All Courts |
Federal Courts |
US Court of Appeals Cases |
Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit |
2007-02 |
-
In the United States Court of Appeals For the Seventh Circuit ____________ No. 06-1160 PHOENIX BOND & INDEMNITY CO. and BCS SERVICES, INC., Plaintiffs-Appellants, v. JOHN BRIDGE, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ____________ Appeal from the United States District Court for the Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division. No. 05 C 4095—James F. Holderman, Chief Judge. ____________ ARGUED JANUARY 16, 2007—DECIDED FEBRUARY 20, 2007 ____________ Before EASTERBROOK, Chief Judge, and POSNER and EVANS, Circuit Judges. EASTERBROOK, Chief Judge. Failure to pay property taxes creates a lien for the amount of the unpaid tax (including interest), plus a penalty. Cook County, Illinois, sells tax liens at auction. The bids are stated as per- centage penalties that the owner must pay (on top of the taxes and interest) to the winning bidder to clear the lien. The bidder willing to accept the lowest penalty wins the auction; the winner pays the back taxes to the County and receives the tax lien plus the right to collect the penalty. If the owner does not pay up, the lien holder can obtain a tax deed and thus become the parcel’s owner. 2 No. 06-1160 State law sets the maximum penalty at 18%, see 35 ILCS 200/21-215, and the County’s regulations set the minimum penalty at zero. Most parcels attract multiple bids at 0% penalty. The bidders expect to make their profits not by collecting surcharges from owners but from reselling (for more than the amount paid to the County in back taxes) the parcels of owners who do not pay. Vigorous competition among bidders has driven the winning penalty down to the floor, and from the County’s perspective this is all to the good: it recovers the taxes, and owners need not pay extra. But multiple, identical bids pose a problem: who wins the auction? The County might allow negative bids (so the owner could redeem by paying less than the face amount of the tax), and then the market would clear, but the regulations forbid such bids—perhaps because a negative penalty would lead rational owners not to pay their taxes until after the liens had been sold. The County’s solution to the problem of multiple bids at 0% is allocation by lot. If X bids 0% on ten parcels, and each parcel attracts five bids at that penalty rate, then the County awards X two of the ten parcels. Winners share according to the ratio of their bids to other iden- tical bids. This creates an incentive to submit multiple bids per parcel, either directly or through agents. If Y submits two bids per parcel, then its take from the auc- tion will be double that of X. To prevent this, the County promulgated what it calls the “Single, Simultaneous Bidder Rule": each “tax buying entity” must submit bids in its own name, and no “related entity” may bid. A “related entity” is any other person or firm that either (a) has a shareholder, partner, principal, or officer in com- mon with the “tax buying entity,” or (b) has a “contractual relationship with” the “tax buying entity.” Thus if Jones is a partner in Y, a bidder at the sale, any other business in which Jones has an ownership or management role is No. 06-1160 3 forbidden to participate; likewise Z can’t participate if it has a contractual relation with Y (for example, if Z has agreed to sell to Y any of the tax liens that Z receives at the auction). Before each auction, every potential bidder must furnish the County with an affidavit that no agent or other related entity will participate in that auction. Phoenix Bond and BCS Services, two regular partici- pants in Cook County’s tax sales, contend that Sabre Group, LLC, and its principal Barrett Rochman regularly violate the Single, Simultaneous Bidder Rule by arrang- ing for related firms to bid, and that as a result Sabre Group obtains an extra portion of profitable liens. If this is so, then Sabre Group’s affidavit must be false; and if it is false, the Sabre Group knows that it is false and hence has committed fraud. Because the tax-sale process employs the mail—perhaps to send affidavits, and cer- tainly to send notices to owners that the liens have been sold and the taxes must be paid or the property for- feited—any fraud that affects which bidders obtain how many liens is “mail fraud.” See Schmuck v. United States,
489 U.S. 705(1989). And because Sabre and its affiliates have engaged in a pattern of mail fraud, the argument goes, a private treble-damages remedy is available under the Racketeer Influenced and Corrupt Organizations Act,
18 U.S.C. §1964. The damages would be set by the value of the liens that would have gone to Phoenix Bond and BCS Services had Sabre Group and its affiliates complied with the Single, Simultaneous Bidder Rule. This at any event is the theory that plaintiffs advance. They did not get very far, however. The district court dismissed the complaint under Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(1) for lack of standing, and thus absence of federal jurisdiction.
