Hoosier Energy Rural Electric v. John Hancock Life Insurance Co ( 2009 )


Menu:
  •                              In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    H OOSIER E NERGY R URAL E LECTRIC C OOPERATIVE, INC.,
    Plaintiff-Appellee,
    v.
    JOHN H ANCOCK L IFE INSURANCE C OMPANY;
    OP M EROM G ENERATION I, LLC; and
    M EROM G ENERATION I, LLC,
    Defendants-Appellants,
    A MBAC A SSURANCE C ORPORATION;
    C OBANK, ACB; AE G LOBAL INVESTMENTS, LLC; and
    A MBAC C REDIT P RODUCTS, LLC,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    Appeals from the United States District Court
    for the Southern District of Indiana, Indianapolis Division.
    No. 1:08-cv-1560-DFH-DML—David F. Hamilton, Chief Judge.
    A RGUED JANUARY 5, 2009—D ECIDED S EPTEMBER 17, 2009
    Before E ASTERBROOK , Chief Judge, and K ANNE and
    W OOD , Circuit Judges.
    2                                  Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    E ASTERBROOK, Chief Judge. Hoosier Energy, a co-op,
    had depreciation deductions that it could not use. John
    Hancock Life Insurance Co. had income exceeding its
    available deductions. The two engaged in a transaction
    designed to move Hoosier Energy’s deductions to
    John Hancock. They entered into a leveraged lease: John
    Hancock paid Hoosier Energy $300 million for a 63-year
    lease of an undivided 2/3 interest in Hoosier Energy’s
    Merom generation plant. Hoosier Energy agreed to lease
    the plant back from John Hancock for 30 years, making
    periodic payments with a present value of $279 million.
    The $21 million difference, Hoosier Energy’s profit,
    represents some of the value to John Hancock of the
    deductions that John Hancock could take as the long-
    term lessee of the power plant.
    The transaction exposed John Hancock to several risks.
    The power station might become uneconomic before the
    parties’ estimate of its remaining useful life (roughly
    30 years). Or Hoosier Energy might encounter financial
    difficulties in its business as a whole. As a debtor in
    bankruptcy, Hoosier Energy would be entitled to
    repudiate the lease, leaving John Hancock with a
    power station that it had no interest in operating. Hoosier
    Energy’s obligation as a repudiating debtor would be
    considerably less than the present value of the rentals.
    See 
    11 U.S.C. §502
    (b)(6). So Hoosier Energy agreed to
    provide John Hancock with additional security, in the
    form of both a credit-default swap and a surety bond.
    Ambac Assurance Corporation and three affiliates
    agreed to pay John Hancock approximately $120 million
    if certain events occurred. (For its part, Hoosier Energy
    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248                                      3
    posted substantial liquid assets to Ambac’s credit,
    in order to protect Ambac should it be required to pay
    John Hancock; this was part of the transaction’s swap
    feature.) A credit-default swap, like a letter of credit, is a
    means to assure payment when contingencies come to
    pass, without proof of loss (as a surety bond would
    require). One of the contingencies in this transaction is
    a reduction in Ambac’s own credit rating. If that rating
    falls below a prescribed threshold, Hoosier Energy has
    60 days to find a replacement that satisfies the con-
    tractual standards.
    During 2008 Ambac’s credit rating slipped below the
    threshold. John Hancock then demanded that Hoosier
    Energy find a replacement, and it extended the deadline
    from 60 days to more than 120 days when Hoosier
    Energy reported trouble. Whether replacing Ambac was
    “impossible” at the time, as Hoosier Energy maintains, or
    just would have cost Hoosier Energy more than it was
    willing to pay, as John Hancock believes, is a subject
    that remains in dispute. When the extended deadline
    arrived, Hoosier Energy told John Hancock that it was
    in negotiations with Berkshire Hathaway to replace
    Ambac. John Hancock concluded that “in negotiations”
    was not good enough (perhaps it suspected Hoosier
    Energy of stalling) and called on Ambac to perform.
