Reifert v. South Central Wisconsin MLS Corp. , 450 F.3d 312 ( 2006 )


Menu:
  •                            In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    ____________
    No. 05-3601
    JAY REIFERT,
    Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.
    SOUTH CENTRAL WISCONSIN MLS CORPORATION,
    REALTORS ASSOCIATION OF SOUTH CENTRAL
    WISCONSIN, INC., ROBERT L. COURTER, SUSAN
    MATTHEWS, DAVID STARK, ROBERT WEBER,
    THOMAS BUNBURY, MAURICE W. HILL, PETER SVEUM,
    MARSHALL ZWYGART, and DAVID MCGRATH,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    ____________
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Western District of Wisconsin.
    Case No. 04-C-0969-S—John C. Shabaz, Judge.
    ____________
    ARGUED FEBRUARY 17, 2006—DECIDED JUNE 12, 2006
    ____________
    Before FLAUM, Chief Judge, and KANNE and WOOD,
    Circuit Judges.
    FLAUM, Chief Judge. Plaintiff-Appellant Jay Reifert
    claims that the defendants violated the Sherman Act by
    tying access to a real estate multi-listing service (“MLS”) to
    membership in a Realtors Association. The district
    court granted summary judgment for all defendants in
    this case, finding no competition in the tied market and
    therefore, no antitrust violation.
    2                                                 No. 05-3601
    For the following reasons, we now affirm the judgment of
    the district court.
    I. Background
    Realtors Association of South Central Wisconsin, Inc.
    (“RASCW”) is a real estate trade association. Its members
    are real estate agents and appraisers in and around
    Madison, Wisconsin. RASCW offers a variety of products
    and services to its members, including lobbying, social
    functions, courses, referral programs, contract forms,
    conventions, publications, and legal information.
    RASCW is associated with the Wisconsin Realtors
    Association and the National Association of Realtors
    (“NAR”). When a person pays membership dues to an
    association affiliated with NAR, that person becomes a
    member of NAR. Normally, Realtors Association1 member-
    ships are packaged as a group including local, state, and
    NAR memberships.
    RASCW owns 100% of the stock in the South Central
    Wisconsin MLS Corp. (“SCWMLS”). The MLS or multiple
    listing service is a computerized database of homes and
    properties listed for sale by SCWMLS participants in south-
    central Wisconsin. Access to this multiple listing service is a
    necessity for real estate agents and appraisers in this area.
    Virtually all active residential real estate agents in the
    region subscribe to SCWMLS. Users are charged a quar-
    terly fee to gain access to the full database and must be a
    member of a Realtors Association affiliated with NAR. The
    Realtors Association membership requirement has existed
    1
    “Realtors Associations” are organizations affiliated with the
    National Association of Realtors and have agreed to abide by the
    NAR Code of Ethics. RASCW is an example of a local Realtors
    Association.
    No. 05-3601                                                 3
    for more than fifty years. Generally, any licensed real estate
    professional who agrees to abide by the NAR Code of Ethics
    and pays the applicable fees is admitted.
    Article 16 of NAR’s Code of Ethics contains a “non-solicita-
    tion” rule. This article and the related standards of practice
    prohibit members from inducing sellers to breach listing
    contracts, advising sellers of superior services or prices
    during the time they are under contract with another
    Realtor, and using “information received through a Multiple
    Listing Service . . . to target clients of other Realtors®.”
    A member-elected board of directors sets dues for
    RASCW. Fees for SCWMLS are also set by members elected
    to a board of directors. Both organizations set their fees
    solely to cover operational costs, with no profit-making
    intent. Annual dues to join the NAR, Wisconsin Association
    of Realtors, and RASCW are approximately $449 a year.
    The plaintiff, Jay Reifert, brings three claims against
    SCWMLS, RASCW, and the directors of SCWMLS. First, he
    alleges that SCWMLS unlawfully ties its services to
    RASCW. Second, Reifert alleges that by conditioning access
    to MLS service on membership in RASCW, an unlawful
    group boycott has occurred. Finally, Reifert alleges that
    Article 16 of the NAR Code of Ethics violates the Section I
    of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    , by prohibiting competi-
    tion.
    Reifert, is a residential real estate broker, exclusively
    representing buyers of real estate in south central Wiscon-
    sin. Reifert has been a member of RASCW (or its predeces-
    sor) and a participant in SCWMLS (or its predecessor) since
    1988. Reifert belongs to the National Association of Exclu-
    sive Buyer’s Agents (“NAEBA”) and has no desire to
    maintain membership in RASCW or the state and national
    Association of Realtors. Reifert objects to the fees he is
    forced to pay for unwanted services and the Code of Ethics
    he must follow to maintain his membership in RASCW and
    NAR.
    4                                                No. 05-3601
    Reifert claims that during the four years at issue in this
    action, he has paid dues in excess of $2000 for an unwanted
    RASCW membership to maintain his SCWMLS access.
    During the relevant four-year period, there have been
    approximately 2,079 annual and 5,600 total SCWMLS
    participants.
    To support an antitrust action, a plaintiff must demon-
    strate that the defendant’s actions have restrained competi-
    tion. Section I of the Sherman Act states, “Every contract,
    combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy,
    in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States
    . . . is declared to be illegal.” 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    . The Supreme
    Court has long recognized that Congress intended to outlaw
    only “unreasonable restraints,” not all contracts in restraint
