Ricardo Vasquez v. Indiana University Health, Inc ( 2022 )


Menu:
  •                                In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    ____________________
    No. 21‐3109
    RICARDO VASQUEZ,
    Plaintiff‐Appellant,
    v.
    INDIANA UNIVERSITY HEALTH, INC., et al.,
    Defendants‐Appellees.
    ____________________
    Appeal from the United States District Court for the
    Southern District of Indiana, Indianapolis Division.
    No. 21‐cv‐1693 — Jane Magnus‐Stinson, Judge.
    ____________________
    ARGUED APRIL 8, 2022 — DECIDED JULY 8, 2022
    ____________________
    Before WOOD, HAMILTON, and JACKSON‐AKIWUMI, Circuit
    Judges.
    WOOD, Circuit Judge. Dr. Ricardo Vasquez is a vascular sur‐
    geon; he has practiced in Bloomington, Indiana, since 2006.
    Vasquez alleges that in the time since he opened up shop, In‐
    diana University Health (IU Health) has amassed considera‐
    ble market power in the region’s medical industry. Vasquez
    sued IU Health, claiming antitrust violations under the Sher‐
    man Act, 
    15 U.S.C. §§ 1
    –7, and the Clayton Act, 
    id.
     §§ 12–27.
    2                                                 No. 21‐3109
    IU Health moved to dismiss, arguing that neither the Sher‐
    man Act nor the Clayton Act claims were premised on a plau‐
    sible geographic market, and that the Clayton Act claims also
    were time‐barred. The district court agreed on both points
    and dismissed the suit. But Vasquez’s allegations passed mus‐
    ter for the pleading stage, and so we reverse.
    I
    We begin with a few more details about Bloomington and
    the surrounding region, Vasquez’s practice, IU Health’s his‐
    tory in the market, and the complaint’s allegations. At this
    stage, we accept all well‐pleaded facts as true and draw all
    reasonable inferences in Vasquez’s favor. Mashallah, Inc. v.
    West Bend Mut. Ins. Co., 
    20 F.4th 311
    , 317 (7th Cir. 2021).
    Bloomington is a city in Monroe County, Indiana, with a
    population of about 90,000. The surrounding metropolitan
    statistical area has a population of about 200,000. Blooming‐
    ton is the largest metro area in its corner of southwestern In‐
    diana. From Bloomington, one can drive an hour and ten
    minutes northeast to Indianapolis (population 865,000); two
    hours southwest to Evansville (population 120,000); two
    hours southeast to Louisville, Kentucky (population 620,000);
    or two and a half hours east to Cincinnati, Ohio (population
    300,000). Most of the region bounded by those larger cities is
    rural, albeit spotted with small cities and large towns.
    Vasquez arrived in Bloomington in 2006 and soon after
    opened an independent vascular‐surgery practice. Many vas‐
    cular‐surgery patients require treatment with specialized
    equipment in a hospital setting, and so Vasquez sought and
    obtained admitting privileges at three different area hospitals:
    Bloomington Hospital, Monroe Hospital, and the Indiana
    No. 21‐3109                                                      3
    Specialty Surgery Center. Vasquez performed the lion’s share
    of his inpatient procedures (over 95%) at Bloomington Hospi‐
    tal, which had the best equipment.
    IU Health entered the Bloomington market in 2010 when
    it acquired Bloomington Hospital. (At the time, IU Health was
    known as Clarian Health Partners; it rebranded in 2011. Clar‐
    ian was formed by the merger of three Indianapolis‐area hos‐
    pitals in 1997.) In May 2017, IU Health expanded its footprint
    in southwestern Indiana by acquiring Premier Healthcare, an
    independent physician group based in Bloomington. At the
    time of the acquisition, Premier employed many of the re‐
    gion’s doctors, especially primary‐care providers (PCPs).
    Vasquez alleges that, as a consequence of the Premier acqui‐
    sition, IU Health now employs 97% of PCPs in Bloomington
    and over 80% of PCPs in the wider region.