    Ambac is ready, willing, and able to meet its obligations.
    But before Ambac could pay, Hoosier Energy filed this
    suit under the diversity jurisdiction, and the district court
    issued a temporary restraining order. The justification
    for that order, since replaced by a preliminary injunction,
    is that if Ambac pays, it will demand that Hoosier
    4                                   Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    Energy cover the outlay, and that this will drive Hoosier
    Energy into bankruptcy—a step that the district court
    called an irreparable injury.
    Irreparable injury is not enough to support equitable
    relief. There also must be a plausible claim on the
    merits, and the injunction must do more good than
    harm (which is to say that the “balance of equities” favors
    the plaintiff). See Winter v. Natural Resources Defense
    Council, Inc., 
    129 S. Ct. 365
     (2008); Illinois Bell Telephone
    Co. v. WorldCom Technologies, Inc., 
    157 F.3d 500
     (7th Cir.
    1998). How strong a claim on the merits is enough
    depends on the balance of harms: the more net harm
    an injunction can prevent, the weaker the plaintiff’s
    claim on the merits can be while still supporting some
    preliminary relief. See Cavel International, Inc. v. Madigan,
    
    500 F.3d 544
     (7th Cir. 2007); Girl Scouts of Manitou
    Council, Inc. v. Girl Scouts of the United States of America,
    Inc., 
    549 F.3d 1079
     (7th Cir. 2008). The district court con-
    cluded that an injunction would have net benefits,
    because John Hancock would remain well secured in its
    absence (it remains the lessee of a power station that is
    essential to Hoosier Energy’s business, so Hoosier
    Energy will not abandon the lease), and that Hoosier
    Energy’s position on the merits is strong enough to
    support relief while litigation continues. 
    588 F. Supp. 2d 919
     (S.D. Ind. 2008). The district court also directed
    Hoosier Energy to post $2 million in cash, a $20 million
    injunction bond with sureties, and an unsecured bond of
    $130 million, to ensure that John Hancock would be
    made whole should it prevail in the litigation.
    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248                                         5
    As for the merits: The district court thought that
    Hoosier Energy has two arguments with enough punch
    to justify interlocutory relief. The first is that the transac-
    tion is an abusive tax shelter. The district court observed
    that the Internal Revenue Service has declined to allow
    similar transactions to transfer deductions from one
    corporation to another and concluded that this trans-
    action probably should be unwound. The second is that,
    under New York law (which the parties agree supplies
    the rule of decision), “temporary commercial impractic-
    ability” permits Hoosier Energy to defer coming up with
    another swap partner until the economy has improved.
    John Hancock disputes both of these conclusions, but
    its appellate brief opens with the contention that Hoosier
    Energy lacks standing to complain. After all, John
    Hancock observes, Ambac is willing and able to per-
    form. What interest does Hoosier Energy have in whether
    Ambac performs under a contract that, the parties
    agreed, would be deemed independent of Hoosier
    Energy’s promises? The answer is that, if Ambac pays
    John Hancock, then Hoosier Energy must pay Ambac.
    (The funds already on deposit with Ambac are insuf-
    ficient to cover all of Hoosier Energy’s obligations.) A
    payout would be injury, caused by John Hancock’s
    acts, and remediable by a favorable judicial deci-
    sion. That’s enough for standing under the Supreme
    Court’s precedents. See, e.g., Steel Co. v. Citizens for a Better
    Environment, 
    523 U.S. 83
    , 102–05 (1998).
    This is a three-corner transaction (four-corner, if one
    counts the IRS). It was accomplished through a series
    6                                  Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    of nominally independent contracts spanning more than
    3,000 pages. But it would press legal fiction beyond
    the breaking point to say that the independent enforce-
    ability of each party’s promises to the others meant that
    any of the three parties lacked standing to complain
    about acts of the others that will produce an immediate,
    concrete injury. It may be that Hoosier Energy has waived
    its right to complain (that, too, is a subject on which
    litigation lies ahead), but a waiver is a defense on the
    merits, which differs from the absence of an Article III
    case or controversy.