    of trade. See State Oil Co. v. Khan, 
    522 U.S. 3
    , 10 (1997)
    (citations omitted). The Clayton Act allows for private suits
    by individuals injured by violations of antitrust laws. See 
    15 U.S.C. §§ 15
    , 26.
    On August 25, 2005, the district court granted summary
    judgment to the defendants and denied summary judg-
    ment to the plaintiff. A tying arrangement violates federal
    antitrust statutes if it has a substantial effect on interstate
    commerce. The district court found that “there is insuffi-
    cient evidence for a fact finder to find that a tie between the
    defendant’s multiple listing service and Realtor member-
    ship has had an effect on interstate commerce as that
    element has been defined by the Supreme Court.”
    As to Reifert’s group boycott claim, the district court
    again found that the plaintiff had failed to prove any anti-
    competitive effects resulting from the tying of Realtors
    Association memberships to MLS services. Accordingly, the
    district court granted summary judgment to the defendants.
    No. 05-3601                                                5
    II. Discussion
    We review a district court’s grant of summary judgment
    de novo, taking all facts in the light most favorable to the
    non-moving party. See, e.g., McCoy v. Harrison, 
    341 F.3d 600
    , 604 (7th Cir. 2003) (citations omitted). An award of
    summary judgment is proper when “there is no genuine
    issue as to any material fact and that the moving party is
    entitled to a judgment as a matter of law.” FED. R. CIV. P.
    56(c); Celotex Corp. v. Catrett, 
    477 U.S. 317
    , 322-23 (1986).
    A. Tying Claim
    Reifert claims that the defendants have engaged in an
    unlawful tying arrangement by limiting SCWMLS access to
    members of a Relators Association. Thus, the alleged “tying
    product” is SCWMLS and the alleged “tied product” is
    membership in a Realtors Association.
    In determining whether a violation of Section I of the
    Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    , has occurred as a result of a tie
    between two products or services, this Court requires the
    plaintiff to prove four elements. See Carl Sandburg Vill.
    Condo. Ass’n No. 1 v. First Condo. Dev. Co., 
    758 F.2d 203
    ,
    208 (7th Cir. 1985) (citing imposition of the “economic
    interest requirement . . . by courts in the Second, Third,
    Fourth, Fifth, Sixth, Ninth, and Eleventh Circuits”).
    In order to establish the per se illegality of a tying
    arrangement, a plaintiff must show that: (1) the tying
    arrangement is between two distinct products or
    services, (2) the defendant has sufficient economic
    power in the tying market to appreciably restrain free
    competition in the market for the tied product, and (3)
    a not insubstantial amount of interstate commerce is
    affected. [ N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    ,
    5-6 (1958)]; Moore v. Matthews & Co., 
    550 F.2d 1207
    ,
    1212 (9th Cir. 1977). In addition, this circuit has held
    6                                                      No. 05-3601
    that an illegal tying arrangement will not be found
    where the alleged tying company has absolutely no
    economic interest in the sales of the tied seller, whose
    products are favored by the tie-in. Ohio-Sealy Mattress
    Mfg. Co. v. Sealy, Inc., 
    585 F.2d 821
    , 835 (7th Cir.
    1978), cert. denied, 
    440 U.S. 930
     (1979); Warner Mgmt.
    Consultants, Inc. v. Data Gen. Corp., 
    545 F.Supp. 956
    ,
    967 (N.D.Ill. 1982).
    Id. at 207-08.
    Following this precedent, the district court correctly
    required Reifert to prove the following four elements of a
    tying violation: (1) a tie exists between two separate
    products; (2) the tying seller (SCWMLS) has sufficient
    economic power in the tying product market to restrain free
    competition in the tied product market (Realtors Associa-
    tion memberships); (3) the tie affects a not-insubstantial
    amount of interstate commerce in the tied product (Realtors
    Association memberships); and (4) the tying seller
    (SCWMLS) has some economic interest in the sales of the
    tied product (Realtors Association memberships). Id. at
    207.2
    2
    We agree with our concurring colleague that a cautious
    approach is always appropriate when anticipating future Supreme
    Court actions. In 1985, our Circuit began to incorporate the rule
    of reason in our tying analysis. At that time, we stated that,
    “According to the Supreme Court, a plaintiff ’s failure to state a
    per se illegal antitrust claim does not necessarily prove fatal to his
    case if he can state a claim under the rule of reason.” Carl
    Sandburg Vill. Condo. Ass’n No. 1, 
    758 F.2d 203
    , 210 (7th Cir.
    1985) (citing Fortner Enter., Inc. v. United States Steel Corp., 
    394 U.S. 495
    , 499-500 (1969); Warner Mgmt. Consultants, Inc. v. Data
    Gen. Corp., 
    545 F. Supp. 956
    , 966 (N.D. Ill. 1982)); see also
    Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    , 35 (1984)
    (O’Connor, J., concurring) (“The time has therefore come to
    (continued...)
    No. 05-3601                                                         7
    There is no question that Reifert has satisfied the require-
    ments for the first two elements. First, access to the multi-
    listing service cannot be obtained without purchasing the
    tied product, a Realtors Association membership. Second,
    SCWMLS has sufficient market power to restrain free
    competition in the tied product market.
    SCWMLS is a unique product. Nearly every available
    home in the relevant geographic area is listed on the
    service. The near-perfect market information created by
    SCWMLS is the result of a requirement that members place
    all listings in the MLS within five days. The MLS allows
    individuals with access to search and filter properties based
    upon detailed criteria including compensation offered to
    buyers’ agents, detailed property information, neighborhood
