Johnson, Cedric v. Daley, George M. ( 2003 )


Menu:
  •                           In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    ____________
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    CEDRIC JOHNSON,
    Plaintiff-Appellee,
    v.
    GEORGE M. DALEY,
    Defendant-Appellant,
    and
    UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
    Intervenor-Appellant.
    ____________
    Appeals from the United States District Court
    for the Western District of Wisconsin.
    No. 98-C-0518-C—Barbara B. Crabb, Chief Judge.
    ____________
    ARGUED APRIL 19, 2001—REARGUED EN BANC
    APRIL 8, 2003—DECIDED AUGUST 19, 2003
    ____________
    Before FLAUM, Chief Judge, and POSNER, COFFEY,
    EASTERBROOK, RIPPLE, MANION, KANNE, ROVNER, DIANE
    P. WOOD, EVANS, and WILLIAMS, Circuit Judges.
    EASTERBROOK, Circuit Judge. Section 803(d) of the
    Prison Litigation Reform Act, codified at 42 U.S.C.
    §1997e(d), sets both absolute and relative limits on attor-
    neys’ fee shifting. The district court held these limits
    unconstitutional because they disadvantage prisoners
    compared with other plaintiffs, whose recoveries under 42
    2                                     Nos. 00-3981 & 00-
    4115 U.S.C. §1988
    (b) in constitutional-tort litigation are not
    subject to any statutory maximum. Johnson v. Daley, 
    117 F. Supp. 2d 889
     (W.D. Wis. 2000). Every court of appeals
    that has considered this question has held, to the contrary,
    that §1997e(d) is within Congress’ authority. See Boivin
    v. Black, 
    225 F.3d 36
     (1st Cir. 2000); Hadix v. Johnson,
    
    230 F.3d 840
     (6th Cir. 2000); Walker v. Bain, 
    257 F.3d 660
    (6th Cir. 2001); Foulk v. Charrier, 
    262 F.3d 687
     (8th Cir.
    2001); Madrid v. Gomez, 
    190 F.3d 990
     (9th Cir. 1999);
    Jackson v. State Board of Pardons & Paroles, 
    331 F.3d 790
    (11th Cir. 2003). Accord, Collins v. Algarin, 1998 U.S. Dist.
    Lexis 83 (E.D. Pa. Jan. 9, 1998), affirmed by an equally
    divided court under the name Collins v. Montgomery
    County Board of Prison Inspectors, 
    176 F.3d 679
    , 686 (3d
    Cir. 1999) (en banc). Like these other circuits, we hold that
    §1997e(d) is rationally related to valid objectives and hence
    is within the legislative power, whether or not it is wise.
    I
    Section 1997e(d) provides:
    (1) In any action brought by a prisoner who is
    confined to any jail, prison, or other correctional
    facility, in which attorney’s fees are authorized
    under [
    42 U.S.C. §1988
    ], such fees shall not be
    awarded, except to the extent that—
    (A) the fee was directly and reasonably
    incurred in proving an actual violation of
    the plaintiff’s rights protected by a stat-
    ute pursuant to which a fee may be
    awarded . . . ; and
    (B)(i) the amount of the fee is propor-
    tionately related to the court ordered relief
    for the violation; or (ii) the fee was directly
    and reasonably incurred in enforcing the
    relief ordered for the violation.
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                          3
    (2) Whenever a monetary judgment is awarded in
    an action described in paragraph (1), a portion of
    the judgment (not to exceed 25 percent) shall be
    applied to satisfy the amount of attorney’s fees
    awarded against the defendant. If the award of
    attorney’s fees is not greater than 150 percent of
    the judgment, the excess shall be paid by the
    defendant.
    (3) No award of attorney’s fees in an action de-
    scribed in paragraph (1) shall be based on an hourly
    rate greater than 150 percent of the hourly rate
    established under [18 U.S.C. §3006A] for payment
    of court-appointed counsel.
    (4) Nothing in this subsection shall prohibit a
    prisoner from entering into an agreement to pay an
    attorney’s fee in an amount greater than the
    amount authorized under this subsection, if the fee
    is paid by the individual rather than by the de-
    fendant pursuant to [§1988].
    Subsections (1) and (2) establish relative limits: fees must
    be “proportionately related to the court ordered relief” and,
    when monetary relief is awarded, the fees attributable to
    that relief cannot exceed 150% of the damages. Subsection
    (3) establishes an absolute limit at 150% of the hourly rate
    for defense counsel under the Criminal Justice Act, times
    the number of hours reasonably devoted to the litigation.
    Because the CJA rate (set by the Judicial Conference of the
    United States) currently is $90 per hour, the maximum that
    the defendant may be directed to underwrite is $135 per
    hour.† The total amount that an attorney may receive,
    †
    Section 3006a, the Criminal Justice Act, authorizes payment
    at $60 per hour for work in court and $40 per hour for other work.
    It permits the Judicial Conference to raise the cap to the greater
    (continued...)
    4                                     Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    however, is greater, not only because the attorney is
    entitled to 25% of the judgment under subsection (2) but
    also because the client is free under subsection (4) to agree
    by contract to pay more—out of the recovery or out of other
    assets.
    This case shows how the statute works. Cedric Johnson
    sued George Daley, the medical director of the Bureau of
    Correctional Health Services for the Wisconsin Depart-
    ment of Corrections, under 
    42 U.S.C. §1983
    , contending
    that Daley subjected him to cruel and unusual punishment
    by waiting three years before certifying that Johnson,
    whose alcoholism had damaged his liver, was eligible for
    a transplant at public expense. Johnson contended that
    Daley had been deliberately indifferent to his serious
    †
    (...continued)
    of $75 per hour or an amount calculated with respect to cost-
    of-living increases awarded to federal employees. In September
    2000 the Judicial Conference authorized use of the $75 rate for
    all work nationwide and determined that the inXation-adjusted
    rate would be $113 per hour, but that appropriated funds did
    not permit compensation at more than $75. The 2002 and 2003
    appropriations acts for the judiciary provide funds sufWcient to
    pay appointed counsel $90 per hour, and it is the policy of the
    Judicial Conference that all work performed after May 1, 2002,
    should be compensated at that level. Johnson’s case came to trial
    in the district court before this increase, so the CJA maximum
    at the time was $75, and the PLRA maximum therefore was
    $112.50 per hour. It is possible that some of the legal work
    performed on Johnson’s behalf is affected by the earlier $60 and
    $40 maximums, which remained in effect in scattered districts. To
    facilitate exposition, we use throughout the opinion the $90 CJA
    funded rate, which implies a maximum of $135 per hour under the
    PLRA. By employing this figure, we do not imply any view on the
    question whether it is the right one, or whether instead $169.50
    (150% of $113) is today’s cap. Compare Webb v. Ada County, 
    285 F.3d 829
    , 838-39 (9th Cir. 2002), with Hernandez v. Kalinowski,
    
    146 F.3d 196
    , 201 (3d Cir. 1998).
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     5
    medical need. See Farmer v. Brennan, 
    511 U.S. 825
     (1994);
    Estelle v. Gamble, 
    429 U.S. 97
     (1976). Johnson was put
    on the eligibility list in June 1999 and appears to have
    suffered no long-term injury from the delay. Nonetheless,
    a jury agreed with Johnson that he should have been made
    eligible sooner and awarded him $10,000 in compensatory
    damages, plus $30,000 in punitive damages. Attorneys from
    Foley & Lardner and Heller Ehrman White & McAuliffe
    represented Johnson at the district judge’s request; Johnson
    did not enter into an agreement with counsel under
    §1997e(d)(4), so compensation depends entirely on the
    application of subsections (1) through (3). Counsel asked the
    judge to direct Daley to pay $92,997.20 in attorneys’ fees.
    This request exceeds both relative and absolute maximums:
    the relative cap under subsection (2) is $60,000 in fees
    (150% of the judgment), and application of the absolute cap
    in subsection (3) produces a lower award of $36,451.50.
    (This figure comes from Johnson’s lawyers. Daley and the
    United States have not questioned its accuracy, nor have
    we plumbed the details of its calculation.) Counsel sought
    compensation for 525.1 hours of work—much of it by
    paralegals with rates under $135 per hour, but some
    time by partners who contended that their market rate is
    as high as $325 per hour. Daley did not deny that this legal
    time had been reasonably devoted to the case, though he
    did dispute the hourly rates.
    Under §1997e(d) counsel could receive a maximum of
    $46,451.50 for legal services—$10,000 from the award plus
    $36,451.50 extra from Daley. As we read subsection (2),
    attorneys’ compensation comes first from the damages, as
    in ordinary tort litigation, and only if 25% of the award is
    inadequate to compensate counsel fully may defendant
    be ordered to pay more under §1988. Cf. Gisbrecht v.
    Barnhart, 
    535 U.S. 789
     (2002) (using this approach in
    Social Security cases, where any excess would be provided
    by the Equal Access to Justice Act, 
    28 U.S.C. §2412
    (d),
    6                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    rather than §1988). The district court proceeded in a dif-
    ferent way, first calculating counsel’s entitlement and then
    determining how much of this should be satisfied from the
    damages. After notifying the United States, which inter-
    vened to defend the constitutionality of the statute, the
    district court declined to enforce subsections (2) and (3).
    Subsection (1)(B)(i), which provides that fees must be “pro-
    portionately related” to the violation, is in the district
    court’s view an appropriate cap—because the judge gets
    to determine how high a “proportion” to use. The court
    concluded that attorneys’ fees should be set at $80,000, or
    200% of the judgment, under §1988, writing that this
    level is not disproportionate to the damages. Next the
    judge held that Johnson should contribute only $200 of
    this out of the judgment, leaving him with $39,800 while
    Daley has been ordered to pay a total of $128,578.81:
    $10,000 in compensatory damages, $30,000 in punitive
    damages, $79,800 in attorneys’ fees, and $8,778.81 in costs.
    The record does not disclose how much, if any, of this tab
    will be picked up by the State of Wisconsin as Daley’s
    employer. Both Daley and the United States have appealed;
    the appeal is limited to the amount by which the attorneys’
    fees exceed the maximum allowed by §1997e(d)(2) and (3).
    Counsel have not cross-appealed to seek a greater portion
    of the damages awarded to Johnson.
    II
    A
    The district court held that §1997e(d)(2) and (3) are
    incompatible with the due process clause of the fifth
    amendment, which since Bolling v. Sharpe, 
    347 U.S. 497
    (1954), has been deemed to include an equal-protection
    principle. See, e.g., Vance v. Bradley, 
    440 U.S. 93
     (1979).
    Yet the Prison Litigation Reform Act (PLRA from now on)
    does not rest on any of the powers granted by Article I of
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                       7
    the Constitution; its genesis is §5 of the fourteenth amend-
    ment, which says that “Congress shall have power to
    enforce, by appropriate legislation, the provisions of this
    article.” Legislation under the power granted by §5 is not
    necessarily subject to limitations on the original grants of
    national power; this is why Fitzpatrick v. Bitzer, 
    427 U.S. 445
     (1976), holds that Congress may use its §5 power to
    subject states to suit in federal court, despite the contrary
    text of the eleventh amendment. So the question to ask
    is whether §1997e(d) “enforces” the fourteenth amendment,
    which points us to the equal protection clause in §1 of that
    amendment without any need to detour through the fifth
    amendment—for a law at odds with the fourteenth amend-
    ment’s substantive provisions cannot be one to “enforce”
    them. See, e.g., City of Boerne v. Flores, 
    521 U.S. 507
     (1997);
    University of Alabama v. Garrett, 
    531 U.S. 356
     (2001).
    Legislation that does not burden a suspect class or af-
    fect fundamental rights satisfies the equal-protection
    requirement if the legislature could think the rule ration-
    ally related to any legitimate goal of government. Prisoners
    are not a suspect class; conviction of crime justifies the
    imposition of many burdens. See, e.g., Connecticut Dep’t of
    Public Safety v. Doe, 
    538 U.S. 1
     (2003) (public identification
    as a felon); Hudson v. United States, 
    522 U.S. 93
     (1997)
    (occupational debarment). Nor is there a fundamental right
    to have one’s adversary, or the public treasury, defray all
    or part of the cost of litigation. That is why we held the
    three-strikes provision in the PLRA, 
    28 U.S.C. §1915
    (g),
    compatible with the Constitution. See Lewis v. Sullivan,
    
    279 F.3d 526
     (7th Cir. 2002). Although prisoners enjoy
    a fundamental right of access to the courts, see Lewis v.
    Casey, 
    518 U.S. 343
     (1996), there is no right of subsidized
    access. See United States v. Kras, 
    409 U.S. 434
     (1973). The
    right to publish a newspaper does not imply a right to
    governmental funding, nor does a right to read books
    imply entitlement to a public library that circulates books
    8                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    without charge. A woman’s right to choose whether to
    have an abortion does not imply a right to have the gov-
    ernment cover the medical costs. See Maher v. Roe, 
    432 U.S. 464
     (1977). A right to education does not imply a
    right to free transportation to school. See Kadrmas v.
    Dickinson Public Schools, 
    487 U.S. 450
     (1988). A right to
    petition for redress of grievances does not imply a right to
    free writing paper and stamps. And a right to seek
    redress in court does not imply entitlement to have some-
    one else pay for your lawyer. The Supreme Court made
    this pellucid, for prisoners in particular, when holding in
    Murray v. Giarratano, 
    492 U.S. 1
     (1989), that a right to
    wage a collateral attack on one’s conviction does not en-
    tail a right to counsel at public expense, even in a capital
    case.
    Legislation singling out prisoners accordingly is an-
    alyzed under the rational-basis standard—as the plaintiffs
    concede, and as the Supreme Court held in McDonald v.
    Board of Election Commissioners, 
    394 U.S. 802
     (1969). See
    also Zehner v. Trigg, 
    133 F.3d 459
     (7th Cir. 1997) (applying
    the rational-basis standard to 42 U.S.C. §1997e(e), a
    part of the PLRA that requires prisoners to show physical
    injury as a condition to recovery, and holding that the
    statute is valid under that standard). Cf. Marshall v.
    United States, 
    414 U.S. 417
     (1974). Chief Justice Warren
    explained in McDonald how the rational-basis standard
    works:
    The distinctions drawn by a challenged statute
    must bear some rational relationship to a legiti-
    mate state end and will be set aside as violative of
    the Equal Protection Clause only if based on rea-
    sons totally unrelated to the pursuit of that goal.
    Legislatures are presumed to have acted constitu-
    tionally even if source materials normally resorted
    to for ascertaining their grounds for action are
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                        9
    otherwise silent, and their statutory classifications
    will be set aside only if no grounds can be conceived
    to justify them. See McGowan v. Maryland, 
    366 U.S. 420
     (1961); Kotch v. Board of River Port Pilot
    Commissioners, 
    330 U.S. 552
     (1947); Lindsley v.
    Natural Carbonic Gas Co., 
    220 U.S. 61
     (1911). With
    this much discretion, a legislature traditionally
    has been allowed to take reform “one step at a
    time, addressing itself to the phase of the problem
    which seems most acute to the legislative mind,”
    Williamson v. Lee Optical of Oklahoma, Inc., 
    348 U.S. 483
    , 489 (1955); and a legislature need not run
    the risk of losing an entire remedial scheme sim-
    ply because it failed, through inadvertence or
    otherwise, to cover every evil that might conceiv-
    ably have been attacked. See Ozan Lumber Co. v.
    Union County National Bank, 
    207 U.S. 251
     (1907).
    
