US Gypsum Co v. IN Gas Co Inc ( 2003 )


Menu:
  •                             In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    ____________
    No. 03-1905
    UNITED STATES GYPSUM COMPANY,
    Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.
    INDIANA GAS COMPANY, INCORPORATED, and
    PROLIANCE ENERGY LLC,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    ____________
    Appeal from the United States District Court for the
    Southern District of Indiana, Indianapolis Division.
    No. IP 00-1675C-Y/K—Richard L. Young, Judge.
    ____________
    ARGUED NOVEMBER 4, 2003—DECIDED NOVEMBER 24, 2003
    ____________
    Before EASTERBROOK, ROVNER, and EVANS, Circuit
    Judges.
    EASTERBROOK, Circuit Judge. Indiana Gas Co. and
    Citizens Gas & Coke, two utilities that supply natural gas
    to customers in Indiana, formed a joint venture (called
    ProLiance Energy) to manage the contracts by which they
    purchase gas and transportation services from the inter-
    state pipelines that pass through that state. United States
    Gypsum (USG) purchases substantial quantities of gas for
    use in manufacturing; it buys gas at the wellhead and deals
    directly with the pipelines for transportation. In this
    litigation under sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. §§ 1
    , 2, USG contends that ProLiance is an unlawful
    2                                               No. 03-1905
    combination that by contract controls a substantial fraction
    of the transport capacity between the gas fields and Indi-
    ana, and that it has used this market power to monopolize.
    Even though USG buys transportation directly from the
    pipelines, it alleges, the price the pipelines can charge for
    their services depends on what ProLiance has done with its
    portion of the capacity. According to USG, pipelines have
    been able to charge more for their residual capacity because
    of ProLiance’s existence (and practices) than the pipelines
    would have been able to charge in its absence.
    Indiana Gas and Citizens Gas have many customers with
    firm entitlements to gas. In order to assure delivery,
    Indiana Gas and Citizens Gas purchase more pipeline
    capacity than needed for daily deliveries; they hold the
    excess as reserve for the benefit of the uninterruptible cus-
    tomers during periods of peak demand, such as cold snaps
    or a business’s high season. During times of average de-
    mand, Indiana Gas and Citizens Gas sold their excess
    transport entitlement on the spot market, where USG
    bought it at attractive prices and used it to secure gas that
    it stored for times when spot market prices were high. After
    ProLiance came into existence, however, it ended (or at
    least greatly curtailed) these spot-market sales, forcing
    USG to pay more for firm capacity from the pipelines (firm
    commitments always sell for more than interruptible or
    spot purchases).
    There are several ways to characterize what happened.
    ProLiance contends that, by managing purchases on behalf
    of both Indiana Gas and Citizens Gas, it has achieved
    efficiencies: when one utility’s demand peaks, the other’s
    may be closer to normal, which means that less aggregate
    reserve capacity is needed. This is the way in which an
    insurer, by pooling many imperfectly correlated risks, cre-
    ates a portfolio that is less risky than any insured standing
    alone. Thus ProLiance needs less standby capacity for peak
    periods and can provide more firm, uninterruptible commit-
    ments per unit of pipeline capacity than either Indiana Gas
    No. 03-1905                                                3
    or Citizens Gas could do on its own. An increase in demand
    from the utilities’ customer base then can be met without
    an increase in price. The upshot, however, is that third
    parties such as USG find fewer bargains in the spot market.
    As USG sees matters, however, the higher spot-market
    prices stem not from risk pooling but from ProLiance either
    holding reserve capacity off the market (a reduction in
    output that drives up prices) or bundling the release of
    reserve transport capacity with gas (which USG describes
    as a monopolistic tie-in sale).