    information, prior sales history, offers made on the prop-
    erty, days on the market, and the sale price of comparable
    homes. The features and information available through
    SCWMLS are not available through any other service. In
    addition, the MLS service targets a different audience—real
    estate agents and appraisers—than free listing services or
    newspapers. In short, it is impossible to perform the tasks
    of a real estate agent or appraiser in the relevant geo-
    2
    (...continued)
    abandon the ‘per se’ label and refocus the inquiry on the adverse
    economic effects, and the potential economic benefits, that the
    tie may have.”). In a related area, the Supreme Court recently
    adopted Justice O’Connor’s reasoning in Jefferson Parish Hosp.
    Dist. No. 2 and held that tying arrangements involving patents
    should be evaluated based upon their market power “rather than
    under the per se rule.” Ill. Tool Works, Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 
    126 S.Ct. 1281
     (2006). Although the per se analysis of the Jefferson
    Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 majority has not been expressly over-
    ruled, in the intervening twenty-one years since Carl Sandburg
    Vill. Condo. Ass’n No. 1, the Supreme Court has not found
    occasion to disagree with this Circuit’s approach.
    8                                               No. 05-3601
    graphic area without using SCWMLS. Thus, it possesses
    sufficient market power to restrain competition.
    The third element of the Sandburg test states that a tying
    arrangement violates antitrust law only if “a substantial
    volume of commerce is foreclosed” because of the tie.
    Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    , 16
    (1984). This element can be broken into two sub-questions:
    (1) Is there at least one competitor in the tied product
    market other than the favored seller; and (2) Is the quantity
    of interstate commerce affected not-insubstantial?
    The district court found no competition in the allegedly
    tied market for Realtors Association memberships. Where
    there is no competition in the tied market, there can be no
    antitrust violation. Forcing a buyer to purchase a product
    he otherwise would not have purchased is insufficient to
    establish the foreclosure of competition. 
    Id.
     (“[W]hen a
    purchaser is ‘forced’ to buy a product he would not have
    otherwise bought even from another seller in the tied
    product market, there can be no adverse impact on competi-
    tion because no portion of the market which would other-
    wise have been available to other sellers has been fore-
    closed.”).
    Despite Reifert’s desire to avoid purchasing a Realtors
    Association membership, without evidence of competitors in
    the market for services offered by the Realtors Association,
    there can be no foreclosure of competition. See Ohio-Sealy
    Mattress Mfg. Co. v. Sealy, Inc., 
    585 F.2d 821
    , 835 (7th Cir.
    1978); 9 PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP,
    ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1723a (2d ed. 2004) (“When there are no
    rival sellers of the tied product to be foreclosed, then the
    alleged tie-in might affect a substantial volume of commerce
    in the tied product and yet not foreclose anyone.”). The
    district court correctly found that despite the “laundry list
    of entities” submitted by the plaintiff, there were no
    competitors in the tied product market.
    No. 05-3601                                                 9
    Products and services are in the same market when they
    are good substitutes for one another. “The outer boundaries
    of a product market are determined by the reasonable
    interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand
    between the product itself and substitutes for it.” Brown
    Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 325 (1962).
    This Court requires that a plaintiff prove that products
    are good substitutes using economic evidence; a conclusory
    assumption of competition where products or services
    appear to be similar is insufficient. See Menasha Corp. v.
    News Am. Mktg. In-Store, Inc., 
    354 F.3d 661
    , 664 (7th Cir.
    2004). Actual data and a reasonable analysis are necessary
    to demonstrate that a product or service is a good substitute
    for another. “Economics, like the other social sciences, has
    its share of counterintuitive findings, so observing things
    that to the untutored eye seem to be substitutes need not
    mean that they are good substitutes.” 
    Id.
    Other federal courts have held that conditioning access to
    a multi-listing service on membership in a Realtors Associa-
    tion is not indicative of an unlawful tying arrangement. See
    Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Bd. of Realtors, 
    850 F.2d 803
     (1st Cir. 1988); O’Riordan v. Long Island Bd. of
    Realtors, Inc., 
    707 F. Supp. 111
     (E.D.N.Y. 1988); Buyer’s
    Corner Realty, Inc. v. No. Ky. Ass’n of Realtors, 
    410 F. Supp. 2d 574
     (E.D. Ky. 2006). One federal court has held that a
    tied real estate association group faced competition and
    therefore created an unlawful tie; as explained below,
    however, we find that case distinguishable. See Thompson
    v. Metro. Multi-List, Inc., 
    934 F.2d 1566
     (11th Cir. 1991).
    Reifert argues that by comparing participation in Realtors
    Associations in areas where MLS services are “open” to
    individuals who have not joined a Realtors Association with
    so called “closed” areas that require membership in a
    Realtors Association, he can demonstrate that agents have
    been forced to purchase Realtors Association memberships.
    This comparison is unreliable, however, because it fails to
    10                                              No. 05-3601
    speak to the central question of whether a competitor exists
    in this particular “closed” market and does not account for
    other possible explanations for the observed differences.
