Washington Mutual, Inc. v. United States , 856 F.3d 711 ( 2017 )


Menu:
  •                      FOR PUBLICATION
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL, INC., as                    No. 14-35289
    successor in interest to H.F.
    Ahmanson & Co. and                              D.C. No.
    Subsidiaries,                              2:06-cv-01550-BJR
    Plaintiff-Appellant,
    v.                             OPINION
    UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
    Defendant-Appellee.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Western District of Washington
    Barbara Jacobs Rothstein, District Judge, Presiding
    Argued and Submitted December 9, 2016
    Seattle, Washington
    Filed May 12, 2017
    Before: Richard C. Tallman and Morgan Christen, Circuit
    Judges, and Morrison C. England, Jr.,* District Judge.
    Opinion by Judge England
    *
    The Honorable Morrison C. England, Jr., United States District
    Judge for the Eastern District of California, sitting by designation.
    2         WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    SUMMARY**
    Tax
    The panel affirmed the district court’s judgment, in a tax
    refund action, finding that taxpayer had failed to establish a
    reliable cost basis in certain rights for which it sought tax
    deductions and losses, in connection with taxpayer’s
    acquisition of certain failed savings and loan associations
    during the 1970s and 1980s.
    In 1981, Home Savings of America, FSB (Home
    Savings), agreed to acquire three failing savings and loan
    associations (thrifts) in exchange for a package of incentives
    from the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation.
    The incentives included the right to maintain branches in
    other states (branching rights) and the right to use the
    purchase method of accounting, which focused on Regulatory
    Accounting Principles (RAP rights). Washington Mutual Inc.,
    as successor in interest to Home Savings, initially appealed
    the district court’s judgment that Home Savings had no cost
    basis in its RAP right to amortization deductions, and its
    abandonment loss deduction for branching rights in Missouri.
    In a previously published opinion, this court held that Home
    Savings had a cost basis in both sets of rights equal to some
    part of the excess of the acquired thrifts’ liabilities over the
    value of their assets, and remanded for determination of that
    cost basis. On remand, the district court determined that
    Washington Mutual had not met its burden of proving Home
    Savings’s cost basis in the rights at issue.
    **
    This summary constitutes no part of the opinion of the court. It has
    been prepared by court staff for the convenience of the reader.
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                  3
    In this subsequent appeal, the panel held that the district
    court permissibly concluded that taxpayer did not meet its
    burden of establishing a cost basis for its intangible assets.
    The panel first held that the district court applied the proper
    legal standards, did not clearly err in determining that the
    evidence was insufficient to reliably value the Missouri
    branching right, and was not required to sua sponte assign a
    value to that right. The panel also held that taxpayer had
    failed to establish that Home Savings had permanently
    abandoned its right to operate in Missouri for purposes of an
    abandonment loss deduction.
    COUNSEL
    Thomas D. Johnston (argued) and Richard J. Gagnon,
    Shearman & Sterling LLP, Washington, D.C.; Maria O’Toole
    Jones, Alan I. Horowitz, and Steven R. Dixon, Miller &
    Chevalier Chartered, Washington, D.C.; for Plaintiff-
    Appellant.
    Arthur Thomas Catterall (argued) and Teresa E. McLaughlin,
    Attorneys, Tax Division/Appellate Section, United States
    Department of Justice, Washington, D.C.; Annette L. Hayes,
    United States Attorney; United States Attorney’s Office,
    Seattle, Washington; for Defendant-Appellee.
    4        WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    OPINION
    ENGLAND, District Judge:
    Plaintiff-Appellant Washington Mutual, Inc.
    (“Appellant”), as successor in interest to H.F. Ahmanson &
    Co., and Ahmanson’s wholly owned subsidiary Home
    Savings of America (“Home”), appeals from a judgment
    entered in favor of Defendant-Appellee United States of
    America (“Government”) after a bench trial in this tax refund
    action. Appellant argued in the district court that it was
    entitled to refunds attributable to losses and deductions it
    should have been afforded for certain intangible assets
    acquired during the savings and loan crisis of the 1970s and
    1980s. The district court, however, determined that the
    valuation model relied upon by Appellant’s expert was
    fundamentally flawed. As such, the district court held that
    Appellant failed to meet its burden to establish the value for
    the intangible assets, as well as its burden to establish a cost
    basis in those assets—a necessary requisite to allowing
    amortization deductions for those assets. Further, the district
    court determined that Appellant failed to show that it
    abandoned the Missouri Branching Right when it closed its
    Missouri deposit-taking branches and, therefore, that it was
    not entitled to an abandonment loss deduction. As a result,
    the district court dismissed the case. We have jurisdiction
    under 28 U.S.C. § 1291, and we affirm.
    I
    A
    The parties’ dispute evolved out of transactions
    originating from the savings and loan crisis. During the
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                     5
    1970s and 1980s, savings and loan associations, or “thrifts,”
    saw their profitability dissipate when the Federal Reserve
    chose to remedy rising inflation by allowing interest rates to
    skyrocket. See United States v. Winstar Corp., 
    518 U.S. 839
    ,
    844–45 (1996). Thrifts were consequently forced to pay
    depositors higher interest rates, while the thrifts’ income
    streams, which derived from long-term mortgage loans with
    low, fixed rates, remained stagnant. 
    Id. at 845.
    The high
    interest rates also decimated the housing market, further
    drying up the thrifts’ revenue streams and forcing the entire
    industry towards insolvency. See H.R. Rep. No. 101-54(I), at
    296 (1989).
    In the event that a thrift’s liabilities exceeded its assets,
    the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation
    (“FSLIC”), as thrift regulator and insurer of thrift deposits,
    was required to initiate a takeover and liquidate the thrift.
    See 
    Winstar, 518 U.S. at 844
    –47. FSLIC lacked the funds
    necessary to liquidate all of the thrifts that were failing at the
    time, however, and the Federal Home Loan Bank Board
    (“Bank Board”) instead chose to encourage healthy thrifts to
    agree to such takeovers through what were referred to as
    “supervisory mergers.” 
    Id. at 847.
    In order to make these
    supervisory mergers attractive to healthy thrifts, the FSLIC
    had to offer non-cash incentives, two of which—both
    exempting limitations otherwise imposed on the operations of
    savings and loan associations—are especially relevant here.
    
