Wisconsin Electric Power Compa v. Union Pacific Railroad Company ( 2009 )


Menu:
  •                            In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    No. 08-2693
    W ISCONSIN E LECTRIC P OWER C OMPANY,
    Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.
    U NION P ACIFIC R AILROAD C OMPANY,
    Defendant-Appellee.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Eastern District of Wisconsin.
    No. 06-C-515—Rudolph T. Randa, Chief Judge.
    A RGUED JANUARY 7, 2009—D ECIDED M ARCH 2, 2009
    Before P OSNER, R IPPLE, and R OVNER, Circuit Judges.
    P OSNER, Circuit Judge. WEPCO, an electric utility that is
    the plaintiff in this diversity suit for breach of contract
    (governed by Wisconsin law), appeals from the grant of
    summary judgment to the defendant, the Union Pacific
    railroad. The contract was for the transportation of coal
    to WEPCO from coal mines in Colorado between the
    beginning of 1999 and the end of 2005. The appeal presents
    2                                               No. 08-2693
    two issues: whether a force majeure clause in the con-
    tract authorized the railroad to increase its rate for ship-
    ping the coal, and whether the railroad breached its
    duty of good-faith performance of its contractual obliga-
    tions by failing to ship the tonnage requested by WEPCO
    on railcars supplied by the railroad.
    The doctrine of impossibility in the common law of
    contracts excuses performance when it would be unrea-
    sonably costly (and sometimes downright impossible)
    for a party to carry out its contractual obligations. If
    the doctrine is successfully invoked, the contract is re-
    scinded without liability. The standard explanation for the
    doctrine is that nonperformance is not a breach if it is
    caused by a circumstance “the non-occurrence of which
    was a ‘basic assumption on which the contract was
    made.’ ” Restatement (Second) of Contracts, introductory
    note to ch. 11, preceding § 261 (1981), quoting UCC § 2-615.
    But this explanation leaves unexplained why parties to a
    contract would have assumed that a condition would
    not occur that has occurred. Was it just a lack of foresight?
    Or is the idea behind the doctrine, rather, that the
    parties, had they negotiated with reference to the con-
    tingency that has come to pass and has made performance
    infeasible or fearfully burdensome, would have excused
    performance? The latter is the more promising line of
    inquiry, and is the line we took in Northern Indiana
    Public Service Co. v. Carbon County Coal Co., 
    799 F.2d 265
    ,
    276-78 (7th Cir. 1986), where we said that “the proper
    question in an ‘impossibility’ case is . . . whether [the
    promisor’s] nonperformance should be excused because
    the parties, if they had thought about the matter, would
    No. 08-2693                                                   3
    have wanted to assign the risk of the contingency that
    made performance impossible or uneconomical to the
    promisor or to the promisee; if to the latter, the promisor
    is excused.” 
    Id. at 276
    . “Impossibility” is thus a doctrine
    “for shifting risk to the party better able to bear it, either
    because he is in a better position to prevent the risk
    from materializing or because he can better reduce the
    disutility of the risk (as by insuring) if the risk does occur.”
    
    Id. at 277
    ; see also Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC,
    
    824 F.2d 981
    , 1016-17 (D.C. Cir. 1987).
    Liability for breach of contract is strict, Globe Refining Co.
    v. Landa Cotton Oil Co., 
    190 U.S. 540
    , 543-44 (1903)
    (Holmes, J.); Evra Corp. v. Swiss Bank Corp., 
    673 F.2d 951
    ,
    956-57 (7th Cir. 1982); Restatement, supra, introductory
    note to ch. 11, preceding § 261, which makes the per-
    forming party an insurer against the consequences of
    his failing to perform, even if the failure is not his fault.
    But formal insurance contracts contain limits of coverage,
    and the impossibility doctrine in effect caps the “insur-
    ance” coverage that strict liability for breach of contract
    provides. Cf. Northern Indiana Public Service Co. v.
    Carbon County Coal Co., supra, 
    799 F.2d at 277
    . The
    analogy is to a provision in a fire insurance contract
    that excepts from coverage a fire caused by an act of war.