    Forcing individuals in Reifert’s position to purchase a
    product they do not want is not a violation of antitrust law.
    See Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2, 
    466 U.S. at 16
    .
    Even without an economic analysis, it is apparent that
    RASCW lacks competition. Each of the twelve organizations
    cited by Reifert fails to qualify as a competitor to the
    national or local Realtors Association:
    1.   Appraisal Institute (AI)- covers only appraisers
    2.   Asian Real Estate Agent Association (AREAA)—serves
    a distinct ethnic community
    3.   Chinese American Real Estate Professionals Associa-
    tion (CAREPA)—serves a distinct ethnic community
    4.   Chinese Real Estate Association of America
    (CREAA)—serves a distinct ethnic community
    5.   Colorado Association of Exclusive Buyer Agents
    (CAEBA)—covers only exclusive buyer agents
    6.   Massachusetts Association of Buyer              Agents
    (MABA)—covers only exclusive buyer agents
    7.   National Association of Exclusive Buyer Agents
    (NAEBA)—covers only exclusive buyer agents
    8.   National Association of Independent Fee Appraisers
    (NAIFA)—covers only appraisers
    9.   National Association of Hispanic Real Estate Profes-
    sionals (NAHREP)—serves a distinct ethnic community
    10. National Association of Independent Real Estate
    Brokers (NAIREB)—serves only independent brokers
    11. National Association of Real Estate Appraisers
    (NAREA)—covers only appraisers
    No. 05-3601                                                11
    12. National Association of Real Estate Brokers
    (NAREB)—primarily devoted to the needs of minority
    brokers
    The district court relied heavily upon the First Circuit’s
    decision in Wells Real Estate. We believe that decision
    effectively captured the central flaw in Reifert’s argument.
    [The plaintiff] has failed to demonstrate the slightest
    market for membership in real estate boards that might
    have been affected by the defendants’ alleged tying
    arrangement. There is no evidence that any other
    broker would have “purchased” membership in any
    other board but for the power exerted by the lure of the
    defendants’ MLS. There is no evidence that a substan-
    tial volume of “commerce” in board membership was
    foreclosed by the tie-in. The tying claim must fail
    absent any proof of anti-competitive effects in the
    market for the tied product.
    Wells Real Estate, Inc., 
    850 F.2d at 815
     (footnotes omitted).
    While the organizations the plaintiff named may provide
    important services, they simply do not compete with
    RASCW or any other Realtors Association. These niche
    associations lack cross-price elasticity with the national and
    local Realtors Associations, and have dissimilar purposes.
    These organizations are unlikely substitutes for a Realtors
    Association in Wisconsin.
    Instead of providing the district court with the required
    economic analysis, Reifert employs a 30-year old decision
    from this Court, Beatrice Foods Co. v. FTC, 
    540 F.2d 303
    ,
    308 (7th Cir. 1976), to frame his discussion of competition.
    Beatrice Foods Co. relied upon the Supreme Court’s deci-
    sion in Brown Shoe Co., 
    370 U.S. at 325
    , and set forth
    several “practical indicia” to determine a market’s bound-
    aries. “These indicia are (1) the industry or public recogni-
    tion of the submarket as a separate economic entity, (2) the
    12                                               No. 05-3601
    product’s peculiar characteristics and uses, (3) unique
    production facilities, (4) distinct customers, (5) distinct
    prices, (6) sensitivity to price changes, and (7) specialized
    vendors.” Beatrice Foods Co., 
    540 F.2d at 308
    . While the
    “practical indicia” named in Brown Shoe and Beatrice Foods
    Co. are important considerations in defining a market, they
    were never intended to exclude economic analysis alto-
    gether. Both opinions recognized the importance of eco-
    nomic analysis, including cross-price elasticity of demand.
    See Brown Shoe, 
    370 U.S. at 325
     (“The outer boundaries of
    a product market are determined by the reasonable
    interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand
    between the product itself and substitutes for it.”); see also
    Beatrice Foods Co., 
    540 F.2d at 308
    .
    This Court has emphasized the use of economic analysis
    in the law. To demonstrate competition in an antitrust case,
    the plaintiff must provide an economic analysis of the
    relevant market. See, e.g., Menasha, 
    354 F.3d 661
     (requiring
    economic evidence to prove the existence of a distinct
    market). Lacking any economic evidence, Reifert has failed
    to show that the tying arrangement has foreclosed any
    portion of the market for real estate services.
    The facts of the instant case stand in contrast to the
    situation analyzed by the Eleventh Circuit in Thompson.
    The defendants in Thompson operated an MLS system and
    tied MLS access to membership in a Realtors Association.
    The Plaintiff, Empire Real Estate Board, was “founded in
    1939 as an African American professional association
    because, at that time, the Realtors [Association] excluded
    African Americans from membership.” Thompson, 
    934 F.2d at 1570
    . The plaintiffs proved that as a result of the tie and
    the prohibitive cost of joining two groups, 400 brokers either
    did not join or quit the Empire Real Estate Board. Thomp-
    son held that where a competitor offering similar services
    loses four hundred members because of a tie between an
    association of real estate agents and an MLS service, there
    No. 05-3601                                                 13
    has been a substantial effect on interstate commerce. 
    Id. at 1578
    . In our case, however, the plaintiff has not presented
    an organization equivalent to Empire Real Estate Board.
    Thompson presented a valid competitor; neither Wells nor
    the instant case does. Thus, Thompson demonstrated a