    394 U.S. at 809
    . Under this standard, a legislative deci-
    sion “is not subject to courtroom fact-finding and may be
    based on rational speculation unsupported by evidence
    or empirical data.” FCC v. Beach Communications, Inc.,
    
    508 U.S. 307
    , 315 (1993). See also, e.g., Nordlinger v. Hahn,
    
    505 U.S. 1
    , 15 (1992); Minnesota v. Clover Leaf Creamery
    Co., 
    449 U.S. 456
    , 463-65 (1981); Vance v. Bradley, 
    440 U.S. at 111
    . “[R]ational-basis review in equal protection analy-
    sis ‘is not a license for courts to judge the wisdom, fairness,
    or logic of legislative choices.’ ” Heller v. Doe, 
    509 U.S. 312
    ,
    319 (1993) (citations omitted). See also, e.g., New Orleans
    v. Dukes, 
    427 U.S. 297
     (1976); Massachusetts Board of
    Retirement v. Murgia, 
    427 U.S. 307
     (1976); University of
    Alabama v. Garrett, 
    531 U.S. at 366-67
     (holding that
    Cleburne v. Cleburne Living Center, 
    473 U.S. 432
     (1985), on
    which the district court relied in this case, does not estab-
    lish a sliding-scale approach).
    10                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    B
    Whether the line drawn in the PLRA between prisoners’
    suits and free persons’ suits is rational may depend on
    answering the question: “equal with respect to what”? The
    district court compared §1997e(d) with §1988, which
    entitles prevailing parties in constitutional cases to recover
    reasonable attorneys’ fees. Section 1988 has been treated as
    asymmetric—that is, prevailing plaintiffs recover their
    legal expenses but prevailing defendants do not. See
    Christiansburg Garment Co. v. EEOC, 
    434 U.S. 412
     (1978)
    (defendants recover legal expenses only if the suit is
    frivolous—in which event they would be entitled to re-
    compense even without regard to a statute). A plaintiff
    achieves “prevailing party” status by recovering any
    judgment, even for nominal damages. Compare Farrar v.
    Hobby, 
    506 U.S. 103
     (1992), with Buckhannon Board &
    Care Home, Inc. v. West Virginia Dep’t of Health & Human
    Resources, 
    532 U.S. 598
     (2001). Although fees must be
    “reasonable”, so that de minimis or Pyrrhic victories do not
    support fee-shifting, see Maul v. Constan, 
    23 F.3d 143
    , 145,
    147 (7th Cir. 1994), the flexible reasonableness standard
    permits a court to award legal fees that substantially
    exceed the damages, see Riverside v. Rivera, 
    477 U.S. 561
    (1986), even though no solvent private litigant in tort or
    contract litigation would agree to pay counsel more than the
    anticipated recovery (or the value of equitable relief). So
    §1988 is exceptionally pro-plaintiff. The district judge asked
    why, if medicine this strong is needed to promote consti-
    tutional claims by free persons against state actors, prison-
    ers do not need at least as much assistance.
    This approach assumes, however, that prisoners and free
    persons have similar constitutional claims. As Johnson’s
    case shows, that is not altogether true. Free persons are
    not constitutionally entitled to liver transplants or other
    costly medical care at public expense. States have ex-
    tra obligations toward prisoners and must provide care
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                   11
    appropriate to their serious medical needs because impris-
    onment takes away their ability to fend for themselves. See
    DeShaney v. Winnebago County Department of Social
    Services, 
    489 U.S. 189
     (1989). A complaint along the lines
    of Johnson’s, if made by a free person, usually would
    take the form of a contention that a physician committed
    the tort of malpractice. And the prevailing party in tort
    litigation must bear 100% of his own attorneys’ fees; that’s
    the American Rule. See Alyeska Pipeline Service Co. v.
    Wilderness Society, 
    421 U.S. 240
     (1975). Now it is true
    that a free person may recover for negligence, while a
    prisoner must show intentional misconduct (where “deliber-
    ate indifference” to his needs counts as intentional); the
    free person therefore is more likely to prevail in any
    given situation. But the free person still must cover his
    own legal costs, even if he shows gross negligence or wilful
    misconduct by the physician. Such proof may lead to
    awards of punitive damages (as in Johnson’s case) but
    will not require the defendant to reimburse the plaintiff
    for the cost of legal representation. If we compare pris-
    oners under §1997e(d) with free persons who received
    bad medical care, perhaps the question should be why
    prisoners receive legal services at defendants’ expense, and
    free persons do not.
    Ordinary tort litigation is not the only option. Suppose
    Johnson had been free and unable to pay for a liver trans-
    plant. He might have requested medical care under
    Medicaid—but if the responsible agency had delayed
    making him eligible, there would not have been any op-
    tion to litigate. The agency’s decision about applications
    for individual benefits is the end of the line under the
    Medicaid program. See Heckler v. Ringer, 
    466 U.S. 602
    (1984). Such a free person is decidedly worse off than a
    prisoner. Or consider how Johnson would have been
    treated as a veteran seeking medical care in a Veterans
    Administration hospital. A decision by the hospital’s staff
    12                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    deferring his eligibility for a liver transplant would have
    been subject to review by an administrative tribunal but
    not the Article III courts. Compare 
    38 U.S.C. §7252
     with
    
    38 U.S.C. §7292
    (d)(2). And, until recently, veterans were
    prohibited from paying attorneys more than $10 out of
    their own resources to seek a favorable result in the
    administrative process. The Supreme Court held in Walters
    v. National Ass’n of Radiation Survivors, 
    473 U.S. 305
    (1985), that this cap was constitutional because Congress
    was entitled to rely on the bar (and veterans’ organizations)
    to donate free legal services. Once again prisoners are
    decidedly better off under the PLRA.
    If a veteran suffers on account of substandard medical
    care at a VA hospital, the legal remedy is under the Federal
    Tort Claims Act. This statute forbids punitive damages. 
    28 U.S.C. §2674
     ¶1. It caps attorneys’ fees at 25% of any
    judgment (20% if the case is settled). 
    28 U.S.C. §2678
    .
    Those legal fees are deducted from the plaintiff’s recovery;
    the United States does not cover any part of a prevailing
    plaintiff’s legal expenses. A prisoner can offer his lawyer
    at defendant’s expense as much as 150% of the recovery
    (plus a quarter of the recovery itself, and any additional
    amount provided by contract), while a veteran can offer
    counsel no more than 25% of a recovery that never in-
    cludes punitive damages. Moreover, the plaintiff is forbid-
    den to supplement these fees by private contract with his
    lawyer. The Westfall Act, 
    28 U.S.C. §2679
    (d), makes this
    remedy against the United States exclusive; any effort to
    evade the cap by suing federal employees will be defeated
    by replacing them with the United States as the sole de-
    fendant. See generally Gutierrez de Martinez v. Lamagno,
    
    515 U.S. 417
     (1995). A litigant who can show that the
    United States took in the litigation itself a position that
    was not substantially justified may recover some attor-
    neys’ fees under the Equal Access to Justice Act, 
    28 U.S.C. §2412
    (d), but even the most egregious pre-litigation con-
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                   13
    duct by federal agents or employees does not permit an
    award of attorneys’ fees. Litigants who qualify for an award
    under the EAJA encounter a statutory cap: “attorney fees
    shall not be awarded in excess of $125 per hour unless the
    court determines that an increase in the cost of living or
    a special factor, such as the limited availability of quali-
    fied attorneys for the proceedings involved, justifies a
    higher fee” (§2412(d)(2)(A)(ii)). By contrast, the PLRA per-
    mits the court to award fees up to $135 per hour, to be paid
    by the defendant, without any need to prove that the
    defendant’s conduct in the litigation was not “substantially
    justified.”
    Counsel readily agree to represent veterans and other
    injured persons in suits under the FTCA, even though these
    suits are subject to caps more stringent than those con-
    fronting prisoners under the PLRA. Congress rationally
    could conclude in light of this experience that prisoners,
    like veterans, will be able to enjoy the benefit of counsel,
    when they have good claims (a vital qualifier).
    It is difficult to ascribe the caps in the PLRA to irra-
    tional antipathy, when prisoners fare better under the
    PLRA than do veterans and other free persons who must
    bear their own legal expenses under the American Rule and
    the FTCA. Caps on attorneys’ fees, far from being unique to
    prisoners (as the district judge supposed), are common in
    litigation against governments and their employees. For
    example, persons claiming benefits under the Social
    Security program must pay their own lawyers (unless the
    EAJA applies because the government’s litigating position
    was unreasonable); and it is unlawful for any claimant
    to agree to pay counsel more than 25% of past-due bene-
    fits as compensation for legal services rendered in ob-
    taining those benefits. 
    42 U.S.C. §406
    (b) (discussed in
    Gisbrecht, 
    supra).
     School children and their parents,
    seeking a better education under the Individuals with
    Disabilities Education Act, may not recover more than
    14                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    $1,300 in attorneys’ fees (at rates of more than $50 per
    hour) in suits within the District of Columbia. D.C. Code.
    §11-2604. That limit (which has since been raised) was
    sustained as rational, even though Congress allows
    greater awards outside the District. See Calloway v.
    District of Columbia, 
    216 F.3d 1
    , 4-5 (D.C. Cir. 2000). In
    a world where veterans, employees who have paid em-
    ployment taxes for a half century, and school children
    must pay for their own lawyers, or accept reimbursement
    at low rates, it is difficult to treat as irrational a statute
    limiting to $135 per hour, or 150% of the recovery, the
    amount of legal fees that courts may require defendants
    to pay in prisoners’ cases.
    Prisoners may think of $135 per hour as munificent,
    compared with the compensation of their lawyers in pre-
    trial and trial proceedings. Solvent defendants must pay
    all of their legal expenses and are not reimbursed if
    they prevail. For insolvent defendants, the Criminal Jus-
    tice Act, 18 U.S.C. §3006A, in conjunction with decisions
    of the Judicial Conference, caps at $90 per hour how
    much the public fisc will pay for counsel—yet criminal
    defendants have a right to counsel far stronger than any
    entitlement to fee-shifting in civil suits. See Gideon v.
    Wainwright, 
    372 U.S. 335
     (1963). The hourly cap under the
    CJA combines with a per-case cap of $5,200 in a felony
    prosecution. Although courts are authorized to approve
    compensation exceeding $5,200 in exceptional cases, few
    criminal trials are so exceptional that defense counsel take
    home $36,000, the PLRA cap for Johnson. If this had been
    a criminal prosecution, and Johnson had been a defen-
    dant rather than the plaintiff, his lawyers would have
    been paid considerably less than $36,000. If $5,200 is
    enough to secure a competent criminal defense—and it
    is—how can the PLRA cap of $36,000 be unconstitu-
    tionally low for a civil plaintiff? The stakes of the crim-
    inal prosecution for the defendant are considerably great-
    er than the stakes in most post-imprisonment civil suits.
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     15
    The kind of post-imprisonment litigation most important
    to inmates is the collateral attack—on the conviction itself
    or on decisions affecting good-time credits (and thus the
    computation of the release date). Yet, when seeking re-
    lease, a prisoner is entitled to no legal assistance at all.
    If the prisoner obtains legal assistance and prevails, with
    the court declaring that the incarceration was unconstitu-
    tional from the outset, the state government will not be
    required to pay a single penny of counsel’s fees. Courts
    and defendants alike rely on—and receive—legal services
    donated by the bar or supplied by legal assistance bureaus
    (defender programs, legal aid clinics at law schools, pro-
    grams underwritten by the Legal Services Corporation, or
    programs funded by IOLTA proceeds, see Brown v. Legal
    Foundation of Washington, 
    123 S. Ct. 1406
     (2003)). Only
    in capital cases does any federal statute provide for post-
    conviction counsel, and even then the rate is capped at
    $125 per hour, see 
    21 U.S.C. §848
    (q)(10)(A), or $10 less
    than the current maximum under the PLRA.
    If asked why $0 for most collateral attacks and prosecu-
    tions of solvent persons, $90 for criminal defense under
    the CJA if the defendant is insolvent, $125 under the
    EAJA and collateral attacks in capital cases, $135 under
    the PLRA, and 25% of back benefits under the Social Se-
    curity system, we might be unable to give a convincing
    answer. Caps have an arbitrary quality; different majorities
    in the legislature at different times have different willing-
    ness to expend public funds (or write checks that must be
    paid by state actors such as Dr. Daley, or the states them-
    selves as indemnitors). Some of these caps depend on an
    interaction between legislation and decisions of the Judicial
    Conference, and these different bodies may have different
    objectives. Some Congresses favor more litigation and
    adjust fee schedules to promote it; other Congresses pay
    more attention to the costs of adding cases to the docket (in-
    cluding the costs to defendants and to the federal system
    16                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    when Congress is adopting rules for state actors) and
    adjust rules to make litigation less attractive. There is no
    one right answer to the question how much litigation
    there should be, and who should pay for that litigation.
    We are conscious that the numbers we have given are
    not directly comparable. Criminal defense counsel re-
    ceives $90 per hour win or lose; a prisoner’s lawyer re-
    ceives as much as $135 per hour, or a Social Security
    claimant’s lawyer 25% of the back benefits, only in the
    event of victory, as with a tort lawyer on contingent fee;
    an award at $125 per hour under the EAJA depends on
    both prevailing in the litigation and showing that the
    government’s position was not substantially justified. So
    the actuarial value of an hour devoted to the case by
    criminal defense counsel may exceed the value of an hour
    under the PLRA. But the value of an hour under the
    PLRA exceeds that of an hour under the EAJA—and any
    fee-shifting system offers more to counsel than does the
    no-shifting approach on post-conviction challenges to the
    fact of incarceration.
    The United States Code and its implementing rules
    are the work of thousands of different actors over scores
    of years; consistency is not possible. But what this means
    is that all of these different systems could be thought
    rational solutions to the question “how much may plaintiffs
    be allowed to spend for legal services, how much of that
    must be paid for by the losing side, and how much of the
    cost of litigation will be covered by the public fisc?” Litiga-
    tion produces benefits (and sometimes costs) for third
    parties; it is to this extent a public good, and determining
    how much of a public good to supply (and at whose cost)
    is an intractable problem. The American Rule is a rational
    approach; the British loser-pays rule is a rational approach;
    asymmetric fee-shifting in §1988 is a rational approach;
    asymmetric fee shifting plus compensation for the risk of
    loss in order to induce counsel to be indifferent between
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                   17
    paying clients and chancy constitutional claims would
    be rational (and is used in common-fund cases, though
    not under statutes such as §1988, see Burlington v. Dague,
    
    505 U.S. 557
     (1992)); and fee caps such as the FTCA, the
    EAJA, and the PLRA also represent rational approaches.
    The observation that prisoners receive less under the
    PLRA than under §1988 no more shows that the PLRA
    is irrational, than the fact that defendants pay more
    under §1988 than under the PLRA (or the FTCA, or the
    EAJA, or the American Rule) shows that §1988 is itself
    irrational. These are simply different legislative solu-
    tions to an enduring problem; in a democracy, each of
    these options is open to the people’s representatives.
    C
    Even if §1988 is the right benchmark for the question
    “compared to what?”, the rational-basis standard permits
    Congress to distinguish prisoners from free persons
    when deciding how much the defendant must subsidize a
    prevailing plaintiff. The PLRA draws many distinctions
    between prisoners and other persons covered by civil rights
    statutes. We held in Zehner that Congress rationally could
    distinguish prisoners from free persons for the purpose
    of suits seeking compensation for mental distress. We
    held in Lewis that Congress rationally applied the three-
    strikes rule to prisoners but not free persons. See also
    Lucien v. DeTella, 
    141 F.3d 773
     (7th Cir. 1998) (PLRA’s fee-
    collection and prepayment system is constitutional). The
    Supreme Court has twice interpreted and enforced the
    PLRA’s rule, 42 U.S.C. §1997e(a), that prisoners (and only
    prisoners) must exhaust administrative remedies be-
    fore filing suit under 
    42 U.S.C. §1983
    . Porter v. Nussle,
    
    534 U.S. 516
     (2002); Booth v. Churner, 
    532 U.S. 731
     (2001).
    Neither decision hints that there is anything prob-
    lematic about treating prisoners differently. After we
    18                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    held unconstitutional the portion of the PLRA making
    equitable relief harder to get (and harder to keep) in prison-
    reform suits than in litigation about other institutions, see
    French v. Duckworth, 
    178 F.3d 437
     (7th Cir. 1999), the
    Supreme Court reversed and held that the PLRA must be
    applied as written. Miller v. French, 
    530 U.S. 327
     (2000).
    None of the Justices suggested that there is any constitu-
    tional problem in distinguishing prisoners’ suits from free
    persons’ suits. And in Martin v. Hadix, 
    527 U.S. 343
     (1999),
    the Supreme Court considered one issue about the scope
    of §1997e(d) itself, again without any of its members
    suggesting that the statute has a constitutional flaw.
    Congress could conclude that prisoners differ from free
    persons in ways relevant to litigation. A rational legislature
    would be entitled to believe the following:
    • Prisoners have time on their hands. Unlike free
    persons, who must skip work or shun family to
    visit a law library and draft legal documents,
    prisoners have ample leisure. Persons with low
    opportunity cost of time substitute their own
    efforts for purchased commodities, such as legal
    services, and demand more of those things (such
    as litigation) that can be had for the investment
    of time alone. As a result, prisoners file many
    more federal suits per person than do free per-
    sons. (Prisoners, who account for less than 1% of
    the population, file more than 20% of all civil
    actions in the federal courts. See Administrative
    Office of the U.S. Courts, Judicial Business of the
    United States Courts 2002 Table C-2. In the year
    preceding the PLRA’s enactment, prisoners filed
    federal suits about 35 times as frequently as
    noninmates. See Margo Schlanger, Inmate Litiga-
    tion, 
    116 Harv. L. Rev. 1555
    , 1575 (2003).)
    • Prisoners receive paper and postage; they have
    access to legal materials, see Bounds v. Smith,
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                       19
    