    Because all we have to go on is USG’s complaint, it is too
    soon to determine whose understanding of these events is
    superior. The district judge concluded that it would never be
    necessary to examine these issues and dismissed the
    complaint, citing Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6), on three grounds:
    first, USG has not suffered antitrust injury because it does
    not buy from ProLiance; second, the suit is barred by the
    four-year period of limitations in 15 U.S.C. §15b; third,
    USG could not prove its claims in light of adverse findings
    by the Indiana Utility Regulatory Commission in a proceed-
    ing to which USG was a party. None of these is a good
    ground on which to dismiss USG’s complaint—and the lat-
    ter two are not permissible even in principle, because the
    statute of limitations and issue preclusion are affirmative
    defenses. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 8(c). Complaints need not
    anticipate or attempt to defuse potential defenses. See
    Gomez v. Toledo, 
    446 U.S. 635
     (1980). A complaint states a
    claim on which relief may be granted when it narrates an
    intelligible grievance that, if proved, shows a legal enti-
    tlement to relief. See Swierkiewicz v. Sorema N.A., 
    534 U.S. 506
     (2002); Bennett v. Schmidt, 
    153 F.3d 516
     (7th Cir.
    1998). A litigant may plead itself out of court by alleging
    (and thus admitting) the ingredients of a defense, see
    Walker v. Thompson, 
    288 F.3d 1005
     (7th Cir. 2002) (apply-
    ing this principle to the period of limitations), but this
    4                                                 No. 03-1905
    complaint does not do so; the district judge thought, rather,
    that the complaint had failed to overcome the defenses. As
    complaints need not do this, the omissions do not justify
    dismissal. What is more, all three grounds are unsound in
    application as well as in principle.
    A private plaintiff must show antitrust injury—which is
    to say, injury by reason of those things that make the prac-
    tice unlawful, such as reduced output and higher prices.
    The antitrust-injury doctrine was created to filter out
    complaints by competitors and others who may be hurt by
    productive efficiencies, higher output, and lower prices, all
    of which the antitrust laws are designed to encourage. See,
    e.g., Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 
    495 U.S. 328
     (1990); Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc., 
    479 U.S. 104
     (1986); Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat,
    Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
     (1977). A plaintiff who wants something,
    such as less competition or higher prices, that would injure
    consumers, does not suffer antitrust injury. In Midwest Gas
    Services, Inc. v. Indiana Gas Co., 
    317 F.3d 703
     (7th Cir.
    2003), we held that the antitrust-injury doctrine prevents
    a suit by one of ProLiance’s business rivals. USG, by
    contrast, is a consumer of gas; it is in the class of persons
    protected from reductions in output and higher prices. And
    USG contends that it has been required to pay higher
    prices. Its injury (if any) is antitrust injury. That at least
    one of ProLiance’s rivals has sued, and that none of its
    indirect purchasers (the customers of Indiana Gas and
    Citizens Gas) has done so, may be informative, but it does
    not prevent USG from attempting to show that ProLiance
    has anticompetitive consequences.
    Portions of the district court’s opinion equate the anti-
    trust-injury doctrine of Brunswick and its successors with
    the direct-purchaser doctrine of Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois,
    
    431 U.S. 720
     (1977), and Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe
    Machinery Corp., 
    392 U.S. 481
     (1968). USG may suffer from
    No. 03-1905                                                  5
    higher prices but does not buy from defendants, which the
    district judge thought dispositive. If USG were seeking
    damages, and ProLiance’s direct or derivative customers
    also wanted (or could seek) monetary relief, then defen-
    dants would have a point. See Kansas v. UtiliCorp United
    Inc., 
    497 U.S. 199
     (1990) (reserving the possibility of suit by
    an indirect customer if the direct customer is a participant
    in the cartel); cf. Paper Systems Inc. v. Nippon Paper
    Industries Co., 
    281 F.3d 629
     (7th Cir. 2002). But the
    direct-purchaser doctrine does not foreclose equitable relief,
    nor does it apply when no purchaser could obtain damages,
    for then there is no risk of double recovery (and no need to
    calculate elasticities in order to apportion damages among
    multiple tiers).