    Vasquez’s alleged problems with IU Health began shortly
    after the Premier acquisition. At this early stage, little turns on
    the details, so we can be brief. Vasquez contends that in
    “[a]pproximately 2017,” around the time of the acquisition, IU
    Health launched “a systematic and targeted scheme” to ruin
    his reputation and practice. The scheme was motivated by
    Vasquez’s commitment to independent practice. IU Health
    preferred to employ the region’s doctors directly, an agenda
    which Vasquez resisted. In June 2018, IU Health threatened to
    revoke Vasquez’s privileges at Bloomington Hospital, and its
    employees began to cast aspersions on his reputation—alleg‐
    ing, for example, that he had been sued with unusual fre‐
    quency. Needless to say, Vasquez disputes the factual accu‐
    racy of these claims. In April 2019, IU Health followed
    through on its threat, revoking Vasquez’s Bloomington ad‐
    mitting privileges.
    4                                                   No. 21‐3109
    In June 2021, Vasquez filed this lawsuit. IU Health moved,
    successfully, to dismiss, and Vasquez now appeals.
    II
    Vasquez’s appeal raises three issues: (1) the dismissal of
    his claims under Sherman Act section 2, 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    , and
    Clayton Act section 7, 
    id.
     § 18, for failure to allege a proper
    geographic market; (2) the dismissal of the Clayton Act claims
    on timeliness grounds; and (3) the decision not to give him
    one opportunity to amend his complaint before dismissing
    with prejudice. We review the first two issues de novo, Warciak
    v. Subway Restaurants, Inc., 
    949 F.3d 354
    , 356 (7th Cir. 2020),
    and the third for abuse of discretion.
    A
    We begin with the geographic‐market analysis. Vasquez’s
    complaint needed to allege only one plausible geographic
    market to survive a motion to dismiss. See Bell Atlantic Corp.
    v. Twombly, 
    550 U.S. 544
    , 555 (2007). A rational jury could find
    that Bloomington is such a market, as we now explain.
    In FTC v. Advocate Health Care Network, 
    841 F.3d 460
     (7th
    Cir. 2016) (“Advocate”), a case concerning a hospital merger,
    we endorsed the use of the “hypothetical monopolist test” to
    analyze geographic healthcare markets. As a general matter,
    that test asks “what would happen if a single firm became the
    only seller in a candidate geographic region.” 
    Id. at 468
    . “If
    that hypothetical monopolist could profitably raise prices
    above competitive levels, the region is a relevant geographic
    market.” 
    Id.
     But if, instead, “customers would defeat the at‐
    tempted price increase by buying from outside the region, it
    is not a relevant market; the test should be rerun using a larger
    candidate region.” 
    Id.
     In this sense, the inquiry “is iterative,
    No. 21‐3109                                                                    5
    meaning it should be repeated with ever‐larger candidates
    until it identifies a relevant geographic market.” 
    Id.
     Im‐
    portantly, the determination of the area of effective competi‐
    tion poses a question of fact, not one of law. See Fishman v.
    Estate of Wirtz, 
    807 F.2d 520
    , 531 (7th Cir. 1986).
    We see no reason to break with Advocate here. The hypo‐
    thetical‐monopolist test remains the best approach to geo‐
    graphic‐market analysis in the healthcare context. It focuses
    courts’ attention on the crucial question whether it is possible,
    within a given defined geographic area, for a hypothetical sin‐
    gle firm to engage in anticompetitive practices (i.e., raising
    price or reducing output, or otherwise harming consumer
    welfare). With that in mind, we turn to Vasquez’s arguments.