    Id. at 848;
    see also Wash. Mut. Inc. v. United States, 
    636 F.3d 1207
    , 1209 (9th Cir. 2011) (“WAMU I”).
    First, thrifts were historically prohibited from opening
    branches outside of their home states. WAMU 
    I, 636 F.3d at 1213
    . Accordingly, the FSLIC offered an incentive to
    healthy associations hoping to expand nationally by allowing
    6        WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    those thrifts an opportunity to operate in a new state if the
    first branch in that state was acquired through a supervisory
    merger. 
    Id. This incentive
    is referred to by the parties as the
    “Branching Right.” 
    Id. at 1209,
    1213.
    Second, thrifts were limited by minimum regulatory
    capital requirements, which mandated that each thrift
    maintain minimum capital of at least three percent of its
    liabilities. See 
    Winstar, 518 U.S. at 845
    –46. This presented
    an obstacle to taking over a failing thrift since, by definition,
    the failing thrift’s liabilities already exceeded its assets. See
    
    id. at 850.
    To counter this, regulators permitted healthy
    thrifts agreeing to a supervisory merger to apply the
    “purchase method” of accounting. 
    Id. at 848.
    Under this
    method, an acquiring thrift was permitted to designate those
    excess liabilities as “supervisory goodwill,” which, in turn,
    could be counted toward the supervisory thrift’s minimum
    regulatory capital requirement. 
    Id. at 848–49.
    Thrifts were
    also permitted to amortize that supervisory goodwill over a
    period of 40 years. 
    Id. at 851.
    These incentives, which
    focused on Regulatory Accounting Principles, are referred to
    as the “RAP Right.” WAMU 
    I, 636 F.3d at 1209
    , 1213.
    Home was a “healthy” thrift and, in 1981, agreed to a
    supervisory merger by which it would take over three failing
    thrifts, two in Missouri and one in Florida. 
    Id. at 1211–12.
    Through a series of transactions Home assumed the liabilities
    of the failing thrifts in exchange for a “generous incentive
    package.” 
    Id. at 1219.
    Under this package, Home received,
    among other things, cash and indemnities as to covered
    assets, and was allowed to structure the transaction as a tax
    free “G” reorganization, giving it significant tax benefits. 
    Id. Home also
    received Branching Rights for Missouri and
    Florida, permitting it to open branches in those states, as well
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                     7
    as the RAP Right and its associated benefits. 
    Id. at 1213,
    1219.
    B
    The current litigation arose after Home sold its Missouri
    branch offices in 1992 and 1993 and was later acquired by
    Appellant in 1998. 
    Id. at 1209,
    1214. Appellant filed
    amended tax returns on behalf of Home in 2005, requesting
    refunds for tax years 1990, 1992, and 1993. 
    Id. at 1214.
    According to Appellant, the Internal Revenue Service (“IRS”)
    had not credited Home for its RAP Right amortization
    deductions during those years, nor had it allowed an
    abandonment loss deduction in 1993 for the Missouri
    Branching Right. 
    Id. Based on
    these denials, Appellant filed
    suit on Home’s behalf. 
    Id. In its
    first review of this case, the district court ruled in
    favor of the Government at summary judgment, deciding that
    Home did not have a cost basis in either the RAP Right or the
    Branching Rights. 
    Id. at 1216.
    As such, the district court
    held that Appellant was not entitled to amortization and loss
    deduction-related refunds. 
    Id. Appellant appealed,
    and we reversed, holding that “Home
    Savings had a cost basis in the RAP rights and the branching
    rights equal to some part of the excess of the three acquired
    thrifts’ liabilities over the value of their assets.” 
    Id. at 1209.
    The panel remanded with instructions to the district court “to
    determine the cost basis and conduct further proceedings in
    accordance to [that] opinion.” 
    Id. at 1221.
    8        WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    C
    On remand, the district court heard evidence over the
    course of an eight-day bench trial and ultimately held that
    Appellant had failed to carry its burden of establishing a
    reliable cost basis for the Missouri Branching Right.
    Accordingly, the court ruled that Appellant had not
    established its right to a tax refund. Appellant similarly failed
    to convince the district court that Home had permanently
    abandoned its right to operate in Missouri. As a consequence,
    the court ruled that it was not entitled to take an abandonment
    loss for the 1993 tax year. The court dismissed Appellant’s
    tax refund claims with prejudice and entered judgment for the
    Government.
    In reaching its decision, the district court initially
    reasoned that, based on our prior remand, Appellant was
    required to do two things to establish the cost basis for each
    right. First, it needed to establish the “Purchase Price” for the
    failed thrifts, which could be determined by subtracting the
    value of the three failed thrifts’ assets from their liabilities.
    See WAMU 
    I, 636 F.3d at 1219
    . Second, Appellant was
    required to show what portion of the Purchase Price should be
    allocated among the various rights. Importantly, however,
    because the Purchase Price was less than the total fair market
    value of Home’s incentive package, it was not enough for
    Appellant to determine the fair market value of a single asset
    and assign to it a proportionate amount of the Purchase Price.
    Instead, Appellant had to establish the fair market value of
    each individual asset to reach a total fair market value for the
    entire incentive package. Appellant could then use this total
    fair market value to determine each asset’s proportionate
    value, and apply that value pro rata to the Purchase Price to
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                 9
    establish the cost basis of each asset. The district court
    explained Appellant’s burden with a helpful illustration:
    Assume that a thrift paid $300 for an
    incentive package it received in a supervisory
    merger. Assume, as well, that the incentive
    package is comprised of three assets: A, B,
    and C. Now assume that the fair market value
    of A is $175, the fair market value of B is
    $125, and the fair market value of C is $100.
    Therefore, the total fair market value of the
    combined assets constituting the incentive
    package is $400. This information is not
    sufficient to allow for the correct allocation of
    the purchase price among A, B, and C. For
    instance, one cannot simply allot $175 of the
    purchase price to A because that would result
    in too much of the purchase price being
    allotted to A. In other words, A would be
    allotted one-hundred percent of its fair market
    value, while B and C would be left with some
    percentage less than one-hundred percent
    because only $125 of the purchase price
    would remain to allocate to B and C, whose
    fair market value is $125 and $100,
    respectively, for a total of $225.
    Wash. Mut., Inc. v. United States, 
    996 F. Supp. 2d 1095
    , 1105
    (W.D. Wash. 2014) (“WAMU II”). Thus, if Appellant failed
    to establish the fair market value for any of the individual
    assets, it would be impossible to determine the total fair
    market value of the incentive package and, thereby, the pro-
    rata share of the Purchase Price—and the cost basis—for each
    individual asset. 
    Id. 10 WASHINGTON
    MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    Considering the evidence adduced at trial, the district
    court concluded that Appellant “failed to establish, to a
    reasonable certainty, the fair market value for the Missouri
    Branching Right” and, therefore, could not establish a cost
    basis in that Right or in the RAP Right.1 
    Id. at 1106.
    The
    district court found that Appellant failed to meet its
    evidentiary burden in large part due to shortcomings in the
    testimony of Appellant’s valuation expert, Roger Grabowski.
    The district court explained the “Grabowski Model” as
    follows:
    Mr. Grabowski used an income approach to
    determine the fair market value of the
    Missouri Branching Right to a hypothetical
    buyer. More specifically, Mr. Grabowski
    used a discounted cash flow model known as
    the “excess earnings” approach. Excess
    earnings represent the cash flows that the
    hypothetical buyer would have expected the
    Branching Right to generate beginning in
    December 1981, net of charges for the use of
    contributory assets, and discounted to present
    value. In order to determine the excess
    earnings (i.e. the cash flow) attributable to the
    Missouri Branching Right under the excess
    earnings approach, Mr. Grabowski employed
    a five-step analysis. First, he projected the net
    operating income generated by the Branching
    Right based on: (a) the projected rate of
    overall statewide thrift deposit market growth
    1
    The district court also concluded that, given this failure, it was not
    required to reach the parties’ remaining disputed issues (e.g., the extent of
    the failing thrifts’ liabilities, assets, and the values for each).
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                 11
    in Missouri; (b) the projected market share
    that the hypothetical buyer could be expected
    to capture in Missouri; (c) the projected
    spread on loans funded by the new deposits;
    and (d) the projected operating expenses for
    the hypothetical buyer. Second, he deducted
    income taxes from the net operating income to
    arrive at the projected net income. Third, Mr.
    Grabowski projected charges for the use of
    contributory assets (commonly referred to as
    “capital charges”) and deducted those charges
    from the net income to arrive at the projected
    cash flow attributable to the Missouri
    Branching Right. Fourth, Mr. Grabowski
    used a 22% discount rate to determine the
    present value of the projected cash flow.
    Lastly, Mr. Grabowski deducted estimated
    transition costs and assemblage value from
    the present value of the cash flow. This
    resulted in Mr. Grabowski finding a fair
    market value of $28.8 million for the Missouri
    Branching Right.
    