    So it is no surprise that in Allanwilde Transport Corp. v.
    Vacuum Oil Co., 
    248 U.S. 377
    , 385-86 (1919), the doctrine
    of impossibility was successfully invoked when a war-
    time embargo prevented the performance of a shipping
    contract because the ship could not complete its voyage.
    See also Israel v. Luckenbach S.S. Co., 
    6 F.2d 996
     (2d Cir.
    1925).
    4                                                  No. 08-2693
    Parties can, however, contract around the doctrine,
    because it is just a gap filler, First National Bank v. Atlantic
    Tele-Network Co., 
    946 F.2d 516
    , 521 (7th Cir. 1991); United
    States v. General Douglas MacArthur Senior Village, Inc.,
    
    508 F.2d 377
    , 381 (2d Cir. 1974); 2 E. Allan Farnsworth,
    Farnsworth on Contracts § 9.6, p. 643 (3d ed. 2004)—a guess
    at what the parties would have provided in their
    contract had they thought about the contingency that has
    arisen and has prevented performance or made it much
    more costly. As Holmes explained, “the consequences of
    a binding promise at common law are not affected by
    the degree of power which the promisor possesses over
    the promised event . . . . In the case of a binding promise
    that it shall rain to-morrow, the immediate legal effect
    of what the promisor does is, that he takes the risk of the
    event, within certain defined limits, as between himself
    and the promisee. He does no more when he promises
    to deliver a bale of cotton.” O.W. Holmes, Jr., The Common
    Law 299-300 (1881); see Field Container Corp. v. ICC, 
    712 F.2d 250
    , 257 (7th Cir. 1983). The key is binding promise.
    To defeat the application of the doctrine of impossibility
    the contract must state that the promisor must pay dam-
    ages even if he commits a breach that could not have
    been prevented at a reasonable cost.
    Modern contracting parties often do contract around
    the doctrine, though not by making the promisor liable
    for any and every failure to perform—rather by
    specifying the failures that will excuse performance. The
    clauses in which they do this are called force majeure
    (“superior force”) clauses. The name suggests a pur-
    pose similar to that of the impossibility doctrine. But it is
    No. 08-2693                                                  5
    essential to an understanding of this case that a force
    majeure clause must always be interpreted in ac-
    cordance with its language and context, like any other
    provision in a written contract, rather than with
    reference to its name. It is not enough to say that the
    parties must have meant that performance would be
    excused if it would be “impossible” within the meaning
    that the word has been given in cases interpreting the
    common law doctrine. Perlman v. Pioneer Ltd. Partnership,
    
    918 F.2d 1244
    , 1248 n. 5 (5th Cir. 1990); PPG Industries,
    Inc. v. Shell Oil Co., 
    919 F.2d 17
    , 18-19 (5th Cir. 1990);
    Williams Cary Wright, “Force Majeure Delays,” 26 Con-
    struction Lawyer 33, 33 (2006); see also Gulf Oil Corp. v.
    FPC, 
    563 F.2d 588
    , 601-02 (3d Cir. 1977).
    The provision at issue in this case does not specify
    circumstances that would make performance impossible
    or infeasible in any sense, and does not excuse the per-
    forming party (the railroad) from performing the con-
    tract. The provision is part of Article XI of the contract, and
    some of the other provisions in the article do specify
    contingencies that would excuse performance, including
    certain “acts of God.” But the provision at issue merely
    provides that if the railroad is prevented by “an event of
    Force Majeure” from reloading its empty cars (after it has
    delivered coal to WEPCO) with iron ore destined for
    Geneva, Utah, it can charge the higher rate that the con-
    tract makes applicable to shipments that do not involve
    backhauling. Cf. 2 Farnsworth, supra, § 9.1, p. 585; 14 Corbin
    on Contracts § 74.19, p. 113 (Joseph M. Perillo ed. 2008). For
    example, the rate for coal shipped from one of the Colo-
    rado mines to WEPCO was specified as $13.20 per ton if
    6                                             No. 08-2693
    there was a backhaul shipment but $15.63 if there was not.
