Phoenix Bond v. Bridge, John ( 2007 )


Menu:
  •                             In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    ____________
    No. 06-1160
    PHOENIX BOND & INDEMNITY CO. and
    BCS SERVICES, INC.,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    JOHN BRIDGE, et al.,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    ____________
    Appeal from the United States District Court for the
    Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division.
    No. 05 C 4095—James F. Holderman, Chief Judge.
    ____________
    ARGUED JANUARY 16, 2007—DECIDED FEBRUARY 20, 2007
    ____________
    Before EASTERBROOK, Chief Judge, and POSNER and
    EVANS, Circuit Judges.
    EASTERBROOK, Chief Judge. Failure to pay property
    taxes creates a lien for the amount of the unpaid tax
    (including interest), plus a penalty. Cook County, Illinois,
    sells tax liens at auction. The bids are stated as per-
    centage penalties that the owner must pay (on top of the
    taxes and interest) to the winning bidder to clear the lien.
    The bidder willing to accept the lowest penalty wins the
    auction; the winner pays the back taxes to the County
    and receives the tax lien plus the right to collect the
    penalty. If the owner does not pay up, the lien holder can
    obtain a tax deed and thus become the parcel’s owner.
    2                                              No. 06-1160
    State law sets the maximum penalty at 18%, see 35
    ILCS 200/21-215, and the County’s regulations set the
    minimum penalty at zero. Most parcels attract multiple
    bids at 0% penalty. The bidders expect to make their
    profits not by collecting surcharges from owners but from
    reselling (for more than the amount paid to the County
    in back taxes) the parcels of owners who do not pay.
    Vigorous competition among bidders has driven the
    winning penalty down to the floor, and from the County’s
    perspective this is all to the good: it recovers the taxes,
    and owners need not pay extra. But multiple, identical
    bids pose a problem: who wins the auction? The County
    might allow negative bids (so the owner could redeem by
    paying less than the face amount of the tax), and then
    the market would clear, but the regulations forbid such
    bids—perhaps because a negative penalty would lead
    rational owners not to pay their taxes until after the
    liens had been sold.
    The County’s solution to the problem of multiple bids at
    0% is allocation by lot. If X bids 0% on ten parcels, and
    each parcel attracts five bids at that penalty rate, then
    the County awards X two of the ten parcels. Winners
    share according to the ratio of their bids to other iden-
    tical bids. This creates an incentive to submit multiple
    bids per parcel, either directly or through agents. If Y
    submits two bids per parcel, then its take from the auc-
    tion will be double that of X. To prevent this, the County
    promulgated what it calls the “Single, Simultaneous
    Bidder Rule": each “tax buying entity” must submit bids
    in its own name, and no “related entity” may bid. A
    “related entity” is any other person or firm that either (a)
    has a shareholder, partner, principal, or officer in com-
    mon with the “tax buying entity,” or (b) has a “contractual
    relationship with” the “tax buying entity.” Thus if Jones
    is a partner in Y, a bidder at the sale, any other business
    in which Jones has an ownership or management role is
    No. 06-1160                                                3
    forbidden to participate; likewise Z can’t participate if it
    has a contractual relation with Y (for example, if Z has
    agreed to sell to Y any of the tax liens that Z receives at
    the auction). Before each auction, every potential bidder
    must furnish the County with an affidavit that no agent
    or other related entity will participate in that auction.
    Phoenix Bond and BCS Services, two regular partici-
    pants in Cook County’s tax sales, contend that Sabre
    Group, LLC, and its principal Barrett Rochman regularly
    violate the Single, Simultaneous Bidder Rule by arrang-
    ing for related firms to bid, and that as a result Sabre
    Group obtains an extra portion of profitable liens. If this
    is so, then Sabre Group’s affidavit must be false; and if
    it is false, the Sabre Group knows that it is false and
    hence has committed fraud. Because the tax-sale process
    employs the mail—perhaps to send affidavits, and cer-
    tainly to send notices to owners that the liens have been
    sold and the taxes must be paid or the property for-
    feited—any fraud that affects which bidders obtain how
    many liens is “mail fraud.” See Schmuck v. United States,
    
    489 U.S. 705
     (1989). And because Sabre and its affiliates
    have engaged in a pattern of mail fraud, the argument
    goes, a private treble-damages remedy is available under
    the Racketeer Influenced and Corrupt Organizations
    Act, 
    18 U.S.C. §1964
    . The damages would be set by the
    value of the liens that would have gone to Phoenix Bond
    and BCS Services had Sabre Group and its affiliates
    complied with the Single, Simultaneous Bidder Rule.
    This at any event is the theory that plaintiffs advance.
    They did not get very far, however. The district court
    dismissed the complaint under Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(1) for
    lack of standing, and thus absence of federal jurisdiction.
    
    2005 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 34912
     (N.D. Ill. Dec. 21, 2005). The
    County is the proper plaintiff, the district court concluded.
