Dennison v. Mony Life Retirement Income Security Plan for Employees , 710 F.3d 741 ( 2013 )


Menu:
  •                            In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    No. 12-2407
    JOHN J. D ENNISON, on behalf of himself and
    all others similarly situated,
    Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.
    MONY L IFE R ETIREMENT INCOME S ECURITY P LAN
    FOR E MPLOYEES, et al.,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Western District of Wisconsin.
    No. 3:10-cv-338-bbc—Barbara B. Crabb, Judge.
    A RGUED JANUARY 18, 2013—D ECIDED M ARCH 6, 2013
    Before P OSNER, F LAUM, and S YKES, Circuit Judges.
    P OSNER, Circuit Judge. The district court certified this
    ERISA suit as a class action, dismissed one of the
    two claims in the suit, and granted the defendants’
    motion for summary judgment on the other one. The
    plaintiff appeals, raising issues of plan interpretation
    and also complaining about the district judge’s refusal to
    2                                                No. 12-2407
    allow him to conduct discovery to determine whether
    the plan’s rejection of his claim was motivated by a
    conflict of interest. The only class member about whom
    there is information in the appellate record is the plaintiff.
    He left MONY (Mutual of New York Insurance Com-
    pany, now a subsidiary of AXA), where he had been
    employed in a senior position, in 1996. While employed
    there he had participated in two retirement plans. One was
    the Retirement Income Security Plan for Employees, which
    the parties call “RISPE”; it is a tax-qualified defined
    benefits pension plan; that is, it guarantees specified
    retirement benefits and provides favorable tax treatment
    both to the employer, who funds the plan, and the plan
    participants. The other plan was the Excess Benefit Plan
    for MONY Employees, which the parties call the “Excess
    Plan.” It too is a defined benefits pension plan, but it is
    an unfunded one—that is, the benefits are paid directly
    by the employer rather than by a trust established and
    funded by the employer, and there are no special tax
    advantages. Such plans, which are intended for highly
    compensated employees, are referred to colloquially as
    “top hat” plans. Comrie v. IPSCO, Inc., 
    636 F.3d 839
    ,
    840 (7th Cir. 2011); In re New Valley Corp., 
    89 F.3d 143
    , 148-
    49 (3d Cir. 1996).
    Both plans entitled the plaintiff to begin receiving the
    benefits promised by them when he turned 55, which
    he did in 2009. And both gave him a choice, to be made
    then, between taking his benefits in the form of a “straight
    life” annuity—a fixed monthly payment for the rest of
    his life—and taking them as a lump sum. The lump
    No. 12-2407                                                 3
    sum form was represented to be the actuarial equivalent
    of the annuity.
    To determine actuarial equivalence requires two spec-
    ifications. The first is an estimate of how long the recipient
    is likely to live (an estimate not challenged by either side
    in this case) and therefore for how long he would be
    likely to receive the monthly annuity payment if he
    chose the annuity rather than the lump sum. The
    second requirement is a discount rate to apply to the
    projected annuity payments. A discount rate is an
    interest rate used not to determine how an investment
    will grow but instead to calculate the present value of
    a future receipt. If (to take a simple example of how
    discounting to present value works) you expect to
    receive $100,000 20 years from now and you want to
    know what that’s worth today and you think that
    interest rates over the next 20 years will be 6 percent,
    you can by using a present-value calculator discover that
    the present value of that expected future payment is
    $31,180.47. That is the amount that, invested at 6 percent
    interest compounded annually, will grow to $100,000 in
    20 years. The lower the assumed interest rate, the more
    slowly the investment will grow and hence the higher
    the present value—the lump sum equivalent. At a
    10 percent rate the present value of $100,000 in 20 years
    is only $14,864.36, while at 3 percent it would be
    $55,367.58. The dispute in this case is over the discount
    rate that the plan used to calculate the lump sum equiva-
    lent of the annuity—$1,888.46 a month—that the plain-
    tiff was entitled to begin receiving when he turned 55.
    4                                               No. 12-2407
    When in 2009 the plaintiff became eligible to begin
    receiving benefits, he told MONY (as we’ll refer collec-
    tively to the defendants, which include besides the insur-
    ance company the two pension plans in which the
    plaintiff participated and their administrators) that he
    wanted lump sums. So MONY cut him two checks.