    Id. at 1107
    (citations omitted).
    The Government responded to the Grabowski Model, not
    by offering its own valuation, but by convincing the trial
    judge that the Model was fundamentally flawed and
    unreliable as a basis for determining the value of the Missouri
    Branching Right. For example, the district court determined
    that Mr. Grabowski’s assumptions regarding Missouri deposit
    market growth were unreliable because his projections
    regarding statewide deposit growth failed to account for the
    12        WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    effects of disintermediation2 and improperly included
    “interest credited” balances as a source of “new” deposit
    growth, thereby inflating his calculations. 
    Id. at 1111.
    The court also discredited Mr. Grabowski’s assumption
    that Home’s ability to capture market share in Missouri could
    be adequately predicted by looking to its prior expansion into
    Northern California. The court explained that Home’s
    intrastate expansion was not a reliable predictor of a
    hypothetical interstate expansion into the Missouri deposit
    market because: (1) Home’s prior expansion occurred in the
    1970s when the economic landscape for thrifts was entirely
    different; (2) Home’s Northern California expansion was
    facilitated primarily by acquiring existing thrifts, while the
    Grabowski Model assumed Missouri growth would be by
    way of organic expansion; and (3) the Grabowski Model
    contradicted Home’s own internal market-share projections
    made at the time of the supervisory merger.
    The court further found that evidence presented at trial
    did not support the Grabowski Model’s underlying
    assumption that a hypothetical buyer could originate a
    sufficiently high volume of new loans to offset the costs of all
    projected new deposits in the market at that time. According
    to the district court, this assumption was flawed because it
    failed to account for the fact that interest rates had risen
    dramatically and that the thrift industry was loan driven—that
    is, if loan demand was high, thrifts would seek to attract
    additional deposits; but if loan demand was weak, earnings
    2
    Disintermediation refers to the withdrawal of deposit accounts from
    the thrift industry. During the savings and loan crisis, this outflow
    resulted from the desire of depositors to get higher interest rates than
    thrifts were allowed to offer on accounts under then-existing regulations.
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                   13
    would drop if there were an inordinate amount of new
    deposits. The Grabowski Model, on the other hand, was
    driven by deposits. Mr. Grabowski assumed that the
    hypothetical buyer would want to attract as many new
    deposits as possible, and would worry about originating
    mortgage income after the fact. But underlying this
    assumption was the notion that the buyer would be able to
    place all newly generated deposits into income-generating
    mortgages. According to the district court, however, the
    likelihood of such an outcome was minimal at best, as the
    evidence produced at trial indicated that the then-existing
    high interest rates were not conducive to increasing loan
    volumes.
    The district court also rejected as “unrealistic” the
    Grabowski Model’s assumption that a hypothetical buyer
    could count on a net interest spread of 2.5% between its
    income-generating loans and its outgoing deposit payments.
    
    Id. at 1114.
    According to the court, Mr. Grabowski assumed
    that Appellant would not have to pay the going market rate
    for new deposits, but would rather be able to attract new, low-
    interest rate deposits by marketing its secure reputation, just
    as it did during the Northern California expansion. But since
    the court had already rejected Appellant’s reliance on
    intrastate California market growth as a predictor of success
    in its interstate venture, the district court was quick to reject
    this assumption.
    With respect to Mr. Grabowski’s final assumption, the
    court faulted the Grabowski Model for attempting to identify
    a license value for the Missouri Branching Right by
    comparing a “without” scenario to a “with” scenario. 
    Id. at 1115.
        Under a “without” or start-up scenario, the
    hypothetical buyer would move into the new Missouri market
    14       WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    without assemblage—i.e., branches, personnel, equipment,
    etc. Under the “with” or baseline scenario, however, the
    same buyer would enter the same market, but would do so
    with existing operational branches. Using this framework,
    Mr. Grabowski attempted to value the Missouri license by
    comparing how long it would take a hypothetical buyer in the
    “without” scenario to reach the same point as a buyer in the
    “with” scenario—and projected that a “without” buyer would
    be able to catch up to the “with” buyer within four years.
    To reach this conclusion, however, the district court noted
    that the hypothetical “without” buyer in the Model would
    have to achieve new deposit growth of between 90% and
    165% over that period. The court observed that such a
    conclusion “simply def[ied] explanation” because
    “[a]ssuming such extravagant growth during a time when
    depositors were fleeing the savings and loan market defie[d]
    credibility.” 
    Id. The court
    further faulted the Grabowski Model’s license
    value projection because it failed to consider that the value of
    the Missouri Branching Right license might actually decline.
    Since other thrifts were similarly obtaining branching rights,
    the district court determined that the Model should have
    addressed the possibility that additional thrifts could be
    granted the right to enter the Missouri market and, thereby,
    dilute the value of Home’s right. But rather than take this
    into account, Mr. Grabowski simply projected a perpetually
    increasing value.
    Ultimately, the court was more persuaded by the
    Government’s expert, Dr. Steven Mann. According to Dr.
    Mann, the premiums paid for intrastate thrift mergers around
    the date of the supervisory merger in this case were similar to
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                  15
    those paid by Home for the right to expand into the new
    Missouri and Florida markets.              Accordingly, the
    Government’s theory was that if, as Appellant argued, Home
    paid a premium for the failing thrifts in 1981 because it
    wanted the Branching Rights, then a similar premium would
    not be present for intrastate mergers, which would, by default,
    not include Branching Rights. But since the purchase
    premiums were similar for both types of mergers, the
    Government argued that the Grabowski Model improperly
    attributed too large a premium to the Branching Right, and
    that the purchase premiums must be driven by some other
    intangible asset associated with the mergers.
    Appellant argued in response that the Government’s
    comparisons were flawed because the interstate acquisitions
    involved assisted takeovers of failing thrifts that were
    qualitatively different than the intrastate mergers. According
    to Appellant, intrastate purchasers benefitted from “marketing
    and operational efficiencies,” which Mr. Grabowski referred
    to as “synergy,” along with “trade name value and market
    positioning,” both of which did not exist in interstate mergers.
    