    Vasquez first posits that the vascular‐surgery market in
    Bloomington is inherently local. This is because “vascular sur‐
    gery patients need ongoing care, oftentimes lifetime care.” So,
    Vasquez reasons, if a Bloomington patient “is sent to Indian‐
    apolis, that patient must continue to travel for a lifetime if he
    or she wants continuity of care.” And because most patients
    would consider that a bad deal—as Advocate recognized, see
    841 F.3d at 470—insurers (the most directly affected buyers
    here) face pressure to provide vascular surgery in or near
    Bloomington.1 An insurer that does not provide such care
    1  We note in this connection that the antitrust laws confer a right of
    action on “any person … injured in his business or property,” see 
    15 U.S.C. § 15
    , and that the Supreme Court has confirmed that both consumers, such
    as the insurers here, and competitors, such as Vasquez, fall within the
    scope of the law. See Assoc. Gen. Contractors of Cal., Inc. v. Cal. State Council
    of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
    , 538 (1983) (“[T]he Sherman Act was enacted to
    assure customers the benefits of price competition, and [the Court’s] prior
    6                                                           No. 21‐3109
    risks being outcompeted by other insurers within Blooming‐
    ton. It follows that a hypothetical monopolist over vascular
    surgery in Bloomington would be able to abuse its market
    power considerably by jacking up payor prices and freezing
    out potential competitors. In particular, because much vascu‐
    lar surgery is performed in a hospital setting with special
    equipment, a hypothetical vertically integrated monopolist
    that controlled the hospital, the equipment, and most of the
    surgeons would be well‐positioned to engage in anticompet‐
    itive practices.
    Vasquez also alleges that vascular surgeons’ reliance on
    referrals makes Bloomington an appropriate geographic mar‐
    ket in a second sense. The idea is that while Bloomington res‐
    idents may be willing to travel to Indianapolis for some cate‐
    gories of specialist care, they will not be willing to drive an
    hour or more for routine primary care. Bloomington, after all,
    has two hospitals, a medical‐school campus, and a metro pop‐
    ulation that ought to be more than adequate to support a
    healthy, competitive primary‐care practice market. All agree
    that vascular surgeons, who are specialists, get most patients
    by referral from primary‐care providers. Thus, a hypothetical
    monopolist over primary‐care services in Bloomington would
    control not only that market but also the flow of patients to
    vascular surgeons. By cutting off the flow of new patients to
    its vascular‐surgery competitors, the monopolist could cap‐
    ture the entire market, thereby positioning itself to raise payor
    prices without repercussion.
    cases have emphasized the central interest in protecting the economic free‐
    dom of participants in the relevant market”).
    No. 21‐3109                                                   7
    Both stories are plausible accounts of how a hypothetical
    monopolist could wield anticompetitive power in Blooming‐
    ton’s vascular‐surgery market. We could stop there; at the
    pleading stage, a plausible scenario is all we require to estab‐
    lish the geographic market. But as it happens, Vasquez goes
    considerably further. He alleges not only that a hypothetical
    monopolist could dominate the Bloomington market in the
    two ways he suggests but also that IU Health already does so.
    With regard to vascular surgery itself, Vasquez contends that
    IU Health controls the hospital with the most advanced
    equipment and, other than him, all the vascular surgeons.
    And regarding upstream referrals, he alleges without contra‐
    diction that IU Health employs 97% of the primary‐care phy‐
    sicians in Bloomington, meaning that virtually every patient
    sees an IU Health PCP. (That is one reason why the existence
    of other hospitals in the Bloomington area does not neces‐
    sarily defeat Vasquez’s claim.) To repeat: these contentions
    are by no means necessary in order adequately to plead a ge‐
    ographic market. But they are sufficient. The hypothetical‐
    monopolist test concerns hypotheticals, as it says on the label,
    not realities. But the detailed allegations about the on‐the‐
    ground realities in Bloomington drive home the key point:
    Vasquez’s allegations easily clear the plausibility bar.
    This is not the time to evaluate the merits of Vasquez’s al‐
    legations, and that in any event is a task that requires expert
    testimony. The motion‐to‐dismiss stage does not lend itself to
    rigorous hypothetical‐monopolist analysis. Normally, the
    way that analysis is conducted is by survey. Experts canvass
    a representative sample of local market participants, asking
    about both their actual behavior in the market as it is and how
    it would change if certain hypothetical conditions came to
    pass. Here, for instance, an expert might try to determine at
    8                                                              No. 21‐3109
    what price point an insurer would stop paying for vascular‐
    surgery services in Bloomington, opting instead to cover only
    patients who went to specialists in Indianapolis. It may turn
    out that Indianapolis providers are close enough to act as a
    market check on any and all price increases. If so, Blooming‐
    ton would not be a geographic market. But for present pur‐
    poses, we cannot substitute our own speculations for the req‐
    uisite analysis.2
    It is worth recalling at this juncture what is required in a
    pleading. As the Supreme Court put it in Twombly, “a com‐
    plaint attacked by a Rule 12(b)(6) motion to dismiss does not
    need detailed factual allegations … .” 