    430 U.S. 817
     (1977); inmate writ-writers provide
    assistance that, for free persons, would be
    deemed the unauthorized practice of law. These
    materials and services make it easier for prison-
    ers to litigate.
    • Many prisoners have a burning desire to turn the
    tables on the guards and other prison personnel,
    discomfiting if not hurting or humiliating them.
    This non-economic incentive to litigate produces
    additional suits, which as grudge matches are
    particularly hard to resolve.
    • For some prisoners, litigation is recreation.
    Although most free persons shun litigation,
    because they have many better ways to amuse
    themselves, prisoners may see a trip to court as a
    vacation.
    • These and other circumstances, including defen-
    dants’ desire not to attract additional nuisance
    suits, make prisoners’ suits unusually hard to
    settle, so that they impose on the judicial system
    (and thus on other litigants) a burden dispropor-
    tionate to their numbers and intrinsic difficulty.
    (Professor Schlanger found that 6% of prisoners’
    civil suits are settled, compared with 28% of
    noninmates’ civil-rights litigation and 50% of
    ordinary tort litigation. 116 Harv. L. Rev. at
    1598. She also determined that the costs federal
    courts and prisons incur in handling prisoners’
    suits top $175 million annually, far exceeding
    prisoners’ damages recoveries. Id. at 1622-26.)
    • Prisoners are less honest than free persons and
    thus more likely to tell tall tales of victimization.
    The convictions that put them in prison establish
    their proclivity to violate the law when they see
    a personal advantage in doing so. (This is a prem-
    20                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    ise of Fed. R. Evid. 609, which permits use of
    prior convictions to impeach the veracity of
    testimony.) The pot o’ gold at the end of litigation
    is a lure that induces dishonest claims.
    • At the same time, however, prisoners are less
    amenable to sanctions for making false claims.
    Many are destitute; none earns wages subject to
    garnishment. The threat of prosecution for per-
    jury holds little terror for a person already in
    prison, as a perjury sentence would be deferred
    until the expiration of existing terms; for those
    serving life sentences without prospect of parole,
    no further penal sanction is possible.
    It is not our part to determine which of these things is
    true; it is enough to say that a legislature could think
    them true without taking leave of its senses. They make
    it apt to ask why, if prisoners file so many suits even
    though they receive legal assistance only 4% of the time,
    they require (or deserve) a subsidy to provide more legal
    assistance at defendants’ expense. The 4% figure for
    prisoners who have counsel comes from the Bureau of
    Justice Statistics and is reported in Roger A. Hanson &
    Henry W.K. Daley, Challenging the Conditions of Prisons
    and Jails: A Report on Section 1983 Litigation 21-22 (1995).
    Some prisoners have counsel from the outset; others,
    including Johnson, benefit from the district court’s assis-
    tance in recruiting counsel. Even after the PLRA’s adop-
    tion, about 4.4% of prisoners’ suits are prosecuted with
    the benefit of counsel. See Schlanger, 116 Harv. L. Rev. at
    1609. Many of these lawyers—who are not appointed or
    otherwise conscripted but serve voluntarily, see Mallard
    v. United States District Court, 
    490 U.S. 296
     (1989)—are
    willing to assist for slight compensation, but a legislature
    rationally may think that the supply of lawyers prepared
    to serve on judicial request is affected by the compensa-
    tion available if the plaintiff prevails. See Stewart J.
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                    21
    Schwab & Theodore Eisenberg, Explaining Constitutional
    Tort Litigation: The Influence of the Attorney Fees Statute
    and the Government as Defendant, 
    73 Cornell L. Rev. 719
    (1988).
    As the district judge perceived matters, the respects in
    which prisoners differ from free persons affect only friv-
    olous and small stakes litigation. Prisoners file a super-
    abundance of frivolous suits, the judge allowed, but none
    of these ends in an award of attorneys’ fees under §1988
    and so none is affected by §1997e(d). Prisoners also file
    a profusion of small-stakes claims over $10 losses, such
    as the hobby kit in Parratt v. Taylor, 
    451 U.S. 527
     (1981),
    that any free person would let slide by rather than pay
    the $150 filing fee and devote costly time to litigation.
    Professor Schlanger found that prisoners lose some 93%
    of all civil suits they file. About 6% are settled: these
    are the only numerically significant victories, as defendants
    win 9/10 of the 3% of cases that make it to trial. 116 Harv.
    L. Rev. at 1598. The median recovery when a prisoner
    prevails at trial is $1,000. Id. at 1602-03. But the district
    judge was sure that pestiferous suits could be deterred
    by limiting attorneys’ fees to what is “reasonable” in light
    of the ends in view (including deterrence of similar petty
    misconduct by guards), without any need to curtail awards
    of legal fees in more substantial litigation.
    Let us start with the second of these propositions—that
    the reasonableness requirement in §1988, coupled with
    decisions such as Farrar v. Hobby, 
    supra,
     and, e.g., Cole
    v. Wodziak, 
    169 F.3d 486
     (7th Cir. 1999), and provisions in
    the PLRA making it harder for prisoners to litigate with-
    out paying the filing fee, suffice to discourage suits over
    trivial harms (or at least to make prisoners no more likely
    to file such suits than are free persons). This assumes
    that Congress is entitled to use only one tool to achieve
    a given objective. Why would that be? Legislatures often,
    and legitimately, select multiple devices. A “reasonable-
    22                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    ness” requirement varies, like the length of the chancellor’s
    foot, from judge to judge. Some are more generous than
    others with defendants’ money, and the district judge’s
    substantial discretion, see Hensley v. Eckerhart, 
    461 U.S. 424
    , 437-38 (1983), which implies deferential appellate
    review of fee awards, ensures inconsistency. Congress
    rationally could conclude—on the ground of equitable
    treatment alone—that a quantitative rule (such as “fees
    can’t exceed 150% of the judgment”) should supplement
    a qualitative one (such as “fees can’t exceed what is rea-
    sonable”).
    As for the contention that §1997e(d) does not affect
    frivolous suits (because none is eligible for fees under
    §1988): a legislature rationally may conclude that, because
    prisoners litigate even frivolous claims to excess, they do
    not need any extra incentive to litigate meritorious claims.
    The district court’s view that the PLRA does not affect
    prisoners’ decisions depends on two assumptions, neither
    of which it justified. The first (which the dissenting opin-
    ion likewise indulges) is that each suit is known from the
    outset to be either frivolous or meritorious. The second is
    that no prisoner makes rational calculations of gains and
    losses from suit. Yet Congress is not bound to use these
    assumptions.
    Take the first: that a suit’s merit (or lack thereof) is
    known to court and counsel. Why is this necessarily true?
    Some suits entail legal uncertainty, others factual uncer-
    tainty—and a legislature could conclude that prisoners’
    proclivity for deceit makes it hard for outsiders to tell
    which end is up. District judges have a hard time telling
    the two apart: prisoners lose half of all cases in which
    the judge deems the claim sufficiently meritorious to re-
    cruit counsel, and others are settled for sums that may
    reflect the defendants’ litigation costs rather than a high
    probability that the prisoner would prevail. See Schwab &
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     23
    Eisenberg, supra, 73 Cornell L. Rev. at 773-74. If district
    judges cannot reliably separate strong from weak claims,
    neither can counsel; and if the suit’s strength is hard to
    determine at the outset, then a law reducing fees in suc-
    cessful suits also affects the filing of weak claims. An
    example makes the point.
    Suppose a prisoner’s complaint alleges that a guard set
    upon and beat him without provocation, and the prisoner
    files an affidavit to that effect. The guard responds that
    the supposed battery never occurred and adds that the
    prisoner’s injury was inflicted by his cellmate in a gam-
    bling dispute. Is this suit frivolous or meritorious? If the
    prisoner is lying, it is frivolous; if the guard is lying, the
    suit is meritorious. The judge cannot be sure who is tell-
    ing the truth and is not authorized to resolve the case
    short of trial. Nor could a lawyer representing the pris-
    oner be sure who is honest; deceitful prisoners have no
    reason to be candid with counsel and may be able to recruit
    fellow inmates as witnesses (for other prisoners may
    want to make life miserable for the guard, and like the
    plaintiff are hard to sanction for perjury).
    Suppose that 9 out of 10 prisoners making such claims
    are lying, while 1 of 10 guards is lying. (This assumption
    tracks Professor Schlanger’s finding that prisoners lose
    90% of suits that go to trial.) Suppose further that, if
    the jury finds for the plaintiff, it will award $50,000 in
    damages and, but for the PLRA, the judge would award
    $150,000 in legal fees (if a lawyer takes the case). Finally,
    suppose that with the assistance of counsel the plain-
    tiff would prevail before a jury 20% of the time, while
    unaided the plaintiff will win only 10% of these cases.
    Before the PLRA’s enactment, this case on filing is worth
    $10,000 (= $50,000 × 0.2) to the prisoner, who will win 20%
    of the time with legal assistance (a form of regression to
    the mean, since most errors will come from the 90% of
    claims in which the prisoner is deceitful); the expected legal
    24                                 Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    award is worth $30,000 to counsel ($150,000 × 0.2), which
    induces counsel to assist; and the expected judgment from
    the guard’s perspective is $40,000 (($50,000 + $150,000) ×
    0.2). With the PLRA in force, the expected legal fee falls
    to $15,000 (assuming that the 150% cap is the effective
    limit), and counsel may be unwilling to take the case. Then
    the prisoner’s expected recovery falls to $5,000 ($50,000 ×
    0.1), and the guard’s anticipated judgment is the same (for
    there will be no legal fees). If it turns out that $15,000 is
    enough to recruit counsel, then the prisoner’s expected
    recovery rises to $10,000 (just as before the PLRA), but
    the guard’s outlay falls to $20,000—which, considering
    the 90% chance that the prisoner is lying, still is too high
    but is more appropriate than the pre-PLRA anticipated
    loss of $40,000.
    By reducing the prisoner’s expected recovery from
    $10,000 to $5,000 in this class of cases, the statute dis-
    courages suits that are frivolous when viewed objec-
    tively—or so Congress rationally could conclude. The
    decision is made ex ante, and at this stage the PLRA has
    a direct effect on counsel’s willingness to represent those
    prisoners making frivolous claims. See Boivin, 
    225 F.3d at 45
    . By reducing the defendant’s anticipated cost of li-
    tigation from $40,000 to $20,000 for this set of claims
    even when counsel takes the prisoner’s case, the PLRA
    brings the outcome closer to the real loss entailed—or so,
    again, Congress rationally could conclude.
    We come to the district court’s second assumption: that
    prisoners just don’t think this way. The judge was cer-
    tain that prisoners who are deluded, or determined to lie
    in court, will do so no matter what, and that prisoners
    determined to file frivolous suits are incorrigible. The
    PLRA then will fail; prisoners won’t desist from filing in
    the class of suits we have described (or any other). Yet
    a legislature could believe that, even if the law has no
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                      25
    effect on plaintiffs, its effect from defendants’ perspective
    (reducing the fees that must be paid on top of damages) is
    a public benefit. Moreover, a legislature rationally could
    conclude that some prisoners will respond to the adjust-
    ments. Marginal effects may differ from average effects.
    Even if 80% of prisoners are insensible to changes in the
    litigation process, different behavior by the other 20%
    would be welcome. A reduction in prisoners’ suits by 20%
    would reduce the total caseload of the federal courts by
    about 5%. The actual reduction between 1995, the year
    before the PLRA’s enactment, and 2001 is even greater. In
    1995 prisoners filed 39,008 federal civil-rights suits, or 24.6
    suits per 1,000 inmates. In 2001 they filed 22,206 such
    suits, at a rate of 11.4 per 1,000 inmates. See Schlanger,
    116 Harv. L. Rev. at 1583. While the number of prisoners
    rose, the number of suits dropped dramatically. (Note that
    this is a decline before application of two other changes
    made by the PLRA: screening under 28 U.S.C. §1915A and
    dismissals under §1997e(a) for failure to exhaust admini-
    strative remedies.)
    That the PLRA has led prisoners to cut by half their
    propensity to sue shows that they do respond to incen-
    tives. Litigation is never free, even to a prisoner, if only
    because it diverts time from exercise and watching tele-
    vision. Congress rationally could believe that the size of
    the expected recovery influences some prisoners’ decisions
    about how to allocate their time. Although the amount
    of the effect attributable to §1997e(d) is hard to calculate,
    its direction is knowable. A rational legislature could
    conclude that a small reduction in weak, trivial, or bogus
    suits is worth achieving even at some potential cost to
    prisoners’ ability to prevail in the less common meritorious
    suit. See, e.g., National Paint & Coatings Ass’n v. Chicago,
    
    45 F.3d 1124
     (7th Cir. 1995) (discussing how the differ-
    ence between marginal and inframarginal behavior af-
    fects analysis under the rational-basis standard).
    26                                 Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    D
    Even if all of this is wrong, Congress rationally could
    suspect that fee awards under §1988 are excessive as a
    rule, and that prisoners’ suits are an appropriate place to
    explore the results of a cutback. The ability to take one
    step at a time, to alter the rules for one subset (to see
    what happens) without changing the rules for everyone,
    is one of the most important legislative powers protected
    by the rational-basis standard. And it would be entirely
    rational to conclude that fees under §1988 are in need
    of recalibration. Although a plurality of the Court in
    Riverside rejected the contention that attorneys’ fees
    must be proportional to damages, see 
    477 U.S. at 573-81
    (opinion of Brennan, J., joined by Marshall, Blackmun &
    Stevens, JJ.), four other Justices concluded that §1988 as
    it stands should be understood to limit awards against
    defendants to the amount that a solvent plaintiff would be
    willing to pay his own lawyer, a sum generally less than the
    prospective recovery. See 
    477 U.S. at 588-96
     (Rehnquist, J.,
    dissenting, joined by Burger, C.J., and White & O’Connor,
    JJ.). Justice Powell, who wrote the dispositive opinion,
    concluded that the award—about $245,000 in fees for legal
    work that led to $33,350 in damages—was unjust to the
    defendants (why should these defendants be made to pay
    for legal services whose principal effect is to improve
    deterrence with respect to other would-be violators?) but
    could not be set aside given deferential appellate review
    and statements in the legislative history implying that
    some Members of Congress thought a hard cap unwar-
    ranted.
    Members of Congress who agreed with Justice Powell
    about fairness to defendants (or for that matter with
    Justice Rehnquist about the appropriate rule for all civil-
    rights cases) rationally could decide to alter the approach
    of §1988 (as Justice Brennan interpreted it) for a subset
    of all cases to which it applies. For reasons we have cov-
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                   27
    ered, prisoners are a sensible subset with which to begin,
    and §1997e(d) is a modest step. The district court’s award
    requires Daley to pay more than 12 times the jury’s esti-
    mate of actual damages; even with the PLRA cap in full
    effect, Daley must pay about 8 times actual damages, which
    is still a hefty multiplier. (A larger multiplier than the
    double-damages approach that, according to State Farm
    Mutual Automobile Insurance Co. v. Campbell, 
    123 S. Ct. 1513
    , 1526 (2003), may be the constitutional limit for
    awards based on emotional distress.) Experience under
    the PLRA may lead to more general modifications—or, if
    too many good claims no longer can be vindicated, this
    experience may lead Congress to lift or adjust the cap
    for prisoners. The Constitution permits this sort of tin-
    kering; it does not put the legislature to an all-or-none
    choice at the outset, before data can be collected.
    The step-at-a-time corollary to the rational-basis stan-
    dard tolerates the sort of inconsistency to which all sys-
    tems of majority voting are prone. See Kenneth J. Arrow,
    Social Choice and Individual Values (2d ed. 1963). Sup-
    pose one-third of all legislators believe with Justice
    Brennan that no limit should be applied to awards of
    attorneys’ fees in any constitutional suit; that one-third
    believe with Justice Rehnquist that awards in all constitu-
    tional suits should be limited to the amount (almost al-
    ways less than the damages) that a solvent private liti-
    gant would be willing to pay for legal assistance; and that
    one-third believe that the plaintiffs with the lowest oppor-
    tunity costs of time (which is to say, prisoners) should
    be required to substitute their own time for lawyers’ time
    to some extent. Two-thirds of these legislators would
    agree with the proposition: “Prisoners and free persons
    should be treated alike with respect to recovering attor-
    neys’ fees from defendants.” But though they would agree
    with an equal-treatment rule, they would not agree on the
    content of that rule. As a result, a proposal to reduce fees
    28                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    in suits by prisoners would carry by a two-thirds majority,
    though a proposal to reduce fees across the board would
    fail. If that form of inconsistency can be called “irrational”
    and condemned as unconstitutional, then it is democracy
    itself that the Constitution forbids—because, as Arrow
    proved, inconsistency is an unavoidable consequence of
    decision by majority rule. The rational-basis approach
    tolerates this sort of legislative inconsistency by asking,
    not what legislators (or judges) actually believe, but
    whether it is possible for a sensible person to believe that
    the law does something useful. People could, and many
    do, believe that §1997e(d) does something useful.
    E
    We have not yet mentioned two mainstays of Johnson’s
    argument and the district court’s holding: Rinaldi v. Yeager,
    
