Richard Hershey v. Pacific Investment Management ( 2009 )


Menu:
  •                               In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    No. 08-1075
    JOSEF A. K OHEN , et al., on their own behalf
    and that of all others similarly situated,
    Plaintiffs-Appellees,
    v.
    P ACIFIC INVESTMENT M ANAGEMENT C OMPANY LLC
    and PIMCO F UNDS,
    Defendants-Appellants.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division.
    No. 05 C 4681—Ronald A. Guzmán, Judge.
    A RGUED A PRIL 1, 2009—D ECIDED JULY 7, 2009
    Before P OSNER, E VANS, and T INDER, Circuit Judges.
    P OSNER, Circuit Judge. The defendants in this class
    action suit have appealed from the district court’s certi-
    fication of a plaintiff class. Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(f). The
    suit, based on section 22(a) of the Commodity Exchange
    Act, 
    7 U.S.C. § 25
    (a), accuses the defendants, collectively
    “PIMCO,” of having violated section 9(a) of the Act, 
    7 U.S.C. § 13
    (a), by cornering a futures market. A corner is
    2                                               No. 08-1075
    a form of monopolization. See United States v. Patten,
    
    226 U.S. 525
    , 539-42 (1913); Great Western Food Distributors,
    Inc. v. Brannan, 
    201 F.2d 476
    , 478-79 (7th Cir. 1953); Peto
    v. Howell, 
    101 F.2d 353
    , 358-59 (7th Cir. 1939); Robert W.
    Kolb & James A. Overdahl, Understanding Futures Markets
    80 (6th ed. 2006) (“a successful effort by a trader or
    group of traders to influence the price of a futures con-
    tract by intentionally acquiring market power in the
    deliverable supply of the underlying good while simulta-
    neously acquiring a large long futures position”).
    The class consists of persons who between May 9 and
    June 30, 2005, bought a futures contract on the Chicago
    Board of Trade in 10-year U.S. Treasury notes. Earlier
    they had sold such notes short, and the purchases they
    made between May 9 and June 30 were pursuant to
    contracts they had with other investors, including PIMCO,
    to deliver to a commodity clearinghouse, for those inves-
    tors’ accounts, on June 30, a specified quantity of the
    notes at the price specified in the futures contracts. With
    rare exceptions, however, futures speculations are com-
    pleted not by delivery of the underlying commodity (such
    as milk, or pork bellies, or in this case Treasury notes) to
    the clearinghouse, though that is an option, but by the
    making of offsetting futures contracts, as described in Kolb
    & Overdahl, supra, at 17; Mark J. Powers & Mark G.
    Castelino, Inside the Financial Futures Markets 20 (3d ed.
    1991); Jeffrey Williams, The Economic Function of Futures
    Markets 9-10 (1989); James M. Falvey & Andrew N. Kleit,
    “Commodity Exchanges and Antitrust,” 4 Berkeley Bus. L.
    J. 123, 127-28 (2007); see also C.B. Reehl, The Mathematics
    of Options Trading 15 (2005). The following table
    illustrates the process.
    No. 08-1075                                                               3
    Futures Contracting
    D ay   Price      Trade         SS’s position         B’s position
    1    $1,000   SS sells      SS deposits          B deposits $100
    contract      $100 (10% of         in his account;
    (to de-       the value of the     acquires the right
    liver pork    contract) in his     to require deliv-
    bellies) to   account with         ery of pork bel-
    B.            clearinghouse        lies from clear-
    (required mar-       inghouse.
    gin); acquires
    the obligation
    to deliver pork
    bellies to clear-
    inghouse.
    2    $1,500   None          SS’s account         B’s account in-
    falls to –$400,      creases to $600; B
    so SS must de-       still has the right
    posit $500 in his    to require deliv-
    account to           ery of pork bel-
    maintain his         lies from the
    10% margin; SS       clearinghouse.
    is still obligated
    to deliver pork
    bellies to the
    clearinghouse.
    3    $1,500   SS caps       SS’s trade ex-       B’s trade extin-
    his losses    tinguishes his       guishes his origi-
    and buys      original con-        nal contract: his
    contract      tract: his obliga-   right to require
    (to de-       tion to deliver      delivery from the
    liver pork    to the clearing-     clearinghouse is
    bellies)      house is offset      offset by his obli-
    from B.       by his right to      gation to deliver
    require delivery     to the clearing-
    from the clear-      house.
    inghouse.
    4                                                No. 08-1075
    In the example in the table, a short seller, SS, sells a
    specified quantity of pork bellies to B (buyer) at a price of
    $1,000 for delivery in June (hence a “June Contract”).
    SS hopes the price will fall by then. But before the delivery
    date arrives the price rises to $1,500, and SS decides to
    cap his losses. The simplest way to do this, as in the
    table, is for SS to buy from B the same quantity of pork
    bellies as SS had sold to B, paying $1,500. SS now has
    offsetting contracts to sell and to buy the same number
    of pork bellies, and B now has offsetting contracts to buy
    and sell the same number of pork bellies, so neither has
    a delivery obligation. Neither wants to have such an
    obligation, because both are speculators rather than
    farmers or meat packers. (Notice in the table that losses
    and gains are debited and credited to the traders’ accounts
    with the clearinghouse every day, to minimize the risk
    of loss to the clearinghouse, which guarantees the ful-
    fillment of the futures contract. But this detail plays no
    role in this case.)
    Changes in the demand for or the supply of the underly-
    ing commodity will make the price of a futures contract
    change over the period in which the contract is in force.
    If the price rises, the “long” (the buyer) benefits, as in our
    example, and if it falls the “short” (the seller) benefits.
    But a buyer may be able to force up the price by “corner-
    ing” the market—in this case by buying so many June
    contracts for 10-year Treasury notes that sellers can fulfill
    their contractual obligations only by dealing with that
    buyer. United States v. Patten, 
    supra,
     