    On the subject of irreparable injury, appellate review
    is deferential at the preliminary injunction stage, and we
    lack an adequate basis on which to disagree with the
    district court’s assessment. That leaves the question
    whether Hoosier Energy has a plausible theory on the
    merits—not necessarily a winning one, but a claim
    strong enough to justify exposing John Hancock to finan-
    cial risks until the district court can decide the merits.
    We do not agree with all of the district judge’s reasoning,
    but we do not think that the court erred in thinking
    Hoosier Energy’s claim sufficient for this limited purpose,
    given Ambac’s continuing ability to perform and the
    injunction bonds posted under Fed. R. Civ. P. 65(c).
    Let us start with the question whether the transaction
    is an illegal tax shelter that must be unwound rather
    than enforced. The district court’s approach has two
    steps: First, the court concluded that the transaction
    lacks economic substance and therefore cannot be em-
    ployed to transfer tax benefits from Hoosier Energy to
    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248                                     7
    John Hancock. Second, the court believed that a tax
    shelter that the Internal Revenue Code does not allow is
    “illegal” as a matter of contract law. The first of these
    steps may or may not be right; the tax treatment of lever-
    aged leases, and related transactions such as the sale
    and leaseback, can be difficult. See, e.g., Frank Lyon Co. v.
    United States, 
    435 U.S. 561
     (1978). The second is wrong.
    A leveraged lease is a perfectly enforceable contract.
    Whether or not the contract lawfully transfers tax
    benefits, there is nothing wrong with, or illegal about, the
    contract itself; only the claim of tax benefits from the
    contract would be problematic.
    All questions about tax benefits to one side, a leveraged
    lease is simply a loan secured by a lease rather than a
    mortgage. John Hancock needs to make investments in
    order to have money available to pay the death benefits
    on its life insurance policies. Often it invests in real
    estate. The transaction with Hoosier Energy is one in
    which John Hancock invested $300 million in exchange
    for a promised stream of repayments that would last
    30 years; it also obtained a security interest in the assets
    that Hoosier Energy would use to produce the funds
    for repayment. Neither New York nor Indiana would call
    such a transaction illegal, and the fact that a credit-
    default swap improved the lender’s security does not
    create any additional problem.
    Hoosier Energy has not cited, and we have not found,
    any decision holding a leveraged lease or sale-and-
    leaseback unenforceable as a matter of contract law,
    just because the main (or even the sole) reason for struc-
    8                                   Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    turing the transaction that way, rather than as a loan, was
    tax benefits. “Economic purpose” is not a requirement
    for the enforceability of contracts. If the Green Bay
    Packers cut a player one day and then re-sign him the
    next, a court would not dream of canceling the new
    contract on the ground that a release-and-resign sequence
    lacks economic purpose. The Commissioner of Internal
    Revenue will address the question whether the leveraged-
    lease transaction provides John Hancock with the tax
    benefits it seeks. If the answer turns out to be no, Hoosier
    Energy still owes John Hancock the promised rental
    payments (and is entitled to keep the $21 million pre-
    mium), while Ambac still provides security for those
    payments.
    New York law is skeptical of contentions that irregular
    dealings between one contracting party and the govern-
    ment excuse the other contracting party’s performance.
    For example, John E. Rosasco Creameries, Inc. v. Cohen,
    
    11 N.E.2d 908
    , 909 (N.Y. 1937), held that the dairy’s
    customer must pay for goods received, even though the
    dairy lacked a license and thus should not have been
    in business. In New York, “[a]s a general rule also, for-
    feitures by operation of law are disfavored, particularly
    where a defaulting party seeks to raise illegality as ‘a
    sword for personal gain rather than as a shield for the
    public good.’ ” Lloyd Capital Corp. v. Pat Henchar, Inc., 
    603 N.E.2d 246
    , 248 (N.Y. 1992), quoting from Charlebois v. J. M.
