Shawne Alston v. Ncaa ( 2020 )


Menu:
  •                  FOR PUBLICATION
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    IN RE NATIONAL COLLEGIATE                 No. 19-15566
    ATHLETIC ASSOCIATION ATHLETIC
    GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST                  D.C. No.
    LITIGATION,                              4:14-md-02541-
    CW
    SHAWNE ALSTON; MARTIN JENKINS;
    JOHNATHAN MOORE; KEVIN PERRY;
    WILLIAM TYNDALL; ALEX
    LAURICELLA; SHARRIF FLOYD; KYLE
    THERET; DUANE BENNETT; CHRIS
    STONE; JOHN BOHANNON; ASHLEY
    HOLLIDAY; CHRIS DAVENPORT;
    NICHOLAS KINDLER; KENDALL
    GREGORY-MCGHEE; INDIA CHANEY;
    MICHEL’LE THOMAS; DON BANKS,
    “DJ”; KENDALL TIMMONS; DAX
    DELLENBACH; NIGEL HAYES;
    ANFORNEE STEWART; KENYATA
    JOHNSON; BARRY BRUNETTI;
    DALENTA JAMERAL STEPHENS,
    “D.J.”; JUSTINE HARTMAN; AFURE
    JEMERIGBE; ALEC JAMES,
    Plaintiffs-Appellees,
    v.
    NATIONAL COLLEGIATE ATHLETIC
    ASSOCIATION, THE NCAA; PACIFIC
    2   IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    12 CONFERENCE; CONFERENCE USA;
    THE BIG TEN CONFERENCE, INC.;
    MID-AMERICAN CONFERENCE;
    SOUTHEASTERN CONFERENCE;
    ATLANTIC COAST CONFERENCE;
    MOUNTAIN WEST CONFERENCE; THE
    BIG TWELVE CONFERENCE, INC.;
    SUN BELT CONFERENCE; WESTERN
    ATHLETIC CONFERENCE; AMERICAN
    ATHLETIC CONFERENCE,
    Defendants-Appellants,
    AMERICAN BROADCASTING
    COMPANIES, INC.; CBS
    BROADCASTING, INC.; ESPN
    ENTERPRISES, INC.; ESPN, INC.; FOX
    BROADCASTING COMPANY, LLC.;
    FOX SPORTS HOLDINGS, LLC.;
    TURNER BROADCASTING SYSTEM,
    INC.,
    Intervenors.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   3
    IN RE NATIONAL COLLEGIATE                  No. 19-15662
    ATHLETIC ASSOCIATION ATHLETIC
    GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST                   D.C. No.
    LITIGATION,                               4:14-md-02541-
    CW
    JOHN BOHANNON; JUSTINE
    HARTMAN, as representatives of the           OPINION
    classes,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    NATIONAL COLLEGIATE ATHLETIC
    ASSOCIATION, THE NCAA; PACIFIC
    12 CONFERENCE; CONFERENCE USA;
    THE BIG TEN CONFERENCE, INC.;
    MID-AMERICAN CONFERENCE;
    SOUTHEASTERN CONFERENCE;
    ATLANTIC COAST CONFERENCE;
    MOUNTAIN WEST CONFERENCE; THE
    BIG TWELVE CONFERENCE, INC.;
    SUN BELT CONFERENCE; WESTERN
    ATHLETIC CONFERENCE; AMERICAN
    ATHLETIC CONFERENCE,
    Defendants-Appellees,
    AMERICAN BROADCASTING
    COMPANIES, INC.; CBS
    BROADCASTING, INC.; ESPN
    ENTERPRISES, INC.; ESPN, INC.; FOX
    BROADCASTING COMPANY, LLC.;
    4     IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    FOX SPORTS HOLDINGS, LLC.;
    TURNER BROADCASTING SYSTEM,
    INC.,
    Intervenors.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of California
    Claudia Wilken, District Judge, Presiding
    Argued and Submitted March 9, 2020
    San Francisco, California
    Filed May 18, 2020
    Before: Sidney R. Thomas, Chief Judge, and Ronald M.
    Gould and Milan D. Smith, Jr., Circuit Judges.
