Southwestern Bell Telephone Co. v. Federal Communications Commission , 138 F.3d 746 ( 1998 )


Menu:
  •                        United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE EIGHTH CIRCUIT
    ___________
    No. 97-3446
    ___________
    Southwestern Bell Telephone Company, *
    *
    Petitioner,                 *
    *
    Bell Atlantic Telephone Companies,       * Petition for Review of An Order
    * of the Federal Communications
    Intervenor on Petition,     * Commission.
    *
    v.                                *
    *
    Federal Communications Commission *
    and United States of America,            *
    *
    Respondents,                *
    *
    New Valley Corporation,                  *
    f/k/a Western Union,                     *
    *
    Intervenor on Petition.     *
    ___________
    Submitted: January 16, 1998
    Filed: March 11, 1998
    ___________
    Before RICHARD S. ARNOLD, Chief Judge, MORRIS SHEPPARD ARNOLD,
    Circuit Judge, and SACHS,1 District Judge.
    ___________
    MORRIS SHEPPARD ARNOLD, Circuit Judge.
    I.
    In the early 1980s, following the breakup of AT&T, the Federal Communications
    Commission required local telephone companies, or local exchange carriers ("LECs"),
    to provide long-distance companies, also called interexchange carriers ("IXCs"), with
    access to local exchange facilities at a regulated and approved rate. Interexchange
    service generally originates with LEC facilities through which the sending party is
    connected to the IXC, and then terminates with LEC facilities. An IXC cannot provide
    service without access to local facilities.
    The LECs provided two types of service to meet the obligation that the FCC
    imposed on them. First, they offered switched access services in which the IXCs used
    the LECs' regular local service facilities for originating and terminating long-distance
    telephone calls; second, they offered special access services in which an IXC would
    have the exclusive use of certain dedicated LEC facilities linking the IXC with its
    customers through the intermediary of LEC serving wire centers ("SWCs"). In return,
    the IXCs would have to pay the LECs a reasonable fee, as determined by the FCC.
    Only the special access charges are relevant to this case.
    During the period that these special access rates were in effect, special access
    circuits were used primarily to transmit telex, telegraph, video, voice, digital, and other
    1
    The Honorable Howard F. Sachs, United States District Judge for the Western
    District of Missouri, sitting by designation.
    -2-
    signals between end users and IXCs. At issue in this appeal are cost allocations
    relating to only two of the nine generally available circuit or channel types, namely,
    metallic and voice-grade channels. Metallic service was the lowest grade of service
    offered, and a voice-grade circuit was, as its name suggests, a circuit capable of
    carrying data in the frequency range of voices.
    The rates charged for special access channels comprised three components. The
    basic component was the charge for utilizing a "loop." The loop is the connection
    between the end user's premises and a nearby SWC, as well as between an IXC's local
    connection point and the appropriate SWC. All IXCs use some amount of loop service
    in connecting interstate lines with end users. The second component of the rate was
    the charge for utilizing a "trunk." The trunk is the connection between two SWCs,
    necessary to facilitate connections between end users and IXCs associated by
    proximity with different SWCs. (Thus a typical long-distance transmission would begin
    with an end user connected by a LEC loop to a nearby SWC. The SWC would, if
    necessary, be connected to another SWC via the LEC's trunk equipment, and another
    loop would connect the SWC to the IXC's line. At the receiving end the same
    sequence would be duplicated in reverse.) The third component of the rates,
    denominated "optional features and functions," is not relevant to this case.
    In the early 1980s, the FCC permitted LECs to charge only a "reasonable rate"
    for this mandatory service, that is, a rate that enabled the LECs to recover the cost of
    providing the service plus something called a "reasonable rate of return." Because the
    LECs used the same facilities to provide different types of service to different
    customers, the rate-setting process necessarily involved the allocation of shared costs
    among disparate users. This case arose from a dispute over the method by which the
    LECs allocated the costs in their tariffs.
