Jerry Jones v. Harris Associates ( 2008 )


Menu:
  •                               In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    ____________
    No. 07-1624
    JERRY N. JONES, M ARY F. JONES, and
    A RLINE W INERMAN,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    H ARRIS A SSOCIATES L.P.,
    Defendant-Appellee.
    ____________
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division.
    No. 04 C 8305—Charles P. Kocoras, Judge.
    ____________
    A RGUED S EPTEMBER 10, 2007—D ECIDED M AY 19, 2008
    ____________
    Before E ASTERBROOK , Chief Judge, and K ANNE and
    E VANS, Circuit Judges.
    E ASTERBROOK, Chief Judge. Harris Associates advises the
    Oakmark complex of mutual funds. These open-end
    funds (an open-end fund is one that buys back its shares
    at current asset value) have grown in recent years be-
    cause their net returns have exceeded the market average,
    and the investment adviser’s compensation has grown
    apace. Plaintiffs, who own shares in several of the
    Oakmark funds, contend that the fees are too high and
    thus violate §36(b) of the Investment Company Act of
    2                                                 No. 07-1624
    1940, 15 U.S.C. §80a–35(b), a provision added in 1970. The
    district court concluded that Harris Associates had not
    violated the Act and granted summary judgment in its
    favor. 2007 U.S. Dist. L EXIS 13352 (N.D. Ill. Feb. 27, 2007).
    Plaintiffs rely on several sections of the Act in addition
    to §36(b), and we can make short work of these. The Act
    requires at least 40% of a mutual fund’s trustees to be
    disinterested in the adviser, see 15 U.S.C. §80a–10(a), and
    obliges the fund to reveal the financial links between
    its trustees and the adviser, see 15 U.S.C. §80a–33(b).
    Compensation for the adviser is controlled by a majority
    of the disinterested trustees. 15 U.S.C. §80a–15(c). Plaintiffs
    say that the Oakmark funds have violated all of these
    rules. Because none of the funds is a party to this suit, an
    order directing the funds to comply is not available as
    relief. Plaintiffs say that the court could require Harris to
    return the compensation it has received, but such a
    penalty would be disproportionate to the wrong. That’s
    not the only problem: although §36(b) creates a private
    right of action, the other sections we have mentioned
    do not. We need not decide whether a private right of
    action should be implied, see Alexander v. Sandoval, 
    532 U.S. 275
    (2001), or whether a sensible remedy could be
    devised, as there has been no violation of §10(a) or §15(c).
    Victor Morgenstern is among the funds’ trustees. Until
    the end of 2000, when he retired, Morgenstern was
    a partner of Harris Associates and counted among
    the funds’ “interested” trustees. Since his retirement,
    Morgenstern has been treated as a disinterested trustee and
    has voted at the special meetings that deal with the ad-
    viser’s compensation. Plaintiffs insist that Morgenstern
    does not meet the statutory standards because Harris
    Associates bought out his partnership with a stream
    No. 07-1624                                               3
    of payments that can be deferred if Harris does not
    satisfy performance benchmarks in a given year. This
    makes the payments a form of profit sharing, plaintiffs
    contend, and because profit-sharing agreements are
    treated as “securities” under 15 U.S.C. §80a–2(a)(36),
    Morgenstern owns securities in Harris Associates and
    is not disinterested. 15 U.S.C. §80a–2(a)(19)(B)(iii). More-
    over, plaintiffs continue, the Oakmark funds did not
    disclose these facts to the public and so are out of com-
    pliance with 15 U.S.C. §80a–33(b).
    Harris Associates contends that payments fixed in
    amount are not “profit sharing” in the statutory sense
    just because the time of payment is uncertain. Let us
    assume (again without deciding) that Morgenstern held
    a “security” under the Act because he was exposed to the
    risk of business reverses at his old firm. Failure to dis-
    close Morgenstern’s post-retirement payments from
    Harris Associates might support an order directing the
    funds to correct their annual reports and other official
    disclosure documents but would not justify any relief
    against Harris Associates. To get anywhere, even with
    a private right of action, plaintiffs would have to show
    the sort of violation that knocks out any valid contract
    between Harris Associates and the funds. Only a viola-
    tion of the 40%-independence rule or the approval-by-a-
    majority-of-disinterested-trustees rule could do that. Yet
    most of the funds’ trustees are disinterested even if
    Morgenstern is treated as interested.