    substantial effect on interstate commerce, while Reifert has
    not.
    Having found no competitors, there are many issues
    raised in the parties’ briefs that we need not reach. We need
    not decide whether the quantity of interstate commerce
    affected is “not-insubstantial,” nor must we address
    whether SCWMLS has a sufficient economic interest in
    the sales of the tied product to satisfy the fourth element of
    an unlawful tying arrangement.
    B. Group Boycott Claim
    Reifert also asks this Court to consider the district court’s
    grant of summary judgment to the defendants on his group
    boycott claim. A group boycott traditionally occurs when a
    particular group or individual is prohibited from joining an
    organization. “Where there are no exclusionary conditions
    attached to Realtor board membership, and there is no
    contention that the cost is prohibitively high, it is difficult
    to see any affront to competition.” Pomanowski v.
    Monmouth County Bd. of Realtors, 
    446 A.2d 83
    , 92 (N.J.
    1982). In the instant case, no licensed real estate agent was
    denied access to SCWMLS because of an anti-competitive
    measure.
    To prove a group boycott, a plaintiff must establish that
    the membership requirement has had an adverse impact
    upon competition in the market for the tied product. As
    stated above, Reifert has failed to demonstrate the exis-
    tence of a competitive market for Realtors Association
    memberships. Thus, there is no need to balance the pro-
    competitive effects of the Realtors Association membership
    14                                               No. 05-3601
    requirement against its anti-competitive effects. See Buyer’s
    Corner Realty, Inc., 
    410 F. Supp. 2d at
    583-84 (citing
    O’Riordan, 
    707 F. Supp. at 116
    ).
    C. Anti-Competitive Effects of the Code of Ethics
    Reifert claims that Article 16 of the Code of Ethics of the
    National Association of Realtors is anti-competitive and
    violates Section I of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    . Article
    16 prohibits members of the National Association of
    Realtors from interfering with the exclusive agreements
    other members have established with clients.
    Reifert’s allegations concerning the anti-competitive
    effects of Article 16, however, are overly broad. As the
    National Association of Realtors, Code of Ethics Standard
    of Practice 16-2 states, “Article 16 does not preclude
    Realtors® from making general announcements to prospects
    describing their services[.]” Rather, the Article’s purpose is
    to prevent the targeted solicitation of individuals who have
    exclusively listed their property with another agent and to
    prevent agents from improperly using multiple listing
    services as a data bank of potential customers.
    We must review a challenge to Article 16 under the rule
    of reason to determine whether the agreement contributes
    to competition and productivity. See Nat’l Soc’y of Prof’l
    Eng’rs v. United States, 
    435 U.S. 679
    , 695 (1978). Under the
    rule of reason, Reifert had the burden to demonstrate that
    Article 16’s net effect was anti-competitive. See Bi-Rite Oil
    Co. v. Ind. Farm Bureau Co-op. Ass’n, Inc., 
    908 F.2d 200
    ,
    203 (7th Cir. 1990).
    The balance between pro- and anti-competitive effects
    weighs heavily in favor of Article 16. Even in “open” MLS
    areas such as Massachusetts and Alaska, where individuals
    who have not joined a Realtors Association may access an
    MLS service, users must agree not to solicit the exclusive
    No. 05-3601                                                 15
    listings of other MLS users during the term of the listing.
    If agents were reluctant to post their listings, for fear that
    other agents would steal their clients, the market would
    become less transparent and less efficient. Article 16 aids
    competition and fulfills the purposes of the Sherman Act by
    providing a more transparent marketplace.
    III. Conclusion
    For the foregoing reasons, the judgment of the district
    court is AFFIRMED.
    WOOD, Circuit Judge, concurring in the judgment.
    Although I agree without reservation with the majority’s
    conclusion that the district court correctly granted summary
    judgment for the defendants in this case, I am concerned
    that some aspects of its opinion are in tension with the
    governing Supreme Court doctrine on tying arrangements.
    For the reasons I explain briefly here, I would take a more
    cautious approach, and leave further developments in tying
    law to the high court.
    In Northern Pacific Ry. Co. v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    (1958), the Supreme Court defined a tying arrangement
    as “an agreement by a party to sell one product but only
    on the condition that the buyer also purchases a different
    (or tied) product, or at least agrees that he will not purchase
    that product from any other supplier.” 
    Id. at 5-6
    . As the
    Court later made clear in Jefferson Parish Hospital Dist.
    No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
     (1984), however, “every refusal to
    16                                                No. 05-3601
    sell two products separately can not be said to restrain
    competition.” 
    Id. at 11
    . The trick is to distinguish between
    tying arrangements that are invalid and those that are
    innocuous, from a competitive standpoint. In Jefferson
    Parish, the Court explained the difference as follows:
    Our cases have concluded that the essential charac-
    teristic of an invalid tying arrangement lies in the
    seller’s exploitation of its control over the tying product
    to force the buyer into the purchase of a tied product
    that the buyer either did not want at all, or might have
    preferred to purchase elsewhere on different terms.
    When such “forcing” is present, competition on the
    merits in the market for the tied item is restrained and
    the Sherman Act is violated.
    