    In 1983, the FCC decided that the system of exchange access compensation then
    in effect was unlawfully discriminatory. See 
    47 U.S.C. § 202
    (a). The FCC thus
    -3-
    decided to replace that system with a more uniform rate structure. Over the course of
    the next year and a half, in order to comply with new FCC guidelines, the LECs
    proposed various revised special access tariffs. All of them were suspended and
    eventually found unlawful by the FCC. In March, 1985, in accordance with a few
    specified adjustments from their previous proposal, the LECs filed tariffs that were
    accepted subject to investigation. Although the FCC never suspended these tariffs, it
    did instruct the LECs to keep accurate accounts of the charges in order to facilitate
    accurate refunds if they should prove necessary. These rates remained in effect for
    about six months.
    Early in 1986, the FCC issued a final order concluding its investigation and
    upholding these special access tariffs. In determining that the cost allocations in the
    tariffs were reasonable, the FCC rejected arguments in particular from Western Union,
    an IXC, that several specific costs allocated to the loop component of the rates should
    be allocated exclusively to the trunk component. It later rejected Western Union's
    argument that metallic service rates should be lowered to preserve their previous
    relationship with low-quality voice-grade service, the rate of which was lowered as a
    result of the FCC's order.
    Western Union petitioned the D.C. Circuit for review of the FCC's order. In
    1988 that court determined that the FCC had failed adequately to explain its rejection
    of Western Union's arguments and remanded the case to the FCC for reconsideration
    of three specific issues. See Western Union Corp. v. FCC, 
    856 F.2d 315
    , 316-17, 320
    (D.C. Cir. 1988). Almost immediately thereafter the FCC's Common Carrier Bureau
    invited interested parties to comment on how it should resolve the issues remanded to
    it. It did not resolve those issues until nearly nine years later. In its order the FCC
    reversed itself on two of the three matters remanded, on the ground that the LECs had
    failed adequately to justify the cost allocations at issue.
    -4-
    Southwestern Bell, an LEC, then filed a timely petition for review with this
    court. We affirm.
    II.
    Both Southwestern Bell and the FCC raise threshold issues only tenuously
    related to the merits of the case: Southwestern Bell argues that certain procedural
    infirmities abrogated the FCC's authority to order these refunds, and the FCC posits a
    procedural bar to this court's authority to consider Southwestern Bell's petition. We
    find none of these arguments persuasive.
    Southwestern Bell maintains that the FCC had no authority to order
    Southwestern Bell to refund money to Western Union because the FCC violated two
    procedural provisions of 
    47 U.S.C. § 204
    (a). The two provisions in question are the
    statute's time limitations and its supposed requirement that before tariffs can be
    retroactively altered they must first be suspended.
    Section 204(a)(1) permits the FCC to suspend a proposed charge or tariff for a
    period of up to five months beyond the time that it would otherwise go into effect,
    during which period the FCC may conduct an investigation to assess the legality of the
    proposed rates. If the FCC does not rule on the legality of the proposed tariffs within
    the allotted time, those tariffs automatically go into effect until it does so. Section
    204(a)(2)(A) limits the time period to five months for the issuance of such a ruling
    (before the 1996 amendments, the period was 12 or 15 months, depending on the
    complexity of the issues involved).
    In this case, the FCC made the rates in question effective on April 1, 1985.
    Then, in orders in January and November, 1986, it concluded that the tariffs were legal
    and ended its investigation. After the D.C. Circuit remanded the matter to the FCC for
    reconsideration, the FCC, as we have said, failed to act on the case for nine years,
    neither ordering refunds nor confirming its earlier position. When the FCC did finally
    -5-
    issue its order, more than 12 years had passed between the effective date of the tariffs
    and the FCC's refund order. Southwestern Bell argues that the FCC is barred from
    ordering these refunds now because of its excessively slow proceeding. We disagree
    because we believe that the time constraint imposed by § 204(a)(2)(A) does not operate
    as a statute of limitations and that its violation therefore does not end the FCC's
    authority to act.