    226 U.S. at 539-41
    ;
    Zimmerman v. Chicago Board of Trade, 
    360 F.3d 612
    , 616
    (7th Cir. 2004); Board of Trade v. SEC, 
    187 F.3d 713
    , 724
    (7th Cir. 1999) (“a person who owns a substantial portion
    No. 08-1075                                                 5
    of the long interest near the contract’s expiration date
    also obtains control over the supply that the shorts need
    to meet their obligations. Then the long demands
    delivery, and the price of the commodity skyrockets. It
    takes time and money to bring additional supplies to
    the delivery point, and the long can exploit these costs to
    force the shorts to pay through the nose”); Roberta
    Romano, “A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities
    and Their Regulation,” 
    55 Md. L. Rev. 1
    , 29-30
    (1996); “United States Commodity Futures Trading Com-
    mission Glossary,” www.cftc.gov/educationcenter/
    glossary/glossary_co.html (visited June 10, 2009).
    Board of Trade v. SEC, supra, 
    187 F.3d at 725
    , remarks that
    since the possibility of manipulation “comes from the
    potential imbalance between the deliverable supply and
    investors’ contract rights near the expiration date[,] . . .
    [f]inancial futures contracts, which are settled in cash,
    have no ‘deliverable supply’; there can never be a mis-
    match between demand and supply near the expiration,
    or at any other time.” But while it is correct that most
    financial futures contracts are settled in cash, CFTC v.
    Zelener, 
    373 F.3d 861
    , 865 (7th Cir. 2004); Kolb, supra, at
    16, and that if a cash option exists there is no market to
    corner (no one can corner the U.S. money supply!), futures
    contracts traded on the Chicago Board of Trade for ten-
    year U.S. Treasury notes are an exception; they are not
    “cash settled.” Short sellers who make delivery must do
    so with approved U.S. Treasury notes; otherwise they
    must execute offsetting futures contracts. Chicago Board
    of Trade Rulebook, “Chapter 19: Long-Term U.S. Treasury
    Note Futures (6 ½ to 10-Year),” www.cmegroup.com/
    rulebook/CBOT/V/19/19.pdf (visited June 22, 2009); CME
    6                                               No. 08-1075
    Group, “U.S. Treasury Futures Delivery Process,” (4th ed.
    2008), www.cmegroup.com/trading/interest-rates/files/
    CL-100_TFDPBrochureFINAL.pdf (visited June 22, 2009).
    The note approved for delivery in this case was the
    “2/12 Treasury Note” (a Treasury note that expires in
    February 2012). The plaintiffs claim that PIMCO increased
    the percentage of these notes that it owned from 12 to
    42 percent over a two-week span, with the result that they
    would have had to pay a monopoly price to get enough
    notes to close out their contracts. So instead they made
    offsetting futures contracts, and they claim that as a result
    they lost more than $600 million, the amount they would
    have saved had they been able to buy offsetting contracts
    at a competitive price. (These are just allegations; we do
    not vouch for their correctness.)
    The class certified by the district court consists, as we
    said, of all persons who between May 9 and June 30, 2005,
    bought a June Contract in order to close out a short posi-
    tion. PIMCO challenges the definition on the ground
    that it includes persons who lack “standing” to sue
    because they did not lose money in their speculation on
    the June Contract. For example, some of the class
    members might have taken both short and long positions
    (in order to hedge—that is, to limit their potential losses)
    and made more money in the long positions by virtue
    of PIMCO’s alleged cornering of the market than they
    lost in their short positions. The plaintiffs acknowledge
    this possibility but argue that its significance is best
    determined at the damages stage of the litigation. If
    PIMCO is found to have cornered the market in the
    June Contract, then each member of the class will have
    to submit a claim for the damages it sustained as a result
    No. 08-1075                                                   7
    of the corner. Carnegie v. Household Int’l, 
    376 F.3d 656
    , 661
    (7th Cir. 2004); 7AA Charles Alan Wright, Arthur R. Miller
    & Mary Kay Kane, Federal Practice & Procedure § 1784
    (2009). Some of the class members, discovering that they
    were not injured at all, will not submit a claim, and others