    One was his RISPE lump sum, $325,054.28 (which
    happens to have been $10,000 less than his annual salary
    in his last year as an employee of MONY), and the other
    his Excess Plan lump sum, $218,726.38. The discount
    rate that the plan used to calculate his lump sum
    RISPE benefits was a blended rate called a “seg-
    ment rate,” 
    26 U.S.C. § 417
    (e)(3)(C), of roughly 5.24 per-
    cent. A segment rate is an interest rate calculated
    by the Treasury Department on the basis of investment-
    grade corporate bond rates. The details of the calcula-
    tion are irrelevant to the appeal and the exact segment
    rate used by MONY in calculating the plaintiff’s
    RISPE benefits is not in the record and is not a subject
    of dispute between the parties. The discount rate
    that MONY used to determine the plaintiff’s Excess
    Plan lump sum was 7.5 percent.
    The plaintiff contends that the discount rate required by
    both plans was a rate computed by the Pension Benefit
    Guaranty Corporation on the basis of annuity premiums
    charged by insurance companies. Applied to the plain-
    tiff’s lump sums under the two plans, this rate, called the
    “PBGC rate,” would have been only 3 percent—less
    than half the average of the two discount rates that the
    plan used; and remember that the lower the discount
    rate, the greater the lump sum. (If the discount rate
    No. 12-2407                                               5
    were zero, the lump sum would be simply the sum of the
    participant’s predicted future benefits.) Oddly, we
    haven’t been told how much greater the lump sums to
    which the plaintiff would be entitled (let alone the
    lump sums to which the other thousand or so members
    of the certified class would be entitled) would be if the
    lower discount rate were used. But as our numerical
    example indicated, the lump sums would undoubtedly
    be much greater.
    When the plaintiff left MONY’s employ in 1996, the
    RISPE plan provided that the discount rate would be the
    PBGC rate as of 120 days before the lump sum was due
    to be paid; and that rate turned out as we just said to be
    3 percent. The Excess Plan did not specify a rate but as
    we’ll explain it almost certainly was 7.5 percent, the rate
    the plan used.
    A decade later, Congress, in the Pension Protection Act
    of 2006, Pub. L. 109-280, 
    120 Stat. 780
    , authorized plan
    sponsors to increase a plan’s lump sum discount rate by
    amendment to the plan, and to make the increase retroac-
    tive if they wanted. See sections 302 and 1170 of the Act,
    
    120 Stat. 920
    -21, 1063. Before the Act took effect, such a
    retroactive increase in the discount rate (and thus reduc-
    tion in the size of the lump sum) would have violated
    ERISA’s anti-cutback provision. 
    29 U.S.C. § 1054
    (g).
    The Pension Protection Act changed this but did (also
    in section 302) place a ceiling on retroactive rate
    increases for tax-qualified plans: the ceiling is the
    segment rate mentioned earlier. The ceiling is inap-
    plicable to the Excess Plan because it is not tax-qualified.
    6                                               No. 12-2407
    In 2009, three years after the Pension Protection Act
    was passed and shortly before the plaintiff turned 55
    and thus became entitled to begin receiving his retire-
    ment benefits, MONY raised the RISPE discount rate to
    the segment rate. The rate that MONY used to compute
    the plaintiff’s benefits under the Excess Plan remained
    at 7.5 percent.
    MONY could lawfully change the RISPE discount rate
    retroactively only if the plan authorized such an amend-
    ment. A plan is not required to do that, and it can if it
    wants promise not to, thereby creating a “contractual anti-
    cutback” rule that is enforceable like any other plan
    provision. Kemmerer v. ICI Americas Inc., 
    70 F.3d 281
    , 288-89
    (3d Cir. 1995). The Pension Protection Act provides an
    out only with respect to the statutory anti-cutback rule.
    The RISPE plan in force when the plaintiff left MONY
    states that the pension rights of an employee who left on
    or before the effective date of a particular amendment
    to the plan “shall be determined solely under the terms
    of the Plan as in effect on the date of his or her termina-
    tion of employment or retirement . . . unless [the amendment
    is] made applicable to former Employees” (emphasis added).