    Weller Associates, Inc., 
    531 N.E.2d 1288
    , 1292 (N.Y. 1988).
    These cases illustrate Justice Holmes’s quip that there
    is a strong “policy of preventing people from getting
    other people’s property for nothing when they purport
    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248                                      9
    to be buying it.” Continental Wall Paper Co. v. Louis Voight
    & Sons Co., 
    212 U.S. 227
    , 271 (1909) (Holmes, J., dissenting).
    John Hancock’s taxes are a matter for it to resolve with
    the IRS; that John Hancock may have set out to take
    larger deductions than the law allows does not affect
    Hoosier Energy’s contractual duties.
    This leaves the doctrine of “temporary commercial
    impracticability.” John Hancock’s principal argument on
    this front is that New York law does not recognize any
    such doctrine. Like other states, New York recognizes
    the doctrine of impossibility—but even then only the
    kind of impossibility that the parties could not have
    anticipated. As John Hancock describes things, the
    parties anticipated the possibility that Hoosier Energy,
    Ambac, or both might get into financial distress and
    provided what was to happen: if Hoosier Energy did not
    come up with better security in 60 days, John Hancock
    could draw on the credit-default swap to protect it-
    self. When the economy turned sour, and the risk mate-
    rialized, John Hancock tried to take advantage of this
    extra security. Yet the district court deemed the risk’s
    coming to pass as a reason why John Hancock could not
    draw on the security. John Hancock sees this as perverse,
    an order that defeats the parties’ bargained-for alloca-
    tion of risks. The district court may have thought
    that economy-wide conditions justified this reallocation,
    but it is hard to see how an economic downturn can
    be alleviated by making contracts less reliable. En-
    forceable contracts are vital to economic productivity.
    See Simeon Djankov, Oliver Hart, Caralee McLiesh &
    Andrei Shleifer, Debt Enforcement around the World, 
    116 J. 10
                                     Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    Pol. Econ. 1105 (2008); Thomas Cooley, Ramon Marimon &
    Vincenzo Quadrini, Aggregate Consequences of Limited
    Contract Enforceability, 112 J. Pol. Econ. 817 (2004).
    Whether Hoosier Energy’s performance was “impossi-
    ble” in the strong sense that contract law requires
    depends on what its obligations were. John Hancock
    urges on us the perspective that, when Ambac’s credit
    rating slipped, Hoosier Energy had an option: find a
    new surety in 60 days, or pay Ambac the sums to
    which Ambac would become entitled once it paid John
    Hancock. The holder of an option may not be able to
    take advantage, but that differs from impossibility. Sup-
    pose that Hoosier Energy had an in-the-money option
    to purchase the Indianapolis Colts by the end of
    December 2008, and that as a result of the reduced avail-
    ability of credit it was unable to find a lender to finance
    the transaction. That would not make performance
    “impossible” and extend the option’s expiration, effec-
    tively giving Hoosier Energy a new option (for 2009) for
    free. Likewise if Hoosier Energy had borrowed
    $100 million and was obliged to pay the money back on
    October 1, 2008. That Hoosier Energy found itself unable
    to borrow money to roll over the loan would not excuse
    repayment; the “impossibility” doctrine never justifies
    failure to make a payment, because financial distress
    differs from impossibility. See Restatement (Second) of
    Contracts §261 & comment d.
    The uranium case illustrates these propositions. Westing-
    house sold uranium on long-term requirements con-
    tracts at fixed prices, thus assuming the risk that market
    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248                                   11
    prices would rise (and it would lose money). Westinghouse
    anticipated that market prices would fall; its customers
    thought they would rise, or at least wanted protection
    against higher prices. And rise they did, partly as a
    result of a cartel. Westinghouse had neglected to protect
    its position in futures markets or through long-term
    forward contracts. Faced with large losses if it had to
    buy uranium on the spot market and resell to customers
    at lower prices, Westinghouse contended that the unan-
    ticipated spike in uranium prices made its performance
    impossible. The argument failed; the court observed
    that Westinghouse and its customers had negotiated
    over the risk of higher prices for uranium, and that the
    occurrence of the risk did not excuse one side’s perfor-
    mance. Even if the losses drove Westinghouse into bank-
    ruptcy, that would not make performance “impossible”;
    it would just assure that all of Westinghouse’s creditors
    received equal treatment. See In re Westinghouse Electric
    Corp. Uranium Contracts Litigation, 
    563 F.2d 992
     (10th Cir.