    will submit a claim that will be rejected because the
    claimant cannot prove damages, having obtained off-
    setting profits from going long.
    PIMCO argues that before certifying a class the district
    judge was required to determine which class members
    had suffered damages. But putting the cart before the
    horse in that way would vitiate the economies of class
    action procedure; in effect the trial would precede the
    certification. It is true that injury is a prerequisite to
    standing. But as long as one member of a certified class
    has a plausible claim to have suffered damages, the
    requirement of standing is satisfied. United States Parole
    Commission v. Geraghty, 
    445 U.S. 388
    , 404 (1980); Wiesmueller
    v. Kosobucki, 
    513 F.3d 784
    , 785-86 (7th Cir. 2008). This is true
    even if the named plaintiff (the class representative) lacks
    standing, provided that he can be replaced by a
    class member who has standing. “The named plaintiff
    who no longer has a stake may not be a suitable class
    representative, but that is not a matter of jurisdiction and
    would not disqualify him from continuing as class repre-
    sentative until a more suitable member of the class was
    found to replace him.” 
    Id. at 786
    .
    Before a class is certified, it is true, the named plaintiff
    must have standing, because at that stage no one else
    has a legally protected interest in maintaining the suit. Id.;
    8                                                No. 08-1075
    Sosna v. Iowa, 
    419 U.S. 393
    , 402 (1975); Walters v. Edgar, 
    163 F.3d 430
    , 432-33 (7th Cir. 1998); Murray v. Auslander, 
    244 F.3d 807
    , 810 (11th Cir. 2001). And while ordinarily an
    unchallenged allegation of standing suffices, a colorable
    challenge requires the plaintiff to meet it rather than
    stand mute. Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife, 
    504 U.S. 555
    , 561
    (1992). PIMCO tried to show in the district court that
    two of the named plaintiffs could not have been injured by
    the alleged corner. We need not decide whether it suc-
    ceeded in doing so, because even if it did, that left one
    named plaintiff with standing, and one is all that is neces-
    sary.
    If the case goes to trial, this plaintiff may fail to prove
    injury. But when a plaintiff loses a case because he
    cannot prove injury the suit is not dismissed for lack of
    jurisdiction. Jurisdiction established at the pleading stage
    by a claim of injury that is not successfully challenged
    at that stage is not lost when at trial the plaintiff fails to
    substantiate the allegation of injury; instead the suit is
    dismissed on the merits. American Civil Liberties Union v.
    St. Charles, 
    794 F.2d 265
    , 269 (7th Cir. 1986). Pressed at
    argument, PIMCO’s counsel retreated, conceded or at
    least seemed to concede that the issue was not jurisdic-
    tional, and clarified that his argument was only that the
    class members lacked “statutory standing.” Then he
    took back his concession, arguing that if any class member
    were found not to have sustained damages, the court
    would have no jurisdiction over that class member, who
    would therefore not be bound by any judgment or settle-
    ment and so could bring his own suit for damages.
    That is to say that if a plaintiff loses his case, this shows
    that he had no standing to sue and therefore can start
    No. 08-1075                                                   9
    over. That would be an absurd result, and PIMCO need
    not fear it. Id.; Bruggeman v. Blagojevich, 
    324 F.3d 906
    , 909
    (7th Cir. 2003).
    The term “statutory standing” is found in many cases,
    e.g., Ortiz v. Fibreboard Corp., 
    527 U.S. 815
    , 830 (1999); Steel
    Co. v. Citizens for a Better Environment, 
    523 U.S. 83
    , 96-97
    and n. 2 (1998); United States v. U.S. Currency, in Amount
    of $103,387.27, 
    863 F.2d 555
    , 560-61 and n. 10 (7th Cir. 1988),
    but it is a confusing usage. It usually refers to a situation in
    which, although the plaintiff has been injured and would
    benefit from a favorable judgment and so has standing in
    the Article III sense, he is suing under a statute that was
    not intended to give him a right to sue; he is not within the
    class intended to be protected by it. Steel Co. v. Citizens for
    a Better Environment, 
    supra,
     