    We have held that "[a]bsent specific statutory direction, an agency's failure to
    meet a mandatory time limit does not void subsequent agency action." Newton County
    Wildlife Ass'n v. U.S. Forest Service, 
    113 F.3d 110
    , 112 (8th Cir. 1997), cert. denied,
    
    66 U.S.L.W. 3355
     (1998). See also Brotherhood of Railway Carmen Division v.
    Pena, 
    64 F.3d 702
    , 704-05 (D.C. Cir. 1995). Section 204(a)(2)(A) contains no
    provision touching on the appropriate remedy, if any, for the FCC's failure to adhere
    to the time limit that it imposes. Thus the section does not operate as a statute of
    limitations, and the FCC does not lose its authority to act for having violated it.
    Southwestern Bell also contends that in failing to suspend the proposed rates the
    FCC failed to comply with a statutory requirement that it do so, and so lost its authority
    to act. But we believe that § 204(a)(1) does not require the FCC to suspend the
    proposed rates before it investigates them -- it only allows the FCC to do so. The
    statute states that, either on its own initiative or upon complaint, and pending a hearing
    concerning the lawfulness of a proposed charge, the FCC "may suspend the operation
    of such charge ... in whole or in part but not for a period longer than five months
    beyond the time when it would otherwise go into effect."
    We believe that the primary purpose of the suspension is to mitigate the
    transaction costs that might be incurred if the FCC eventually rejects the tariff: If the
    investigation can be completed in five months, and the rates are found to be illegal, no
    refunds are necessary if the tariffs were suspended, because the illegal rates were never
    imposed. But in any case the language of § 204(a)(1) is permissive, not mandatory:
    -6-
    it does not require the FCC to suspend proposed tariffs; it only gives it the authority to
    do so. But see Illinois Bell Tel. Co. v. FCC, 
    966 F.2d 1478
    , 1481-82 (D.C. Cir. 1992).
    The fact that the FCC customarily suspends proposed rates does not mean that
    its failure to do so in any particular instance invalidates its subsequent action.
    Furthermore, a possible secondary purpose of the suspension, that is, to put the
    company with the proposed rates on notice of possible defects in the tariff, is served
    by another provision in the section, namely, that the FCC may require the proposing
    companies to keep an accounting during the period of investigation in order to facilitate
    a refund should one be necessary. That is precisely what the FCC did in this case.
    III.
    The FCC also raises a procedural objection to our immediate adjudication of this
    case. Its argument is that 
    47 U.S.C. § 405
    (a) requires Southwestern Bell to exhaust all
    administrative remedies prior to raising an issue before the court. That statute forbids
    judicial review of a dispute where the party seeking review "relies on questions of fact
    or law upon which the Commission ... has been afforded no opportunity to pass." 
    Id.
    Southwestern Bell's procedural issues relating to the interpretation of § 204(a) present
    questions of law not yet passed on by the FCC. Thus, the FCC argues, Southwestern
    Bell must present these issues to the FCC itself in an application for review before
    raising them in this court.
    But exhaustion is not required when unreasonable administrative delay would
    render the administrative remedy inadequate. See Gibson v. Berryhill, 
    411 U.S. 564
    ,
    575, n.14 (1973) (noting that administrative remedies are deemed inadequate "[m]ost
    often ... because of delay by the agency"), and Smith v. Illinois Bell Tel. Co., 
    270 U.S. 587
    , 591-92 (1926) (petitioner "is not required indefinitely to await a decision of the
    rate-making tribunal before applying to a federal court for equitable relief"). In this
    case, the FCC failed for nine years to adjudicate the issue before it on remand from the
    -7-
    D.C. Circuit, in part, no doubt, because the tariffs at issue in this appeal were in effect
    for only six months before they were replaced and are thus no longer relevant. The
    resolution of the issues that this case raises will therefore have little or no future effect.
    But precisely because the issues are stale and irrelevant from the FCC's point of
    view, we believe that if we were to defer first to the FCC to resolve them, further delay
    would be not only possible but inevitable. As the FCC's attorney noted at oral
    argument, "There is a lot going on at the Commission -- this case is almost a relic."