    384 U.S. 305
     (1966), and Lindsey v. Normet, 
    405 U.S. 56
     (1972). Neither case supports the conclusion that
    §1997e(d) is invalid.
    Rinaldi dealt with a law requiring prisoners—but not
    criminal defendants whose sentences had been suspended,
    or those fined but not sentenced to prison—to repay the
    cost of any transcripts prepared for use on direct appeal.
    The state apparently failed to offer any defense of this
    distinction (at least, the Justices did not discuss any
    proffered justification), and the majority held it to be
    irrational because inexplicable and unreasoned. Wisconsin
    and the United States have defended the line drawn by
    §1997e(d); as Part II.C demonstrates it is not an “unrea-
    soned distinction” (
    384 U.S. at 310
    ); and that is enough
    to show that Rinaldi does not undermine the PLRA. But
    there is more.
    Rinaldi is among a series of decisions in the 1950s
    and 1960s that clear away what the Justices deemed to
    be obstacles to appeals by indigent criminal suspects.
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     29
    See, e.g., Griffin v. Illinois, 
    351 U.S. 12
     (1956); Douglas v.
    California, 
    372 U.S. 353
     (1963). These and other similar
    decisions were revisited in Ross v. Moffitt, 
    417 U.S. 600
    (1974), which concluded that Griffin and its successors
    rest more comfortably on the due process clause—because
    they determine what process states must afford to those
    accused of crime—than on the equal protection clause. Ever
    since Ross it has been understood that cases such as
    Rinaldi protect only the rights of defendants. This means
    principally criminal defendants, though occasionally the
    principle has some application to defendants in civil
    litigation of exceptional import, such as those that may
    terminate parental rights concerning their children. See
    M.L.B. v. S.L.J., 
    519 U.S. 102
     (1996). Neither Rinaldi nor
    any of the other cases in its sequence ever has been used to
    hold that the defendant must subsidize plaintiffs’ civil
    litigation. That is why we held in Lewis that Congress may
    require civil plaintiffs to pay their own way.
    As for Lindsey: the Court held that, consistent with the
    equal protection clause, a state may distinguish eviction
    suits from other litigation about property and may re-
    quire tenants to post bonds for the rent accruing pending
    decision. 
    405 U.S. at 69-74
    . Indigent litigants unable to post
    bonds for accrued rent may lose the litigation summarily,
    the Court held, as far as the Constitution is concerned.
    These aspects of Lindsey strongly support the kind of
    distinctions drawn in the PLRA. The Court added in
    Lindsey that requiring the tenant to post a bond (to be
    forfeited in the event of affirmance) for double all accrued
    and impending rentals is irrational; double-or-nothing is
    a game of chance, not a mode of civilized litigation. 
    Id. at 74-79
    . What Lindsey establishes is that forcing one par-
    ty (in Lindsey, the tenant-defendant) to pay extra (double
    rent) to the adversary as a condition of receiving a deci-
    sion on the merits violates the Constitution. If that hold-
    ing has any resonance here, it casts a shadow on §1988
    30                                Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    itself, for, as a condition of receiving a decision on the
    merits, Daley had to wager not only his own legal expenses
    but also Johnson’s. We do not think that fee-shifting laws
    are problematic; they have been sustained many times, see
    In re Mann, 
    311 F.3d 788
    , 790 (7th Cir. 2002) (collecting
    cases); but nothing in Lindsey implies that fee-shifting
    ever is required.
    Unlike the double-or-nothing statute in Lindsey, the
    PLRA  does not compel the defendant to pay extra (com-
    pared with §1988) as a condition of receiving a decision on
    the merits. The district court turned Lindsey on its head,
    treating it as a requirement that one side subsidize the
    other by enough to ensure that litigation occurs. Nothing
    of the kind can be found in Lindsey (which, recall, held
    that a single-bond requirement is valid even for impecu-
    nious tenants) or in any other decision of which we are
    aware. If the American Rule is constitutional, which it is,
    there can be no doubt about the validity of the PLRA, which
    does not impose a “litigation tax” on prisoners but simply
    reduces the extent to which defendants must underwrite
    prisoners’ suits.
    The judgment of the district court is reversed, and the
    case is remanded for an award of attorneys’ fees that
    complies with §1997e(d).
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     31
    RIPPLE, Circuit Judge, concurring in the judgment. In
    my view, this case requires a straightforward application
    of the well-known and frequently applied rational basis test
    of constitutional analysis. When a classification is subject
    to this review, it is not appropriate for a court to second-
    guess “the wisdom, fairness, or logic of legislative choices.”
    FCC v. Beach Communications, Inc., 
    508 U.S. 307
    , 313
    (1993). Only one issue is appropriately before us: Whether
    Congress could have believed that the classification imple-
    mented by the legislation had a rational relationship to
    some legitimate government purpose. See 
    id.
     In conduct-
    ing this inquiry, the classification “is accorded a strong
    presumption of validity,” Heller v. Doe, 
    509 U.S. 312
    , 319
    (1993), and must be upheld so long as there is some
    “reasonably conceivable state of facts that could provide a
    rational basis for the classification,” Beach Communica-
    tions, 
    508 U.S. at 313
    .
    When Congress enacted the classification in question
    in this case, it had specific goals in mind: (1) to bring re-
    lief to a federal civil justice system that, in its view, was
    overburdened by meritless lawsuits brought by prisoners;
    and (2) to protect the public treasury from unwise expendi-
    tures. See 141 Cong. Rec. S14611-01, at S14626 (daily ed.
    Sept. 29, 1995) (statement of Sen. Hatch) (“This landmark
    legislation will help bring relief to a civil justice system
    overburdened by frivolous prisoner lawsuits.”); 141 Cong.
    Rec. S7498-01, at S7524 (daily ed. May 25, 1995) (statement
    of Sen. Dole) (“[W]e have witnessed an alarming explosion
    in the number of lawsuits filed by State and Federal
    prisoners. . . . Frivolous lawsuits filed by prisoners tie up
    the courts, waste valuable judicial and legal resources, and
    affect the quality of justice enjoyed by the law-abiding
    population.”); 
    id.
     at S7526 (statement of Sen. Kyl) (“The
    volume of prisoner litigation represents a large burden on
    the judicial system, which is already overburdened by
    increases in nonprisoner litigation.”); 141 Cong. Rec.
    32                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    S14312-03, at S14317 (daily ed. Sept. 26, 1995) (statement
    of Sen. Abraham) (“[A]ttorney’s fees must be propor-
    tionally related to the court ordered relief. No longer will
    attorneys be allowed to charge massive amounts to the
    State for the service of correcting minimal violations.”).
    These are certainly legitimate government concerns, and
    it is certainly not open to us to second-guess the con-
    gressional judgment that there was a need to address
    these problems. Congress had a sufficient basis for its
    determination that the present state of civil litigation in
    the federal courts required legislative intervention.
    Congress also had sufficient grounds for concluding that,
    with respect to civil rights litigation, prisoners present
    a unique situation that requires a particularized remedy.
    See Boivin v. Black, 
    225 F.3d 36
    , 44 (1st Cir. 2000); Madrid
    v. Gomez, 
    190 F.3d 990
    , 996 (9th Cir. 1999). The hardships
    of prison life, the prisoners’ lack of any control over the
    conditions of their incarceration, the availability of a
    great deal of free time, and the absence of the usual
    economic disincentives in initiating legal action all combine
    to affect the type of litigation brought by prisoners, the
    frequency with which it is brought, and the manner in
    which it is presented to the courts. Although other conclu-
    sions reasonably might be drawn from the evidence,
    Congress was entitled to conclude that these factors lead
    prisoners to see high potential gains from bringing litiga-
    tion and low opportunity costs associated with the ven-
    ture. See Boivin, 
    225 F.3d at 44
    ; Madrid, 
    190 F.3d at 996
    ;
    see also 141 Cong. Rec. S7498-01, at S7526 (daily ed. May
    25, 1995) (statement of Sen. Kyl) (“Unlike other prospec-
    tive litigants who seek poor person status, prisoners have
    all the necessities of life supplied, including the materials
    required to bring their lawsuits. For a prisoner who quali-
    fies for poor person status, there is no cost to bring a
    suit and, therefore, no incentive to limit suits to cases that
    have some chance of success.”). Congress may well have
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                       33
    been dead wrong in coming to that conclusion, but we
    cannot say that the decision to view prisoners as present-
    ing special problems requiring a special remedy was an
    irrational one.
    Nor does the rational basis standard permit us to substi-
    tute our judgment for the determination of Congress
    with respect to the appropriate means to address the
    identified problems. One manner in which Congress chose
    to address the problem was by imposing restrictions on the
    attorneys’ fees available for the successful prosecution of
    § 1983 litigation brought by a prisoner. This approach is
    certainly not the only way of addressing the prisoner
    litigation problem. Nor is it, in all probability, the best one.
    It may well be correct that the restriction on attorneys’ fees,
    while discouraging attorneys from bringing frivolous
    cases, will hardly prevent the prisoners from bringing
    the same suits without the assistance of counsel. It also
    may turn out that the attorneys’ fees restriction does more
    harm than good by discouraging attorneys from taking
    meritorious cases and thereby reducing the effectiveness
    of § 1983. Indeed, the restriction might increase the number
    of meritorious cases brought by prisoners without the
    assistance of counsel and therefore increase significantly
    the judicial resources needed to unravel the issues.
    These concerns demonstrate the possibility that Con-
    gress might have misjudged the effectiveness of the remedy
    that it chose. That Congress may have made an unwise
    choice of remedy does not establish, however, that Congress
    acted irrationally. See Massachusetts Bd. of Retirement v.
    Murgia, 
    427 U.S. 307
    , 316 (1976) (per curiam) (“[T]he
    State perhaps has not chosen the best means to accom-
    plish [its] purpose. But where rationality is the test, a
    State ‘does not violate the Equal Protection Clause mere-
    ly because the classifications made by its laws are imper-
    fect.’ ” (quoting Dandridge v. Williams, 
    397 U.S. 471
    , 485
    (1970))). Congress may well have thought that, if lawyers
    34                                 Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    declined to take meritless lawsuits, prisoners, aware of
    other provisions, including the “three strikes” provision of
    the PLRA, would take the implicit advice in the attor-
    ney’s decision and decide not to bring the cases on their
    own. See Walker v. Bain, 
    257 F.3d 660
    , 669 (6th Cir. 2001);
    Hadix v. Johnson, 
    230 F.3d 840
    , 845 (6th Cir. 2001).
    Congress also might have believed that, in the past,
    attorneys had brought a good number of meritless lawsuits
    in the hope that, despite the frivolousness of the suit, a
    recovery might be obtained. See Jackson v. State Bd. of
    Pardons & Paroles, 
    331 F.3d 790
    , 798 (11th Cir. 2003);
    Walker, 
    257 F.3d at 669
    ; Hadix, 
    230 F.3d at 845
    . Congress
    may well have been wrong in making such estimations;
    at the very least, it may have overestimated the value of
    the attorneys’ fees restriction as a remedy. But, in imple-
    menting the rational basis test, we are not grading the
    wisdom of the legislative branch. See Heller, 
    509 U.S. at 319
    ; Beach Communications, 
    508 U.S. at 313
    . As long as
    our legislators could have had a rational basis for their
    action, we must allow their judgment to stand. We have no
    right to demand that Congress achieve a perfect, or even a
    near perfect, accommodation between means and ends. See
    Heller, 
    509 U.S. at 321
     (“[C]ourts are compelled under
    rational-basis review to accept a legislature’s generaliza-
    tions even when there is an imperfect fit between means
    and ends.”). Indeed, Congress has the perfect right to
    experiment. It can implement a “solution,” monitor its
    effectiveness and later determine to change course in its
    quest for a solution.
    On this basis, I join the judgment of the court.
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     35
    ROVNER, Circuit Judge, with whom EVANS, DIANE P.
    WOOD, and WILLIAMS, Circuit Judges, join, dissenting. In
    concluding that this PLRA provision satisfies rational
    relationship scrutiny, the majority as well as other courts
    have held that Congress could rationally believe the
    PLRA provisions furthered its interest in deterring frivo-
    lous or trivial litigation. The journey from the PLRA fee
    restrictions to the reduction in trivial or frivolous filings,
    however, requires so many leaps, many ridiculous, as to
    destroy any semblance of rationality. To believe that the
    fee restriction impacts the filing decision of pro se pris-
    oners, Congress would have to believe that (1) prisoners
    would be inclined to bring frivolous or trivial lawsuits and
    (2) those prisoners would not be deterred from filing
    such suits by the likelihood that their own damages would
    be minimal or non-existent but (3) those prisoners would
    be deterred from filing those suits by the prospect that the
    fees available to their as-then non-existent attorneys
    were restricted under the PLRA even though (4) those
    attorneys would not have been entitled to fees for such suits
    even absent the PLRA and even though (5) the chances
    of those prisoners ever obtaining counsel was practically
    nil, given that only 1% of prisoner civil rights cases in-
    volve private attorneys, and another 4% involve appointed
    counsel (who presumably would not be appointed for our
    hypothetical trivial/frivolous cases). See Roger A. Hanson
    & Henry W.K. Daley, Challenging the Conditions of
    Prison and Jails: A Report on Section 1983 Litigation 21-
    22 (1995); see, e.g., McKeever v. Israel, 
    689 F.2d 1315
    , 1320
    (7th Cir. 1982) (in determining whether to appoint counsel,
    “the threshold question is whether the claim is of sufficient
    merit”). Such a belief is fanciful, not rational. In the
    alternative, to believe that the fee restriction impacts the
    decision of private attorneys bringing suits on behalf of
    such prisoners, Congress would have to believe that (1)
    there are private attorneys who are willing to bring suits
    on behalf of prisoners despite the difficult standards of
    36                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    proof and the absence of traditional damages such as lost
    wages and future earnings and (2) those attorneys would
    file a trivial or frivolous lawsuit even though fees for such
    lawsuits are not available under § 1988 but (3) those same
    attorneys would decide not to file the law suit once fees
    were merely restricted under the PLRA. This sequence is
    made even more ridiculous considering that only 1% of
    all prisoner civil rights litigation involves private attor-
    neys, including groups such as the ACLU, but yet we are
    asked to believe that Congress rationally could think
    those attorneys are choosing to bring the frivolous or
    trivial lawsuits and would be deterred from that course
    by the fee restriction under the PLRA but not the fee
    prohibition under § 1988. If this connection is a rational
    one, then this test truly has lost all meaning. The only
    impact this provision will have is on the meritorious pris-
    oner actions, rendering it even more difficult for prisoners
    to adequately present these meritorious claims to the
    courts, and more difficult for the court to find counsel
    willing to accept appointments to represent prisoners in
    such cases. The government does not purport to have a
    legitimate interest in deterring prisoners from filing
    meritorious suits, nor could it, and therefore the provision
    is unconstitutional.
    Rather than apply traditional equal protection analysis
    to the classification at issue here, as did all of the
    other circuits to consider this claim, the plurality opinion
    engages in a free-ranging discussion of myriad unrelated
    statutes under the mantra of answering the question “equal
    compared to what?” But the classification at issue here
    is not a mystery—the singling out of prisoners from the
    § 1988 fee structure available to all other civil rights
    litigants—and the sole issue in this case is whether that
    classification is rationally related to a legitimate govern-
    mental goal. Rather than addressing that question, the
    plurality examines a host of unrelated policy issues in-
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     37
    cluding whether the fees available in civil rights actions
    are too generous as compared with those available in
    other causes of actions and whether prisoners are less
    worthy of benefits than other groups. Those are interest-
    ing issues for legislators or political candidates, but they
    are mere detours here, irrelevant to the equal protection
    claim before us. The plurality approach stands in stark
    contrast to that of the other circuits to consider the issue,
    which at least have engaged in a straightforward analy-
    sis of the classification and applied traditional equal pro-
    tection analysis to the issue. The plurality opinion travels
    so far afield from equal protection jurisprudence in its
    opinion that before we can examine the rationality of the
    classification at issue here, we are compelled to clarify
    what is not at issue in this case.
    I.
    First, no one claims that the right of access to the courts
    is a right of subsidized access. In demonstrating that
    there is no constitutional right to attorney’s fees, the
    plurality opinion lists a number of constitutional rights
    for which there is no right of funding, but it is a point that
    is undisputed and therefore the discussion is gratuitous.
    This is not a case concerning whether prisoners, or any
    other persons, have a constitutional right to attorney’s fees
    in civil litigation. The only issue here is whether, in grant-
    ing fees to prevailing plaintiffs in civil rights actions,
    Congress may constitutionally single out one group of per-
    sons for differing treatment, and all parties (as well as the
    other circuits to consider the issue) agree that the rational
    relationship test is the appropriate one for analyzing that
    question.
    Second, this case is not a forum to analyze whether
    attorney’s fees should be available in civil rights litigation
    as a whole, whether such litigation is more important
    38                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    than other types of litigation, or whether prisoners as a
    whole are a group less worthy of fees than “free persons.”
    Although such a discussion in the current climate may
    well foster a visceral reaction of outrage (why should
    veterans have a lesser right to fees than prisoners!), it is
    an illusory comparison unrelated to the equal protection
    issue, and it foments the type of resentment towards a
    disfavored group that the equal protection clause is de-
    signed to address. It is difficult to understand why so
    much of the plurality opinion is devoted to a comparison of
    the fees available to prisoners in civil rights suits with the
    fees available to persons in miscellaneous other causes
    of actions. There is no constitutional requirement that
    fees be equal across causes of actions, nor is there any
    constitutional mandate that fees must be lower if a court
    deems the cause of action “less important” or the litigants
    “less worthy.” Such a wide-ranging approach to the equal
    protection clause would transform courts into a “super-
    legislature.” See Heller v. Doe by Doe, 
    509 U.S. 312
    , 319
    (1993) (rational basis review in equal protection does not
    “authorize ‘the judiciary [to] sit as a superlegislature to
    judge the wisdom or desirability of legislative policy deter-
    minations’ ”). We are not the proper body to determine
    whether the spectrum of benefits afforded prisoners is more
    than those given veterans, or whether prisoners or any
    other group of persons are less deserving of benefits
    than veterans and therefore should get less. The end result
    of such an approach would be one that I suspect the
    majority would not endorse. Should we compare benefits
    afforded the elderly with those given to impoverished
    children? What about those given to senior citizens regard-
    less of income as opposed to those provided to the work-
    ing poor, or to the unemployed? Are we to judge who is
    more worthy? Of course not. The court ventures into that
    dangerous territory in comparing the fees available to
    prisoners with those provided under other statutes, a
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                    39
    comparison that has no basis in equal protection juris-
    prudence.
    Moreover, the comparison is an illusory one for another
    reason. The PLRA applies to all civil rights actions by
    prisoners. This particular case happens to address the
    denial of appropriate medical care, which leads the plural-
    ity into a comparison with other unrelated statutes relat-
    ing to medical care—including medical malpractice tort
    law, the FTCA, and Medicaid. But the case could have
    just as easily involved an entirely different field of law.
    Under the plurality’s approach, if the civil rights claim
    concerned the conditions under which the prisoner was
    forced to live, we would examine all habitability provisions,
    or landlord-tenant laws. The logical extension of that
    approach would be that the constitutionality of the PLRA
    provision might well vary depending on the nature of
    the underlying lawsuit. The equal protection clause re-
    quires no such free-ranging examination of the fairness or
    wisdom of a provision in light of analogous but unrelated
    statutes. In fact, after raising the false comparisons, the
    plurality explicitly recognizes that the numbers upon
    which it bases much of its argument are “not directly
    comparable.” Op. at 16.
    The plurality in the end does not appear to be question-
    ing the availability of attorney’s fees to prisoners as
    much as the allowance of prisoner suits under § 1983 at all.
    Much of its analysis challenges why prisoners are al-
    lowed to litigate at all for deliberate indifference to their
    serious medical needs, comparing prisoners’ litigation
    options to those of veterans and medicaid recipients
    among others. But that is not the subject of the PLRA
    provisions before us. We are concerned here only with the
    restriction on attorney’s fees under the PLRA, not the
    wisdom of the varying litigation options among statutes,
    and therefore this discussion has no place in an equal
    protection analysis of the PLRA provision at issue here.
    40                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    As we stated, the question “equal compared to what” is
    not answered by comparing prisoners in civil rights ac-
    tions to litigants in unrelated causes of actions. For nearly
    all of those unrelated causes of action (i.e. malpractice
    tort law, the FTCA, etc.), all claimants filing suit under
    those actions are treated identically. Although there may
    be variations in the availability of fees among differ-
    ent causes of actions, there is no such discrepancy within
    a cause of action, with the exception of the IDEA which
    we will discuss shortly. The PLRA, however, creates just
    such a classification within a cause of action. Section 1988
    grants attorney’s fees to prevailing plaintiffs in civil rights
    litigation. The PLRA specifically targets those litigants,
    and creates a sub-group (prisoners) that will not have
    the same access to fees, stating that “[i]n any action
    brought by a prisoner . . . in which attorney’s fees are
    authorized under section 1988 [footnote omitted] of this
    title, such fees shall not be awarded except that . . . .” It is
    that classification between classes of individuals under
    § 1988 that must pass equal protection scrutiny.
    An example may illustrate the fallacy of the plurality’s
    approach. Suppose instead of limiting fees for prisoners, the
    PLRA reduced the availability of fees under § 1988 for all
    blue-eyed litigants. Under the plurality’s reasoning, there
    would be no equal protection problem with that statute.
    The same arguments used to justify the restriction for
    prisoners would apply to blue-eyed litigants: blue-eyed
    civil rights litigants would still be “decidedly better off”
    under those fee restrictions than veterans under the
    FTCA or persons claiming benefits under the Social Secu-
    rity program; litigants in those other causes of action
    manage to obtain attorney representation so there is no
    reason to believe that equal fees are necessary for the blue-
    eyed civil rights litigants to do the same; civil rights
    litigation is not nearly as important as collateral attacks
    on a conviction, and there are less fees available there;
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                    41
    there is no constitutional right to attorney’s fees; and
    finally, other statutes have widely divergent fee structures,
    and “what this means is that all of these different systems
    could be thought rational solutions.” Yet most rational
    people would balk at the suggestion that Congress could,
    consistent with equal protection, single out persons with
    a certain eye color and deny them the same attorney’s
    fees as all other litigants pursuing the same constitutional
    claims. That is because the detour into other causes of
    actions ignores the proper focus, which is on the classifica-
    tion itself viewed in the context of the statute authoriz-
    ing fees for that particular cause of action. The classifica-
    tion must be rationally related to the legitimate govern-
    mental goal. That analysis is not even addressed until
    well into the plurality opinion, but it is the only relevant
    one for purposes of equal protection. The plurality’s po-
    lemic may have (intuitive) appeal only because it exploits
    our own preconceptions about prisoners as a class and
    their worthiness—in other words, because it highlights
    why they are a disfavored group. But that tendency to
    act arbitrarily against a disfavored group is precisely the
    reason why the equal protection clause is necessary.
    Only one of the examples offered by the plurality, that
    of the District of Columbia claimants under the IDEA,
    actually addresses a sub-group of litigants who were
    singled out for reduced fees as compared to others assert-
    ing the same cause of action. The D.C. Circuit in Calloway
    upheld that disparity only after determining that the
    classification was rationally related to the legitimate
    goal of addressing an acute funding need in the District.
    