    523 U.S. at 97
    ; Warth v. Seldin,
    
    422 U.S. 490
    , 500 (1975); Harzewski v. Guidant Corp., 
    489 F.3d 799
    , 803-04 (7th Cir. 2007). This is not such a case.
    What is true is that a class will often include persons who
    have not been injured by the defendant’s conduct; indeed
    this is almost inevitable because at the outset of the case
    many of the members of the class may be unknown, or if
    they are known still the facts bearing on their claims may
    be unknown. Such a possibility or indeed inevitability does
    not preclude class certification, Carnegie v. Household Int’l,
    supra, 
    376 F.3d at 661
    ; 1 Alba Conte & Herbert Newberg,
    Newberg on Class Actions § 2:4, pp. 73-75 (4th ed. 2002),
    despite statements in some cases that it must be reasonably
    clear at the outset that all class members were injured by
    the defendant’s conduct. Adashunas v. Negley, 
    626 F.2d 600
    ,
    604 (7th Cir. 1980); Denney v. Deutsche Bank AG, 
    443 F.3d 253
    , 264 (2d Cir. 2006). Those cases focus on the class
    10                                                No. 08-1075
    definition; if the definition is so broad that it sweeps within
    it persons who could not have been injured by the defen-
    dant’s conduct, it is too broad.
    A related point is that a class should not be certified if
    it is apparent that it contains a great many persons who
    have suffered no injury at the hands of the defendant,
    see Oshana v. Coca-Cola Co., 
    472 F.3d 506
    , 514-15 (7th Cir.
    2006); Romberio v. Unumprovident Corp., 
    2009 WL 87510
    , at
    *8 (6th Cir. Jan. 12, 2009); cf. Brown v. American Honda, 
    522 F.3d 6
    , 28-29 (1st Cir. 2008), if only because of the in
    terrorem character of a class action. In re Bridgestone/
    Firestone Tires Products Liability Litigation, 
    288 F.3d 1012
    ,
    1015-16 (7th Cir. 2002); Parker v. Time Warner Entertainment
    Co., L.P., 
    331 F.3d 13
    , 22 (2d Cir. 2003); EP Medsystems, Inc.
    v. EchoCath, Inc., 
    235 F.3d 865
    , 881 (3d Cir. 2000). When
    the potential liability created by a lawsuit is very great,
    even though the probability that the plaintiff will succeed
    in establishing liability is slight, the defendant will be
    under pressure to settle rather than to bet the company,
    even if the betting odds are good. Blair v. Equifax Check
    Services, 
    181 F.3d 832
    , 834 (7th Cir. 1999); In re Rhone-
    Poulenc Rorer Inc., 
    51 F.3d 1293
    , 1297-1300 (7th Cir. 1995).
    For by aggregating a large number of claims, a class action
    can impose a huge contingent liability on a defendant.
    PIMCO is a very large firm, however, with assets under
    management of more than $750 billion, www.pimco.com/
    LeftNav/PressCenter/PIMCOFacts.htm (visited June 10,
    2009). This suit does not jeopardize its existence. But it
    has good reason not to want to be hit with a multi-
    hundred-million-dollar claim that will embroil it in
    protracted and costly litigation—the class has more than
    a thousand members, and determining the value of
    No. 08-1075                                                11
    their claims, were liability established, might thus
    require more than a thousand separate hearings.
    So if the class definition clearly were overbroad, this
    would be a compelling reason to require that it be nar-
    rowed. Adashunas v. Negley, 
    supra,
     