    The FCC's record of delay in this matter may not, as we have said, invalidate its action,
    but it does render an administrative remedy manifestly inadequate.
    IV.
    When the D.C. Circuit remanded matters relevant to this case to the FCC, it
    singled out three issues for further consideration: The misallocation of costs in the
    determination of loop rates, the misallocation of plant investment to the rates for
    metallic service, and the disproportionate rates charged to users of two-wire metallic
    service. See Western Union Corp., 836 F.2d at 318-19. The court did not determine
    that these allocations are unreasonable, merely that the FCC acted arbitrarily in
    confirming them. Id. at 320. Upon review, the FCC reversed itself on the first two
    issues and stood by its decision on the third. Southwestern Bell argues that in reversing
    its earlier decisions on these two issues, the FCC acted arbitrarily and capriciously.
    A.
    Southwestern Bell bases this argument, in part, on an incorrect interpretation of
    the FCC's order on remand. It contends correctly that the FCC merely requested
    comments from interested parties on whether the record as it existed was adequate for
    the FCC to determine how the costs should be allocated. But Southwestern Bell goes
    on to maintain that because the FCC asked only whether supplemental information
    might be necessary and did not actually request any supplemental information, its final
    -8-
    determination that the LECs did not adequately justify their cost allocations was
    arbitrary because this conclusion did not follow logically from the requests in its order.
    That is, Southwestern Bell argues that the determination that the record was not
    sufficient to justify the cost allocations should have been made only after the LECs
    were asked to submit any necessary supplemental information, and that they did not do
    so because the order on remand did not request it. The only proper determination that
    the FCC could have made, Southwestern Bell argues, short of deciding that the record
    was sufficient and that the costs were justified, was a determination on how the record
    should be supplemented.
    But this conclusion misses the point. The FCC was under no obligation to
    inform the LECs how they might best supplement the record, or even to request that the
    record be supplemented. The question on remand was whether the FCC was correct
    in determining that the LECs properly justified their cost allocations in 1985, and the
    FCC asked for comments relating to its ability to make this determination. But it did
    not seek new justifications. It then determined that, in fact, the LECs did not meet their
    burden of proof in justifying the relevant cost allocations. Southwestern Bell is off the
    mark in arguing that it should have been told how it might supplement the record in
    order to justify its allocations. Furthermore, the FCC notes in its refund order that if
    the LECs can offer supplemental evidence to suggest that the refunds should be
    reduced, they may do so. It is in this context that the LECs may attempt anew to justify
    some or all of their 1985 allocations. But on the question addressed by the D.C.
    Circuit's remand and the FCC's order, namely, whether the allocations were properly
    justified at the time that they were made, supplemental evidence was irrelevant. It is
    worth pointing out, too, that all of the LECs that responded to the FCC's request for
    comments argued that the record as it existed provided more than adequate support for
    their cost allocations.
    -9-
    Southwestern Bell also argues that the FCC simply did not provide any basis for
    its opinion on remand that the LECs did not in fact adequately justify their original cost
    allocations. It is to this question that we now turn.
    B.
    The first contested aspect of the LECs' special access rate structure is the
    allocation of some of the costs associated with voice-grade performance investment
    (VGP) and facilities interface equipment (FACIF) to the loop component of the rate.
    The LECs contend that both of these are charges for equipment used to provide circuit
    continuity between a customer's premises and its SWC. But it is not clear if, in fact,
    the equipment is more properly associated with loop service or with trunk service.
    Prior to the 1985 tariff-system shift, VGP charges were placed in a category
    called "other special" along with investment costs in other sorts of equipment not
    otherwise specifically categorized in the old system. The IXCs contend that this old
    category contained charges properly attributable only to the trunk portion of a circuit.
    FACIF charges were, in the pre-1985 system, allocated on a facility- and user-specific
    basis. In the 1985 rate scheme, however, VGP charges were allocated to the loop
    component, and FACIF charges were aggregated (i.e., no longer facility- and user-
    specific) and allocated to the loop component of each service with which they were
    associated (thus there was a separate FACIF charge in the loop component for metallic
    service, for video service, etc.).