    During the time covered by the suit, the funds had
    nine or ten trustees, at least seven of whom are independ-
    ent even if we count Morgenstern as interested. That’s
    comfortably over the statutory requirement that 40% of
    trustees be disinterested. And as the disinterested trustees
    4                                              No. 07-1624
    unanimously approved the contracts with Harris Associ-
    ates, it makes no difference how Morgenstern is classi-
    fied. Plaintiffs ask us to suppose that Morgenstern pos-
    sessed some Svengali-like sway over the other trustees, so
    that his presence in the room was enough to spoil their
    decisions. But in 2000 and before, when Morgenstern
    had been treated as interested, the disinterested trustees
    met in his absence and approved Harris’s compensation.
    More: although the disinterested directors initially meet
    separately, the whole board ultimately discusses and
    votes on the contract. 15 U.S.C. §80a–15(a)(2). Interested
    directors are not silenced. So it is impossible to see
    how Morgenstern’s role from 2001 through 2004 can be
    treated as poisoning the deliberations.
    Now for the main event: plaintiffs’ contention that the
    adviser’s fees are excessive. They rely on §36(b), which
    provides:
    For the purposes of this subsection, the investment
    adviser of a registered investment company shall
    be deemed to have a fiduciary duty with respect
    to the receipt of compensation for services, or of
    payments of a material nature, paid by such regis-
    tered investment company, or by the security
    holders thereof, to such investment adviser or any
    affiliated person of such investment adviser. An
    action may be brought under this subsection by
    the Commission, or by a security holder of such
    registered investment company on behalf of such
    company, against such investment adviser . . . .
    With respect to any such action the following
    provisions shall apply:
    (1) It shall not be necessary to allege or
    prove that any defendant engaged in per-
    No. 07-1624                                                5
    sonal misconduct, and the plaintiff shall
    have the burden of proving a breach of
    fiduciary duty.
    (2) In any such action approval by the
    board of directors of such investment
    company of such compensation or pay-
    ments, or of contracts or other arrange-
    ments providing for such compensation or
    payments, and ratification or approval of
    such compensation or payments, or of
    contracts or other arrangements providing
    for such compensation or payments, by
    the shareholders of such investment com-
    pany, shall be given such consideration by
    the court as is deemed appropriate under
    all the circumstances. . . .
    The district court followed Gartenberg v. Merrill Lynch Asset
    Management, Inc., 
    694 F.2d 923
    (2d Cir. 1982), and con-
    cluded that Harris Associates must prevail because its
    fees are ordinary. Gartenberg articulated two variations on
    a theme:
    [T]he test is essentially whether the fee schedule
    represents a charge within the range of what
    would have been negotiated at arm’s-length in the
    light of all of the surrounding 
    circumstances. 694 F.2d at 928
    . And
    [t]o be guilty of a violation of §36(b) . . . the
    adviser-manager must charge a fee that is so
    disproportionately large that it bears no reasonable
    relationship to the services rendered and could
    not have been the product of arm’s-length bar-
    gaining.
    6                                                No. 07-1624
    
    Ibid. Oakmark Fund paid
    Harris Associates 1% (per year)
    of the first $2 billion of the fund’s assets, 0.9% of the next
    $1 billion, 0.8% of the next $2 billion, and 0.75% of any-
    thing over $5 billion. The district court’s opinion sets out
    the fees for the other funds; they are similar. It is undis-
    puted that these fees are roughly the same (in both level
    and breakpoints) as those that other funds of similar
    size and investment goals pay their advisers, and that
    the fee structure is lawful under the Investment Advisers
    Act. See 15 U.S.C. §80b–5. The Oakmark funds have
    grown more than the norm for comparable pools, which
    implies that Harris Associates has delivered value for
    money.