    626 F.2d at 603-04
    ;
    Robidoux v. Celani, 
    987 F.2d 931
    , 937 (2d Cir. 1993); Eastland
    v. Tennessee Valley Authority, 
    704 F.2d 613
    , 617-18 (11th
    Cir. 1983); 7AA Charles Alan Wright et al., supra, § 1760,
    pp. 139-49; cf. Crawford v. Equifax Payment Services, 
    201 F.3d 877
    , 882 (7th Cir. 2000). But this has not yet been
    shown. Although some of the class members probably
    were net gainers from the alleged manipulation, there is
    no reason at this stage to believe that many were. A
    short seller hopes the price of the security that he’s
    selling will fall. He knows it may rise and his speculative
    gamble therefore fail, but if the rise is caused or increased
    by a violation of law the incremental loss caused by
    the violation entitles him to an award of damages. And
    while it is true that short sellers may want to hedge part
    of the risk of a rise in the price of the security that they
    are selling short, they will not hedge the entire risk, as
    that would eliminate the prospect of speculative gains
    that motivates short selling. Suppose a short seller sells
    a security at $80, hoping the price will fall below that by
    the delivery date; but fearing that it might rise far enough
    to bankrupt him, he hedges by contracting to buy the
    security at $100 should it rise that high. That will cap
    his potential loss at $20, but he will sustain a loss if the
    defendant drives the price of the security to any level
    above $80.
    12                                              No. 08-1075
    A further possibility, however, is that some of the
    members of the class were actually speculating on a rise
    in the price of the June Contract, and made some short
    sales merely as a hedge, and because of PIMCO’s alleged
    conduct obtained a net profit. We do not know how
    many of these “long” speculators the class may contain,
    but probably not many. Otherwise PIMCO would not
    have made huge purchases of the June Contract in order
    to drive up the price at which short sellers would have
    to close out their sales. Put differently, were there not a
    great many net short sellers of the June Contract, PIMCO
    could not have driven its price to an artificially high
    level because only short sellers would buy at such a
    price, for they alone would have to close out their short
    positions by buying the June Contract. (Not that the
    plaintiffs have proved that PIMCO tried to corner the
    market, or succeeded; but at this stage in the pro-
    ceeding we must assume that they can prove it.)
    So while PIMCO states correctly in its reply brief that “a
    proper class definition cannot be so untethered from
    the elements of the underlying cause of action that it
    wildly overstates the number of parties that could
    possibly demonstrate injury,” it has failed to justify the
    use of the word “wildly” to describe the extent to which
    the class definition may be too broad.
    PIMCO’s repeated, indeed obsessive, citations to the
    Supreme Court’s decision in Dura Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v.
    Broudo, 
    544 U.S. 336
     (2005), a case that does not involve
    class certification, suggests desperation. The Court held
    in that case that an allegation that the plaintiffs had
    No. 08-1075                                                   13
    bought securities at “artificially inflated prices” did not
    state a claim that the plaintiffs had been injured by the
    inflation because, for all that appeared, the prices had
    remained at that level, or even a higher one, or the plain-
    tiffs had sold before the price bubble burst. The Court
    refused to “allow recovery where a misrepresentation
    leads to an inflated purchase price but nonetheless does
    not proximately cause any economic loss.” 
    Id. at 346
    .
    In this case, too, the plaintiffs claim that the defendants
    forced up the price, but there the resemblance between