    A cartel cuts output, which elevates price throughout the
    market; customers of fringe firms (sellers that have not
    joined the cartel) pay this higher price, and thus suffer
    antitrust injury, just like customers of the cartel’s members.
    We noted and reserved in Loeb Industries, Inc. v. Sumitomo
    Corp. of America, 
    306 F.3d 469
     (7th Cir. 2002), a number of
    potentially difficult issues about the design of relief when
    the customer of a fringe firm sues the (supposed) cartel
    members and the injury is derivative. See also Associated
    General Contractors of California, Inc. v. California State
    Council of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
     (1983); Blue Shield of
    Virginia v. McCready, 
    457 U.S. 465
     (1982). Courts some-
    times label this “antitrust standing,” despite the potential
    for confusion with Article III standing (which requires only
    injury in fact plus redressability.) We did not resolve these
    issues in Loeb and need not do so here either. It is enough
    to reiterate, as Loeb holds, that the buyers from fringe firms
    suffer antitrust injury, that their complaints cannot be
    dismissed at the outset under the Illinois Brick doctrine,
    and that the potential to establish injury through elevation
    of price in the affected market satisfies any distinct “anti-
    6                                                No. 03-1905
    trust standing” requirement. See also Metallgesellschaft AG
    v. Sumitomo Corp. of America, 
    325 F.3d 836
     (7th Cir. 2003).
    Now we turn to the statute of limitations. ProLiance was
    formed in March 1996, and USG did not file this suit until
    October 2000. The statute of limitations is four years—but,
    as the district judge recognized, this time runs from the
    most recent injury caused by the defendants’ activities
    rather than from the cartel’s inception. See, e.g., Zenith
    Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 
    401 U.S. 321
    (1971); United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 
    353 U.S. 586
     (1957). Cf. Klehr v. A.O. Smith Corp., 
    521 U.S. 179
    , 188-91 (1997) (describing how this approach works).
    The district court wrote that the complaint was deficient
    because USG failed to “show some injurious overt act within
    the limitations period”—but, as we have observed already,
    complaints need not allege facts that tend to defeat affirma-
    tive defenses. The right question is whether it is possible to
    imagine proof of the critical facts consistent with the
    allegations actually in the complaint. See Hishon v. King &
    Spalding, 
    467 U.S. 69
     (1984); Conley v. Gibson, 
    355 U.S. 41
    (1957). Proof that ProLiance had committed an
    anticompetitive act after October 1996 would not contradict
    any of the complaint’s allegations. Obviously USG hopes to
    show that ProLiance regularly keeps some capacity off the
    market, ties gas and transport together, or performs other
    acts that could be thought to violate the antitrust laws.
    Otherwise what’s the point of USG’s suit?
    To the extent that defendants believe that even new
    anticompetitive acts and fresh injury within the four years
    before suit are insufficient, if the joint activity began
    earlier, that position cannot be reconciled with du Pont,
    which held that old activity (in du Pont, a stock acquisition
    preceding the suit by 30 years) is not immunized, if the po-
    tential for a reduction in output is created or realized more
    recently as market conditions change. Cooperative ventures
    No. 03-1905                                                   7
    may begin innocently but acquire market power (or begin to
    exercise it) afterward; if this occurs, a suit within four years
    of any anticompetitive activity is timely. This is clear
    enough if we apply the label “cartel” to what Indiana Gas
    and Citizens Gas call a “joint venture.” Choice of terminol-
    ogy does not shorten the time for suit. A merger may be
    complete at closing, see Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick
    Corp., 
    207 F.3d 1039
    , 1050-53 (8th Cir. 2000), but a joint
    venture or cartel is a continuing cooperative activity that
    may be discontinued, or amended, from time to time.