    The LECs assert, of course, that these allocations were reasonable and justified.
    But because certain IXCs (most notably for this appeal, Western Union) used no trunk
    service (or very little trunk service), those IXCs objected to portions of the new
    allocation system that saddled them with VGP and FACIF costs arguably associated
    only with providing trunk service, and which were only newly allocated to the loop
    component in the tariffs.
    -10-
    Upon consideration of this argument, the FCC originally concluded that it was
    indeed proper to allocate some VGP and FACIF costs to the loop rate element. In
    reviewing this conclusion, however, the D.C. Circuit found that in approving the tariffs,
    the FCC had failed to address the pertinent question raised by Western Union, which,
    the court held, was not whether it was proper to allocate some of the VGP and FACIF
    costs to the loop element, but rather how much of those costs was properly chargeable
    to it.
    In response to the order from the FCC inviting comments on this matter, the
    LECs presented several justifications for the apparent shift in cost allocations. Several
    LECs argued that the category that formerly included VGP and FACIF tariffs, the
    "other special" category, was only a means for grouping costs and was not limited to
    trunk equipment. Some argued that VGP and FACIF costs were in fact incurred in the
    provision of both loops and trunks. And one LEC argued that the category in which
    these charges were placed was not based on the function of the equipment at all, and
    so that costs assigned to trunk categories were not necessarily even trunk costs.
    Other LECs argued that they had allocated costs in the "other special" category
    to loop and trunk rate elements on the basis of unit-cost studies, and that it was
    impossible to disaggregate VGP and FACIF costs from other costs in the category.
    (Unit-cost studies identify the cost to a LEC of providing one unit of a particular
    service and recommend rates based on recovering that cost plus a reasonable portion
    of overhead. Thus, costs determined by a unit-cost study will be determined by
    reference to the aggregated costs for all of the equipment required to provide a service.)
    But the FCC determined that the LECs did not offer sufficient engineering data
    to demonstrate the extent to which they used VGP and FACIF equipment to provide
    loop services. Furthermore, the FCC faulted the LECs for failing to explain how they
    actually conducted their unit-cost studies and, notably, for failing to submit those
    studies. These determinations find support in the record.
    -11-
    The FCC then concluded that the specific allocations were unjustified because
    in a § 204(a) investigation the carrier bears the burden of proving the reasonableness
    of its charges. See 
    47 U.S.C. § 204
    (a)(1) ("the burden of proof to show that the new
    or revised charge, or proposed charge, is just and reasonable shall be upon the carrier").
    The FCC found that although the LECs did show that they used some amount of VGP
    and FACIF equipment in providing loop service, their arguments did not provide a
    reasonable basis for determining how much; the FCC further found that the LECs did
    not carry the burden of demonstrating that the allocation that they used was in fact
    reasonable. The FCC did not adopt Western Union's proposal that none of these costs
    should be allocated to loop charges; it concluded only that the LECs did not properly
    justify the costs as loop charges.
    As the D.C. Circuit noted in its 1988 opinion, an agency's decision will be
    overturned only if it is found to be "arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or
    otherwise not in accordance with law." Western Union Corp., 
    856 F.2d at 318
    . See
    also 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A). We discern none of these defects in the FCC's order.
    Southwestern Bell mischaracterizes the order as holding that none of these VGP and
    FACIF costs should have been allocated to the loop component of the tariff. But the
    order actually states only that Southwestern Bell failed to meet its burden of proving
    how much of these costs were properly allocated to that component. The order goes
    on to require Southwestern Bell to refund the charges to Western Union because the
    LECs did not justify their allocation to the loop element. It is of course open to the
    LECs to supply that justification and to argue that full refunds are not in order. But
    until they provide such a justification, there is nothing arbitrary about the FCC's order.
    It merely applies the strict standard that Congress imposed in § 204(a)(1).
    C.