    the two cases ends. The plaintiffs sold short, so, prima
    facie at least—being forced as they were to cover by
    June 30—they were injured if the price of cover was
    artificially inflated during the period between their
    sale and the delivery date.
    At argument PIMCO’s lawyer told us that he could
    obtain names of class members. If so, he can, as in Bell v.
    Farmers Ins. Exchange, 
    9 Cal. Rptr. 3d 544
    , 550-51, 568, 571
    (Cal. App. 2004), and Long v. Trans World Airlines, Inc., 
    1988 WL 87051
    , at *1 (N.D. Ill. Aug. 18, 1988), depose a
    random sample of class members to determine how
    many were net gainers from the alleged manipulation
    and therefore were not injured, and if it turns out to be
    a high percentage he could urge the district court to
    revisit its decision to certify the class. Cf. Hilao v. Estate of
    Marcos, 
    103 F.3d 767
    , 782-84 (9th Cir. 1996); Long v. Trans
    World Airlines, Inc., 
    761 F. Supp. 1320
    , 1325-30 (N.D. Ill.
    1991); Marisol A. v. Giuliani, 
    1997 WL 630183
    , at *1
    (S.D.N.Y. Oct. 10, 1997). PIMCO has not done this;
    should it take the hint and try to do so now, this will be
    an issue for consideration by the district judge.
    14                                                No. 08-1075
    PIMCO also argues that class certification should have
    been denied because of potential conflicts of interest
    among class members that will make it impossible for
    class counsel to represent all of them all impartially. Fed.
    R. Civ. P. 23(a)(4); Amchem Products, Inc. v. Windsor, 
    521 U.S. 591
    , 625-26 (1997); Secretary of Labor v. Fitzsimmons, 
    805 F.2d 682
    , 697 (7th Cir. 1986); Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva
    Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 
    350 F.3d 1181
    , 1189 (11th Cir. 2003);
    Pickett v. Iowa Beef Processors, 
    209 F.3d 1276
    , 1280-81 (11th
    Cir. 2000). Class members covered by buying the June
    Contract, thus capping their losses, at different times
    during the seven-week period embraced by the complaint.
    One who covered very early would want to show that the
    effect of PIMCO’s alleged misconduct peaked then.
    Moreover, the curve of rising prices for the June Contract
    dipped at one point during the complaint period and
    class members who covered during the dip might want
    to show that PIMCO’s effect on the price level was com-
    pleted by then and the post-dip rise in prices was due
    to market forces for which PIMCO was not responsible.
    Suppose the price had risen from $100 at the beginning
    of the complaint period to $130 at the bottom of the
    dip, and from $130 to $150 between then and the
    delivery date. Short sellers who covered during the dip
    would want to show that it was PIMCO who pushed the
    price up from $100 to $130, and that insofar as market
    forces were shown to be responsible for part of the
    price rise they operated after the dip rather than before.
    Short sellers who covered at the end of the period would
    want to show that the entire price increase, from $100
    to $150, was due to PIMCO’s illegal activity.
    No. 08-1075                                                15
    At this stage in the litigation, the existence of such
    conflicts is hypothetical. If and when they become real,
    the district court can certify subclasses with separate
    representation of each, Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(c)(5); Reynolds
    v. Benefit Nat’l Bank, 
    288 F.3d 277
    , 282 (7th Cir. 2002);
    Blackie v. Barrack, 
    524 F.2d 891
    , 909 (9th Cir. 1975); 7AA
    Charles Alan Wright et al., supra, § 1769.1, pp. 455-58, if
    that would be consistent with manageability. In re Cendant
    Corp. Securities Litigation, 
    404 F.3d 173
    , 201 (3d Cir. 2005);
    John C. Coffee Jr., “Class Action Accountability: Reconcil-
    ing Exit, Voice, and Loyalty in Representative Litigation,”
    