    Opinion by Chief Judge Thomas;
    Concurrence by Judge Milan D. Smith, Jr.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.              5
    SUMMARY*
    Antitrust
    The panel affirmed the district court’s order in an antitrust
    action, enjoining the National Collegiate Athletic Association
    from enforcing rules that restrict the education-related
    benefits that its member institutions may offer students who
    play Football Bowl Subdivision football and Division I
    basketball.
    In O’Bannon v. NCAA (O’Bannon II), 
    802 F.3d 1049
    (9th
    Cir. 2015), the court affirmed in large part the district court’s
    ruling that the NCAA illegally restrained trade, in violation
    of section 1 of the Sherman Act, by preventing FBS football
    and D1 men’s basketball players from receiving
    compensation for the use of their names, images, and
    likenesses, and the district court’s injunction insofar as it
    required the NCAA to implement the less restrictive
    alternative of permitting athletic scholarships for the full cost
    of attendance.
    Subsequent antitrust actions by student-athletes were
    consolidated in the district court. After a bench trial, the
    district court entered judgment for the student-athletes in part,
    concluding that NCAA limits on education-related benefits
    were unreasonable restraints of trade, and accordingly
    enjoining those limits, but declining to hold that NCAA limits
    on compensation unrelated to education likewise violated
    section 1.
    *
    This summary constitutes no part of the opinion of the court. It has
    been prepared by court staff for the convenience of the reader.
    6   IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    The panel affirmed the district court’s conclusion that
    O’Bannon II did not foreclose this litigation as a matter of
    stare decisis or res judicata.
    The panel held that the district court properly applied the
    Rule of Reason in determining that the enjoined rules were
    unlawful restraints of trade under section 1 of the Sherman
    Act. The panel concluded that the student-athletes carried
    their burden at the first step of the Rule of Reason analysis by
    showing that the restraints produced significant
    anticompetitive effects within the relevant market for student-
    athletes’ labor on the gridiron and the court.
    At the second step of the Rule of Reason analysis, the
    NCAA was required to come forward with evidence of the
    restraints’ procompetitive effects. The district court properly
    concluded that only some of the challenged NCAA rules
    served the procompetitive purpose of preserving amateurism
    and thus improving consumer choice by maintaining a
    distinction between college and professional sports. Those
    rules were limits on above-cost-of-attendance payments
    unrelated to education, the cost-of-attendance cap on athletic
    scholarships, and certain restrictions on cash academic or
    graduation awards and incentives. The panel affirmed the
    district court’s conclusion that the remaining rules, restricting
    non-cash education-related benefits, did nothing to foster or
    preserve consumer demand. The panel held that the record
    amply supported the findings of the district court, which
    reasonably relied on demand analysis, survey evidence, and
    NCAA testimony.
    The panel affirmed the district court’s conclusion that, at
    the third step of the Rule of Reason analysis, the student-
    athletes showed that any legitimate objectives could be
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.     7
    achieved in a substantially less restrictive manner. The
    district court identified a less restrictive alternative of
    prohibiting the NCAA from capping certain education-related
    benefits and limiting academic or graduation awards or
    incentives below the maximum amount that an individual
    athlete may receive in athletic participation awards, while
    permitting individual conferences to set limits on education-
    related benefits. The panel held that the district court did not
    clearly err in determining that this alternative would be
    virtually as effective in serving the procompetitive purposes
    of the NCAA’s current rules, and could be implemented
    without significantly increased cost.
    Finally, the panel held that the district court’s injunction
    was not impermissibly vague and did not usurp the NCAA’s
    role as the superintendent of college sports. The panel also
    declined to broaden the injunction to include all NCAA
    compensation limits, including those on payments untethered
    to education. The panel concluded that the district court
    struck the right balance in crafting a remedy that both
    prevented anticompetitive harm to student-athletes while
    serving the procompetitive purpose of preserving the
    popularity of college sports.
    Concurring, Judge M. Smith wrote that because he was
    bound by O’Bannon II, he joined the panel opinion in full.
    He wrote separately to express concern that the current state
    of antitrust law reflects an unwitting expansion of the Rule of
    Reason inquiry in a way that deprived the student-athletes of
    the fundamental protections that the antitrust laws were
    meant to provide them.
    8   IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    COUNSEL
    Seth P. Waxman (argued), Leon B. Greenfield, Daniel S.