    The second contested substantive issue in this case is the LECs' allocation of
    some of the costs associated with supplying station apparatus and large private branch
    exchange (PBX) equipment (both located on customer premises) to Western Union's
    -12-
    two-wire metallic and voice-grade services, and the LECs' allegedly excessive
    allocation of central office equipment (COE) costs to providing Western Union's
    metallic service. Western Union argues that, although station apparatus and PBX
    equipment were not used at all to supply it with two-wire metallic and voice-grade
    channel termination services, and although COE only very marginally contributed to
    the provision of metallic service, Western Union was nevertheless charged for these
    apparatuses. At the time that this allocation system was proposed, the FCC accepted
    the notion that rates for a particular service, provided to a specific customer, should be
    based on the pro-rated cost of providing that service to all of an LEC's customers, not
    just on the cost of the specific equipment required to provide the service to that
    particular customer. In fact, the FCC had previously rejected as needlessly expensive
    a proposal for an allocation mechanism that distributed costs associated with voice-
    grade service on the basis of individual use.
    In reviewing these arguments, the D.C. Circuit found, first, that the FCC had
    failed to address Western Union's allegation that the LECs allocated a disproportionate
    part of COE costs to providing metallic service. See Western Union Corp., 
    856 F.2d at 319
    . Second, the court found that, although the FCC explained why it had rejected
    the user-specific allocation system with respect to the provision of voice-grade service,
    it did not address Western Union's argument that such a system saddled customers of
    metallic service with costs for which they received no benefits. 
    Id.
    Upon reconsideration, the FCC concluded that the LECs did not meet their
    burden of justifying the amount of PBX and station apparatus allocated to metallic
    service rates. The FCC concluded that the record was at least inconclusive regarding
    whether the LECs ever employed more than a de minimis amount of this equipment in
    providing metallic service, and the LECs, in response, provided only general statements
    indicating that they did in fact use this equipment to provide metallic service. In earlier
    statements, however, and in connection with other complaint proceedings, the LECs
    had indicated that they employed little or no "circuit equipment" in providing metallic
    -13-
    service. Furthermore, the FCC pointed out that even if the LECs did use large amounts
    of COE to provide metallic service, they had submitted no records from which it would
    have been possible to determine whether the specific rate charged was reasonable.
    The FCC concedes that it might very well have been reasonable, at times, to
    provide metallic service over existing voice lines, thereby occasionally utilizing these
    facilities. But the LECs have not indicated how often this was done, nor have they
    indicated the portion of voice-grade COE costs actually attributable to providing
    metallic service. Because the LECs bear the burden of justifying their rates, the FCC
    concluded, they are liable for refunds to Western Union for some portion of these
    unsupported cost allocations. We believe that nothing in this conclusion or its
    reasoning even approaches the arbitrary and capricious. The FCC was again merely
    following the relevant provisions of § 204(a)(1).
    Southwestern Bell makes much of the fact that the FCC's order represents a
    reversal of its earlier holding that found these allocations reasonable. In fact,
    Southwestern Bell argues that "such an about-face is arbitrary and capricious
    decisionmaking." But the mere change of an administrative opinion after a lawful
    reconsideration can hardly be arbitrary and capricious on its face. In this case, the D.C.
    Circuit ruled that the FCC's prior order accepting the LECs' cost allocations was
    arbitrary and capricious. See Western Union Corp., 
    856 F.2d at 320
    . The court, as we
    have been at pains to say, made no ruling on the actual reasonableness of the
    allocations, but ruled only that the FCC accepted those allocations without proper
    justification. 
    Id.
     Neither the D.C. Circuit nor the FCC has declared that the cost
    allocations are unreasonable, but both have declared them to be unjustified. This order
    by the FCC, far from being arbitrary and capricious, incorporates a degree of court-
    imposed reflection and, we believe, corrects previous arbitrary and capricious behavior.
    V.
    For the reasons indicated, we affirm the order of the FCC.
    -14-
    A true copy.
    Attest:
    CLERK, U.S. COURT OF APPEALS, EIGHTH CIRCUIT.
    -15-