    Id. at 1116.
    As a result, Mr. Grabowski argued that, while the
    purchase premiums may be similar for both types of mergers,
    the premiums in each were a result of different assets—the
    intrastate mergers due to “synergies” and the interstate
    mergers due to Branching Rights—and that Dr. Mann’s
    analysis therefore did not undermine the Grabowski Model’s
    projections.
    The district court, however, rejected this explanation.
    The court found that it did not adequately explain why the
    premiums were similar and that it was contradicted by other
    parts of Dr. Mann’s testimony, which indicated that acquiring
    premiums paid by both large and small thrifts were similar
    16       WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    despite the fact that the identified “synergies” would not have
    been as beneficial to the bigger entities. The district court
    found Dr. Mann’s testimony undermined Mr. Grabowski’s
    testimony and the trustworthiness of his model. And given
    the multiple weaknesses it identified in Appellant’s evidence,
    the district court ultimately concluded that Appellant failed to
    carry its burden of establishing either a cost basis in the
    Missouri Branching Right or its corresponding entitlement to
    the tax refunds it sought.
    The court then went on to consider Appellant’s
    abandonment claim, holding that Home had not abandoned
    the Missouri Branching Right in 1993 and was therefore not
    entitled to an abandonment loss deduction for that tax year.
    The court properly determined that to establish abandonment,
    Appellant was required to show both that “Home intended to
    abandon the Missouri Branching Right” and that it
    “performed an overt act of abandonment.” 
    Id. at 1117.
    Appellant offered evidence that, in the early 1990s, Home
    entered into three agreements to either sell or exchange the
    Missouri branches, and that each agreement contained a
    covenant not to compete, prohibiting Home from soliciting
    deposits for a limited period (two or three years) in the
    designated geographic area.
    The district court, however, focused on the fact that the
    non-compete clauses contained exceptions. For example, one
    of the agreements allowed Home to purchase and operate
    branches within Missouri if Home merged with, purchased,
    or was purchased by another thrift already operating in the
    non-compete area. The other two agreements permitted
    Home to continue operating its existing branches, and one of
    those agreements also permitted Home to open new loan
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                 17
    offices in the area. Home’s Senior Vice President, Verne
    Kline, further testified that the non-compete clauses were
    intended to provide Home with flexibility “should an
    opportunity arise or if there [was] a change of a decision.” In
    fact, Mr. Kline indicated that one of his goals in negotiating
    the sale of the Missouri branches was to retain “the most
    flexibility that [Home] could get.” As Mr. Kline explained,
    Home was trying to anticipate and avoid future obstacles in
    the event “[Home] were to go out and acquire another
    national firm that perhaps had branches in these [non-
    compete] areas.”
    Despite the above exceptions and Mr. Kline’s testimony,
    Appellant argued that the totality of the evidence
    demonstrated that Home intended to abandon the Missouri
    Branching Right. Appellant pointed out that it had notified
    stock analysts, shareholders, and the Office of Thrift
    Supervision that Home was closing its Missouri branches,
    and that these facts evidenced that it had abandoned the
    Missouri Right and the Missouri thrift market.
    The district court disagreed. It noted that the express
    language of the covenants not to compete undermined
    Appellant’s argument, and Mr. Kline’s testimony cast further
    doubt on its position as well. The court was not persuaded by
    the notices Home provided to interested parties, as that
    evidence failed to demonstrate that Home was permanently
    abandoning its right to re-enter the Missouri market. In fact,
    the court found that the evidence actually supported the
    conclusion that “Home recognized the value in leaving the
    Missouri Branching Right intact,” 
    id. at 1119,
    as it would
    remain useful to Home’s nationwide thrift business, rather
    than just its Missouri operations and, thus, had value to
    Home’s potential future growth. The district court concluded
    18        WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    that Home had taken action to “safeguard,” as opposed to
    “permanently disavow,” its Branching Right and that no
    deduction was warranted. 
    Id. at 1120.
    The district court then
    dismissed Appellant’s claims.
    D
    On appeal, Appellant contends that the district court
    improperly concluded that no cost basis could be assigned to
    the relevant intangible assets because: (1) it committed
    reversible legal error when it declined to estimate a cost basis
    for the Missouri Branching Right; (2) its error was due, at
    least in part, to its misunderstanding of the applicable burden
    of proof; (3) Appellant offered sufficient evidence from
    which the court could have, under the proper standard,
    calculated the value of the Missouri Branching Right, even if
    it disagreed with Mr. Grabowski’s ultimate valuation; and
    (4) in any event, the district court’s disagreement was itself
    based on a clearly erroneous criticism of the inputs Mr.
    Grabowski used for his mid-case scenario.3
    Appellant also contends that the district court erred by
    denying the abandonment loss deduction for the Missouri
    Branching Right because: (1) it misapplied the test for
    determining whether an abandonment loss was warranted and
    improperly required Appellant to show that it “permanently
    discarded” the Missouri Branching Right, ignoring the fact
    that the abandonment test is disjunctive and permits a loss if
    a taxpayer simply discontinues its business; (2) it improperly
    3
    As part of his scenario analysis, Mr. Grabowski ran his Model using
    a variety of assumptions that were probability weighted. He ultimately
    picked the “mid-case scenario” for his final analysis and testimony in the
    district court.
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                  19
    held that the Missouri Branching Right was useful to Home’s
    nationwide thrift business as opposed to only its Missouri
    operations; and (3) it attached too much significance to the
    covenants not to compete.
    II
    We apply de novo review to questions of law, such as the
    question whether the district court applied the correct burden
    of proof. See Husain v. Olympic Airways, 
    316 F.3d 829
    , 835
    (9th Cir. 2002); Taisho Marine & Fire Ins. Co. v. M/V Sea-
    Land Endurance, 
    815 F.2d 1270
    , 1274 (9th Cir. 1987).
    Whether that burden of proof has been met, however, is
    reviewed for clear error. See Potts, Davis & Co. v. Comm’r,
    
    431 F.2d 1222
    , 1227 (9th Cir. 1970). Whether the district
    court applied the correct legal standard to evaluate an
    abandonment loss claim is subject to de novo review. See
    A.J. Indus., Inc. v. United States, 
    503 F.2d 660
    , 662 (9th Cir.
    1974).
    “Where the trial has been by a judge without a jury, the
    judge’s findings must stand unless clearly erroneous.”
    Comm’r v. Duberstein, 
    363 U.S. 278
    , 291 (1960) (internal
    quotation marks and citation omitted). “Clear error review is
    deferential to the district court, requiring a definite and firm
    conviction that a mistake has been made.” 
    Husain, 316 F.3d at 835
    (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).
    III
    A
    The district court permissibly concluded that Appellant
    did not meet its burden of establishing a cost basis for its
    20         WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    intangible assets. More specifically, the district court (1) held
    Appellant to the correct burden; (2) did not make any clearly
    erroneous factual findings; (3) permissibly determined that
    the cumulative fundamental flaws underlying the Grabowski
    Model rendered it incapable of producing a reliable value for
    the Missouri Branching Right; and (4) was thus not required
    to sua sponte assign a value to that Right.
    1
    Because this is a refund case, Appellant’s burden is “to
    prove not only that the Commissioner erred in his
    determination of tax liability but also to establish the correct
    amount of the refund due.” Fed-Mart Corp. v. United States,
    