    Volchok, David M. Lehn, and Kevin M. Lamb, Wilmer
    Cutler Pickering Hale and Dorr LLP, Washington, D.C.; Bart
    H. Williams, Scott P. Cooper, Kyle A. Casazza, Jennifer L.
    Jones, and Shawn S. Ledingham Jr., Proskauer Rose LLP,
    Los Angeles, California; Leane K. Capps and Caitlin J.
    Morgan, Polsinelli PC, Dallas, Texas; Amy D. Fitts,
    Polsinelli PC, Kansas City, Missouri; Mark A. Cunningham,
    Jones Walker LLP, New Orleans, Louisiana; Beth A.
    Wilkinson and Brant W. Bishop, Wilkinson Walsh &
    Eskovitz LLP, Washington, D.C.; Sean Eskovitz, Wilkinson
    Walsh & Eskovitz LLP, Los Angeles, California; Jeffrey A.
    Mishkin and Karen Hoffman Lent, Skadden Arps Slate
    Meagher & Flom LLP, New York, New York; Robert W.
    Fuller III, Pearlynn G. Houck, and Lawrence C. Moore III,
    Robinson Bradshaw & Hinson P.A., Charlotte, North
    Carolina; Mark J. Seifert, Seifert Law Firm, San Francisco,
    California; Andrew J. Pincus, Charles A. Rothfeld, and
    Richard J. Favretto, Mayer Brown LLP, Washington, D.C.;
    Britt M. Miller and Andrew S. Rosenman, Mayer Brown
    LLP, Chicago, Illinois; Meryl Macklin, Bryan Cave Leighton
    Paisner LLP, San Francisco, California; Richard Young and
    Brent E. Rychner, Bryan Cave Leighton Paisner LLP,
    Colorado Springs, Colorado; Benjamin C. Block, Covington
    & Burling LLP, Washington, D.C.; R. Todd Hunt and
    Benjamin G. Chojnacki, Walter Haverfield LLP, Cleveland,
    Ohio; D. Erik Albright and Gregory G. Holland, Fox
    Rothschild LLP, Greensboro, North Carolina; Jonathan P.
    Heyl, Fox Rothschild LLP, Charlotte, North Carolina;
    Charles L. Coleman III, Holland & Knight LLP, San
    Francisco, California; for Defendants-Appellants.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   9
    Steve Berman (argued), Craigh R. Spiegel, and Emilee N.
    Sisco, Hagens Berman Sobol Shapiro LLP, Seattle,
    Washington; Jeffrey L. Kessler (argued), David G. Feher, and
    David L. Greenspan, Winston & Strawn LLP, New York,
    New York; Bruce L. Simon and Benjamin E. Shiftan, Pearson
    Simon & Warshaw LLP, San Francisco, California; Elizabeth
    C. Pritzker, Jonathan K. Levine, Bethany L. Caracuzzo, and
    Shiho Yamamoto, Pritzker Levine LLP, Oakland, California;
    Linda T. Coberly, Winston & Strawn LLP, Chicago, Illinois;
    Sean D. Meenan and Jeanifer E. Parsigian, Winston & Strawn
    LLP, San Francisco, California; for Plaintiffs-Appellees.
    Maurice M. Suh, Gibson Dunn & Crutcher LLP, Los
    Angeles, California; Andrew S. Tulumello and Nick Harper,
    Gibson Dunn & Crutcher LLP, Washington, D.C.; for Amici
    Curiae National Football League Players Association and
    National Basketball Players Association.
    Bradley S. Pauley, Horvitz & Levy LLP, Burbank, California,
    for Amicus Curiae National Federation of State High School
    Associations.
    Emma Rebhorn, Change to Win, New York, New York;
    Sandeep Vaheesan, Open Markets Institute, Washington,
    D.C.; Najah A. Farley, National Employment Law Project,
    New York, New York; for Amici Curiae Open Markets
    Institute, Change to Win, National Employment Law Project,
    and Economics and Law Professors.
    10 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    OPINION
    THOMAS, Chief Judge:
    We consider an appeal and cross-appeal from an order
    enjoining the National Collegiate Athletic Association (the
    “NCAA”) from enforcing rules that restrict the education-
    related benefits that its member institutions may offer
    students who play Football Bowl Subdivision (“FBS”)
    football and Division I (“D1”) basketball (collectively,
    “Student-Athletes”). See In re NCAA Athletic Grant-In-Aid
    Cap Antitrust Litig. (Alston), 
    375 F. Supp. 3d 1058
    (N.D. Cal.