    1977); Richard A. Posner & Andrew M. Rosenfield,
    Impossibility and Related Doctrines of Contract Law: An
    Economic Analysis, 6 J. Legal Studies 83 (1977).
    Much the same can be said about Hoosier Energy. If
    keeping its promise to Ambac drives it into bankruptcy,
    this ensures equal treatment of its creditors. It is hard to
    see why Hoosier Energy should be able to stiff John
    Hancock or Ambac, while paying 100¢ on the dollar to all
    of its other trading partners, just because the very risk
    specified in the contracts between Hoosier Energy and
    John Hancock has occurred. Hoosier Energy did not
    expect an economic downturn, but Westinghouse did not
    12                                  Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    expect an international uranium cartel. Downturns and
    cartels are types of things that happen, and against which
    contracts can be designed. When they do happen,
    the contractual risk allocation must be enforced rather
    than set aside. The district court called the credit crunch
    of 2008 a “once-in-a-century” event. That’s an overstate-
    ment (the Great Depression occurred within the last
    100 years, and the 20th Century also saw financial
    crunches in 1973 and 1987), and also irrelevant. An
    insurer that sells hurricane or flood insurance against a
    “once in a century” catastrophe, or earthquake insur-
    ance in a city that rarely experiences tremblors, can’t
    refuse to pay on the ground that, when a natural event
    devastates a city, its very improbability makes the
    contract unenforceable.
    We postponed discussing New York law until the
    general points of contract doctrine had been set out. New
    York law is consistent with what we have said; indeed,
    New York takes a very dim view of “impossibility”
    defenses and has never suggested that, when an impossi-
    bility defense is unavailable, a “temporary commercial
    impracticability” defense might serve instead. New York
    courts refuse to excuse performance where difficulty
    “is occasioned only by financial difficulty or economic
    hardship, even to the extent of insolvency or bank-
    ruptcy.” 407 East 61st Garage, Inc. v. Savoy Fifth Avenue
    Corp., 
    244 N.E.2d 37
    , 41 (N.Y. 1968). This applies to finan-
    cial instruments—and, although impossibility might
    allow a party to suspend its obligations under a finan-
    cial swap contract, this means more than a short-term
    inability to pay money. General Electric Co. v. Metals
    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248                                    13
    Resources Group Ltd., 
    741 N.Y.S.2d 218
     (App. Div. 2002). For
    its part, Hoosier Energy all but ignores New York law;
    its brief cites only a single decision, by a trial court; ap-
    pellate decisions go unmentioned. And the trial-court
    decision that Hoosier Energy cites speaks of temporary
    impossibility, not “temporary commercial impractic-
    ability.”
    All of this assumes, however, that John Hancock is
    right to characterize Hoosier Energy as having an option
    to find a better surety. As Hoosier Energy understands
    the contract, however, it had a duty to find a better
    surety, and failure to perform this duty was the default
    allowing John Hancock to draw on the swap. Then it
    might be possible to make out a real impossibility
    defense, meaning that (a) all parties to the transaction
    assumed, when they negotiated the terms, that it
    would be possible to find some other intermediary with
    adequate credit standing, and (b) as a result of a finan-
    cial crisis, no such intermediary existed in late 2008, no
    matter how much Hoosier Energy offered to post in
    liquid assets to secure its obligations.