    572 F.2d 235
    , 238 (9th Cir. 1978) (quoting Crosby v. United
    States, 
    496 F.2d 1384
    , 1390 (5th Cir. 1974)). “Thus, if
    insufficient evidence is adduced upon which to determine the
    amount of the refund due, the Commissioner’s determination
    of the amount of tax liability is regarded as correct.” 
    Id. (quoting Crosby,
    496 F.2d at 1390).4 Appellant contends
    4
    To be clear, this is precisely what occurred in the district court. The
    district court determined that Appellant’s evidence was insufficient to
    support a valuation of the Missouri Branching Right and, as such,
    Appellant could not meet its burden to establish a cost basis in any of the
    rights. And because Appellant had the burden of proof in this action,
    Appellant consequently could not prove that it was entitled to a refund.
    Despite the fact that the result to Appellant was ultimately a zero recovery,
    the district court did not hold that Appellant had a cost basis of zero in the
    Rights—it simply found a failure of proof. To the extent this seems
    draconian, we note that the United States is not entirely immune from this
    type of rule. In a deficiency case, for example, if a taxpayer proves that
    the Government’s deficiency notice is not only wrong, but also that it is
    arbitrary and lacking in foundation, then the IRS is likewise required to
    prove the amount of the deficiency. If the Government fails to meet its
    respective burden in such a case, the deficiency noticed is reversed in its
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                          21
    that, in concluding it had not met its burden, the district court
    improperly held Appellant to an unwarranted standard and
    required Appellant to establish the market value of the
    Missouri Branching Right under a heightened level of
    “certainty” and “precision,” instead of simply requiring only
    a reasonable estimation of its value. We disagree.
    Contrary to Appellant’s argument, the district court did
    not require an unprecedented level of precision. The court
    made clear that the burden was on Appellant to prove its
    refund entitlement and that the case law at times used the
    word “exact.” See, e.g., Compton v. United States, 
    334 F.2d 212
    , 216 (4th Cir. 1964) (“To put it another way, the ultimate
    question in a suit for refund is not whether the Government
    was wrong, but whether the plaintiff can establish that taxes
    were in fact overpaid. The plaintiff, to prevail, must establish
    the exact amount which she is entitled to recover.”). But the
    district court tempered its use of that word by employing the
    phrase “reasonable certainty” to make clear that it was not
    holding Appellant to a more stringent standard of
    “exactness,” “certainty,” or “precision.” See, e.g., Trigon Ins.
    Co. v. United States, 
    234 F. Supp. 2d 581
    , 586 n.7 (E.D. Va.
    2002) (“The ‘exact amount’ text is not to be taken literally,
    but instead is subject to the general proviso that claims for
    refunds, like those for damages, must be supported by
    evidence proving the claim amount with reasonable
    specificity.”). In fact, the district court agreed with Appellant
    that, assuming the existence of a sufficient evidentiary record,
    an estimate would suffice for valuation purposes.
    Accordingly, when the isolated phrases on which Appellant
    entirety, judgment is entered for the taxpayer, and there is zero recovery
    by the IRS. See, e.g., Morrissey v. Comm’r, 
    243 F.3d 1145
    (9th Cir.
    2001); Estate of Simplot v. Comm’r, 
    249 F.3d 1191
    (9th Cir. 2001).
    22       WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    relies are taken in context, they are unremarkable and do not
    detract from the conclusion that the court understood the
    appropriate standard.
    Appellant’s argument based on the district court’s use of
    the phrase “heavy burden” similarly misses the mark. The
    district court used that phrase only while discussing Capital
    Blue Cross v. Commissioner, 
    431 F.3d 117
    (3d Cir. 2005), a
    case relied upon by Appellant for the proposition that where
    “the Government refuses to submit expert valuation
    testimony regarding particular adjustments to a proffered
    valuation, a court will essentially be forced to start from the
    taxpayer’s valuation.” While the district court did observe
    that the taxpayer bears a “heavy burden” to show that an
    intangible asset is capable of separate valuation, see Capital
    Blue 
    Cross, 431 F.3d at 129
    –30, the district court also noted
    that this “heavy burden” was not a new burden being imposed
    on Appellant. Rather, the district court was merely
    explaining the difficulties that may confront some taxpayers
    who are simply unable to show that their assets are capable of
    individual valuation.
    Indeed, Capital Blue Cross elaborated that “[o]nce it is
    established that the assets have a reasonably ascertainable
    value, the court is obligated to seek the correct value of the
    contracts not, upon catching the taxpayer in an error, to deny
    any deduction automatically.” 
    Id. at 130.
    Thus, the “heavy
    burden” referred to by the district court here only went to the
    potential difficulty in proving that intangible assets are
    capable of separate valuation. In this context, the district
    court’s use of the phrase “heavy burden” did not alter the
    burden of proof. It merely explained that in some instances
    that burden is difficult to carry.
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                    23
    2
    Having determined that the district court correctly
    understood and applied the appropriate standards, we turn to
    Appellant’s contentions that the district court’s criticisms of
    the Grabowski Model were clearly erroneous. According to
    Appellant, the district court’s findings in this regard were
    flawed for two primary reasons: (1) the court’s approach to
    the valuation was overly pessimistic; and (2) the court
    overlooked the fact that Mr. Grabowski factored risk into his
    model by using a 22% discount rate and, therefore,
    improperly faulted Mr. Grabowski for failing to adequately
    address the risks inherent to the thrift industry in 1981.
    Appellant further contends that the district court
    misunderstood a number of complex and technical issues that
    arose during trial, which resulted in the court’s clearly
    erroneous rejection of the Grabowski Model in its entirety.
    More specifically, Appellant asks us to find that the district
    court: (1) erred by rejecting the Grabowski Model’s reliance
    on Home’s intrastate Northern California expansion;
    (2) misconstrued the Grabowski Model’s projected growth of
    the Missouri deposit market; (3) incorrectly held that “interest
    credited” should not be considered a source of “new” funds
    for lending; and (4) failed to recognize that its criticism of the
    Grabowski Model’s net interest spread was actually an attack
    on Home’s business judgment and the basic premise that a
    willing buyer would have thought that the projected spread
    was feasible. However, because the district court’s findings
    were based on a permissible view of the evidence, none of
    these arguments are persuasive.
    As to the first argument, Appellant takes the position that
    the district court’s pessimistic perspective is incompatible
    24        WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    with the perspective of a “willing buyer.” But Appellant
    points to no authority standing for the proposition that a
    willing buyer cannot also realistically assess a market in the
    manner undertaken by the district court. Moreover, the
    district court’s conclusion was amply supported by the
    record. It is undisputed that Home engaged in the
    supervisory mergers against the backdrop of the savings and
    loan crisis. Despite this, Mr. Grabowski projected that Home
    would see healthy growth and that it would be able to convert
    all of its projected Missouri deposits into new loans. Not
    only did Mr. Grabowski’s projections seem to contravene the
    economic realities at the time, they were also contrary to
    Home’s own 1981 market projections.5
    Additionally, the Government offered evidence that
    projecting high loan volumes in 1981 was ill advised given
    the high interest rates at the time. Not only was it difficult for
    buyers to qualify for loans, specifically adjustable rate
    mortgages, but Home’s management was not sure whether
    such loans would have any widespread appeal. Given the
    profuse evidence supporting a more pessimistic market
    outlook, the district court was justified in rejecting Mr.
    Grabowski’s optimistic assumptions.
    Appellant further contends that the district court ignored
    the Grabowski Model’s use of a 22% discount rate and,
    therefore, incorrectly concluded that Mr. Grabowski failed to
    5
    In fact, there was evidence in the record to support the conclusion
    that, contrary to Appellant’s current arguments, Home had no interest in
    the Missouri market and it purchased those branches only to acquire the
    Florida Branching Right. To the extent Appellant is addressing the value
    of the Missouri Branching Right, this evidence cuts against Appellant’s
    argument that the district court took too pessimistic a view of the
    evidence.
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                  25
    adequately address risk in his Model and improperly required
    Appellant to account for the same risks twice. This argument
    is flawed, however, because it suggests that the 22% discount
    rate was intended to counter-balance the overly optimistic
    projections identified by the district court. In fact, Mr.
    Grabowski used the same discount rate for each of his
    scenarios, regardless of whether he used conservative or
    optimistic industry-wide assumptions for those scenarios.
    The 22% risk premium was therefore directed at his view of
    the thrift industry as a whole and was not adjusted at any
    point to address the overly optimistic assumptions identified
    by the district court.
    The district court’s remaining factual findings were also
    not clearly erroneous. Appellant claims that the district court
    improperly rejected the Grabowski Model’s reliance on
    Home’s previous intrastate expansion because the court
    erroneously concluded that disintermediation would have
    reduced both the Missouri deposit market as a whole and the
    hypothetical buyer’s proportional share of that shrinking
    market. But while disintermediation may not directly affect
    a hypothetical buyer’s ability to capture deposit market share,
    that was not the only reason the district court rejected
    Appellant’s attempt to use Home’s Northern California
    expansion as a predictor of its anticipated results in Missouri.
    To the contrary, the court determined that predicting future
    success of an interstate merger at a time when the thrift
    industry was insolvent by reference to Home’s prior ability to