    2019). We have jurisdiction under 28 U.S.C. § 1291, and we
    affirm.
    We conclude that the district court properly applied the
    Rule of Reason in determining that the enjoined rules are
    unlawful restraints of trade under section 1 of the Sherman
    Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. We further conclude that the record
    supports the factual findings underlying the injunction and
    that the district court’s antitrust analysis is faithful to our
    decision in O’Bannon v. NCAA (O’Bannon II), 
    802 F.3d 1049
    (9th Cir. 2015).
    I
    A. The NCAA and its Compensation Rules
    Founded in 1905, the NCAA regulates intercollegiate
    sports.
    Id. at 1053.
    Its mission statement is to “maintain
    intercollegiate athletics as an integral part of the educational
    program and the athlete as an integral part of the student body
    and, by so doing, retain a clear line of demarcation between
    intercollegiate athletics and professional sports.” NCAA
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.       11
    regulations govern, among other things, the payments that
    student-athletes may receive in exchange for and incidental
    to their athletic participation as well as in connection with
    their academic pursuits.
    The NCAA divides its member schools into three
    competitive divisions. D1 schools—some 350 of the
    NCAA’s approximately 1,100 member schools—sponsor the
    largest athletic programs and offer the most financial aid. D1
    football has two subdivisions, one of which is the FBS.
    In August 2014, the NCAA amended its D1 bylaws (the
    “Bylaws”) to grant the so-called “Power Five”
    conferences—the FBS conferences that generate the most
    revenue—autonomy to adopt collectively legislation in
    certain areas, including limits on athletic scholarships known
    as “grants-in-aid.”1 In January 2015, the Power Five voted to
    increase the grant-in-aid limit to the cost of attendance
    (“COA”) at each school. Since August 2015, the Bylaws
    have provided that a “full grant-in-aid” encompasses “tuition
    and fees, room and board, books and other expenses related
    to attendance at the institution up to the [COA],” as
    calculated by each institution’s financial aid office under
    federal law. See 20 U.S.C. §§ 1087kk, ll. The Bylaws also
    contain an “Amateurism Rule,” which strips student-athletes
    of eligibility for intercollegiate competition if they “[u]se[]
    [their] athletics skill (directly or indirectly) for pay in any
    1
    The Power Five conferences are the Atlantic Coast Conference (the
    “ACC”), Big Ten Conference, Big 12 Conference, Pacific 12 Conference
    (the “Pac-12”), and Southeastern Conference (the “SEC”). Student-
    Athletes named the Power Five as defendants, along with Conference
    USA, the Mid-American Conference (the “MAC”), Mountain West
    Conference, Sun Belt Conference, Western Athletic Conference, and
    American Athletic Conference (the “AAC”).
    12 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    form in [their] sport.” “[P]ay” is defined as the “receipt of
    funds, awards or benefits not permitted by governing
    legislation.”
    However, governing legislation permits a wide range of
    above-COA payments—both related and unrelated to
    education. Without losing their eligibility, student-athletes
    may receive, for instance: (i) awards valued at several
    hundred dollars for athletic performance (“athletic
    participation awards”),2 which may take the form of Visa gift
    cards; (ii) disbursements—sometimes thousands of
    dollars—from the NCAA’s Student Assistance Fund (“SAF”)
    and Academic Enhancement Fund (“AEF”) for a variety of
    purposes, such as academic achievement or graduation
    awards, school supplies, tutoring, study-abroad expenses,
    post-eligibility financial aid, health and safety expenses,
    clothing, travel, “personal or family expenses,” loss-of-value
    insurance policies, car repair, personal legal services, parking
    tickets, and magazine subscriptions;3 (iii) cash stipends of
    several thousands of dollars calculated to cover costs of
    2
    Athletic participation awards include the “Senior Scholar-Athlete
    Award,” which is a postgraduate scholarship of $10,000 or less that
    institutions may award two student-athletes per year, and awards for
    achievement in special events, such as all-star or post-season bowl games.