    550 U.S. at 555
    . Indeed,
    the allegations do not even need to establish the probability
    of the plaintiff’s recovery. 
    Id. at 556
    . They need only present
    “enough fact to raise a reasonable expectation that discovery
    will reveal evidence” of illegal acts. 
    Id.
     So too in this case, we
    need not decide whether Vasquez’s story is probable; we are
    assessing only its plausibility.
    The district court found Vasquez’s complaint wanting for
    two reasons. First, it thought that Vasquez’s geographic‐mar‐
    ket allegations were contradictory. The purported contradic‐
    tion was between two factual claims in the complaint: (1) that
    2 We note, in this connection, that Vasquez alleges an alternative mar‐
    ket, “Southern Indiana,” which he defines to include Morgan, Owen,
    Monroe, Brown, Greene, Daviess, Martin, Lawrence, Orange, and Wash‐
    ington counties. For present purposes, we focus on Bloomington, both be‐
    cause it is the smallest plausible market alleged and because the alterna‐
    tive market includes it. That said, the Southern Indiana market may turn
    out to be the best object of analysis as this litigation progresses and further
    facts emerge. Our present attention to the Bloomington market should in
    no way be taken to limit the parties to arguments about that market.
    No. 21‐3109                                                    9
    patients “prefer to stay within Bloomington to receive care,”
    and (2) that “many of the patients who arrive at Bloomington
    Hospital for care travel from rural areas, some of them up to
    two hours away.” The district court saw an inconsistency be‐
    tween the two claims, and it thought that clash undermined
    the Bloomington market’s plausibility.
    We see several problems with this reasoning. First, Federal
    Rule of Civil Procedure 8(d)(3) specifically permits contradic‐
    tory pleadings, and so this criticism was misplaced. And in
    any event, our own examination of the allegations persuades
    us that they are not contradictory at all. They concern two dif‐
    ferent groups of people—urban and rural patients—with dif‐
    ferent expectations, motivations, and market behaviors.
    Bloomington is a regional hub, home to a major university
    and substantial medical infrastructure. Patients who reside
    there no doubt expect to get most medical care close to home.
    Patients in surrounding rural communities, in contrast, real‐
    istically expect to travel to hospitals in large cities when the
    alternative is getting sick or dying, though they may other‐
    wise prefer to purchase services at home in Loogootee (popu‐
    lation 2,751) or French Lick (population 1,841). Both allega‐
    tions could be true; indeed, both are true in many places. On
    top of that, the allegation about two‐hour travel is hardly the
    linchpin of Vasquez’s theory of the geographic market. It
    comprises two clauses buried thirty pages into the complaint,
    in the context of a tangential discussion of the impacts IU
    Health’s alleged monopoly has on patients. And even assum‐
    ing some level of tension between Vasquez’s allegations, a fi‐
    nal problem is that the district court did not attempt to situate
    that tension in any antitrust market‐analysis doctrine. A con‐
    tradiction could undermine a market’s plausibility if it
    10                                                   No. 21‐3109
    showed that the alleged market failed the hypothetical‐mo‐
    nopolist test. But we do not see how that could be true here.
    The district court also reasoned that Bloomington could
    not be “the appropriate geographic market” if “a significant
    portion of [IU Health’s] patients regularly travel substantial
    distances to get to Bloomington.” But this confuses two dif‐
    ferent sorts of market. The geographic market for an antitrust
    claim need not—and very often will not—correspond to the
    comprehensive market that the alleged monopolist serves.