    capture intrastate market share in a growing market during a
    relatively stable period was unreliable. The court also noted
    that this comparison was especially problematic because
    Home’s growth into Northern California was based on
    acquiring existing institutions, which it did not have in
    Missouri, and because Home’s own projections with regard
    26        WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    to Missouri market share were much more conservative.6
    These findings were not in error.
    The district court’s conclusion that Mr. Grabowski
    overstated potential statewide deposit growth was also
    permissible. As the district court noted, Mr. Grabowski
    included “interest credited” as a source of “new deposit
    growth.” And while it is true that interest posted to the
    accounts of existing customers can still be used for lending,
    the district court did not err when it determined that “interest
    credited” did not constitute “new” growth and, therefore,
    should not have been included as such in the Model.
    Unlike true new deposit dollars that are essentially open
    for capture, “interest credited” dollars typically stay within
    their existing institution. Thus, these dollars are not a
    categorical source of new funds flowing into the thrift
    market; rather, a hypothetical buyer would have to convince
    a depositor to leave its current establishment in favor of the
    newcomer. But to do so, the buyer would have to offer a
    6
    It appears the district court did err in citing the wrong line of an
    exhibit when it was discussing Mr. Grabowski’s projections for Missouri
    deposit growth. Rather than citing to the numbers corresponding to
    statewide growth, the court mistakenly cited to a line that corresponded to
    a hypothetical buyer’s anticipated growth in deposits within the state.
    Despite this essentially clerical error, however, the district court made
    clear that it properly understood the Grabowski Model to reflect that, “in
    real dollar terms, Missouri’s deposit market did not actually grow.”
    WAMU 
    II, 996 F. Supp. 2d at 1107
    . Further, it recognized that
    Appellant’s “contention that the Grabowski Model actually shows nominal
    deposit growth if it is adjusted for inflation” was “only true for the
    Model’s statewide deposit projections” and not for a hypothetical buyer’s
    individual deposit projections. 
    Id. at 1111.
    The court was thus clear that
    the higher percentages to which it referred were tied to individual deposit
    growth as opposed to statewide growth.
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                            27
    higher rate of return to the depositor than the existing
    institution—a scenario that was highly unlikely during the
    savings and loan crisis. Accordingly, the district court
    correctly faulted the Model for including these funds and
    artificially skewing Missouri’s deposit market growth.7
    Last, the district court did not clearly err when it rejected
    Mr. Grabowski’s projected 2.5% net interest spread, which he
    claimed a hypothetical buyer could expect to achieve in
    Missouri. Appellant takes the position that the district court
    should have deferred to that projection because it mirrored
    Home’s actual forecasts at the time of the underlying
    transactions. Nothing in the record or the case law, however,
    supports the conclusion that the court was bound by Home’s
    estimates.
    In sum, none of the district court’s challenged factual
    findings were clearly erroneous, and we decline to reverse on
    this ground. See 
    Husain, 316 F.3d at 835
    .
    3
    Finally, the district court did not clearly err when it
    determined that the cumulative flaws underlying the
    Grabowski Model rendered it incapable of producing a
    reliable value for the Branching Right. Appellant pleads to
    the contrary, arguing first that no such finding was ever made
    and, second, that any such finding was unsupported. Again,
    we disagree.
    7
    This conclusion is not undermined by the fact that the district court
    cited to the incorrect percentages in one part of its discussion. See supra
    note 6. The district court’s qualitative challenges to projected statewide
    deposit growth are valid, and this minor error does not warrant reversal.
    28       WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    When read against the backdrop of the extensive record
    in this case, including counsels’ post-trial arguments, the
    district court’s decision makes clear that it accepted the
    Government’s primary contention that the Grabowski Model
    was “too flawed to form a reliable basis for valuing the
    Missouri Branching Right.” WAMU 
    II, 996 F. Supp. 2d at 1109
    . The trier of fact agreed when it ruled that the evidence
    was too unreliable to support even an estimation of the value
    of the Rights. And although the court did not expressly state
    that no reliable evidence would permit an “informed
    estimation” of the intangible assets, that conclusion was
    implicit in its findings that Mr. Grabowski’s assumptions
    were “unreliable” and “unrealistic.” While it may have been
    helpful if the trial court had made a more exacting statement
    to that effect, it is clear to us that the court did in fact reach
    that conclusion.
    Even more, the court made clear that it was familiar with
    the relevant authorities, including those standing for the
    proposition that, assuming sufficient evidence had been
    produced, an informed estimate was all that was required.
    The district court also went to great lengths to explain that it
    “[was] not required to, and indeed [could not], derive the cost
    basis from unreliable evidence.” WAMU 
    II, 996 F. Supp. 2d at 1103
    (citing Norgaard v. Comm’r, 
    939 F.2d 874
    , 879 (9th
    Cir. 1991)); see also 
    id. (“[C]ourts decline
    to apply Cohan[ v.
    Commissioner, 
    39 F.2d 540
    (2d Cir. 1930),] in cases where
    there is no doubt that the taxpayer incurred some deductible
    expense, but the taxpayer failed to present evidence sufficient
    to allow the court to make an accurate finding on the amount
    of the deduction.”).
    In sum, the court’s extensive discussion of the evidentiary
    prerequisites to making an informed estimate undermines the
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                           29
    theory that the district court misunderstood the standard or
    applied it erroneously. The very fact that the court did not
    engage in an estimation exercise—when it knew that an
    estimation should be made if sufficient evidence was
    presented—further supports the conclusion that the court had
    already determined that the evidence before it was
    inadequate.8 See 
    Norgaard, 939 F.2d at 879
    –80. We see no
    error in the district court’s understanding of this evidentiary
    standard.
    We also agree with the district court’s application of that
    standard and its ultimate determination that estimation based
    on the evidence in the record was effectively impossible.9
    Contrary to Appellant’s arguments, the district court’s
    criticisms of Appellant’s evidence were not limited to inputs
    but were, in fact, much more fundamental. The district court
    did not just disagree with Mr. Grabowski’s quantitative
    8
    The substantial flaws identified in this case also render it
    distinguishable from Capital Blue Cross, 
    431 F.3d 117
    . The Capital Blue
    Cross case depends on the assumptions that (1) the taxpayer has shown
    that an asset has a reasonably ascertainable value and (2) the Government
    identified only minor flaws in the taxpayer’s analysis. 
    Id. at 130.
    Here,
    however, the Government identified major, systemic flaws, and it did not
    concede that the value of the Rights may be determined separately and
    with reasonable precision.
    9
    We need not decide whether the ascertainability of an asset’s value
    is a question of law or of fact, thus affecting our standard of review.
    Compare Steen v. United States (In re Steen), 
    509 F.2d 1398
    , 1404 n.9
    (9th Cir. 1975) (“While the amount of the fair market value of property is
    a question of fact, whether value is ascertainable is reviewable question
    of law.”), with Clodfelter v. Comm’r, 
    426 F.2d 1391
    , 1395 (9th Cir. 1970)
    (“Whether property has ascertainable market value on a particular date and
    the amount of that value is a question of fact.”). Under any standard of
    review, we agree with the district court that the evidence was insufficient
    to derive a value.
    30         WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    inputs; it disagreed with the qualitative assumptions
    underlying the Model itself. While interest rates or market
    share inputs could potentially be modified in isolation, it is
    much less clear how the court could have unilaterally
    modified the Model to address Mr. Grabowski’s reliance on:
    (1) an unrealistically “rosy” view of the future of the thrift
    industry in 1981 (e.g., by failing to properly consider
    disintermediation and relying on statistics that included
    “interest credited” balances); (2) an unrealistic estimate of
    Home’s ability to capture market share; (3) a flawed income-
    based approach to evaluating whether a hypothetical buyer in
    a loan-driven industry would be able to use new deposits to
    generate new loans; (4) an unrealistic hypothetical net interest
    spread; (5) an improbable growth rate during a time when
    associations were struggling to attract and retain depositors;
    and (6) a potential decrease in the Missouri Branching
    Right’s license value.10
    Given the above, Appellant’s argument that the court was
    required to sua sponte estimate some value for the Rights is
    foreclosed. On these facts, such a proposition would
    essentially do away with the taxpayer’s burden. Instead, the
    cases make clear that a district court may only be obligated to
    value an asset when it determines that the asset “may be
    valued separately” or has “a reasonably ascertainable value,”
    10
    While we do believe it possible that some of the flaws identified by
    the district court could potentially have been addressed in reliance on
    other evidence in the record (e.g., the district court could perhaps have
    substituted a different net interest spread), the record does not reflect any
    obvious manner in which the court could have addressed, for example,
    Grabowski’s overestimates regarding a hypothetical buyer’s ability to
    generate new loans or the value of the license. These flaws go to defects
    in the Model itself, and it remains unclear to us how a court could address
    all of Model’s flaws simultaneously and reach any principled result.
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                            31
    or “sufficient evidence was introduced to allow the [district]
    court to reach a reasonable conclusion” as to value. Capital
    Blue 
    Cross, 431 F.3d at 129
    –30; R.M. Smith, Inc. v. Comm’r,
    