    Id. at 12
    . Going on, over the objection of Justice O’Connor
    (who concurred in the judgment because of this point), the
    majority had this to say about the analytical approach
    toward tying arrangements:
    Per se condemnation—condemnation without inquiry
    into actual market conditions—is only appropriate if
    the existence of forcing is probable. Thus, application of
    the per se rule focuses on the probability of
    anticompetitive consequences.
    
    Id. at 15-16
    . The Court went on to describe the circum-
    stances under which that probability would exist: first,
    there must be a substantial potential for impact on competi-
    tion, which would be shown if a substantial volume of
    commerce is foreclosed by the arrangement; second,
    anticompetitive forcing must be likely, which is the case
    when it is probable that the seller has market power. 
    Id. at 16-17
    . If the seller does not have “either the degree or the
    kind of market power that enables him to force customers
    to purchase a second, unwanted product in order to obtain
    the tying product,” then the per se rule cannot be used and
    No. 05-3601                                                17
    the arrangement must be assessed under a full rule of
    reason. 
    Id. at 18
    .
    Despite Justice O’Connor’s forceful opinion concurring
    in the judgment, in which she argued that the time had
    come to jettison the per se rule in tying cases, see 
    id. at 35
    ,
    and despite the opportunity it had as recently as March
    2006 to take that step, see Illinois Tool Works Inc. v.
    Independent Ink, Inc., 
    126 S.Ct. 1281
     (2006), the Court has
    refused to do so. Illinois Tool Works held only that the fact
    that a tying product is patented does not support a pre-
    sumption that the seller has market power over that
    product. See 
    126 S.Ct. at 1291
    . It concluded that “tying
    arrangements involving patented products should be
    evaluated under the standards applied in cases like Fortner
    II and Jefferson Parish rather than under the per se rule
    applied in Morton Salt and Loew’s,” both cases involving
    intellectual property (patents in Morton Salt, copyrights in
    Loew’s). In my view, Illinois Tool Works thus stands only for
    the proposition that a plaintiff must prove that a holder of
    intellectual property has “either the degree or the kind of
    market power that enables him to force customers” to
    purchase the tied product. If a plaintiff can do so, then the
    framework established by Jefferson Parish continues to
    apply.
    In the case before us, we must decide whether Reifert has
    produced enough evidence to survive summary judgment
    with respect to the allegation that the defendant Realtors
    Associations have tied the multi-listing service (MLS, the
    tying product) to membership in the Realtors Association of
    South Central Wisconsin, Inc. (RASCW, the tied product).
    The district court concluded that Reifert had not come
    forward with the requisite evidence. I agree. The D.C.
    Circuit offered a useful summary of the elements of a tying
    case in United States v. Microsoft Corp., 
    253 F.3d 34
     (D.C.
    Cir. 2001):
    18                                                No. 05-3601
    There are four elements to a per se tying violation: (1)
    the tying and tied goods are two separate products; (2)
    the defendant has market power in the tying product
    market; (3) the defendant affords consumers no choice
    but to purchase the tied product from it; and (4) the
    tying arrangement forecloses a substantial volume of
    commerce.
    
