    the costs. Entrepreneurial attorneys
    already supply risk-bearing services in
    class actions. They invest legal time on
    contingent fee, taking the risk of
    failure in exchange for a premium award
    if the class prevails. A suit such as
    this, designed to generate a substantial
    financial return, induces lawyers to
    compete for the opportunity to represent
    the class. What we held in Rand is that,
    without violating ethical standards,
    attorneys may agree to bear the risk of a
    costs award, as well as the risk that
    their time will go uncompensated. By
    moving the risk of loss from the
    representative plaintiffs to the lawyers
    (who spread that risk across many cases
    and thus furnish a form of insurance)
    counsel can eliminate the financial
    disincentive that costs awards otherwise
    would create. In this case, however, the
    representative plaintiffs filed suit
    without securing from their lawyers any
    undertaking to pick up the tab; the
    lawyers have not volunteered to do so now
    that the plaintiffs have lost. The eight
    pensioners may view this as churlish--and
    other would-be plaintiffs may take this
    into account when deciding whether to
    sign on with these lawyers--but a
    decision by the representatives and their
    lawyers not to strike the bargain
    approved in Rand is a poor reason to drop
    the costs back in defendants’ laps. If
    this tactic succeeded, no sane class-
    action lawyer would again make the
    promise that the plaintiffs’ lawyers made
    in Rand.
    Plaintiffs have not cited, and we have
    not found, any case holding that
    responsibility for costs must be parceled
    out so that no member of a class pays
    more than a pro rata share. A few cases
    hold that costs awards should be several,
    rather than joint, when different groups
    of plaintiffs raise distinct issues that
    give rise to segregable costs of
    litigation. See, e.g., In re Paoli
    Railroad Yard PCB Litigation, 
    221 F.3d 449
    , 468-71 (3d Cir. 2000); Davis v.
    Parkman, 
    71 F. 961
    , 964 (1st Cir. 1895).
    Plaintiffs do not contend, however, that
    a subset of their number was responsible
    for a discrete portion of defendants’
    costs in this case. There is no basis for
    an award on other than the normal joint
    and several terms of liability.
    Affirmed