    Even this would be a difficult defense to make out
    under New York law. The leading New York case on
    impossibility, Kel Kim Corp. v. Central Markets, Inc., 
    519 N.E.2d 295
     (N.Y. 1987), says that the defense works only
    if some unexpected event upsets all parties’ expectations;
    it is not enough that the unexpected event puts one side
    in a bind. The lessee of a roller skating rink was
    required by contract to obtain liability insurance, which
    it got and maintained six years before the insurer
    14                                 Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    declined to renew. When the policy expired, the lessor
    asserted default, and the lessee sought a declaration that
    performance was excused by impossibility, because no
    insurer would underwrite a liability policy for a roller
    rink at any price. Rejecting the lessee’s argument, the
    Court of Appeals stated that impossibility can excuse
    performance only if the new event “could not have
    been foreseen or guarded against” in the contract.
    Financial distress could be and was foreseen; that’s
    what the credit-default swap is all about. But if no one
    could have foreseen the extent of the credit crunch in
    2008—and if it really made performance impossible, a
    subject on which the parties profoundly disagree—then
    the sort of argument that Hoosier Energy makes could
    satisfy the requirements of Kel Kim.
    We have said enough to show that there is uncertainty
    about how this suit comes out under New York law. It is
    uncertain whether Hoosier Energy had a duty to replace
    Ambac, or just an option; the impossibility defense is
    unavailable if the option characterization is correct. (We
    have avoided quoting the documents; some portions
    of these lengthy contracts support each side’s charac-
    terization of them.) It is uncertain whether the extent of
    the 2008 credit crunch, which extended into 2009, was
    foreseeable. It is uncertain whether Hoosier Energy
    could have replaced Ambac by offering more, or better,
    security to another intermediary. Hoosier Energy under-
    mined its own position in the litigation by telling
    John Hancock that it was negotiating with Berkshire
    Hathaway and could strike a deal with just a little
    more time, which implies that replacing Ambac was not
    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248                                 15
    impossible, but John Hancock returned the favor by
    suggesting that this deal was just pie in the sky and that
    Hoosier Energy would not or could not ever replace
    Ambac—and, if “could not” is the right understanding,
    perhaps performance was impossible after all.
    All of these uncertainties collectively support the
    district court’s conclusion that Hoosier Energy has some
    prospect of prevailing on the merits. Because appellate
    review is deferential, the district court’s understanding
    must prevail at the interlocutory stage.
    But what was impossible in fall 2008 may well be possi-
    ble in fall 2009. What is more, the longer this impasse
    continues, the more the balance of equities tilts in favor
    of John Hancock. Recall that the reason for the credit-
    default swap was concern that the Merom station would
    eventually become non-economic because of changes in
    the market for electricity, the regulation of emissions
    from coal-fired stations, or the advancing age of the
    plant. The more time passes, the more serious this
    risk—and the greater the risk that one or another
    problem may afflict Hoosier Energy as a firm. If, as
    Hoosier Energy asserts, meeting Ambac’s demands
    under the swap contract will drive it into bankruptcy,
    then Hoosier Energy must be skating close to the edge,
    and the longer it skates there the greater the cumulative
    risk that it will fall over. Similarly Ambac may become
    less desirable as a swap partner; while this appeal has
    been under advisement, Ambac’s credit rating has been
    reduced twice.
    John Hancock is entitled to the security it negotiated
    against these possible outcomes. The injunction bonds,
    16                                    Nos. 08-4030 & 08-4248
    at only $22 million in liquid security, do not cover
    John Hancock’s exposure. The change in Ambac’s credit
    rating, in particular, requires the district court to take a
    new look at the adequacy of the Rule 65(c) security
    promptly after receiving this court’s mandate (which
    will be issued together with this opinion). So although
    we affirm the district court’s preliminary injunction, we
    conclude that, if Hoosier Energy has not produced a
    replacement for Ambac by the end of 2009, the time
    will have arrived when the court must let John Hancock
    realize on its security. The district court itself stressed the
    word “temporary” in “temporary commercial imprac-
    ticability”; we are confident that the court will not allow
    “temporary” to drag out in the direction of permanence.
    A FFIRMED
    9-25-09