    So the plan did allow MONY to amend it to change
    the discount rate retroactively. But the plan also pro-
    vides “that no amendment shall . . . reduce the Accrued
    Benefit of any Participant.” The plaintiff was a plan
    participant and his benefit had “accrued” back in 1996,
    when he left the company. But “Accrued Benefit” is a
    defined term in the plan—defined as “the value of a
    Participant’s Retirement Benefit expressed as a Straight-
    No. 12-2407                                              7
    Life Annuity determined according to the terms of the
    Plan.” “Retirement Benefit” is another defined term: it
    “means a benefit payable on the dates, in the forms”
    specified in a section of the plan that under the heading
    “Optional Forms” allows the participant to choose a
    lump sum “in lieu of the Normal Form,” which is the
    straight-life annuity.
    We interpret these provisions to mean that
    the Accrued Benefit—that which cannot be reduced
    retroactively by amendment—is the annuity, and that
    the lump sum, while a Retirement Benefit, is not the
    Accrued Benefit and therefore can be reduced retroac-
    tively. The term “Retirement Benefit” encompasses all
    forms of benefits payment that a participant can choose,
    including the lump sum option that the plaintiff chose
    in lieu of the annuity. See Call v. Ameritech Management
    Pension Plan, 
    475 F.3d 816
    , 820-21 (7th Cir. 2007). Nothing
    in the plan forbids retroactively amending the discount
    rate used to calculate the lump sum benefit if the par-
    ticipant chooses the lump sum in preference to the annuity.
    The plaintiff cites our decision in Call as authority
    for interpreting “accrued benefit” (that which under
    the terms of the MONY plan can’t be changed retroac-
    tively) to include a lump sum “retirement benefit.” But
    the plan in Call had not defined “accrued benefit.” And
    the issue in that case was not whether a lump sum
    pension benefit was excluded by the term “accrued bene-
    fit” but whether an early-retirement benefit, regardless
    of the form it took, was excluded by the term.
    So the plaintiff’s complaint about his RISPE benefit
    fails, but what about the lump sum he received as a
    8                                               No. 12-2407
    participant in the Excess Plan? That plan isn’t mentioned
    in RISPE. The Excess Plan is very short—eight pages,
    compared to RISPE’s more than a hundred pages—and
    incorporates many provisions of the longer plan by ref-
    erence. It does not specify a discount rate, as we men-
    tioned. But it provides that benefits “shall be paid . . . in
    accordance with an automatic payout provision of the
    Retirement Plan.” In the definitions section of the Excess
    Plan we learn that “Retirement Plan” means RISPE. The
    parties agree that this is a directive to look to RISPE for
    guidance to what discount rate to use to calculate
    lump sum benefits under the Excess Plan. But RISPE
    doesn’t specify an interest rate for computing lump
    sum benefits under the Excess Plan. What it says (in
    section 1.3(a)) is that “for purposes of determining
    lump sum distributions and for all other payment
    forms subject to [Internal Revenue] Code Section
    417(e)”—that is, for tax-preferred plan payments—the
    “applicable interest rate shall be the interest rate
    prescribed by the Secretary of the Treasury under Code
    Section 417(e),” and that is the segment rate. But section
    1.3(c) of RISPE provides that “for all other purposes
    under the Plan” the discount rate is “7.5 percent per
    year compounded annually.”
    So the question is whether the reference to “lump
    sum distributions” in section 1.3(a) includes benefits
    under the Excess Plan. If not, section 1.3(c) governs and
    the discount rate applicable to the Excess Plan is the
    “for all other purposes” rate of 7.5 percent. The latter is
    undoubtedly the correct reading because section 1.3(a)
    No. 12-2407                                                 9
    is limited to benefits from tax-preferred plans and
    the Excess Plan is not tax preferred.