    Standing is not a problem in this suit. Plaintiffs suffer
    injury in fact, and that injury can be redressed by dam-
    4                                               No. 06-1160
    ages. Extra bids reduce plaintiffs’ chance of winning any
    given auction, and loss of a (valuable) chance is real injury.
    So the Supreme Court held in Northeastern Florida
    Chapter, Associated General Contractors of America v.
    Jacksonville, 
    508 U.S. 656
     (1993). Thousands of liens are
    sold at each auction. Plaintiffs suffer an actual (and
    substantial) reduction in the number of liens they take
    away. No more need be said about standing.
    Injury in fact is not sufficient under RICO, however; the
    plaintiff also must establish that its injury was proxi-
    mately caused by the defendants’ scheme. See Anza v.
    Ideal Steel Supply Corp., 
    126 S. Ct. 1991
     (2006); Holmes v.
    SIPC, 
    503 U.S. 258
     (1992). The Court acknowledged in
    Holmes that “proximate causation,” a term long used
    in tort law, poses a set of questions to ask; it is not a
    formula that may be applied algorithmically. 
    503 U.S. at 268-70
    . Is someone else a distinctly better enforcer? Does
    the presence of intermediate parties make it too hard to
    calculate damages—or create a risk that recovery by this
    plaintiff will come at the expense of someone with a better
    claim? If so, then suit by the remotely injured person
    should not be allowed.
    In Holmes, for example, manipulation supposedly
    caused the price of shares in six firms to decline substan-
    tially; broker-dealers that had specialized in those firms’
    securities for their own accounts went bankrupt and were
    liquidated; when the broker-dealers failed, customers
    whose funds had been invested in other securities suf-
    fered because the broker-dealers could not keep promises
    to their customers (for example, could not pay in full for
    other securities that the customers had sold); the Securi-
    ties Investor Protection Corp., which paid off the custom-
    ers’ claims against the broker-dealers, then sued the
    persons supposedly responsible for the manipulation
    that set off this chain of events. The Court held that the
    broker-dealers (or their trustees in bankruptcy) that had
    No. 06-1160                                                 5
    invested in the securities subject to the manipulation, and
    not persons who suffered derivative injury when the
    broker-dealers failed, were the right plaintiffs. SIPC
    was subrogated to the customers’ claims, but the cus-
    tomers did not suffer immediate injury and could not
    use RICO to recover ahead of the broker-dealers’ other
    customers. See also Mid-State Fertilizer Co. v. Exchange
    National Bank, 
    877 F.2d 1333
     (7th Cir. 1989) (favorably
    cited in Holmes, 
    503 U.S. at 274
    ). Any money that the
    broker-dealers recovered could be used to satisfy all
    claims against them. Recovery by the SIPC would cut
    out the broker-dealers’ other creditors.
    In Anza the plaintiffs were business rivals of retailers
    that allegedly had cheated on their taxes. The theory of
    causation was that, by not paying sales taxes, defendants
    reduced their costs of doing business and thus could cut
    the retail price; consumers then bought less from the
    plaintiffs (and for less per unit, as plaintiffs had to com-
    pete with defendants’ low prices). The entity directly
    injured by the fraud was the polity entitled to the taxes,
    and the Court thought that it would be too difficult to
    determine how much (if any) of the tax savings had been
    passed on to customers. Cf. Kansas v. Utilicorp United
    Inc., 
    497 U.S. 199
     (1990); Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 
    431 U.S. 720
     (1977). Instead of trying to determine what had
    been passed on—and to apportion damages if the gov-
    ernmental bodies also sued—the Court thought it best to
    allocate the entire claim to the immediate victim.
    Defendants maintain that Cook County is the victim of
    their fraud (supposing, as they must at the pleading
    stage, that they have committed fraud). Yet Cook County
    did not lose even a penny: each winning bidder always
    pays all back taxes and interest. The bidding at these
    auctions concerns how much the owners must pay in
    penalties, not how much the County receives. And as long
    as competition drives the bidding down to 0% penalty,
    6                                             No. 06-1160
    property owners are indifferent to who acquires the tax
    lien. The only injured parties are the losing bidders, who
    acquire fewer tax liens than they would if the Single,
    Simultaneous Bidder Rule were followed.
    To see this, suppose the FCC decides to award 500 radio
    licenses for $10,000 each by lottery and insists that each
    person submit only one entry directly or through any
    related entity. If Jones arranges for friends, family, and
    a raft of newly formed corporations to submit 1,000
    entries, honest entrants would be crowded out, while
    Jones could end up with multiple licenses. The honest
    entrants would be the only losers: the federal Treasury
    would still receive $10,000 per license, and the general
    population would be indifferent (presumably all winners
    would resell their licenses to whoever could make best
    use of the frequencies).