    (According to the state agency, ProLiance’s basic agree-
    ments had to be renegotiated in 2000. Opinion at 57.) The
    parties’ decision to keep a joint venture in operation or
    manage the operations in ways that may violate antitrust
    rules is one that may be challenged when adverse effects
    are felt.
    As for issue preclusion (collateral estoppel): USG’s
    principal argument is that the state commission did not
    have “jurisdiction” to resolve a federal antitrust claim, so as
    a matter of federal law its findings must be disregarded.
    That’s wrong, for two reasons. First, the preclusive effect of
    a state judicial decision depends on state rather than
    federal law. See 
    28 U.S.C. §1738
    . (A state agency acting in
    a judicial capacity is a court for this purpose. See University
    of Tennessee v. Elliott, 478 U.S 788, 799 (1986). USG does
    not contest the district judge’s conclusion that the Indiana
    Utility Regulatory Commission, whose decision was af-
    firmed by the state’s highest court, United States Gypsum,
    Inc. v. Indiana Gas Co., 
    735 N.E.2d 790
     (Ind. 2000), was
    acting in such a capacity.) State law controls with respect
    to preclusion even when a federal court has exclusive
    jurisdiction of a federal claim that may be affected by the
    state’s decision. Marrese v. American Academy of Orthopae-
    dic Surgeons, 
    470 U.S. 373
     (1985). Second, USG confuses
    issue preclusion with claim preclusion. An agency or court
    8                                                No. 03-1905
    that lacks authority to decide whether ProLiance has
    violated the antitrust laws nonetheless may resolve a
    disputed issue—such as whether ProLiance has market
    power—that has significance beyond the particular adjudi-
    cation in which the issue is addressed. Indiana gives
    preclusive effect to issues actually and necessarily decided
    in a contested adjudication. See McClanahan v. Remington
    Freight Lines, Inc., 
    517 N.E.2d 390
    , 394 (Ind. 1988). All
    doubts about the proper use of Rule 12(b)(6) to one side, the
    right question to ask is what, in particular, the state agency
    actually decided.
    When Indiana Gas and Citizens Gas formed ProLiance,
    USG and several other customers asked the Indiana Utility
    Regulatory Commission to block the plan. They offered two
    lines of argument: first, that ProLiance would itself be a
    utility that could not come into existence without the
    Commission’s permission; second, that Indiana Gas and
    Citizens Gas (which are utilities subject to the Commis-
    sion’s jurisdiction) did not satisfy the “public interest”
    standard when forming ProLiance. The Commission re-
    jected the first on grounds that do not matter to this anti-
    trust litigation. It rejected the second after finding that
    ProLiance serves the public interest by enabling Indiana
    Gas and Citizens Gas to make better use of their joint
    reserve capacity. Petition by Ratepayers of Indiana Gas Co.,
    No. 40437 (Sept. 12, 1997), affirmed under the name United
    States Gypsum, Inc. v. Indiana Gas Co., 
    735 N.E.2d 790
    (Ind. 2000).
    One month after the state Supreme Court’s decision, USG
    filed this antitrust action, only to be met by the argument
    that the Commission’s decision knocks out essential
    elements of the federal claim. The district court wrote that
    USG loses because “the issue sought to be precluded—the
    improper creation and operation of ProLiance—is the same
    as that involved in [the] prior action that was before the”
    No. 03-1905                                                 9
    Commission. But “the improper creation and operation of
    ProLiance” is not an “issue”; that is far too lofty a level of
    generality. Putting the matter this way suggests that the
    district court has equated issue preclusion with claim
    preclusion. Indiana did not require USG to present its fed-
    eral antitrust claims to the Commission, so the rules of
    merger and bar do not block this litigation. Unless the
    agency decided some concrete issue that also bears on the
    antitrust claim, USG does not encounter a problem with
    preclusion.