    The reason for the higher rate, obviously, was that if the
    railroad’s cars were empty on the trip back to Colorado,
    the railroad would obtain no revenue on that trip; it
    would be underutilizing the cars.
    The iron ore that the railroad’s freight train would
    have picked up in Minnesota on its way back was in-
    tended for a steel mill in Utah owned by the Geneva Steel
    company. (The mill had been built during World War II
    well inland because of fear that the Japanese might attack
    the West Coast.) The company was bankrupt when the
    parties signed the contract. It was still operating, but
    obviously might cease to do so; hence the provision. Why
    the parties used the term “force majeure,” rather than
    simply providing that the railroad could charge the
    higher rate if the steel company stopped buying iron
    ore, has not been explained. More careful drafting
    might have averted this lawsuit.
    In November 2001 the steel mill shut down, never to
    reopen. It was closed for good in February 2004. A couple
    of months after that final closing the railroad wrote
    WEPCO to declare “an event of Force Majeure” and that
    henceforth it would be charging WEPCO the higher rate
    applicable to shipments without a backhaul. It did not
    attempt to make the rate change retroactive. Had it in-
    voked the force majeure clause when the steel mill first
    shut down, WEPCO would have incurred an extra
    $7 million in shipping charges between then and the
    belated declaration of force majeure.
    Despite this windfall, WEPCO argues that the railroad
    broke the contract by invoking the force majeure clause
    No. 08-2693                                                 7
    when it did. The fact that the railroad didn’t invoke the
    clause earlier shows that the shutting down of the steel
    mill did not prevent the railroad from charging the low,
    backhaul rate. Well of course not; it is never “impossible”
    to offer a discount. But what the contract says is that the
    railroad may charge the higher rate if it is prevented from
    reloading its cars, rather than if it is prevented from
    charging a lower rate.
    WEPCO points out that Article XI requires prompt
    notification of an event of force majeure and also
    requires the invoker to make reasonable efforts to
    eliminate or abate the force majeure. It argues that the
    railroad violated its duty of prompt notice and by doing
    so waived its right to declare a force majeure. But
    another clause in the contract provides that a failure of a
    party to insist on a right that the contract confers on it
    shall not be deemed a waiver. That scotches WEPCO’s
    argument except insofar as it wishes to complain not
    about the declaration of force majeure as such but
    simply about the breach of the duty of prompt notice.
    A “no waiver” clause is appropriate in a complex multi-
    year contract that imposes (as we will see) duties of
    performance on both parties, as distinct from a simple
    sales contract in which one party performs and the
    other pays. If a party lost a contract right through
    waiver by failing to assert it as soon as it was violated, the
    process of amicable adjustment of contingencies bound
    to arise in the course of performing the contract would be
    impeded by premature assertion of legal claims. Monarch
    Coaches, Inc. v. ITT Industrial Credit, 
    818 F.2d 11
    , 13 (7th
    8                                                  No. 08-2693
    Cir. 1987); S & R Co. of Kingston v. Latona Trucking, Inc., 
    159 F.3d 80
    , 85-86 (2d Cir. 1998); S.H.V.C. v. Roy, 
    450 A.2d 351
    , 353 (Conn. 1982); Sean J. Young, “Reaping the
    Benefits of ‘Forbearance’ in Contract Through the
    Doctrine of Election,” 9 Florida Coastal Law Rev. 65, 85-89
    (2007) (“the waiver regime discourages forbearance
    because it gives the injured party a strong incentive to
    object, which necessarily rules out forbearance”); Jason
    Scott Johnston, “The Return of Bargain: An Economic
    Theory of How Standard-Form Contracts Enable Coopera-
    tive Negotiation Between Businesses and Consumers,” 
    104 Mich. L. Rev. 857
    , 891 (2006). When the parties were
    getting along and there was some possibility that Geneva
    Steel would not be liquidated, the railroad was dis-
    inclined to stand on its rights. But at about the same time
    that the steel mill closed irrevocably, WEPCO threatened
    the railroad with a lawsuit over alleged poor service.