    See United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 
    353 U.S. 586
    ,
    593 (1957) (explaining that “the bounds of a relevant market
    for the purposes of [a] case” need not be “coextensive with the
    total market”). At the fringes, even a monopolist is likely to
    face competition. Under Advocate, 841 F.3d at 476, the appro‐
    priate object of the geographic‐market analysis is the smallest
    market a hypothetical monopolist could dominate. Patient
    flows may help to define the borders of that market, but such
    flows are just one piece of data in the broader picture—they
    are not likely to be dispositive. To hold otherwise would be to
    carve a large loophole into antitrust law; realistically, some
    fuzziness about market boundaries will occur in most cases.
    To sum up: Either of Vasquez’s accounts of how a hypo‐
    thetical monopolist could dominate Bloomington’s vascular‐
    surgery market suffice for the pleading stage. Dismissal was
    thus not warranted.
    B
    The district court also gave a second reason for dismissing
    Vasquez’s Clayton Act claims (but not his Sherman Act
    claims): timeliness. The Clayton Act’s statute of limitations
    requires a damages action to be “commenced within four
    No. 21‐3109                                                   11
    years after the cause of action accrued.” 15 U.S.C. § 15b. The
    district court understood that requirement to bar Vasquez’s
    Clayton Act damages claim, and by analogy applied the equi‐
    table doctrine of laches to bar his injunctive claims. (Like the
    district court, we treat the laches defense at issue here as ris‐
    ing or falling with the statute of limitations defense, though it
    need not in every case.)
    Timeliness is an affirmative defense. “An antitrust cause
    of action accrues and the statute begins to run when a defend‐
    ant commits an act that injures a plaintiffʹs business.” In re
    Copper Antitrust Litig., 
    436 F.3d 782
    , 789 (7th Cir. 2006)
    (cleaned up). That rule “is qualified by the discovery rule,
    which postpones the beginning of the limitations period from
    the date when the plaintiff is wronged to the date when he
    discovers he has been injured.” 
    Id.
     (cleaned up). We have ap‐
    plied a demanding standard to dismissals on timeliness
    grounds at the pleading stage of antitrust cases, asking
    whether “the plaintiff pleads itself out of court.” Xechem, Inc.
    v. Bristol‐Myers Squibb Co., 
    372 F.3d 899
    , 902 (7th Cir. 2004).
    Vasquez did not. To be sure, he filed suit four years and
    one month after IU Health acquired Premier. So, if that acqui‐
    sition started the clock, Vasquez missed his window by a
    month. But to affirm the dismissal, we would need to be sure
    that the undisputed facts show that the operative injury both
    occurred and was discovered at the moment of acquisition (or
    at the latest, during the following month). But the complaint
    does not paint such a one‐sided picture.
    The earliest potential injury the complaint identifies is its
    allegation of a “systematic and targeted scheme to ruin Dr.
    Vasquez’s reputation and practice” in “approximately 2017,
    around the time that IU Health acquired Premier.” But
    12                                                 No. 21‐3109
    “[a]round the time” plausibly could mean “six weeks after,”
    which would be enough to save the Clayton Act claims for
    now. Nor do we have enough information, at this stage, to
    ascertain exactly when Vasquez learned of the purported
    scheme, which is what really matters. Another plausible
    measuring stick occurred a year later, in June 2018, when IU
    Health’s anti‐Vasquez vendetta is alleged to have started in
    earnest. That is when, for instance, IU Health employees be‐
    gan to suggest that Vasquez had often been sued and to
    threaten termination of privileges. A third plausible measur‐
    ing stick is the actual revocation of Vasquez’s privileges in
    April 2019—the event that one assumes would have had the
    most concrete impact on Vasquez’s income. Until IU Health
    took that step, Vasquez reasonably may have thought that an
    accommodation was possible.
    Without discovery, choosing among these alternatives is
    difficult, if not impossible. What matters is that the complaint
    presents a plausible account under which his suit is timely.
    We note as well that timeliness is an affirmative defense and
    thus normally (and here) is not properly resolved at the Rule
    12(b)(6) stage.
    III
    Given our disposition of Vasquez’s principal arguments,
    we have no need to discuss his request to file an amended
    complaint. The district court’s grant of IU Health’s motion to
    dismiss is REVERSED and the case is REMANDED for further pro‐
    ceedings consistent with this opinion.