    216 F.3d 1
    . Notably, the court did not uphold the classifi-
    cation under the theory proposed by the majority that
    all fee structures vary and therefore all could be consid-
    ered rational, nor did it uphold it because the fees that
    remained available were better than those afforded other
    groups such as veterans. Indeed, Calloway provides no
    42                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    support for the theories presented in this majority opinion.
    A glance at Calloway is revealing in its contrast to the
    present case.
    Calloway considered the constitutionality of a provi-
    sion that limited the fees that the District of Columbia
    could pay to attorneys for prevailing parties in IDEA
    lawsuits. The reason for singling out District of Columbia
    litigants from all other IDEA litigants was clear from the
    record, which demonstrated that in one year alone, “al-
    though the DCPS [District of Columbia Public Schools]
    served less than two-thousandths of one percent of the
    nation’s disabled students, over forty-five percent of
    requests for due process hearings nationwide were made
    in D.C.” 
    Id. at 4
    . Because attorney’s fees were available
    under the IDEA, legal representation in D.C. had grown
    from an obscure niche into a booming, lucrative industry,
    costing the DCPS over $10 million in attorney’s fees in
    fiscal year 1998. 
    Id.
     The Secretary of Education had
    determined that immediate compliance by the DCPS with
    the requirements of the IDEA was not feasible because
    the root causes of its failures were so extensive; the Secre-
    tary had thus entered into a compliance agreement with
    DCPS mandating full compliance within three years. 
    Id.
    Against this unusual background, Congress acted to re-
    duce the amount of attorney’s fees available for IDEA
    actions in D.C. The D.C. Circuit considered whether the
    classification at issue there—the singling out of D.C.
    litigants from other IDEA litigants—was rationally re-
    lated to a legitimate governmental goal. The government
    argued that “in view of DCPS’s manifest inability to meet
    its obligations under IDEA, Congress could rationally have
    concluded that ‘it was more important for the District to
    spend its funds on remedying those systemic defects
    and providing primary services rather than upon litigation
    fees.’ ” 
    Id. at 8
    . The D.C. Circuit held that Congress could
    rationally believe that limiting payments to attorneys
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     43
    would leave more funds available for direct services, and
    that assisting disabled children by allocating funds to-
    wards primary educational services rather than attor-
    ney’s fees was a legitimate governmental goal. 
    Id. at 8-9
    .
    Accordingly, the provision survived equal protection
    scrutiny.
    The plurality opinion establishes no similar connection
    between reduced attorney’s fees in prisoner civil rights
    litigation and any legitimate governmental goal. Unlike
    Calloway, there is no booming, lucrative business in the
    prisoner segment of civil rights litigation. With only 1% of
    all prisoner civil rights cases even involving attorneys not
    appointed by the court, that can not possibly be iden-
    tified as a fee drain out of proportion to the other litigants
    under the civil rights statutes. It is that connection be-
    tween attorney’s fees and a legitimate governmental goal
    that the plurality never makes, choosing instead to devote
    much of the opinion to a condemnation of prisoner civil
    rights litigation generally (without regard to attorney rep-
    resentation or fees) or decrying the extent of fees available
    in civil rights actions generally as compared with other
    causes of actions that the majority appears to deem more
    significant. The Equal Protection Clause, however, ad-
    dresses the fit between the particular classification and
    the legitimate governmental goal, and that is lacking here.
    In a late effort to tie its discussion to traditional equal
    protection analysis, the plurality declares that the other
    statutes with lesser attorney’s fees are relevant compari-
    sons because litigants under those statutes do not have
    difficulties obtaining counsel, and therefore Congress could
    assume that prisoners under a more favorable statutory
    structure would not either. That comparison is so superfi-
    cial as to be meaningless. First, as has been mentioned, the
    focus on medical cases is misplaced, because the PLRA
    limits fees in all types of prisoner civil rights actions.
    Moreover, damages cannot be compared with any meaning
    44                                Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    in prisoner versus non-prisoner litigation, because the
    absence of earning capacity in the former necessarily skews
    the damages. This case is a good example of the discrep-
    ancy. Diagnosed with end stage liver disease, Johnson
    lapsed into a coma multiple times. In February 1996, he
    was examined by Dr. Alexandru Musat, medical director
    of the Liver Transplantation Program at the University
    of Wisconsin Hospital, who recommended that Johnson
    should be evaluated to determine whether he was an
    appropriate candidate for a liver transplant, as “the only
    viable option for resolution of his symptoms and liver
    failure.” Without a liver transplant, Dr. Musat estimated
    that Johnson’s life expectancy would be in the range of
    three to four years.
    The defendant Dr. George Daley, the medical director of
    the Bureau of Correctional Health Services for the Wiscon-
    sin Department of Corrections, refused to authorize that
    evaluation. On a number of subsequent occasions, Dr. Daley
    denied written requests from two prison doctors seeking
    authorization for the treatment recommended by Dr.
    Musat. Johnson then filed suit pursuant to 
    42 U.S.C. § 1983
    alleging that Dr. Daley denied him adequate medical care
    for his liver disease in violation of the Eighth Amendment.
    In July 1998, the district court dismissed that action
    without prejudice for failure to exhaust administrative
    remedies, but the complaint was reinstated in December
    1998, after Johnson satisfied the exhaustion requirement.
    In April 1999, Dr. Daley finally approved the request to
    have Johnson evaluated by the University of Wisconsin for
    a liver transplant, and in June 1999, the University of
    Wisconsin Hospital, with the approval of Dr. Daley, placed
    Johnson’s name on the list as a potential recipient for a
    donated liver. The case proceeded to trial on the issues of
    whether the initial denials of the evaluation constituted
    deliberate indifference to Johnson’s serious medical needs
    and whether the three-year delay in evaluation and place-
    ment on the transplant list caused him any harm.
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                   45
    Despite the length of the delay and the clear risk to
    Johnson’s life, recognized even by the prison doctors,
    Johnson was awarded only $10,000 in compensatory dam-
    ages and $30,000 in punitive damages, amounts that
    undoubtedly would have been much higher were he not
    a prisoner. Even the plurality opinion reflects the deval-
    uation of a prisoner’s life, stating dismissively that “he
    appears to have suffered no long-term injury from
    the delay,” but that “[n]onetheless, a jury agreed with
    Johnson . . . and awarded him . . . damages.” I doubt that
    the plurality would be so cavalier about a three-year
    delay in being placed on a transplant list if it were they
    or a loved one awaiting a life-saving procedure, and the
    plurality opinion fails to mention that but for the law-
    suit, Johnson would probably still not be on the transplant
    list.
    The reality is that both the deep-seated societal antip-
    athy towards prisoners as a class as well as the absence
    of lost wages or future earnings damages ensures that
    damages in prisoner cases will nearly always be minimal.
    See Roger A. Hanson & Henry W.K. Daley, Challenging
    the Conditions of Prison and Jails: A Report on Section
    1983 Litigation 37 (1995) (recognizing that prisoner settle-
    ments and verdicts are smaller because wages are non-
    existent and a substantial component of compensatory
    damages is either lost wages or foregone earnings). More
    fundamentally, the comparison with the other statutes is
    flawed in its extrapolation of the experience under other
    statutes to this context. The plurality concludes that if
    attorneys are widely available under statutes with less
    liberal fee provisions, Congress could conclude they
    would be widely available under the PLRA. But even pre-
    PLRA, attorneys were rarely available to prisoners. Prison-
    ers are represented by attorneys in only 4% of all prison-
    er litigation, and the vast majority of those attorneys
    are court appointed. Because attorneys were scarce in
    46                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    prisoner civil rights litigation even before the PLRA
    reduced the fees, the comparison to other statutes is
    meaningless.
    The plurality opinion raises a host of other question-
    able arguments, not the least of which is that all pris-
    oners are liars and all of their cases lost are lost because
    they lied. It is difficult to imagine any other group of
    persons for whom such sweeping (and unsupported) gener-
    alizations would be tolerated, let alone given credence, in
    a judicial opinion. Nevertheless, the generalizations do not
    further the plurality’s argument. In fact, many of those
    alleged prisoner traits posited by the plurality would
    demonstrate that their filing decisions are entirely unaf-
    fected by attorney’s fees. There is, for instance, no reason to
    believe that prisoners motivated to file lawsuits to get a
    day away from prison, to pass the time, or to harass pris-
    on staff, will be moved to abstain from such conduct by
    the prospect that their hypothetical future attorney will
    receive less in fees if the suit is successful. But that is
    precisely the basis of the rationality analysis offered by
    the plurality. The plurality further uses these preconcep-
    tions about character to engage in an even more fanciful
    calculation of the hypothetical effects of the PLRA on
    prisoner behavior. For instance, assuming all prisoners are
    liars, the plurality postulates that a frivolous case often
    will not be recognized as such until the trial, but that
    ignores the reality that the vast majority of prisoner cases
    are resolved without an evidentiary hearing. See Roger A.
    Hanson & Henry W.K. Daley, Challenging the Condi-
    tions of Prison and Jails: A Report on Section 1983 Litiga-
    tion 22 (1995) (noting that evidentiary hearings are not
    held in 97% of cases). The calculations are in large part
    based on unsupported assumptions and unrecognized fac-
    tors. For instance, from the statistic that prisoners lose
    90% of all fully tried cases, the majority then assumes that
    9 out of 10 prisoners making claims are lying, and only 1
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     47
    out of 10 guards is lying. That is unsupportable. Only 3%
    of cases reach evidentiary hearings or trials. 
    Id.
     In the
    97% that do not, courts assume the prisoners are truth-
    ful in their allegations but find that prisoners none-
    theless lack the support necessary to satisfy the rela-
    tively demanding prerequisites to relief (i.e., in medical
    cases, prisoners need to demonstrate not mere malprac-
    tice, but deliberate indifference to a serious medical need).
    For the overwhelming majority of cases, then, there is no
    basis to assume that the case is lost because the prisoner
    is lying. Likewise, of the cases that go to trial, there is
    no reason to believe that the lack of success establishes
    that the prisoner was lying as opposed to the possibility
    that the prisoner lacked the corroboration to support a
    claim or simply could not meet the high burden, but in
    any case 90% of 3% is only 2.7%. All of the expected recov-
    ery calculations flow from that false assumption.
    The potential reduction in litigation that the majority
    portends as a result of these PLRA provisions is sim-
    ilarly baseless. For instance, the majority concludes that
    the PLRA fee restrictions will reduce the percentage of
    prisoners filing cases, but does not consider whether that
    decrease, by making it less risky for guards to engage in
    unconstitutional behavior, will increase such behavior
    and therefore offset some of that alleged “gain.” In any case,
    the calculations are far removed from the issue here
    and the reality of filing decisions in the prison context.
    Furthermore, the majority declares that “even if 80% of
    prisoners are insensible to changes in the litigation pro-
    cess, different behavior by the other 20% would be wel-
    come.” Given that only 4% of prisoners will ever be repre-
    sented by counsel, the 20% prediction is baseless. When
    we further consider that the vast majority of those 4%
    involve appointed counsel and therefore are cases that
    the court does not consider trivial, it becomes clear that
    the cases potentially deterred are not the trivial ones in
    48                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    which the government claims an interest, but the meritori-
    ous ones in which it does not. McKeever, 
    689 F.2d at 1320
    (in determining whether to appoint counsel, “the threshold
    question is whether the claim is of sufficient merit”). No
    amount of statistical shell games can rationally establish
    otherwise.
    We turn, then, to the only issue presented here—the
    connection between the classification and the legitimate
    governmental interest. A proper application of the rational
    relationship test renders the PLRA fee restrictions uncon-
    stitutional.
    II.
    We begin our analysis with a brief explanation of the
    genesis of the PLRA provisions. The PLRA was enacted in
    response to a veritable flood of prisoner litigation, most of
    it without merit, that clogged up the dockets of federal
    courts and drained resources away from meritorious cases.
    The magnitude of the problem was apparent. See, e.g.,
    Roller v. Gunn, 
    107 F.3d 227
    , 230 (4th Cir. 1997) (“In 1995,
    prisoners brought over 25% of the civil cases filed in the
    federal courts. In this circuit alone, in forma pauperis
    (IFP) filings accounted for almost half of the court’s 1995
    caseload and prisoners were responsible for 75% of those
    filings.”) (citations omitted); Boivin v. Black, 
    225 F.3d 36
    , 41
    (1st Cir. 2000). In addressing this problem, Congress
    recognized that the unique circumstances of prison life
    provided a breeding ground for frivolous litigation. Inmates
    have a great deal of time on their hands, and no disin-
    centive to spend it filing suits. Although a court appear-
    ance is a nuisance and often a real hardship on a non-
    incarcerated person, who must arrange for time off from
    work or child care, the inmate has no such concerns. To
    the contrary, a trip to the courtroom is a benefit for an
    inmate who is otherwise confined to a cell. In addition, the
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                      49
    availability of IFP status, as well as the provision of all the
    inmate’s daily needs in prison, removed any financial
    impediment to litigation. As a result, the type of cost-
    benefit assessment in which a non-prisoner might en-
    gage, to determine whether the constitutional issue was
    worth the effort and cost of pursuing federal court relief,
    was artificially skewed in the context of the prison suits.
    See Hadix v. M. Johnson, 
    230 F.3d 840
    , 844 (6th Cir.
    2000); Boivin, 
    225 F.3d at 44
    ; Tucker v. G. Branker, 
    142 F.3d 1294
    , 1300 (D.C. Cir. 1998); Mitchell v. Farcass, 
    112 F.3d 1483
    , 1488-89 (11th Cir. 1997); Roller, 
    107 F.3d at 234
    .
    Congress responded to that problem by enacting the
    PLRA in an attempt to redress the epidemic of frivolous
    prisoner litigation.
    We have already upheld a number of PLRA provisions
    as constitutional. See, e.g., Lewis v. Sullivan, 
    279 F.3d 526
    (7th Cir. 2002) (holding constitutional PLRA requirement
    that prisoners prepay filing fees if they have a history of
    frivolous litigation except where under imminent danger of
    serious physical injury); Zehner v. Trigg, 
    133 F.3d 459
     (7th
    Cir. 1997) (holding constitutional PLRA limitation that
    forbids recovery for mental or emotional damages without
    a prior showing of physical injury). Although we have
    upheld those provisions against equal protection chal-
    lenges, each PLRA provision must be examined on its own
    merits.
    We are concerned in this case only with §§ 1997e(d)(2) &
    (3), which provide that in cases brought by an inmate in
    which fees are authorized under § 1988, the award of
    attorney’s fees is limited to 150% of the amount of judg-
    ment, § 1997e(d)(2), and the hourly rate payable to a
    prisoner’s attorney is restricted to 150% of the hourly
    rate allowed for court-appointed counsel in criminal cases
    under the Criminal Justice Act (18 U.S.C. § 3006A),
    § 1997e(d)(3) (collectively referred to as “the PLRA fee
    restrictions”).
    50                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    Because those PLRA fee restrictions apply only to cases
    in which fees are authorized under § 1988, in order to
    assess the equal protection challenge we first must
    place those provisions in the context of the fees otherwise
    available under § 1988. See § 1997e(d); Martin v. Hadix,
    