2005 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 34912(N.D. Ill. Dec. 21, 2005). The County is the proper plaintiff, the district court concluded. Standing is not a problem in this suit. Plaintiffs suffer injury in fact, and that injury can be redressed by dam- 4 No. 06-1160 ages. Extra bids reduce plaintiffs’ chance of winning any given auction, and loss of a (valuable) chance is real injury. So the Supreme Court held in Northeastern Florida Chapter, Associated General Contractors of America v. Jacksonville,
508 U.S. 656(1993). Thousands of liens are sold at each auction. Plaintiffs suffer an actual (and substantial) reduction in the number of liens they take away. No more need be said about standing. Injury in fact is not sufficient under RICO, however; the plaintiff also must establish that its injury was proxi- mately caused by the defendants’ scheme. See Anza v. Ideal Steel Supply Corp.,
126 S. Ct. 1991(2006); Holmes v. SIPC,
503 U.S. 258(1992). The Court acknowledged in Holmes that “proximate causation,” a term long used in tort law, poses a set of questions to ask; it is not a formula that may be applied algorithmically.
503 U.S. at 268-70. Is someone else a distinctly better enforcer? Does the presence of intermediate parties make it too hard to calculate damages—or create a risk that recovery by this plaintiff will come at the expense of someone with a better claim? If so, then suit by the remotely injured person should not be allowed. In Holmes, for example, manipulation supposedly caused the price of shares in six firms to decline substan- tially; broker-dealers that had specialized in those firms’ securities for their own accounts went bankrupt and were liquidated; when the broker-dealers failed, customers whose funds had been invested in other securities suf- fered because the broker-dealers could not keep promises to their customers (for example, could not pay in full for other securities that the customers had sold); the Securi- ties Investor Protection Corp., which paid off the custom- ers’ claims against the broker-dealers, then sued the persons supposedly responsible for the manipulation that set off this chain of events. The Court held that the broker-dealers (or their trustees in bankruptcy) that had No. 06-1160 5 invested in the securities subject to the manipulation, and not persons who suffered derivative injury when the broker-dealers failed, were the right plaintiffs. SIPC was subrogated to the customers’ claims, but the cus- tomers did not suffer immediate injury and could not use RICO to recover ahead of the broker-dealers’ other customers. See also Mid-State Fertilizer Co. v. Exchange National Bank,
877 F.2d 1333(7th Cir. 1989) (favorably cited in Holmes,
503 U.S. at 274). Any money that the broker-dealers recovered could be used to satisfy all claims against them. Recovery by the SIPC would cut out the broker-dealers’ other creditors. In Anza the plaintiffs were business rivals of retailers that allegedly had cheated on their taxes. The theory of causation was that, by not paying sales taxes, defendants reduced their costs of doing business and thus could cut the retail price; consumers then bought less from the plaintiffs (and for less per unit, as plaintiffs had to com- pete with defendants’ low prices). The entity directly injured by the fraud was the polity entitled to the taxes, and the Court thought that it would be too difficult to determine how much (if any) of the tax savings had been passed on to customers. Cf. Kansas v. Utilicorp United Inc.,
497 U.S. 199(1990); Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois,
431 U.S. 720(1977). Instead of trying to determine what had been passed on—and to apportion damages if the gov- ernmental bodies also sued—the Court thought it best to allocate the entire claim to the immediate victim. Defendants maintain that Cook County is the victim of their fraud (supposing, as they must at the pleading stage, that they have committed fraud). Yet Cook County did not lose even a penny: each winning bidder always pays all back taxes and interest. The bidding at these auctions concerns how much the owners must pay in penalties, not how much the County receives. And as long as competition drives the bidding down to 0% penalty, 6 No. 06-1160 property owners are indifferent to who acquires the tax lien. The only injured parties are the losing bidders, who acquire fewer tax liens than they would if the Single, Simultaneous Bidder Rule were followed. To see this, suppose the FCC decides to award 500 radio licenses for $10,000 each by lottery and insists that each person submit only one entry directly or through any related entity. If Jones arranges for friends, family, and a raft of newly formed corporations to submit 1,000 entries, honest entrants would be crowded out, while Jones could end up with multiple licenses. The honest entrants would be the only losers: the federal Treasury would still receive $10,000 per license, and the general population would be indifferent (presumably all winners would resell their licenses to whoever could make best use of the frequencies). It is possible to imagine circumstances under which the County (or at least its taxpayers) would be a victim of cooperation among bidders. If all of the potential