    The clincher to this interpretation is the plan admin-
    istrators’ consistent, unchallenged practice over many
    years of using the 7.5 percent figure to calculate lump
    sum benefits under the Excess Plan. When the con-
    sistent performance of parties to a contract accords with
    one of two alternative interpretations of the contract,
    that’s strong evidence for that interpretation. This is a
    general principle of contract interpretation rather than a
    provision of ERISA, 2 E. Allan Farnsworth, Farnsworth on
    Contracts § 7.13, pp. 329-30 (3d ed. 2004); Restatement
    (Second) of Contracts, § 202, comment (g) (1981), but it is a
    principle that is applied in the interpretation of ERISA
    plans. See Gallo v. Amoco Corp., 
    102 F.3d 918
    , 920-22 (7th
    Cir. 1996); McDaniel v. Chevron Corp., 
    203 F.3d 1099
    , 1113-
    14 (9th Cir. 2000); Allen v. Adage, Inc., 
    967 F.2d 695
    , 702-03
    (1st Cir. 1992); Schultz v. Metropolitan Life Ins. Co., 
    872 F.2d 676
    , 679-80 (5th Cir. 1989).
    And it’s no surprise that the discount rate in the
    Excess Plan should be as high as it is. “Top hat” plans
    provide gravy for highly compensated employees, and
    one expects them to be less risk averse than other em-
    ployees, hence more likely to prefer taking their benefits
    in a lump sum, which they can invest in risky ventures
    with a high expected return—financial risk and return
    being positively correlated. If interest rates turned out
    to exceed the discount rate in the plan, the lump sum
    generated by the plan rate would confer a windfall on
    the participant, for remember that the lower the dis-
    10                                             No. 12-2407
    count rate, the larger the lump sum, which the recipient
    can invest at whatever current interest rates are. MONY
    minimizes its exposure by fixing a high discount rate,
    which both reduces the size of its lump sum outlays
    and encourages plan participants to choose the annuity
    over the lump sum option, since, the smaller the lump
    sum relative to the annuity, the more attractive the
    annuity is.
    That leaves for decision only the plaintiff’s claim to
    be allowed discovery to determine whether a conflict of
    interest vitiates the rejection of his interpretation by
    the plans’ benefits appeals committee. He thinks it suspi-
    cious that the committee upheld the ruling, initially
    made by a benefits administrator, on a ground different
    from the administrator’s. There is nothing suspicious
    about such a sequence (which is common in adjudica-
    tion) if the committee’s ground is valid. But he also
    points out that the RISPE plan was having financial
    troubles in 2009 (unsurprisingly, given the state of the
    economy then), which required MONY to make
    additional contributions to the plan. And because the
    Excess Plan is not funded at all, the benefits payable
    under it come directly out of the company’s pocket
    rather than out of a trust fund. At the oral argument the
    plaintiff’s lawyer told us that MONY’s liability to the
    class if the class action is successful would be in
    the neighborhood of $10 million—a large sum, though
    we haven’t been told the size of either RIPSE or the
    Excess Plan, and MONY’s parent company, AXA,
    manages $450 billion in assets and has $18 billion in
    equity. See Axa Equitable, 10-Q Consolidated Balance Sheet,
    No. 12-2407                                             11
    September 30, 2012, www.sec.gov/cgi-bin/viewer?action=
    view&cik=727920&accession_number=0001193125-12-
    462659 (visited Feb. 19, 2013).
    The plaintiff wants as a first step to see the minutes of
    the meeting at which the committee voted to deny his
    claims. But his lawyer made clear at oral argument that
    if he received them this would be followed by his
    deposing the committee’s members.
    We do not think that benefits review officers should
    be subjected to extensive discovery on a thinly based
    suspicion that their decision was tainted by a conflict of
    interest. There is a latent conflict of interest any time
    someone is asking for money from a company (from
    anyone, in fact), though it is muted to an extent if the
    party asking is an employee or former employee, since
    good relations with employees are a corporate asset.
    Marrs v. Motorola, Inc., 
    577 F.3d 783
    , 787 (7th Cir. 2009).
    Formal adjudicators, such as judges, jurors, arbitrators,
    administrative law judges, and members of appellate
    boards of agencies, are largely insulated by immunity
    doctrines from interrogatories and depositions aimed
    at finding evidence of conflicts of interest. Informal
    adjudicators, such as members of a pension fund’s
    benefits review committee, have a legitimate claim to a
    degree of similar protection from discovery, used so
    often as a form of harassment. Courts are drowning in
    discovery; imagine the burdens, not only on them but
    on employers, of discovery requests that must be
    complied with every time there is a colorable claim
    that private pension or welfare benefits were wrongly
    12                                              No. 12-2407
    denied. Especially in a class action suit with a thousand
    or more class members, the burdens on the benefits
    review process of discovery in search of evidence of
    a conflict of interest could be considerable.