    3
    The record indicates that the NCAA does little to regulate or monitor
    the use of these funds. While it controls the total pool of money that an
    institution may distribute each year, it has not capped the amount that an
    individual athlete may receive. The SAF is broadly available to “assist
    student-athletes in meeting financial needs that arise in conjunction with
    participation in intercollegiate athletics, enrollment in an academic
    curriculum or to recognize academic achievement as determined by
    conference offices.” And the NCAA “encourage[s]” schools to allocate
    AEF funds to provide “direct benefits to student-athletes that enhance
    [their] welfare.”
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.          13
    attendance beyond the fixed costs of tuition, room and board,
    and books, but used wholly at the student-athlete’s
    discretion;4 (iv) mandatory medical care (available for at least
    two years after the athlete graduates) for an athletics-related
    injury; (v) unlimited meals and snacks; (vi) reimbursements
    for expenses incurred by student-athletes’ significant others
    and children to attend certain athletic competitions; and
    (vii) a $30 per diem for “unitemized incidental expenses
    during travel and practice” for championship events.
    The NCAA has carved out many of these exceptions in
    the past five years. For example, before 2015, athletic
    participation awards did not take the form of cash-like Visa
    gift cards. And once the NCAA permitted grants-in-aid for
    the full COA, effective August 2015, many more student-
    athletes began to receive above-COA payments, such as cash
    stipends, Pell Grants, and AEF as well as SAF distributions.
    This expansion of above-COA compensation has
    coincided with rising revenue from D1 basketball and FBS
    football for the NCAA and its members. In the 2015–16
    academic year, these programs generated $4.3 billion in
    revenue (a $300 million increase from the previous year) for
    the Power Five. And in 2016, the NCAA negotiated an eight-
    year extension (until 2032) of its multimedia contract for the
    broadcasting rights to March Madness, the annual D1 men’s
    basketball tournament. Under that agreement, the NCAA will
    receive $1.1 billion per year (an annual increase of over $325
    million).
    4
    Under the Bylaws, student-athletes who have already received Pell
    Grants (calculated to cover the COA) may also receive these stipends.
    14 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    B. The O’Bannon Litigation
    The NCAA is no stranger to antitrust litigation arising
    from its compensation rules. In 2009, Ed O’Bannon, a
    former UCLA basketball player, sued the NCAA after
    learning that a college basketball video game featured an
    avatar that resembled him and sported his jersey number.
    O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1055
    . “The gravamen of [his]
    complaint” was that the NCAA illegally restrained trade, in
    violation of section 1, by preventing FBS football and D1
    men’s basketball players from receiving compensation for the
    use of their names, images, and likenesses (“NILs”).5
    Id. After a
    bench trial, the district court agreed under the
    Rule of Reason and entered relief for the plaintiffs. See
    O’Bannon v. NCAA (O’Bannon I), 
    7 F. Supp. 3d 955
    , 962–63
    (N.D. Cal. 2014), aff’d in part, rev’d in part, O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1079
    . The district court acknowledged the
    NCAA’s evidence that college athletics’ “amateur tradition”
    helps maintain their popularity as a product distinct from
    professional sports.
    Id. at 999.
    It nevertheless concluded that
    this procompetitive benefit did not justify the NCAA’s
    “sweeping prohibition” on NIL compensation.
    Id. Based on
    evidence that “school loyalty and geography” primarily drive
    consumer demand and a lack of proof that small payments to
    student-athletes would diminish college sports’ popularity,
    5
    The O’Bannon class included “[a]ll current and former student-
    athletes” who had played D1 men’s basketball or FBS football “and whose
    [NILs] may be, or have been, included or could have been included (by
    virtue of their appearance in a team roster) in game footage or in
    video[]games licensed or sold by Defendants, their co-conspirators, or
    their licensees.”
    Id. at 1055–56.
        IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   15
    the district court determined that the NCAA could justify, at
    most, restrictions on large payments.
    Id. at 1000–01.
    After identifying two less restrictive alternatives
    (“LRAs”) to the challenged rules,
    id. at 1004–07,
    the district
    court implemented those LRAs through an injunction that
    required the NCAA to permit its schools to (i) “use the
    licensing revenue generated from the use of their student-
    athletes’ [NILs] to fund stipends covering the [COA]”; and
    (ii) to make deferred, post-eligibility cash payments in NIL
    revenue, not to exceed $5,000, to student-athletes.