    Plaintiffs contend that we should not follow Gartenberg,
    for two principal reasons: first, that the second circuit
    relies too much on market prices as the benchmark of
    reasonable fees, which plaintiffs insist is inappropriate
    because fees are set incestuously rather than by competi-
    tion; second, that if any market should be used as the
    benchmark, it is the market for advisory services to unaffil-
    iated institutional clients. The first argument stems from
    the fact that investment advisers create mutual funds,
    which they dominate notwithstanding the statutory
    requirement that 40% of trustees be disinterested. Few
    mutual funds ever change advisers, and plaintiffs con-
    clude from this that the market for advisers is not competi-
    tive. The second argument rests on the fact that Harris
    Associates, like many other investment advisers, has
    institutional clients (such as pension funds) that pay
    less. For a client with investment goals similar to
    Oakmark Fund, Harris Associates charges 0.75% of the
    first $15 million under management and 0.35% of the
    amount over $500 million, with intermediate break-
    No. 07-1624                                               7
    points. Plaintiffs maintain that a fiduciary may charge its
    controlled clients no more than its independent clients.
    Like the plaintiffs, the second circuit in Gartenberg
    expressed some skepticism of competition’s power to
    constrain investment advisers’ fees.
    Competition between [mutual] funds for share-
    holder business does not support an inference that
    competition must therefore also exist between
    adviser-managers for fund business. The former
    may be vigorous even though the latter is virtually
    non-existent. Each is governed by different 
    forces. 694 F.2d at 929
    . The second circuit did not explain why this
    is so, however. It was content to rely on the observation
    that mutual funds rarely advertise the level of their man-
    agement fees, as distinct from the funds’ total expenses
    as a percentage of assets (a widely publicized benchmark).
    Holding costs down is vital in competition, when inves-
    tors are seeking maximum return net of expenses—and as
    management fees are a substantial component of adminis-
    trative costs, mutual funds have a powerful reason to
    keep them low unless higher fees are associated with
    higher return on investment. A difference of 0.1% per
    annum in total administrative expenses adds up by
    compounding over time and is enough to induce many
    investors to change mutual funds. That mutual funds
    are “captives” of investment advisers does not curtail
    this competition. An adviser can’t make money from
    its captive fund if high fees drive investors away.
    So just as plaintiffs are skeptical of Gartenberg because
    it relies too heavily on markets, we are skeptical about
    Gartenberg because it relies too little on markets. And this
    is not the first time we have suggested that Gartenberg
    8                                                No. 07-1624
    is wanting. See Green v. Nuveen Advisory Corp., 
    295 F.3d 738
    , 743 n.8 (7th Cir. 2002). Two courts of appeals (in
    addition to the second circuit) have addressed claims
    against the advisers of open-end mutual funds. One circuit
    has followed Gartenberg. See Midgal v. Rowe Price–Fleming
    International, Inc., 
    248 F.3d 321
    (4th Cir. 2001). The other
    has concluded that adherence to the statutory proce-
    dures, rather than the level of price, is the right way to
    understand the “fiduciary” obligation created by §36(b).
    See Green v. Fund Asset Management, L.P., 
    286 F.3d 682
    (3d Cir. 2002). Our own Green opinion, though it dealt
    with the obligations of advisers to closed-end funds,
    indicated sympathy for the third circuit’s position.
    Having had another chance to study this question, we
    now disapprove the Gartenberg approach. A fiduciary
    duty differs from rate regulation. A fiduciary must
    make full disclosure and play no tricks but is not subject
    to a cap on compensation. The trustees (and in the end
    investors, who vote with their feet and dollars), rather
    than a judge or jury, determine how much advisory
    services are worth.
    Section 36(b) does not say that fees must be “reasonable”
    in relation to a judicially created standard. It says
    instead that the adviser has a fiduciary duty. That is a
    familiar word; to use it is to summon up the law of trusts.
    Cf. Firestone Tire & Rubber Co. v. Bruch, 
    489 U.S. 101
    (1989).
    And the rule in trust law is straightforward: A trustee
    owes an obligation of candor in negotiation, and honesty
    in performance, but may negotiate in his own interest
    and accept what the settlor or governance institution
    agrees to pay. Restatement (Second) of Trusts §242 & com-
    ment f. When the trust instrument is silent about com-
    pensation, the trustee may petition a court for an
    No. 07-1624                                               9
    award, and then the court will ask what is “reasonable”;
    but when the settlor or the persons charged with the
    trust’s administration make a decision, it is conclusive.