    Since WEPCO was standing on its claimed rights, the
    railroad decided to stand on its own. We cannot see
    anything wrong in that. Cf. 2 Farnsworth, supra, § 8.19a,
    p. 543.
    It is true that while nonwaiver clauses are no longer
    unenforceable, e.g., Roboserve, Inc. v. Kato Kagaku Co.,
    Ltd., 
    78 F.3d 266
    , 277 (7th Cir. 1996); DeValk Lincoln Mer-
    cury, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co., 
    811 F.2d 326
    , 334 (7th Cir. 1987);
    Klipsch, Inc. v. WWR Technology, Inc., 
    127 F.3d 729
    , 735-
    36 (8th Cir. 1997), there is still some authority for
    treating them as themselves waivable. E.g., Exxon Corp. v.
    Crosby-Mississippi Resources, Ltd., 
    40 F.3d 1474
    , 1491-
    92 (5th Cir. 1995); Westinghouse Credit Corp. v. Shelton, 
    645 F.2d 869
     (10th Cir. 1981); but see DeValk Lincoln
    No. 08-2693                                                  9
    Mercury, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co., supra, 
    811 F.2d at 334
    . But
    if that notion were taken literally, no-waiver clauses
    would be worthless. Fortunately, it is not taken literally;
    the waiver of a no-waiver clause must be “proved by
    clear and convincing evidence,” Chicago College of Osteo-
    pathic Medicine v. George A. Fuller Co., 
    776 F.2d 198
    , 202 (7th
    Cir. 1985); see also Roboserve, Inc. v. Kato Kagaku Co., Ltd.,
    supra, 
    78 F.3d at 277-78
    , a condition not fulfilled here.
    Granted, the cases that we have cited are not Wisconsin
    cases; the only case that we can find from Wisconsin is
    an unpublished, nonprecedential intermediate appellate
    opinion, 121 Langdon Street Group v. Heiligman, 
    2005 WL 613493
     (Wis. App. Mar. 17, 2005), which, however,
    for what it is worth, rules that no-waiver clauses are en-
    forceable and does not suggest any limitations on their
    enforceability.
    A claim arising from breach of the prompt-notice
    clause might have merit were there doubt whether
    there really had been an event of force majeure. The
    argument would be that for want of receiving prompt
    notice WEPCO had lost an opportunity to investigate
    and discover that there was no such event. But
    WEPCO does not suggest that the steel mill may not
    really have shut down, for good as it later turned out, in
    November of 2001. It does argue that if notified promptly
    of the shut down it might have explored alternative ways
    of obtaining coal at a rate below the higher, no-backhaul
    rate. The contract required WEPCO to ship specified
    minimum tonnages of coal by the railroad, but it
    shipped more, and conceivably would have shipped
    10                                              No. 08-2693
    less—perhaps making up the difference from some other
    coal mine—had it been able to find a cheaper rate from
    some other railroad. But there is no evidence that such
    alternatives ever existed, or, more to the point, existed
    in 2001 but evaporated by 2004.
    Not only has WEPCO failed to show any detrimental
    reliance on the failure to receive prompt notice of the
    higher rate; it refuses, contrary to the most elementary
    principles of damages, to acknowledge that had it relied
    to its detriment any damages caused by that reliance
    would have to be reduced by $7 million. That is the cost
    WEPCO saved as a result of the railroad’s forbearance to
    invoke the force majeure clause at the earliest possible
    opportunity.
    WEPCO argues that the railroad made no reasonable
    effort to abate the force majeure, as the contract re-
    quired. The railroad did not explore the possibility of
    finding some other commodity, besides iron ore, to ship
    west. (It couldn’t be iron ore, because Geneva Steel was
    the only buyer of iron ore served by the railroad.) But that
    is not what the duty of abatement contemplated. The
    event of force majeure—the event that the railroad was
    required to exert reasonable efforts to abate—was an
    event that prevented the railroad from reloading its
    cars with iron ore for the trip back west.