    A finding that “X is in the public interest” is compatible
    with subsequent antitrust litigation. See California v. FPC,
    
    369 U.S. 482
    , 489 (1962); United States v. Radio Corp. of
    America, 
    358 U.S. 334
    , 351-52 (1959). It might mean simply
    that Indiana has decided that cartels serve the public
    interest, a conclusion that under the Supremacy Clause
    must yield to contrary federal policy. (Antitrust law makes
    an exception for state policies that compel monopolistic
    organization of regulated industries, see Cantor v. Detroit
    Edison Co., 
    428 U.S. 579
     (1976); Parker v. Brown, 
    317 U.S. 341
     (1943), but no one argues that Indiana required the
    utilities to form ProLiance.)
    Defendants do not rely on the district court’s understand-
    ing. Instead they contend that the agency made a favorable,
    concrete finding: that ProLiance lacks market power. If that
    is so, then USG’s antitrust claim fails at the threshold. See,
    e.g., Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
     (1984); Elliott v. United Center, 
    126 F.3d 1003
     (7th
    Cir. 1997); Digital Equipment Corp. v. Uniq Digital Tech-
    nologies, Inc., 
    73 F.3d 756
     (7th Cir. 1996); Chicago Profes-
    sional Sports Limited Partnership v. National Basketball
    Ass’n, 
    95 F.3d 593
     (7th Cir. 1996); Polk Bros., Inc. v. Forest
    City Enterprises, Inc., 
    776 F.2d 185
     (7th Cir. 1985). We have
    searched the agency’s decision in vain for such a finding,
    however. Although the agency mentioned market power as
    10                                               No. 03-1905
    a factor worth consideration, it did not find that ProLiance
    has none. What it did say is that (a) the pipelines’ transpor-
    tation capacity to Indiana is unaffected by ProLiance, so
    that no matter how much of the capacity has been commit-
    ted to ProLiance by contract, total deliverable supplies
    cannot fall; and (b) ProLiance had to date acted to make
    better use of the existing capacity by pooling amounts held
    in reserve.
    “To date” is a vital qualifier. The Commission issued its
    opinion in September 1997. More than six years have
    passed since then. What is ProLiance doing today? It does
    not take a leap of fancy to envisage a joint venture behaving
    itself long enough to win regulatory approbation, and only
    then applying the squeeze in the market. The agency found
    that in 1997 ProLiance was beneficial to consumers and
    that a “thriving robust . . . secondary market” (opinion at
    40) protected third parties such as USG. It wrote: “[m]ost
    important to our decision is witness Feingold’s uncontra-
    dicted evidence that, post-ProLiance, the market place
    continues to function with no ill effects.” Id. at 41. “[T]he
    affected markets are as robust after the formation of
    ProLiance as they were prior to its formation.” Id. at 55.
    That was 1997. What of 2003? The agency recognized that
    its record had been compiled quickly and reflected only the
    initial months of ProLiance’s operations. “There simply is
    little experience with the actual operation of the alli-
    ance. . . . [E]xperience under the current agreements may
    indicate that their actual operation does not comport with
    the public interest even though we find that they do so
    now.” Id. at 57. Reviewing this decision, the Supreme Court
    of Indiana made a similar point, observing that, if circum-
    stances change, the agency may revisit the subject. 735
    N.E.2d at 804. These reservations foreclose any argument
    that Indiana would deem the agency’s decision preclusive
    with respect to the economic effects of ProLiance in the
    period after September 1997. If the findings made in 1997
    No. 03-1905                                               11
    would not block Indiana itself from revisiting the subject in
    2003—and they don’t—then under §1738 they do not block
    adjudication in federal court either. It may be that a fresh
    look will lead to the same conclusions reached six years ago,
    but nothing in the agency’s decision prevents a federal court
    from taking that fresh look in antitrust litigation.
    VACATED    AND   REMANDED
    A true Copy:
    Teste:
    ________________________________
    Clerk of the United States Court of
    Appeals for the Seventh Circuit
    USCA-02-C-0072—11-24-03