    Id. at 85
    . Here, I am willing to say that Reifert has brought
    forth enough evidence to permit a trier of fact to rule in his
    favor on the first three of those elements. His proof fails,
    however, on the fourth.
    The key point is not the measurement of how much
    commerce in the tied product market was affected. It is the
    fact that Reifert offered no evidence to show that there was
    any foreclosure in the tied product market. As far as we can
    tell from this record, no one refrained from joining any
    other organization because of the cost of membership in the
    Realtor Associations (RASCW and the others) before us.
    This is what distinguishes our case from the Eleventh
    Circuit’s opinion in Thompson v. Metro. Multi-List, Inc., 
    934 F.2d 1566
     (11th Cir. 1991). In that case, the court explicitly
    rested its decision on foreclosure, to which it referred as the
    “coercion element,” explaining that “plaintiffs need to show
    that [defendant] Metro not only has [ ] market power but
    also has wielded this market power to force brokers to alter
    their choice of professional associations.” 
    Id. at 1577
    . It
    then reported that the evidence in the record showed “that
    400 of Empire’s prospective and current members did not
    join Empire or quit Empire because of the prohibitive cost.”
    
    Id. at 1578
    . This is precisely the type of showing that
    Reifert failed to make.
    Analytically, the majority may well be right that the rule
    of reason approach it sees in Carl Sandburg Vill. Condo.
    Ass’n No. 1 v. First Condo. Dev. Co., 
    758 F.2d 203
     (7th Cir.
    1985), would be a more sensible way to approach all tying
    No. 05-3601                                                19
    cases. But it is not for this court to anticipate the Supreme
    Court’s overruling of its earlier decisions, even if the
    passage of time and the impact of later cases that create
    doctrinal tensions are evident to all. Just as we did in Khan
    v. State Oil Co., 
    93 F.3d 1358
     (7th Cir. 1996), overruled by
    State Oil Co. v. Khan, 
    522 U.S. 3
     (1997), we should limit
    ourselves to pointing out the problems we see and then
    attempting to apply the law as it stands as best we can. In
    the present case, unlike State Oil, faithful application of the
    existing law leads to the same outcome as the more ambi-
    tious approach the majority has chosen. For that reason, I
    am happy to concur in the outcome that the majority
    reaches, but I must respectfully decline to join its opinion.
    A true Copy:
    Teste:
    ________________________________
    Clerk of the United States Court of
    Appeals for the Seventh Circuit
    USCA-02-C-0072—6-12-06
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 05-3601