    Moved by such concerns we held in Semien v. Life Ins. Co.
    of North America, 
    436 F.3d 805
    , 815 (7th Cir. 2006), that
    discovery in a case challenging the benefits determina-
    tion of plan administrators is permissible only in “excep-
    tional” circumstances—circumstances in which the claim-
    ant can “identify a specific conflict of interest or instance
    of misconduct” and “make a prima facie showing that
    there is good cause to believe limited discovery will
    reveal a procedural defect.” The continued validity of
    that holding has been questioned, however, see, e.g.,
    Gessling v. Group Long Term Disability Plan for Employees
    of Sprint/United Mgmt. Co., 1:07-cv-483-DFH-DML, 
    2008 WL 5070434
     (S.D. Ind. Nov. 26, 2008), in light of the
    Supreme Court’s decision, subsequent to Semien, in Metro-
    politan Life Ins. Co. v. Glenn, 
    554 U.S. 105
     (2008).
    Glenn is not about discovery, but it implies a role for
    discovery in judicial review of benefits determinations
    when a conflict of interest is alleged. Murphy v. Deloitte
    & Touche Group Ins. Plan, 
    619 F.3d 1151
    , 1161-64 (10th
    Cir. 2010). How big a role is the question. We have inter-
    preted the Supreme Court’s opinion to mean that “the
    likelihood that the conflict of interest influenced the deci-
    sion [of the plan administrator] is . . . the decisive con-
    sideration” in whether to uphold a decision “that
    might just as well have gone the other way.” Marrs
    v. Motorola, Inc., supra, 
    577 F.3d at 789
     (emphasis in origi-
    No. 12-2407                                                13
    nal). In other words, while “the correct standard of
    review to be applied [if the plan delegates interpretive
    authority to the plan administrator] . . . remains [after
    Glenn] the arbitrary and capricious standard, . . one of the
    factors that must be taken into account in applying that
    standard is any conflict of interest.” Fischer v. Liberty Life
    Assurance Co., 
    576 F.3d 369
    , 375 (7th Cir. 2009). And to
    determine the likelihood and gravity of a conflict of
    interest might require discovery to “identify a specific
    conflict of interest or instance of misconduct,” a task of
    identification that in Semien we said was a prerequisite to
    discovery, not a goal of discovery.
    These cases suggest a softening, but not a rejection, of
    the standard announced in Semien; and there can be no
    doubt that even when some discovery is necessary in
    a particular case to explore a conflict of interest, trial
    courts retain broad discretion to limit and manage dis-
    covery under Rule 26 of the civil rules.
    With the case law in flux, this is not the occasion for
    our trying to trace out the contours of permissible dis-
    covery under ERISA. The reader may have noticed that
    in discussing the plaintiff’s claim to be entitled to the
    lower discount rate, we said nothing about deferring to
    the benefits committee’s decision; we sang no hosannas
    to discretion. We treated the claim as if it were a claim
    of breach of contract that had been rejected by a
    district court and was being reviewed by us de novo. We
    had no occasion to defer to a plan administrator’s deter-
    mination with which we might disagree—the only situa-
    tion in which a deferential standard of judicial review
    bites. For we agreed with it.
    14                                            No. 12-2407
    The plaintiff could argue that if discovery were permit-
    ted and turned up evidence of a conflict of interest
    serious enough to vitiate the decision of the benefits
    appeals committee, he would be entitled to a further
    hearing. But a hearing before whom? Any committee
    composed of plan officials would have the same conflict
    of interest. The plaintiff would want the district court
    to conduct the hearing. In other words, he would want
    to convert this to a straightforward breach of contract
    case. And he would want us to review the district
    court’s decision de novo. Well, that’s what we’ve done;
    and we’ve concluded that even under that favorable (to
    the plaintiff) standard of review, which gives no weight
    to the decision of the benefits appeals committee, the
    committee’s ruling must stand.
    A FFIRMED.
    3-6-13