    John H. Langbein, The Contractarian Basis of the Law of
    Trusts, 105 Yale L. J. 625 (1995). It is possible to imagine
    compensation so unusual that a court will infer that
    deceit must have occurred, or that the persons respon-
    sible for decision have abdicated—for example, if a uni-
    versity’s board of trustees decides to pay the president
    $50 million a year, when no other president of a com-
    parable institution receives more than $2 million—but
    no court would inquire whether a salary normal among
    similar institutions is excessive.
    Things work the same way for business corporations,
    which though not trusts are managed by persons who
    owe fiduciary duties of loyalty to investors. This does not
    prevent them from demanding substantial compensa-
    tion and bargaining hard to get it. Publicly traded corpora-
    tions use the same basic procedures as mutual funds: a
    committee of independent directors sets the top managers’
    compensation. No court has held that this procedure
    implies judicial review for “reasonableness” of the re-
    sulting salary, bonus, and stock options. These are con-
    strained by competition in several markets—firms that
    pay too much to managers have trouble raising money,
    because net profits available for distribution to investors
    are lower, and these firms also suffer in product markets
    because they must charge more and consumers turn
    elsewhere. Competitive processes are imperfect but
    remain superior to a “just price” system administered by
    the judiciary. However weak competition may be at
    weeding out errors, the judicial process is worse—for
    judges can’t be turned out of office or have their
    salaries cut if they display poor business judgment.
    10                                                No. 07-1624
    Lawyers have fiduciary duties to their clients but are
    free to negotiate for high hourly wages or compensation
    from any judgment. Rates over $500 an hour and con-
    tingent fees exceeding a third of any recovery are
    common. The existence of the fiduciary duty does not
    imply judicial review for reasonableness; the question a
    court will ask, if the fee is contested, is whether the
    client made a voluntary choice ex ante with the benefit
    of adequate information. Competition rather than litiga-
    tion determines the fee—and, when judges must set fees,
    they try to follow the market rather than demand that
    attorneys’ compensation conform to the judges’ prefer-
    ences. See, e.g., In re Synthroid Marketing Litigation, 
    325 F.3d 974
    (7th Cir. 2003); In re Continental Illinois Securities
    Litigation, 
    962 F.2d 566
    (7th Cir. 1992). A lawyer cannot
    deceive his client or take strategic advantage of the de-
    pendence that develops once representation begins, but
    hard bargaining and seemingly steep rates are lawful.
    The list could be extended, but the point has been
    made. Judicial price-setting does not accompany fiduciary
    duties. Section 36(b) does not call for a departure from
    this norm. Plaintiffs ask us to look beyond the statute’s
    text to its legislative history, but that history, which
    Gartenberg explores, is like many legislative histories in
    containing expressions that seem to support every pos-
    sible position. Some members of Congress equated fidu-
    ciary duty with review for reasonableness; others did not
    (language that would have authorized review of rates
    for reasonableness was voted down); the Senate com-
    mittee report disclaimed any link between fiduciary duty
    and reasonableness of fees. 
    See 694 F.2d at 928
    .
    Statements made during the debates between 1968
    and 1970 rest on beliefs about the structure of the mutual-
    No. 07-1624                                                 11
    fund market at the time, and plaintiffs say that because
    many members of Congress deemed competition inade-
    quate (and regulation essential) in 1970, we must act as if
    competition remains weak today. Why? Congress did not
    enact its members’ beliefs; it enacted a text. A text authoriz-
    ing the SEC or the judiciary to set rates would be
    binding no matter how market conditions change. Section
    36(b) does not create a rate-regulation mechanism, and
    plaintiffs’ proposal to create such a mechanism in 2008
    cannot be justified by suppositions about the market
    conditions of 1970. A lot has happened in the last 38 years.
    Today thousands of mutual funds compete. The pages
    of the Wall Street Journal teem with listings. People can
    search for and trade funds over the Internet, with negligi-
    ble transactions costs. “At the end of World War II,
    there were 73 mutual funds registered with the Securities
    and Exchange Commission holding $1.2 billion in assets.