    100 Colum. L. Rev. 370
    , 398 (2000). To deny class certifica-
    tion now, because of a potential conflict of interest that
    may not become actual, would be premature. Int’l Wood-
    workers of America, etc. v. Chesapeake Bay Plywood Corp., 
    659 F.2d 1259
    , 1269 (4th Cir. 1981); 1 Conte & Newberg,
    supra, § 3.25, p. 422; cf. Smilow v. Southwestern Bell Mobile
    Systems, Inc., 
    323 F.3d 32
    , 40 (1st Cir. 2003).
    PIMCO’s attempt to derail this suit at the outset is ill
    timed, ill conceived, and must fail. The district court’s
    class certification is
    A FFIRMED.
    7-7-09
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 08-1075

Judges: Posner

Filed Date: 7/7/2009

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/24/2015

Authorities (35)

julie-robidoux-individually-and-on-behalf-of-all-persons-similarly , 987 F.2d 931 ( 1993 )

Ortiz v. Fibreboard Corp. , 119 S. Ct. 2295 ( 1999 )

Henry Lee Pickett v. Iowa Beef Processors , 209 F.3d 1276 ( 2000 )

in-the-matter-of-bridgestonefirestone-inc-tires-products-liability , 288 F.3d 1012 ( 2002 )

raymond-zimmerman-individually-and-on-behalf-of-a-class-of-similarly , 360 F.3d 612 ( 2004 )

Great Western Food Distributors, Inc. v. Brannan , 201 F.2d 476 ( 1953 )

beverly-blair-and-letressa-wilbon-on-behalf-of-themselves-and-a-class-of , 181 F.3d 832 ( 1999 )

31 Fair empl.prac.cas. 1578, 31 Empl. Prac. Dec. P 33,571 ... , 704 F.2d 613 ( 1983 )

lawrence-crawford-on-behalf-of-himself-and-a-class-of-others-similarly , 201 F.3d 877 ( 2000 )

andrew-parker-eric-debrauwere-v-time-warner-entertainment-company-lp , 331 F.3d 13 ( 2003 )

American Civil Liberties Union of Illinois, Kathryn ... , 794 F.2d 265 ( 1986 )

Warth v. Seldin , 95 S. Ct. 2197 ( 1975 )

Steel Co. v. Citizens for a Better Environment , 118 S. Ct. 1003 ( 1998 )

Dura Pharmaceuticals, Inc. v. Broudo , 125 S. Ct. 1627 ( 2005 )

secretary-of-labor-v-frank-e-fitzsimmons-david-dutchak-and-secretary-of , 805 F.2d 682 ( 1986 )

Cheryl Reynolds v. Beneficial National Bank, Appeals of ... , 288 F.3d 277 ( 2002 )

Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharmaceuticals, Inc. , 350 F.3d 1181 ( 2003 )

cathleen-murray-shelly-wilson-v-charles-auslander-acting-administrator , 244 F.3d 807 ( 2001 )

Carol B. Oshana v. Coca-Cola Company, a Delaware Corporation , 472 F.3d 506 ( 2006 )

Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife , 112 S. Ct. 2130 ( 1992 )

View All Authorities »