    527 U.S. 343
    , 363-64 (1999) (Scalia, J., dissenting) (“[i]n
    reality . . . the PLRA simply revises the fees provided for
    by § 1988, and it seems that the underlying purpose of
    that provision must govern its amendment as well—which
    purpose was to provide an appropriate incentive for law-
    yers to work on (among other civil rights cases) prisoner
    suits.”); Heller v. Doe by Doe, 
    509 U.S. 312
    , 321 (1993)
    (“even the standard of rationality as we so often have
    defined it must find some footing in the realities of the
    subject addressed by the legislation”). See also Romer v.
    Evans, 
    517 U.S. 620
     (1996) (analyzing amendment in light
    of pre-existing law to determine that rational relationship
    test was violated); Lindsey v. Normet, 
    405 U.S. 56
    , 78 (1972)
    (analyzing the statutory double-bond requirement in
    the context of the pre-existing state statutes); Reitman
    v. Mulkey, 
    387 U.S. 369
    , 373 (1967) (in equal protection
    challenge to state constitutional provision, court should
    consider its “’immediate objective,’ its ‘ultimate effect’
    and its ‘historical context and the conditions existing
    prior to its enactment.’ ”). In enacting § 1988, Congress
    recognized that civil rights actions for damages are dis-
    tinct from private tort suits that benefit only the individ-
    ual plaintiffs. Unlike ordinary tort litigation, civil rights
    suits “vindicate important civil and constitutional rights
    that cannot be valued solely in monetary terms.” City of
    Riverside v. Rivera, 
    477 U.S. 561
    , 574 (1986). Congress
    determined that many victims of civil rights violation
    were unable to obtain representation in the private
    market because of high attorney fees, and therefore § 1988
    provides for payment of a reasonable fee—that is, “a fee
    large enough to induce competent counsel to handle the
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     51
    plaintiff’s case, but no larger.” Simpson v. Sheahan, 
    104 F.3d 998
    , 1002 (7th Cir. 1997).
    Consistent with that purpose, § 1988 allows for the
    award of fees only to “prevailing parties.” In order to be
    considered a prevailing party, the plaintiff must have
    obtained some judicially sanctioned relief on the merits
    of the claim. Specifically, a plaintiff prevails when actual
    relief on the merits of the claim, provided by a court
    judgment or consent decree, materially alters the legal
    relationship between the parties by modifying the defen-
    dant’s behavior in a way that directly benefits the plain-
    tiff. Buckhannon Bd. and Care Home, Inc. v. West Vir-
    ginia Dept. of Health and Human Resources, 
    532 U.S. 598
    , 604 (2001); Farrar v. Hobby, 
    506 U.S. 103
    , 111-112
    (1992); Simpson, 
    104 F.3d at 1001
    . Once that hurdle is
    surmounted, a court may award fees but only in an amount
    that is reasonable in light of the degree of overall success.
    Farrar, 
    506 U.S. at 114
    . Where a plaintiff is a prevailing
    party but the success is merely technical or de minimis,
    the presumption is that no fees should be awarded. See
    
    id. at 115
     (where the plaintiff recovers only nominal
    damages “the only reasonable fee is usually no fee at all”);
    Cole v. Wodziak, 
    169 F.3d 486
    , 488 (7th Cir. 1999) (“a paltry
    jury award . . . implies that the only reasonable fee is
    zero”); Monticello School Dist. No. 25 v. George L. on Behalf
    of Brock L., 
    102 F.3d 895
    , 907 (7th Cir. 1996) (“when a
    plaintiff’s success is simply technical or de minimis, no
    fees may be awarded, even if the plaintiff has succeeded
    on an issue in the litigation and may thus be technically
    a ‘prevailing party’ ”); Maul v. Constan, 
    23 F.3d 143
    , 145
    & 147 (7th Cir. 1994) (award of attorney’s fees is inappropri-
    ate where victory is de minimis).
    The ultimate question in entitlement to fees under
    § 1988, therefore, is whether the plaintiff’s victory is
    significant or merely de minimis. Maul, 
    23 F.3d at 145
    . In
    recognition that “[n]ominal relief does not necessarily a
    52                                 Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    nominal victory make,” Farrar, 
    506 U.S. at 121
     (O’Connor,
    J. concurring), courts may award fees in cases of minimal
    damages only if other factors establish that the victory,
    although monetarily small, is actually a significant one.
    In making that assessment, we look to the three factors
    set forth in Justice O’Connor’s concurrence in Farrar: “(1)
    the difference between the judgment recovered and the
    recovery sought; (2) the significance of the legal issue on
    which the plaintiff prevailed; and (3) the public purpose
    of the litigation.” Farrar, 
    506 U.S. at 122
    ; Simpson, 
    104 F.3d at 1001
    ; Briggs v. Marshall, 
    93 F.3d 355
    , 361 (7th Cir.
    1996). Where those factors establish that the victory is
    not de minimis but is instead significant, fees may be
    available under § 1988. If those factors are not met, then
    the plaintiff achieved only a technical or de minimis vic-
    tory and fees are unavailable under § 1988. Of course, if
    a case is frivolous, no fees can be awarded under § 1988,
    and in fact plaintiff and plaintiff’s counsel can be sanc-
    tioned for the pursuit of such a suit. Farrar, 
    506 U.S. at 111-12
    .
    III.
    With that background, I turn to the constitutionality of
    the PLRA fee restrictions. The parties agree that the
    appropriate level of review is the rational relationship
    test because the challenged provisions do not impact
    fundamental rights and the prisoners do not constitute
    a suspect class which would have triggered a higher de-
    gree of scrutiny. The issue, therefore, is whether those
    PLRA fee restrictions are rationally related to a legiti-
    mate governmental interest. Although the district courts
    have diverged on the issue, the federal appellate courts
    that have considered the rationality of the PLRA fee
    restrictions have upheld them or split on the question. The
    Third Circuit sitting en banc split evenly on the issue,
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                  53
    which had the effect of upholding the provisions as con-
    stitutional because the district court had so held. Collins
    v. Montgomery County Bd. Of Prison Inspectors, 
    176 F.3d 679
    , 686 (3d Cir. 1999). The First, Sixth, Eighth,
    Ninth, and Eleventh Circuits held the provisions constitu-
    tional. Boivin v. Black, 
    225 F.3d 36
     (1st Cir. 2000); Hadix
    v. Johnson, 
    230 F.3d 840
     (6th Cir. 2000) and Walker v.
    Bain, 
    257 F.3d 660
     (6th Cir. 2001); Foulk v. Charrier, 
    262 F.3d 687
     (8th Cir. 2001); Madrid v. Gomez, 
    190 F.3d 990
    (9th Cir. 1999); Jackson v. State Board of Pardons and
    Paroles, 
    331 F.3d 790
     (11th Cir. 2003). Those opinions
    are deserving of careful attention. Nevertheless, the split
    in the Third Circuit en banc and the dissents in the Sixth
    Circuit cases caution against a rush to judgment, and
    Apprendi v. New Jersey, 
    530 U.S. 466
     (2000), and McNally
    v. United States, 
    483 U.S. 350
     (1987), both of which over-
    ruled nearly uniform lower court precedent, certainly
    illustrate that strength of numbers does not always sig-
    nify an analysis convincing to the Supreme Court. See
    Buckhannon, 
    532 U.S. at 621
     (noting that “our disagree-
    ing with a ‘clear majority’ of the Circuits is not at all a
    rare phenomenon. Indeed, our opinions sometimes con-
    tradict the unanimous and long-standing interpretation
    of lower federal courts.”).
    We begin with the interests that animate the PLRA fee
    restrictions. The government and Dr. Daley propose five
    possible governmental interests furthered by the fee
    provisions, which mirror the interests asserted in the
    other circuit cases. It does not matter whether Congress
    had those interests in mind when enacting the PLRA
    fee restrictions, or whether they are mere conjecture,
    because Johnson must negate every conceivable basis
    which might support the legislation whether or not the
    basis has any foundation in the record. Heller, 
    509 U.S. at 320
    . The PLRA fee restrictions purportedly are related
    to the government’s interest in: (1) deterring the filing
    54                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    of frivolous claims; (2) regulating the filing of suits predi-
    cated on trivial harms; (3) protecting the public fisc; (4)
    regulating federal court intervention into States’ manage-
    ment of their prison systems; and (5) preventing wind-
    fall fee awards. We will consider these in turn.
    Two of the circuits as well as the concurrence here uphold
    the fee restrictions based solely on the governmental
    interest in deterring frivolous litigation. In the Ninth
    Circuit case of Madrid, the inmates acknowledged that
    the government had a legitimate interest in deterring
    frivolous filings, but maintained that it was not rational
    to distinguish between inmates and non-inmates in fur-
    therance of that goal. 
    190 F.3d at 996
    . The court rejected
    that argument, holding that the government could ratio-
    nally believe that prisoners are responsible for the major-
    ity of frivolous suits, and therefore could classify on that
    basis. 
    Id.
     That argument is in fact consistent with our
    decision in Lewis, 
    279 F.3d at 528-29
    , and with the deci-
    sions of many other circuits upholding the constitutional-
    ity of the filing fee provisions of the PLRA. Congress
    could well have determined that inmates are responsible
    for a disproportionate percentage of frivolous litigation
    in the federal courts, and could properly create a disin-
    centive to such filings, as by holding them responsible for
    the filing fees. In Madrid, the court held that Congress
    could rationally distinguish between inmates and lay-
    persons in its effort to deter frivolous litigation.
    The parties here concede Madrid’s point that the govern-
    ment has a legitimate interest in deterring frivolous
    litigation, and that Congress could properly focus that
    effort on inmates who are disproportionately responsible
    for the problem. Johnson maintains, however, that the
    PLRA fee restrictions at issue here are not rationally
    related to that goal—in other words, that the fit between
    the end and the means is so attenuated as to render the
    restrictions arbitrary. The Madrid court never addressed
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                        55
    that more critical issue of whether this particular classifi-
    cation—the attorney fee restriction—is related to that goal.
    The First Circuit in Boivin faced a challenge more
    analogous to the one before us. In that case, Boivin pre-
    sented “in skeletal form” an argument that there was a
    “complete lack of fit between the means that Congress
    chose (capping attorney’s fees) and the end that it sought
    to achieve (reducing frivolous prisoner litigation).” 
    225 F.3d at 44-45
    . The First Circuit understood the argument
    to be that the fee cap would not deter the filing of frivolous
    actions because fees are awarded only to prevailing par-
    ties. The Boivin court rejected that argument:
    [c]ommon sense suggests that this ex post view is
    untenable. Congress presumably feared the moti-
    vating effect of the prospect of attorneys’ fees, ex
    ante, and the fee cap quells that effect by capping
    the potential payoff. This changes the odds, and
    forces both lawyer and client, out of self-interest, to
    assess likely outcomes with greater care before
    filing a suit that, even if nominally successful,
    might leave them holding a nearly empty bag.
    