    Had Geneva Steel owed the railroad some small amount
    of money and begged it to forbear to sue to collect
    because that would force the company into bankruptcy,
    forbearance to sue might conceivably be a reasonable
    effort to avoid the railroad’s having to send its trains
    No. 08-2693                                            11
    west without a backhaul, and therefore an effort that the
    railroad was obligated to undertake. But there is no
    suggestion of that. WEPCO’s argument, rather, is that
    the railroad should have looked for something else to
    carry back in its trains. But that would have placed on
    the railroad a burdensome open-ended duty to explore
    the possibility of reconfiguring its operations, which
    would have required searching for, finding, and making
    contracts with other shippers and perhaps purchasing or
    renting railcars optimized to carry those shippers’ com-
    modities. Disputes over the adequacy of the railroad’s
    efforts would present unmanageable issues for litigation.
    This cannot have been what the abatement clause en-
    visaged.
    The point about unmanageability goes far to resolve
    the other issue presented by the appeal. Article VI of the
    contract required WEPCO to notify the railroad monthly
    of how many tons of coal (within the maximum
    tonnage specified by the contract) it wanted shipped the
    next month, and “the parties agree to make good faith
    reasonable efforts to meet the Monthly Shipping Sched-
    ule.” Nowhere did the contract require the railroad to
    comply with the schedule; it merely had to make, in
    good faith, a reasonable effort to do so. Article VII did
    require the railroad to transport tonnages specified by
    WEPCO, but only if WEPCO supplied the railcars for
    the shipment, and it did not; the railroad did; during
    the period in which WEPCO charges that the railroad
    was acting in bad faith, the railroad transported in its
    own cars 84 percent of the total shipments of coal re-
    quested by WEPCO.
    12                                              No. 08-2693
    Not enough, argues WEPCO. Without specifying the
    minimum percentage that would have demonstrated
    good faith, it argues that it would have exceeded
    90 percent. It says that the railroad shipped less because
    it had other customers who paid higher rates. WEPCO
    invokes the legal duty of good faith in the performance
    of a contract. The duty entails the avoidance of conduct
    such as “evasion of the spirit of the bargain, lack of dili-
    gence and slacking off, willful rendering of imperfect
    performance, abuse of a power to specify terms, and
    interference with or failure to cooperate in the other
    party’s performance.” Foseid v. State Bank, 
    541 N.W.2d 203
    , 213 (Wis. App. 1995).
    But the duty of good faith does not require your
    putting one of your customers ahead of the others, even
    if the others are paying you more. “Parties are not pre-
    vented from protecting their respective economic inter-
    ests.” John Edward Murray, Jr., Murray on Contracts § 90,
    p. 501 (4th ed. 2001). As we explained, interpreting Wis-
    consin law in Market Street Associates Ltd. Partnership v.
    Frey, 
    941 F.2d 588
    , 594 (7th Cir. 1991), “even after you
    have signed a contract, you are not obliged to become
    an altruist toward the other party and relax the terms if
    he gets into trouble in performing his side of the bargain.”
    Another customer of the railroad might be paying a
    very high rate because it had an urgent need for ser-
    vice—so could it charge the railroad with bad faith if it
    had a contract similar to the railroad’s contract with
    WEPCO and the railroad told it, very sorry, but we
    cannot serve you; it is not that we love you less, but that
    No. 08-2693                                              13
    we love WEPCO more? “A duty of good faith does not
    mean that a party vested with a clear right is obligated
    to exercise that right to its own detriment for the
    purpose of benefiting another party to the contract.” Rio
    Algom Corp. v. Jimco Ltd., 
    618 P.2d 497
    , 505 (Utah 1980).
    And it certainly doesn’t mean exercising that right to the
    detriment of another party with which it has a contract.
    Again WEPCO invites the court to undertake an unman-
    ageable judicial task—that of working out an equitable
    allocation of Union Pacific’s railcars among its various
    customers. Cf. Exacto Spring Corp. v. Commissioner, 
    196 F.3d 833
    , 838 (7th Cir. 1999); Micro Data Base Systems, Inc.
    v. Nellcor Puritan Bennett, Inc., 
    165 F.3d 1154
    , 1156 (7th
    Cir. 1999).
    A FFIRMED.
    3-2-09