bid- ders get together and agree to raise the penalty to 10% or even 18%, that would constitute a monopsony cartel, and the taxpayers would be the worse for it. But defen- dants (understandably) do not contend that they have organized a cartel, a line of argument that would win this suit at the expense of establishing the Antitrust Division and the property owners as potential plaintiffs. For their part, plaintiffs do not allege that defendants have formed a cartel, for a cartel would be to their benefit. If defen- dants raised the penalty bid even to 1%, plaintiffs and anyone else outside the group could bid 0% and obtain all of the liens. Even a few non-cooperating bidders would spoil the cartel. On the allegations of plaintiffs’ complaint there is no cartel, and therefore plaintiffs rather than the County or the property owners are the immediately injured parties. No. 06-1160 7 Doubtless the County could enforce its own rule, even though it loses nothing financially from the submission of multiple bids by related bidders. But of course the com- plaint alleges that defendants are lying to the County, which makes enforcement difficult—defendants’ affidavits assure the County that the Rule is being complied with. Anyway, the proposition “G can penalize fraud” differs from the proposition “G is the immediate victim of fraud.” If a government’s ability to penalize fraud knocked out private litigation, then §1964 would no longer apply when the predicate act is fraud, for governments always have some ability to detect and penalize frauds. According to defendants, the suit should be dismissed even if plaintiffs are the immediate and principal (if not the only) losers. That’s so, defendants say, for two reasons: first, no false statements were made to plaintiffs; the affidavits were filed with the County. Second, plaintiffs are not in the “zone of interests” protected by the statute making mail fraud a federal crime. These come to largely the same thing, and the argument is not sound which- ever way it is put. The mail fraud statute,
18 U.S.C. §1341, defines a fraudulent scheme, rather than a particular false state- ment, as the crime. It is illegal to obtain money by a scheme that entails fraud, if use of the mail is integral to the scheme. That’s why it is unnecessary to show that the false statement was made to the victim. A scheme that injures D by making false statements through the mail to E is mail fraud, and actionable by D through RICO if the injury is not derivative of someone else’s. So we held in both In re EDC, Inc.,
930 F.2d 1275, 1279-80 (7th Cir. 1991), and Israel Travel Advisory Service, Inc. v. Israel Identity Tours, Inc.,
61 F.3d 1250, 1257 (7th Cir. 1995), and we see no reason to change course. Three other circuits that have considered this question agree with our conclusion that the direct victim may recover through 8 No. 06-1160 RICO whether or not it is the direct recipient of the false statements. See Mid Atlantic Telecom, Inc. v. Long Dis- tance Services, Inc.,
18 F.3d 260, 263-64 (4th Cir. 1994); Systems Management, Inc. v. Loiselle,
303 F.3d 100, 103- 04 (1st Cir. 2002); Ideal Steel Supply Corp. v. Anza,
373 F.3d 251, 263 (2d Cir. 2004), reversed on other grounds, Anza v. Ideal Steel Supply Corp.,
126 S. Ct. 1991(2006). But see Vandenbroeck v. CommonPoint Mortgage Co.,
210 F.3d 696, 701 (6th Cir. 2000) (plaintiffs must show that they “in fact relied upon [the defendant’s] material misrep- resentation”); Sikes v. Teleline, Inc.,
281 F.3d 1350, 1360- 61 (11th Cir. 2002) (same). The box score is thus four circuits on one side and two on the other; we shall ad- here to the majority position. (Changing sides could not eliminate the conflict.) Defendants say that Phoenix Bond and BCS Services are not in the zone of interests protected by the mail fraud statute because they weren’t taken in by any false statement. That’s just a different take on the proposition that only recipients of the untruth have a remedy. When we articulated a zone-of-interests approach in EDC and Israel Travel, it was to drive home the point that the injury must be direct rather than derivative. We said, for example, that “business rivals may not use RICO to complain about injuries derivatively caused by mail frauds perpetrated against customers” (
61 F.3d at 1258) and that “victims of fraud are the object of solicitude; §1341 does not establish a regime of truth-telling without regard to details like who is losing out and why” (ibid.). We summed up: “firms suffering derivative injury from business torts . . . must continue to rely on the common law . . . rather than resorting to RICO” (ibid.). Because a zone-of-interests approach so closely overlaps the law as developed in Holmes and Anza, it serves no independent role. When the injury satisfies the requirements of Holmes and Anza, it cannot be knocked out by a zone-of-interests No. 06-1160 9 requirement that has no purchase in the text of either §1341 or RICO. REVERSED AND REMANDED A true Copy: Teste: ________________________________ Clerk of the United States Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit USCA-02-C-0072—2-20-07
Document Info
Docket Number: 06-1160
Judges: Per Curiam
Filed Date: 2/20/2007
Precedential Status: Precedential
Modified Date: 9/24/2015