    Id. at 45
    . The court’s “ex post” and “ex ante” distinction,
    however, fails to recognize that the PLRA fee restrictions
    do not impose any added disincentive ex ante to the filing
    of frivolous litigation, because § 1988 already prohibits
    fees for such litigation. Boivin theorizes that Congress
    feared that potential attorney’s fees could provide motiva-
    tion for litigation. It then holds that the prospect of a
    limited fee may alter that analysis at the beginning, thus
    diminishing frivolous litigation. That assumes an initial
    assessment by the inmate of the strength of the case,
    because the fee recovery under the PLRA is tied to the
    damages attained. If § 1988 authorized the payment of
    fees for even frivolous litigation, then the PLRA fee re-
    strictions would indeed reduce the motivation for filing
    56                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    that such fee availability provides. Just the opposite is
    true, however.
    Under § 1988, no fees are possible for a frivolous case,
    and in fact sanctions may be imposed for such litigation.
    Therefore, the PLRA fee restrictions, by their very terms,
    are inapplicable to such a case, because those restrictions
    apply only to inmate cases “in which attorney’s fees are
    authorized under section 1988.” See § 1997e(d)(1) & (2). In
    addition, the § 1988 provisions deny all fees for frivolous
    litigation, thus imposing a greater disincentive ex ante to
    filing than the PLRA fee restrictions themselves would
    impose. The First Circuit failed to answer how an in-
    mate filing frivolous litigation would be motivated to
    withdraw it by the prospect that he could obtain only
    150% of the judgment as fees, when the law prior to the
    PLRA already established that he could obtain no fees at
    all for such litigation. If the goal is to reduce frivolous
    litigation, the PLRA fee restriction adds nothing to the
    equation. The law under § 1988 already removed the
    prospect of any fees in such circumstances, and therefore
    any contemplative effect that potential fees might have
    on the filing decision was already fully leveraged by
    § 1988. Given the prohibition on fees under § 1988 for
    frivolous litigation, the PLRA fee restrictions have no
    impact whatsoever on the filing of frivolous litigation that
    is not already provided by § 1988. The language of the
    statute acknowledges that by limiting the PLRA fee
    restrictions to cases in which fees are authorized under
    § 1988. Instead, the impact of the PLRA fee restrictions
    ex ante is only on the inmate contemplating the filing of
    non-frivolous litigation in which fees are potentially
    available under § 1988. See Hadix, 
    230 F.3d at
    844 n.3
    (“with respect to truly frivolous claims, it could be plausibly
    argued that the provision would have at best a very attenu-
    ated effect on the litigation decision of a pro se inmate,
    whose claims must be certified as possessing at least
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     57
    some merit at an early stage in the litigation. Further, the
    fee cap provisions only apply to cases in which the prisoner
    has actually prevailed, thereby assuring that at least one
    claim was meritorious.”). The government, however, does
    not and cannot argue that Congress has a legitimate
    interest in discouraging meritorious litigation by inmates.
    In recognition of the weakness of the frivolousness
    argument, the Sixth, Eighth, and to some extent the
    Eleventh Circuits rested their decisions on the second
    asserted governmental interest—that of decreasing mar-
    ginal or trivial lawsuits. I will assume for purposes of
    this dissent that the government may have a legitimate
    interest in decreasing the number of meritorious civil rights
    suits that involve trivial harms. The government links
    its interest in decreasing trivial litigation with the fee
    restrictions by opining that: (1) the fee restrictions will
    provide a disincentive that did not previously exist for an
    attorney to take a case involving trivial violations; (2) this
    will increase the likelihood that attorneys will decline
    to take such cases and (3) that prospect will in turn cause
    inmates to refrain from filing such cases because they
    will have to proceed pro se, or it will cause them to aban-
    don their suits when unable to obtain representation.
    Again, however, the PLRA adds no restriction on fees
    that was not already present under § 1988, and therefore
    does not add a disincentive for the prisoner to file that
    trivial litigation. For the same reason, the PLRA fee
    restrictions would not impact an attorney’s decision to
    file a frivolous or trivial suit in the first place. Under
    either the PLRA or § 1988, that attorney would need to
    initially assess the potential for fees before filing such a
    case, and because § 1988 already prohibits fees in a frivo-
    lous or trivial suit, the PLRA does not create any addi-
    tional disincentive to filing such suits. All the PLRA does
    is to notify attorneys filing frivolous prisoner civil rights
    actions that they will get a maximum of 150% of zero
    58                                 Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    instead of zero. The Sixth Circuit in Hadix and Walker
    failed to analyze the PLRA restrictions in the context of
    § 1988 fees generally, and therefore did not address
    whether the PLRA fee restriction added any disincentive
    that was not already provided by § 1988 fee restrictions.
    Because the Eighth Circuit’s analysis consisted entirely
    of a quote from Walker, and the Eleventh Circuit merely
    quoted Walker and Hadix without separate analysis, those
    decisions manifest the same shortcoming. The § 1988
    context is critical, however, in determining whether the
    means are rationally related to the ends; the search for a
    link between the classification and objective is what
    gives substance to the requirement of equal protection.
    Romer, 
    517 U.S. at 632-33
     (to survive rational relationship
    scrutiny, the law must be “narrow enough in scope and
    grounded in a sufficient factual context for us to ascertain
    some relation between the classification and the purpose
    it served”).
    The PLRA fee restriction, placed in the context of the
    § 1988 remedy that it modifies, fails to cross the first
    step in the three-step sequence that would supposedly
    reduce the volume of trivial litigation, because it does not
    provide a disincentive that did not previously exist for an
    attorney to take a case involving trivial violations. That
    is because attorney’s fees are already presumptively
    unavailable in cases involving trivial or de minimis viola-
    tions. See discussion supra at 16-18. Only where other
    factors establish that a seemingly minimal victory was
    actually significant, as where it involves a significant
    legal issue and serves an important public interest, will
    fees be available for a case that would otherwise be con-
    sidered trivial or de minimis. Farrar, 
    506 U.S. at 122
    ;
    Simpson, 
    104 F.3d at 1001
    . The government does not
    argue, nor could it, that it has a legitimate interest in
    discouraging the filing of constitutional claims involving
    a significant public interest. Therefore, that exception
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     59
    is inapplicable. We are left with the pre-existing § 1988
    law that presumes that no fees are available for cases
    involving de minimis or trivial harms. Therefore, before
    the PLRA, an inmate deciding whether to file a lawsuit
    would be presented with the prospect of attorney’s fees
    for meritorious cases involving significant harms, but
    with no fees available if the suit prevailed but involved
    only trivial harms, and with no fees and possibly sanctions
    if the suit was frivolous. The PLRA fee restrictions do
    nothing to alter the status quo for the inmate who
    brings the frivolous or trivial suit. It serves only to create
    a significant disadvantage for those presenting signifi-
    cant, meritorious challenges. Once again, however, the
    government does not allege that it has a legitimate inter-
    est in deterring the filing of such meritorious suits, nor
    does it argue that prisoners as opposed to others are re-
    sponsible for more of those suits or are otherwise a proper
    class to single out for such a goal.
    Even if fees were available under § 1988 to attorneys
    representing prisoners in trivial civil rights actions, the
    subset of cases in that category impacted by the PLRA
    fee restrictions is so small that it may actually be zero.
    We begin with the reality that only 1% of all prisoner
    cases even involve private attorneys. The other 4% in-
    volve appointed counsel, and by definition courts do not
    appoint counsel in trivial cases. Within that 1% of cases,
    we are asked to believe that some of those cases are
    trivial but that an attorney nonetheless agreed to repre-
    sent the prisoner, that the attorney would not be de-
    terred from filing by the prospect of little or no fees
    under the “qualitative” restriction of § 1988, but that the
    attorney will be deterred by the “quantitative” restriction
    of the PLRA. There is no reason to believe that any cases
    fall within that hypothetical reach.
    The district court, faced with the reality of prisoner
    litigation on a daily basis, was skeptical of this line of
    60                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    reasoning. The court noted that “in nearly 100%” of pris-
    oner cases involving representation, the attorneys were
    appointed by the court, and that of the 1,980 prisoner civil
    rights cases filed in the Wisconsin federal courts between
    January 1995 and September 1999, only 2.5% had coun-
    sel appointed. Johnson v. Daley, 
    117 F. Supp.2d 889
    , 898
    (W.D. Wis. 2000); see also Roger A. Hanson & Henry W.K.
    Daley, United States Dept. of Justice, Bureau of Justice
    Statistics, Challenging the Conditions of Prisons and
    Jails: A Report on Section 1983 Litigation, at 21-22 (Table
    6) (Dec. 1994) (recounting that 96% of prisoner civil rights
    actions are filed pro se, with attorneys appointed in ap-
    proximately 4% and private attorneys in approximately
    1% of the cases). The court noted that in its thirty years
    of handling prison civil rights cases, it could think of
    none that were attorney initiated. 
    117 F. Supp.2d at 898
    .
    The court concluded that the asserted connection between
    the filing decision and attorney’s fees was too tenuous:
    At the heart of defendant’s argument is the idea
    that prisoners perform a cost-benefit analysis in
    deciding whether to file a lawsuit, weighing a
    variety of factors. Although it is reasonable to
    assume that a pro se prisoner does do this, it is
    irrational to conclude that he bases his decision on
    the distant possibility that at some future time, his
    presently non-existent lawyer might recover a
    smaller rather than a larger amount of fees.
    