    591 F.2d 248
    , 251 (3d Cir. 1979). Since the district court
    permissibly determined that the Missouri Branching Right did
    not have a “reasonably ascertainable value,” it was not
    required to undertake such an exercise here.11
    The district court applied the proper legal standards and
    did not clearly err in criticizing the Grabowski Model or in
    determining that the evidence was insufficient to reliably
    value the Missouri Branching Right. The court properly
    determined that Appellant failed to meet its burden and, thus,
    appropriately dismissed Appellant’s claims on this basis.
    B
    Even assuming the Missouri Branching Right could be
    valued, Appellant nonetheless failed to show reversible error
    as to the denial of its abandonment deduction.
    Internal Revenue Code § 165(a) provides for an
    abandonment deduction for “any loss sustained during the
    taxable year and not compensated for by insurance or
    otherwise.” 26 U.S.C. § 165(a). An abandonment loss may
    be appropriate if “[the] business or transaction is discontinued
    11
    Nor was the district court constrained by the mandate from the first
    appeal to calculate a cost basis for each of the rights. That appeal did not
    address any arguments regarding the actual valuation itself. On remand,
    the court simply directed the district court to “proceed to determine the
    cost basis and conduct further proceedings in accordance to this opinion.”
    WAMU 
    I, 636 F.3d at 1221
    . The district court remained free to conduct
    the proceedings as it deemed necessary to independently calculate the
    value of the Rights.
    32       WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    or where such property is permanently discarded from use
    therein.” Treas. Reg. § 1.165-2(a). A deduction is proper if
    there is “(1) an intention on the part of the owner to abandon
    the asset, and (2) an affirmative act of abandonment.” A.J.
    Indus., Inc. v. United States, 
    503 F.2d 660
    , 670 (9th Cir.
    1974).
    Appellant contends that the district court misapplied the
    test for determining whether an abandonment loss was
    warranted and, thus, committed legal error. First, Appellant
    argues that the district court improperly required Appellant to
    show that it had “permanently discarded” the Missouri
    Branching Right and ignored the disjunctive nature of the
    abandonment test, which also permits a loss if the taxpayer
    discontinues its business. Second, Appellant contends that
    the court improperly defined the business in which the
    Missouri Branching Right was used as Home’s nationwide
    thrift business, rather than as a more limited Missouri-based
    operation. In addition, Appellant argues that the district court
    clearly erred in its factual analysis by attaching too much
    significance to the covenants not to compete that were
    included in the transfer agreements for the sale of the
    Missouri branches.
    Despite the fact that the district court never explicitly
    stated in its written order that the disjunctive test requires
    inquiry into whether “such business . . . is discontinued or . . .
    such property is permanently discarded from use therein,” it
    nonetheless applied the correct legal standard. Treas. Reg.
    § 1.165-2(a) (emphasis added). The district court expressly
    acknowledged that, “[a]ccording to [Appellant], Home
    abandoned the Missouri Branching Right by closing its
    Missouri deposit-taking branches.” WAMU II, 
    996 F. Supp. 2d
    at 1118. More specifically, the district court identified
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                          33
    Appellant’s argument to be that “Home [] abandon[ed] the
    [Missouri Branching] Right by abandoning the economically
    inefficient business in which it used the Right (i.e., Missouri
    deposit taking), disposing of the assets it used in that business
    (i.e., the Missouri branches), and ceasing to use the Right in
    that business.” 
    Id. The district
    court then explained the Government’s
    competing position. According to the district court, the
    Government claimed that the closing of the Missouri deposit-
    taking branches was insufficient to prove abandonment in
    light of (1) the covenants not to compete that reserved for
    Home the right to re-enter the market, and (2) the testimony
    of Home’s executives indicating that Home had not
    foreclosed the option of using the Missouri Branching Right
    in the future. Id.12
    Based on both parties’ arguments and the evidence before
    it, the district court expressly determined that Home had not
    shown that it intended to discontinue the business in which
    the Branching Right was used. In doing so, the district court
    repeatedly addressed Home’s sale of the Missouri branches
    and its decision to withdraw from the Missouri market at the
    time. Appellant’s problem is not that the district court
    misunderstood the legal standard, but that the court disagreed
    with Appellant as to the factual importance of the limitations
    on the covenants not to compete and the contemporaneous
    evidence that Home intended to keep its future options open.
    12
    Our conclusion is further supported by the fact that, as argued by
    Appellant, it was impossible for Home to “permanently discard” the
    Missouri Branching Right. Since the Right could not be discarded, the
    only relevant prong that the court could have considered was whether the
    business in which the Right applied had been discontinued.
    34        WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES
    Accordingly, the district court applied the correct standard.
    Appellant simply disputes the result.
    To that end, Appellant primarily takes issue with the
    district court’s conclusion that Home’s relevant “business” be
    viewed at the national level. But contrary to Appellant’s
    arguments, the district court’s determination on that issue was
    permissible. The district court properly determined that the
    Missouri Branching Right remained potentially useful to
    Home’s ongoing national business to the extent Home could
    either decide to re-enter the Missouri market or attempt to
    entice a merger with or a sale to another thrift with similar
    inclinations to expand outside of its home state. The record
    clearly permits this finding and the court’s broad view of
    Home’s business was not clearly erroneous.
    We further conclude that the district court attached the
    proper significance to the covenants not to compete and to the
    testimony of Home’s executives that Home had not
    permanently given up on the idea of operating deposit
    institutions in Missouri.13 The district court permissibly
    reasoned that the Missouri Branching Right retained value
    upon disposition of the existing branches because the
    13
    To the extent Appellant’s argument turns on the district court’s use
    of the word “permanently,” that argument is not well taken. The district
    court may have used the phrases “permanently abandoned” and
    “permanently disavowed,” but it appears that use of the word
    “permanently” was not necessarily intended to refer to the issue of
    whether an asset was discarded. Rather, it seems “permanently” was used
    to differentiate between a “permanent” and “temporary” action. The
    district court essentially concluded that, because of the limitations on the
    covenants not to compete, Home’s withdrawal from Missouri was, by
    definition, only “temporary” and, thus, did not support the finding that
    Home really intended to discontinue its business there.
    WASHINGTON MUTUAL V. UNITED STATES                           35
    Right—and the attendant ability to re-enter the Missouri
    market—held value beyond just the ability to purchase or
    operate branches. Stated another way, Home did not show
    that it intended to discontinue its business—or abandon the
    Branching Right—when it expressly reserved the right to re-
    enter the Missouri market. Rather, it is clear that Home
    recognized that the Branching Right itself remained
    potentially valuable to its nationwide thrift business as an
    asset that might be attractive to a suitor in a merger or
    acquisition. The district court’s interpretation of the evidence
    before it was appropriate, and Appellant has failed to point to
    any error warranting reversal.14
    Costs are awarded to the Appellee.
    AFFIRMED.
    14
    Appellant’s argument that the district court incorrectly applied a
    heightened burden of proof akin to a criminal standard to this issue is
    rejected. Passing use of the word “doubt” is insufficient to justify the
    inference that the district court confused the civil preponderance standard
    with the tougher criminal standard.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 14-35289