    It is possible to imagine circumstances under which the
    County (or at least its taxpayers) would be a victim
    of cooperation among bidders. If all of the potential bid-
    ders get together and agree to raise the penalty to 10% or
    even 18%, that would constitute a monopsony cartel, and
    the taxpayers would be the worse for it. But defen-
    dants (understandably) do not contend that they have
    organized a cartel, a line of argument that would win this
    suit at the expense of establishing the Antitrust Division
    and the property owners as potential plaintiffs. For their
    part, plaintiffs do not allege that defendants have formed
    a cartel, for a cartel would be to their benefit. If defen-
    dants raised the penalty bid even to 1%, plaintiffs and
    anyone else outside the group could bid 0% and obtain
    all of the liens. Even a few non-cooperating bidders
    would spoil the cartel. On the allegations of plaintiffs’
    complaint there is no cartel, and therefore plaintiffs
    rather than the County or the property owners are the
    immediately injured parties.
    No. 06-1160                                                7
    Doubtless the County could enforce its own rule, even
    though it loses nothing financially from the submission of
    multiple bids by related bidders. But of course the com-
    plaint alleges that defendants are lying to the County,
    which makes enforcement difficult—defendants’ affidavits
    assure the County that the Rule is being complied with.
    Anyway, the proposition “G can penalize fraud” differs
    from the proposition “G is the immediate victim of fraud.”
    If a government’s ability to penalize fraud knocked out
    private litigation, then §1964 would no longer apply when
    the predicate act is fraud, for governments always have
    some ability to detect and penalize frauds.
    According to defendants, the suit should be dismissed
    even if plaintiffs are the immediate and principal (if not
    the only) losers. That’s so, defendants say, for two reasons:
    first, no false statements were made to plaintiffs; the
    affidavits were filed with the County. Second, plaintiffs
    are not in the “zone of interests” protected by the statute
    making mail fraud a federal crime. These come to largely
    the same thing, and the argument is not sound which-
    ever way it is put.
    The mail fraud statute, 
    18 U.S.C. §1341
    , defines a
    fraudulent scheme, rather than a particular false state-
    ment, as the crime. It is illegal to obtain money by a
    scheme that entails fraud, if use of the mail is integral to
    the scheme. That’s why it is unnecessary to show that
    the false statement was made to the victim. A scheme
    that injures D by making false statements through the
    mail to E is mail fraud, and actionable by D through
    RICO if the injury is not derivative of someone else’s. So
    we held in both In re EDC, Inc., 
    930 F.2d 1275
    , 1279-80
    (7th Cir. 1991), and Israel Travel Advisory Service, Inc. v.
    Israel Identity Tours, Inc., 
    61 F.3d 1250
    , 1257 (7th Cir.
    1995), and we see no reason to change course. Three other
    circuits that have considered this question agree with our
    conclusion that the direct victim may recover through
    8                                               No. 06-1160
    RICO whether or not it is the direct recipient of the false
    statements. See Mid Atlantic Telecom, Inc. v. Long Dis-
    tance Services, Inc., 
    18 F.3d 260
    , 263-64 (4th Cir. 1994);
    Systems Management, Inc. v. Loiselle, 
    303 F.3d 100
    , 103-
    04 (1st Cir. 2002); Ideal Steel Supply Corp. v. Anza, 
    373 F.3d 251
    , 263 (2d Cir. 2004), reversed on other grounds,
    Anza v. Ideal Steel Supply Corp., 
    126 S. Ct. 1991
     (2006).
    But see Vandenbroeck v. CommonPoint Mortgage Co., 
    210 F.3d 696
    , 701 (6th Cir. 2000) (plaintiffs must show that
    they “in fact relied upon [the defendant’s] material misrep-
    resentation”); Sikes v. Teleline, Inc., 
    281 F.3d 1350
    , 1360-
    61 (11th Cir. 2002) (same). The box score is thus four
    circuits on one side and two on the other; we shall ad-
    here to the majority position. (Changing sides could not
    eliminate the conflict.)
    Defendants say that Phoenix Bond and BCS Services
    are not in the zone of interests protected by the mail
    fraud statute because they weren’t taken in by any false
    statement. That’s just a different take on the proposition
    that only recipients of the untruth have a remedy. When
    we articulated a zone-of-interests approach in EDC and
    Israel Travel, it was to drive home the point that the
    injury must be direct rather than derivative. We said, for
    example, that “business rivals may not use RICO to
    complain about injuries derivatively caused by mail
    frauds perpetrated against customers” (
    61 F.3d at 1258
    )
    and that “victims of fraud are the object of solicitude;
    §1341 does not establish a regime of truth-telling without
    regard to details like who is losing out and why” (ibid.). We
    summed up: “firms suffering derivative injury from
    business torts . . . must continue to rely on the common
    law . . . rather than resorting to RICO” (ibid.). Because a
    zone-of-interests approach so closely overlaps the law as
    developed in Holmes and Anza, it serves no independent
    role. When the injury satisfies the requirements of Holmes
    and Anza, it cannot be knocked out by a zone-of-interests
    No. 06-1160                                            9
    requirement that has no purchase in the text of either
    §1341 or RICO.
    REVERSED AND REMANDED
    A true Copy:
    Teste:
    ________________________________
    Clerk of the United States Court of
    Appeals for the Seventh Circuit
    USCA-02-C-0072—2-20-07