Citation Numbers: 450 F.3d 312

Judges: Flaum, Kanne, Wood

Filed Date: 6/12/2006

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024

Authorities (19)

Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc. , 126 S. Ct. 1281 ( 2006 )

State Oil Co. v. Khan , 118 S. Ct. 275 ( 1997 )

Buyer's Corner Realty, Inc. v. Northern Kentucky Ass'n of ... , 410 F. Supp. 2d 574 ( 2006 )

Warner Management Consultants, Inc. v. Data General Corp. , 545 F. Supp. 956 ( 1982 )

arlie-mack-moore-evanell-e-moore-alfred-l-paulson-and-mary-e-paulson , 550 F.2d 1207 ( 1977 )

fletcher-l-thompson-dba-fletcher-l-thompson-realty-empire-real-estate , 934 F.2d 1566 ( 1991 )

Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Board of Realtors , 850 F.2d 803 ( 1988 )

Fortner Enterprises, Inc. v. United States Steel Corp. , 89 S. Ct. 1252 ( 1969 )

Celotex Corp. v. Catrett, Administratrix of the Estate of ... , 106 S. Ct. 2548 ( 1986 )

Beatrice Foods Company v. Federal Trade Commission , 540 F.2d 303 ( 1976 )

Northern Pacific Railway Co. v. United States , 78 S. Ct. 514 ( 1958 )

Tiffany McCoy v. Raymond Harrison, in His Individual ... , 341 F.3d 600 ( 2003 )

bi-rite-oil-company-inc-v-indiana-farm-bureau-cooperative-association , 908 F.2d 200 ( 1990 )

O'Riordan v. Long Island Board of Realtors, Inc. , 707 F. Supp. 111 ( 1988 )

Brown Shoe Co. v. United States , 82 S. Ct. 1502 ( 1962 )

United States v. Microsoft Corp. , 253 F.3d 34 ( 2001 )

Barkat U. Khan and Khan & Associates, Inc. v. State Oil ... , 93 F.3d 1358 ( 1996 )

ohio-sealy-mattress-manufacturing-company-sealy-mattress-company-of , 585 F.2d 821 ( 1978 )

Menasha Corporation v. News America Marketing In-Store, Inc.... , 354 F.3d 661 ( 2004 )

View All Authorities »