    Id. at 896
    . The court further noted that although the
    purported goal was to discourage frivolous cases, there
    was “no chance” of counsel being appointed in frivolous
    cases, and accordingly the only prisoners affected by the
    fee provisions were those who filed meritorious com-
    plaints for whom the court could not secure counsel
    because of the limited fees available under the PLRA.
    Congress’ goal of reducing the burden of prisoner suits on
    federal courts would be ill-served by a fee restriction that
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                    61
    forced district courts to plod through pro se filings in
    meritorious cases because of the inability to obtain ap-
    pointed counsel. The reality in which the fee restrictions
    operates negated the purported connection between the
    classification and the goals. Id at 900; see Heller, 
    509 U.S. at 321
    (noting that “even the standard of rationality as
    we so often have defined it must find some footing in the
    realities of the subject addressed by the legislation”).
    On the other hand, the PLRA fee restrictions have a
    very direct, foreseeable, and inevitable impact on the
    meritorious actions filed by attorneys, whether appointed
    or privately retained. Where the relation with the al-
    leged governmental interest is that dubious, and the
    impact on an unrelated class of meritorious cases so ob-
    vious and severe, no rational connection exists between
    the classification and the purported interest.
    I must emphasize that we are not concerned here with the
    possibility that the PLRA fee restrictions are merely
    cumulative of provisions in § 1988. Statutes do not vio-
    late equal protection solely because they overlap some-
    what with other pre-existing remedies. The problem in
    this case is that the government interest justifying the
    classification is in the deterrence of frivolous and trivial
    suits, yet the PLRA restrictions will not even apply to
    such suits. The language of the PLRA clarifies that the
    fee restrictions apply to actions in which § 1988 fees
    are authorized, thus making the contours of § 1988 the
    starting point in the analysis. Because no fees are avail-
    able for frivolous or trivial cases, the PLRA fee restric-
    tions will never apply to such cases, and therefore the
    governmental interest in deterring those cases is wholly
    inapposite.
    Although the fit between means and ends need not
    be perfect, there must be some fit in order for the legisla-
    tion to survive rational relationship scrutiny. If the inter-
    62                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    est is in deterring frivolous and trivial litigation, but the
    legislation impacts only non-trivial meritorious litiga-
    tion, that fit is lacking. The present case bears witness
    to the lack of fit between the fee restrictions and the
    deterrence of frivolous litigation. Johnson’s meritorious
    claim concerned actions which placed his life in danger.
    His claim cannot be characterized as trivial under any
    definition of that term. Nevertheless, he presented evi-
    dence to the district court that at least four private at-
    torneys refused to take his case, and he obtained represen-
    tation only after counsel was appointed for him by the
    district court. That attorney, having accepted the appoint-
    ment from the court, is now faced with the prospect of
    recovering fees which are inadequate to compensate for
    the effort reasonably expended and the risk undertaken,
    and that meager compensation is attributable solely to the
    status of the client as incarcerated rather than to the
    relative merit of the claim. Of course, a statute does not
    fail the rational relationship test solely because its im-
    precise reach impacts persons beyond those within its
    legitimate interest. Neither, however, can we analyze the
    claim in some kind of Never-Neverland, where the con-
    text and the actual reach of the statute are ignored. See
    Romer, 
    517 U.S. at 632-33
     (to survive rational relation
    scrutiny, law must be grounded in sufficient factual con-
    text for Court to ascertain some relation between the
    classification and the purpose it serves); Heller, 
    509 U.S. at 321
    (“even the standard of rationality as we so often have
    defined it must find some footing in the realities of the
    subject addressed by the legislation”); Lindsey, 
    405 U.S. at 78
     (analyzing the statutory double-bond requirement in
    the context of the pre-existing state statutes). The PLRA
    fee restrictions go well beyond being somewhat under-
    inclusive or overinclusive; rather, essentially all of the
    interests that the restrictions allegedly target are ex-
    cluded from its reach by § 1988, whereas the PLRA fee
    restrictions have a direct, foreseeable impact on the class
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                    63
    of litigation in which Congress claims no interest. Bur-
    lington Northern R. Co. v. Ford, 
    504 U.S. 648
    , 653 (1992)
    (recognizing that equal protection clause is violated if
    the underinclusiveness and overinclusiveness is so great
    that the rules can no longer be said rationally to imple-
    ment the policy judgment); Romer v. Evans, 
    517 U.S. 620
    ,
    632 (1996) (amendment fails rational relationship test
    where “its sheer breadth is so discontinuous with the
    reasons offered for it that [it] seems inexplicable by any-
    thing but animus toward the class it affects”). Where the
    means are completely divorced from the end, as here, the
    litigation fails the rational relationship test. See Massa-
    chusetts Bd. of Retirement v. Murgia, 
    427 U.S. 307
    , 314
    (1976) (examining whether mandatory retirement stat-
    ute “has the effect of excluding from service so few officers
    who are in fact unqualified as to render age 50 a criterion
    wholly unrelated to the objective of the statute.”).
    This conclusion is required if the rational relationship
    inquiry is to retain any meaning at all, and comports
    with an analogous Supreme Court case, Lindsey v.
    Normet, 
    405 U.S. 56
     (1972). In Lindsey, the Court ad-
    dressed the constitutionality of an Oregon Forcible Entry
    and Detainer statute that required tenants appealing an
    adverse determination to post bond in twice the amount
    of the rent expected to accrue pending the appellate de-
    cision. 
    Id. at 64
    . The governmental interest advanced
    for that double-bond requirement was to prevent frivo-
    lous appeals for dilatory purposes, because absent an
    added cost the tenant would have no disincentive to fore-
    go the appeal. Additionally, the Oregon Supreme Court
    opined that the additional bond payment would compen-
    sate for waste or would be in lieu of damages for unlawful
    holding over. 
    Id. at 76
    .
    The U.S. Supreme Court analyzed the double-bond
    provision in the context of the pre-existing Oregon appeal
    provisions for civil cases generally. 
    Id. at 74-78
    . In ordin-
    64                                 Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    ary civil litigation, the litigant was required to file an
    undertaking with one or more sureties covering all dam-
    ages, costs and disbursements which might be awarded
    against the appellant on appeal. Moreover, for an appel-
    lant to obtain a stay of execution in a case involving a
    monetary judgment, the undertaking had to also provide
    that the appellant would satisfy the judgment if she lost
    the appeal. Where the judgment was for real property,
    that undertaking had to provide that the appellant
    would commit no waste during the pendency of the appeal,
    and would pay for the use of property during that time
    should the appellant lose the appeal. 
    Id. at 74-75
    . The
    double-bond provision imposed additional obligations for
    appeals from Forcible Entry and Detainer judgments. In
    addition to the undertaking required of all civil litigants,
    an appellant in such an action was compelled to provide
    an undertaking with two sureties for the payment of twice
    the rental value of the premises, and if the judgment
    was affirmed, the landlord was automatically entitled to
    twice the rents accruing during the appeal. 
    Id. at 75
    .
    The Court began its analysis of the double-bond provi-
    sion by recognizing that even though the state is not
    required to provide appellate review, when an appeal
    is afforded, equal protection required that the right not
    be arbitrarily and capriciously granted to some litigants
    and not others. 
    405 U.S. at 77
    . We are presented with a
    similar situation here: Congress was not required to
    provide a mechanism for awarding attorney’s fees, but
    once provided the fees cannot be arbitrarily and capri-
    ciously denied to one class of litigants without violating
    equal protection.
    Although the Lindsey Court went on to acknowledge
    that Oregon had a legitimate interest in ensuring that
    appellants post adequate security for appeal, the Court
    held that the double-bond requirement did not effectuate
    that purpose. The Court emphasized that the undertak-
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                   65
    ing already protected the landlord by assuring payment
    for accrued rent and protection against waste. 
    Id. at 77-78
    .
    The Court rejected the claim that the double-bond provi-
    sion would screen out frivolous appeals, because “it not
    only bars nonfrivolous appeals by those who are unable
    to post the bond but it also allows meritless appeals by
    others who can afford the bond.” 
    Id. at 78
    . Thus, the Court
    recognized that the statute was deficient because it was
    both over- and under-inclusive, and because pre-existing
    statutes already protected the state’s asserted interest.
    Lindsey’s criticisms parallel the problems presented
    by the PLRA. The asserted interests in deterring frivolous
    and trivial litigation are already covered by § 1988, which
    does not allow any fees at all in such cases. In that con-
    text, the limitation on the amount of fees is meaningless
    for those type of cases. Moreover, the PLRA inevitably
    impacts the non-trivial, meritorious civil rights cases
    which Congress claims no interest in deterring. The im-
    pact of the 150% limitations are magnified in the prison
    context, where damage awards are consistently lower
    than are provided in actions by non-prisoners and where
    the risk of no recovery is much greater. By linking fees to
    a percentage of those lower damages, the fee has a great-
    er adverse impact in the prison context than might be
    experienced in non-prisoner litigation. Finally, the fee
    restrictions at issue in this case are just two of a num-
    ber of other restrictions on fees in § 1997e(d). Section
    1997e(d)(1) limits the fee amount in two ways: the fee
    must be directly and reasonably incurred in proving an
    actual violation, and the amount must be proportion-
    ately related to the court ordered relief or directly and
    reasonably incurred in enforcing the relief ordered for the
    violation. Therefore, the 150% cap on total fees and on the
    hourly rate will in all cases operate to reduce the fee
    award below that baseline amount of fees that were di-
    rectly, reasonably incurred and proportionate to the
    66                                  Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    relief ordered. This impact further undermines the argu-
    ments made in this case. The fee restrictions have no
    impact on the frivolous and trivial cases, and operate
    only to reduce the fee award in meritorious litigation
    below the amount that was both reasonably incurred and
    proportionate to the relief. The restrictions therefore
    lack the fit between classification and governmental
    interest that is necessary to ensure that the classification
    is not drawn for the purpose of disadvantaging the group
    burdened by the law. Romer, 
    517 U.S. at 633
    . The fit
    between means and ends is even more attenuated in this
    case than in Lindsey, and therefore the PLRA fee restric-
    tions violate equal protection. See also Rinaldi v. Yeager,
    
    384 U.S. 305
    , 310 (1966) (invalidating requirement that
    only incarcerated persons repay the costs of transcripts;
    holding that the statutory interest in deterring frivolous
    appeals cannot survive equal protection scrutiny be-
    cause the statute inevitably burdens many whose unsuc-
    cessful appeals were nonfrivolous, while leaving untouched
    many whose appeals were frivolous.)
    The remaining interests asserted by the government
    similarly are insufficient to survive even that minimal
    level of scrutiny. The government maintains that the
    PLRA fee restrictions are rationally related to the govern-
    ment interests in reducing federal court intervention into
    state management of prisons, preventing windfall fee
    awards, and protecting the public fisc. The first argument
    is that successful prison litigation may result in consent
    decrees, involving the federal court in state management
    of prisons, and that the fee restrictions may reduce the
    incentive for prisoners to file such claims, thus diminishing
    federal court involvement in state management of the
    prisons. The remaining arguments similarly focus on the
    impact of meritorious litigation on the state, asserting that
    the fee restrictions would cabin judicial discretion in
    awarding fees, thus reducing the potential for windfall fee
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                      67
    awards, and would protect the public fisc by decreasing
    the fees that must be paid out of the state treasuries. All
    of these justifications focus on the impact occasioned by
    meritorious prisoner litigation. Certainly, the states
    would save money if less meritorious litigation were filed
    against them, and if fees available for such litigation
    were restricted (although, again, the government’s inter-
    est must be a legitimate one to survive scrutiny.) Similar
    savings could be obtained if Congress passed a similar
    fee restriction applicable to all blue-eyed litigants, all
    government employee litigants, or all litigation concerning
    the educational system. Equal protection, however, re-
    quires more than just a showing that some goal is furthered
    by the legislation; rather, equal protection requires “some
    rationality in the nature of the class singled out.” Rinaldi,
    
    384 U.S. at 308-09
    ; Schlib v. Kuebel, 
    404 U.S. 357
    , 368
    (1971).
    The Court examined the need for that fit between classifi-
    cation and goal in Rinaldi. There, a New Jersey statute
    required indigent persons convicted of a crime, who
    were confined to prison, to repay the cost of the transcript
    if they were unsuccessful on appeal. It required no such
    repayment, however, from those who received a suspended
    sentence, probation, or only a fine. The state argued that
    its statute was designed to replenish the county treasury
    from those who had benefitted from county expenditures,
    and that it would deter frivolous appeals. 
    384 U.S. at
    309-
    10. The Court rejected that argument, however, holding
    that the statute was unconstitutional under the Equal
    Protection Clause. Certainly, the statute would help re-
    plenish the county treasury, but that furtherance of the
    fiscal goal did not end the Court’s inquiry. Instead, the
    Court held that the Equal Protection Clause requires that,
    “in defining a class subject to legislation, the distinctions
    that are drawn have ‘some relevance to the purpose for
    which the classification is made.’ ” 
    Id. at 308-09
    . In Rinaldi,
    68                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    the classification distinguished institutionalized unsuccess-
    ful appellants from those not institutionalized. The Court
    held, however, that “[t]here is no defensible interest served
    by focusing on that distinction as a classifying feature in a
    reimbursement statute, since it bears no relationship
    whatsoever to the purpose of the repayment provision.” 
    Id. at 309
    . Whether a person was institutionalized or not, or
    the nature of the sentence imposed, was a trait unrelated
    to the fiscal objective of the statute. 
    Id. at 309-310
    . The
    Court further rejected the state’s claim that the classifica-
    tion was a matter of administrative convenience, because
    those punished by fines could be reached through ordinary
    garnishment, and repayment could easily be made a
    condition of probation. 
    Id. at 310
    . Thus, the Court again
    recognized that the constitutionality of a statute cannot
    be analyzed in a vacuum, but must include a recognition
    of the real context in which it operates. Because incarcera-
    tion status had no rational connection to a transcript cost,
    the Court held that the statute lacked rationality in the
    nature of the class singled out and was unconstitutional
    under the Equal Protection Clause. Id.; Schlib, 404 U.S.
    at 368; see also James v. Strange, 
    407 U.S. 128
     (1972)
    (relying on Rinaldi and holding that statute giving
    state right to recover legal defense costs from indigent
    defendants and depriving them of protective exemptions
    violates equal protection).
    We are presented with the same situation in address-
    ing the remaining governmental interests asserted here.
    The government asserts an interest in diminishing the
    fiscal burden of fees on the states, and also in decreasing
    the costs associated with defending and monitoring com-
    pliance in cases of meritorious litigation. There is no
    rationality, however, in imposing such a restriction on
    attorneys representing institutionalized persons, because
    the locale of the litigant is unrelated to the fiscal objective.
    Although Congress can approach a problem piece-meal,
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                     69
    there is no attempt in the briefs to explain why inmates
    should be singled out over non-inmates for the restriction
    in cases involving meritorious litigation, which is all that
    is addressed by these last three proffered governmental
    interests. For instance, the prisoner/non-prisoner classifica-
    tion makes no sense if the interest is in simply protect-
    ing the public fisc, because there is no reason to believe
    that prisoners are filing more non-trivial meritorious
    cases than non-prisoners, or that they are achieving
    windfall fee awards in greater numbers in such cases. In
    fact, the record indicates that at the time the PLRA fee
    restrictions were enacted, nearly 96% of all prison litigation
    was pro se, and there is no correlation between inmate
    status and windfall fee awards (at least no correlation that
    would indicate such awards are more likely to be provided
    to inmates; the reverse, however, might be true). There
    is no rational basis to connect inmate status with the
    goal of reducing the fiscal burden any more than Congress
    could single out blue-eyed litigants and restrict their fees.
    The classification itself has to be related to the interest
    asserted, and it is not. Congress in enacting the PLRA
    was concerned with the flood of frivolous litigation, not
    the flood of meritorious litigation. There is simply no
    basis in the record or in theory upon which we could hold
    that meritorious litigation by prisoners is creating an
    economic burden justifying the singling out of inmates for
    this type of restriction. There is, in short, no connection
    between the fiscal goals of the statute and the status of
    the meritorious litigant as either an inmate or a non-
    institutionalized individual.
    As a means of discouraging frivolous or trivial suits
    by prisoners, the PLRA imposes no restriction on fees
    that § 1988 does not already impose. As a means of reduc-
    ing the burden on states, there is no rational reason to
    single out prisoners. The PLRA fee restrictions will,
    however, have a significant, predictable impact on the
    70                                   Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115
    ability of prisoners with meritorious cases to obtain repre-
    sentation. As the district court recognized, “the only
    prisoners affected are those who file meritorious complaints
    for whom the court cannot secure counsel because of the
    limited fees available to lawyers in such cases.” Johnson,
    
    117 F. Supp. 2d at 896
    . Rather than decrease the burden on
    courts, these restrictions will have the opposite effect,
    making it more difficult for courts to persuade lawyers to
    accept appointment. 
    Id. at 898
    . The inevitable result will be
    that constitutional violations against prisoners will go
    unremedied, and that is contrary to the purposes of the civil
    rights acts and § 1988. Congress has no legitimate govern-
    mental interest in deterring the filing of meritorious
    lawsuits. As such, the classification is not rationally related
    to the goals and fails Equal Protection scrutiny. I respect-
    fully dissent.
    FLAUM, Chief Judge, dissenting. In my judgment, as
    Judge Rovner has indicated in her dissent, the plurality’s
    proposed benchmarks for answering the “compared to
    what?” question miss the mark. The appropriate focus
    should be between prisoner and nonprisoner litigants
    seeking fees under § 1988—indeed, I believe that perhaps
    the most apt comparison would be between former pris-
    oners bringing suit for violations that occurred during
    their imprisonment and current prisoners bringing suit
    for identical violations. Cf. Kerr v. Puckett, 
    138 F.3d 321
    ,
    323 (7th Cir. 1998) (holding that prisoner as defined in 42
    U.S.C. § 1997e(h) does not comprehend a felon who has
    been released). Concluding that Judge Rovner has identi-
    fied the correct approach for comparison purposes and
    agreeing with the well-reasoned analysis contained in Parts
    II and III of her opinion, I respectfully dissent.
    Nos. 00-3981 & 00-4115                                71
    A true Copy:
    Teste:
    ________________________________
    Clerk of the United States Court of
    Appeals for the Seventh Circuit
    USCA-02-C-0072—8-19-03
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 00-3981

Judges: Per Curiam

Filed Date: 8/19/2003

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/24/2015

Authorities (67)

Lindsey v. Normet , 92 S. Ct. 862 ( 1972 )

McDonald v. Board of Election Comm'rs of Chicago , 89 S. Ct. 1404 ( 1969 )

Marshall v. United States , 94 S. Ct. 700 ( 1974 )

Kotch v. Board of River Port Pilot Comm'rs for Port of New ... , 330 U.S. 552 ( 1947 )

Parratt v. Taylor , 101 S. Ct. 1908 ( 1981 )

Burlington Northern Railroad v. Ford , 112 S. Ct. 2184 ( 1992 )

Mitchell v. Farcass , 112 F.3d 1483 ( 1997 )

everett-hadix-96-25672568-mary-glover-96-25862588 , 230 F.3d 840 ( 2000 )

McNally v. United States , 107 S. Ct. 2875 ( 1987 )

City of Boerne v. Flores , 117 S. Ct. 2157 ( 1997 )

Miller v. French , 120 S. Ct. 2246 ( 2000 )

Board of Trustees of Univ. of Ala. v. Garrett , 121 S. Ct. 955 ( 2001 )

Brown v. Legal Foundation of Washington , 123 S. Ct. 1406 ( 2003 )

Johnson v. Daley , 117 F. Supp. 2d 889 ( 2000 )

alejandro-madrid-carlos-lutz-ronnie-dewberry-steven-villa-bruce , 190 F.3d 990 ( 1999 )

Tucker, Cornelius v. Branker, G. , 142 F.3d 1294 ( 1998 )

Darryl Simpson v. Michael Sheahan, Sheriff of Cook County, ... , 104 F.3d 998 ( 1997 )

connie-j-briggs-michael-brown-jr-michael-j-carnes-v-william-f , 93 F.3d 355 ( 1996 )

michael-t-collins-v-montgomery-county-board-of-prison-inspectors-joseph , 176 F.3d 679 ( 1999 )

Ozan Lumber Co. v. Union County Nat. Bank of Liberty , 28 S. Ct. 89 ( 1907 )

View All Authorities »