    By the end of 2002, over 8,000 mutual funds held more
    than $6 trillion in assets.” Paul G. Mahoney, Manager-
    Investor Conflicts in Mutual Funds, 18 J. Econ. Perspectives
    162, 162 (Spring 2004). Some mutual funds, such as
    those that track market indexes, do not have investment
    advisers and thus avoid all advisory fees. (Total expenses
    of the Vanguard 500 Index Fund, for example, are under
    0.10% of assets; the same figure for the Oakmark Fund
    in 2007 was 1.01%.) Mutual funds rarely fire their invest-
    ment advisers, but investors can and do “fire” advisers
    cheaply and easily by moving their money elsewhere.
    Investors do this not when the advisers’ fees are “too
    high” in the abstract, but when they are excessive in
    relation to the results—and what is “excessive” depends
    on the results available from other investment vehicles,
    rather than any absolute level of compensation.
    12                                               No. 07-1624
    New entry is common, and funds can attract money
    only by offering a combination of service and manage-
    ment that investors value, at a price they are willing to
    pay. Mutual funds come much closer to the model of
    atomistic competition than do most other markets. Judges
    would not dream of regulating the price of automobiles,
    which are produced by roughly a dozen large firms;
    why then should 8,000 mutual funds seem “too few” to
    put competitive pressure on advisory fees? A recent,
    careful study concludes that thousands of mutual funds
    are plenty, that investors can and do protect their interests
    by shopping, and that regulating advisory fees through
    litigation is unlikely to do more good than harm. See
    John C. Coates & R. Glenn Hubbard, Competition in the
    Mutual Fund Industry: Evidence and Implications for Policy,
    33 Iowa J. Corp. L. 151 (2007).
    It won’t do to reply that most investors are unsophisti-
    cated and don’t compare prices. The sophisticated inves-
    tors who do shop create a competitive pressure that
    protects the rest. See Alan Schwartz & Louis Wilde,
    Imperfect Information in Markets for Contract Terms, 
    69 Va. L
    .
    Rev. 1387 (1983). As it happens, the most substantial and
    sophisticated investors choose to pay substantially
    more for investment advice than advisers subject to §36(b)
    receive. A fund that allows only “accredited investors” (i.e.,
    the wealthy) to own non-redeemable shares is exempt
    from the Investment Company Act. See 15 U.S.C.
    §80a–6(a)(5)(A)(iii). Investment pools that take advan-
    tage of this exemption, commonly called hedge funds,
    regularly pay their advisers more than 1% of the pool’s
    asset value, plus a substantial portion of any gains from
    successful strategies. See René M. Stulz, Hedge Funds: Past,
    Present, and Future, 21 J. Econ. Perspectives 175 (Spring
    No. 07-1624                                              13
    2007). See also Joseph Golec & Laura Starks, Performance fee
    contract change and mutual fund risk, 73 J. Fin. Econ. 93
    (2004). When persons who have the most to invest, and
    who act through professional advisers, place their assets
    in pools whose managers receive more than Harris Associ-
    ates, it is hard to conclude that Harris’s fees must be
    excessive.
    Harris Associates charges a lower percentage of assets to
    other clients, but this does not imply that it must be
    charging too much to the Oakmark funds. Different
    clients call for different commitments of time. Pension
    funds have low (and predictable) turnover of assets.
    Mutual funds may grow or shrink quickly and must
    hold some assets in high-liquidity instruments to facilitate
    redemptions. That complicates an adviser’s task. Joint
    costs likewise make it hard to draw inferences from fee
    levels. Some tasks in research, valuation, and portfolio
    design will have benefits for several clients. In competi-
    tion those joint costs are apportioned among paying
    customers according to their elasticity of demand, not
    according to any rule of equal treatment.
    Federal securities laws, of which the Investment Com-
    pany Act is one component, work largely by re-
    quiring disclosure and then allowing price to be set by
    competition in which investors make their own choices.
    Plaintiffs do not contend that Harris Associates pulled
    the wool over the eyes of the disinterested trustees or
    otherwise hindered their ability to negotiate a favorable
    price for advisory services. The fees are not hidden from
    investors—and the Oakmark funds’ net return has at-
    tracted new investment rather than driving investors
    away. As §36(b) does not make the federal judiciary a
    rate regulator, after the fashion of the Federal Energy
    14                                       No. 07-1624
    Regulatory Commission, the judgment of the district
    court is affirmed.
    USCA-02-C-0072—5-19-08