Citation Numbers: 856 F.3d 711, 119 A.F.T.R.2d (RIA) 1803, 2017 U.S. App. LEXIS 8451, 2017 WL 1959979

Judges: Tallman, Christen, England

Filed Date: 5/12/2017

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 11/5/2024

Authorities (18)

Trigon Insurance v. United States , 234 F. Supp. 2d 581 ( 2002 )

United States v. Winstar Corp. , 116 S. Ct. 2432 ( 1996 )

mr-r-h-crosby-and-mrs-v-ethel-crosby-mrs-v-ethel-crosby-as-of-the , 496 F.2d 1384 ( 1974 )

Capital Blue Cross and Subsidiaries v. Commissioner of ... , 431 F.3d 117 ( 2005 )

Taisho Marine & Fire Insurance Co., Ltd. v. M/v Sea-Land ... , 815 F.2d 1270 ( 1987 )

Cohan v. Commissioner of Internal Revenue , 39 F.2d 540 ( 1930 )

james-j-morrissey-alan-s-bercutt-cpa-diane-fantl-co-executors-of-the , 243 F.3d 1145 ( 2001 )

A. J. Industries, Inc. v. United States , 503 F.2d 660 ( 1974 )

Washington Mut. Inc. v. United States , 636 F.3d 1207 ( 2011 )

In the Matter of Charles A. Steen, Debtor. Dick Dimond, ... , 509 F.2d 1398 ( 1975 )

Estate of Richard R. Simplot, Deceased John Edward Simplot, ... , 249 F.3d 1191 ( 2001 )

Preben Norgaard Sandra C. Norgaard v. Commissioner Internal ... , 939 F.2d 874 ( 1991 )

rubina-husain-individually-and-as-personal-representative-of-the-estate-of , 316 F.3d 829 ( 2002 )

Commissioner v. Duberstein , 80 S. Ct. 1190 ( 1960 )

R. M. Smith, Inc. v. Commissioner of Internal Revenue , 591 F.2d 248 ( 1979 )

Nannie v. Compton v. United States of America , 334 F.2d 212 ( 1964 )

The Fed-Mart Corporation, a California Corporation v. The ... , 572 F.2d 235 ( 1978 )

Floyd R. Clodfelter and Enna L. Clodfelter v. Commissioner ... , 426 F.2d 1391 ( 1970 )

View All Authorities »