    Id. at 1007–08;
    see also
    id. at 1008
    (finding no evidence that “such
    a modest payment” would “undermine[]” NCAA’s
    “legitimate procompetitive goals”). The NCAA appealed.
    A majority of a Ninth Circuit panel concluded that the
    district court’s decision, the first of its kind, was “largely
    correct.” O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1053
    ;
    id. at 1079
    (Thomas, C.J., concurring in part and dissenting in part). The
    panel unanimously affirmed the injunction insofar as it
    required the NCAA to permit athletic scholarships for the full
    COA, but a panel majority reversed and vacated the
    injunction’s requirement that the NCAA allow deferred NIL
    payments.
    Id. at 1053.
    In pertinent part, the panel rejected the NCAA’s threshold
    argument that its amateurism rules, including those governing
    compensation, are “valid as a matter of law” under NCAA v.
    Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 
    468 U.S. 85
    (1984). O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1061
    . The panel
    acknowledged the Supreme Court’s observation, in “dicta,”
    that the NCAA has historically preserved its product by, inter
    alia, prohibiting payments to student-athletes.
    Id. at 1063
    (citing Bd. of 
    Regents, 468 U.S. at 102
    ). But it declined to
    16 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    read that statement as perpetual blanket approval for the
    NCAA’s compensation rules, which were not at issue in
    Board of Regents.
    Id. Though conceding
    that the NCAA’s
    “amateurism rules are likely to be procompetitive,”6
    id. at 1053,
    the panel refused to exempt them from antitrust
    scrutiny, see
    id. at 1064
    (explaining that a procompetitive rule
    “can still be invalid under the Rule of Reason”).
    The panel then affirmed much of the district court’s
    analysis. See
    id. at 1069–76.
    As is relevant here, it found,
    based on the record, “a concrete procompetitive effect in the
    NCAA’s commitment to amateurism: namely that the
    amateur nature of collegiate sports increases their appeal to
    consumers.”
    Id. at 1073.
    As to LRAs, it agreed that the ban
    on funding COA scholarships with NIL revenue was
    “patently and inexplicably stricter” than necessary to
    differentiate college from professional sports.
    Id. at 1075
    (“[B]y the NCAA’s own standards, student-athletes remain
    amateurs as long as any money paid to them goes to cover
    legitimate educational expenses.”). It clarified that courts
    must invalidate such restraints but may not “micromanage
    organizational rules” or “strike down largely beneficial
    market restraints[.]”
    Id. A panel
    majority, however, found error in the district
    court’s adoption of deferred NIL compensation “untethered
    to [student-athletes’] education expenses” as a viable LRA.
    Id. at 1076.
    It explained that “not paying student-athletes is
    precisely what makes them amateurs” and disagreed that
    6
    In O’Bannon II, “amateurism rules” refers to, inter alia, the
    NCAA’s “financial aid rules” and other rules “that limit student-athletes’
    compensation and their interactions with professional sports leagues.”
    Id. at 1055.
            IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.           17
    “being a poorly-paid professional” is “‘virtually as effective’
    for that market as being a[n] amateur.”
    Id. To avert
    a
    “transition[]” to “minor league status” and to heed the
    “Supreme Court’s admonition that [courts] must afford the
    NCAA ‘ample latitude’ to superintend college athletics,” the
    majority vacated this portion of the injunction.
    Id. at 1079
    (quoting Bd. of 
    Regents, 468 U.S. at 120
    ). In closing, it
    “emphasize[d] the limited scope of [its] decision,” explaining
    that “in th[at] case,” the Rule of Reason did “not require”
    anything “more” of the NCAA than to permit student-athletes
    to receive scholarships for the COA. Id.7
    C. The Alston Litigation
    In March 2014, while the NCAA was litigating O’Bannon
    I, FBS football and D1 men’s and women’s basketball players
    filed several antitrust actions against the NCAA and eleven
    D1 conferences that were transferred to and, with one
    exception, consolidated before the same district court
    presiding over O’Bannon I. Rather than confining their
    challenge to rules prohibiting NIL compensation, Student-
    Athletes sought to dismantle the NCAA’s entire
    compensation framework.
    7
    I dissented from this vacatur, mostly on the basis of the standard of
    review, because I concluded that the record supported the entirety of the
    judgment.
    Id. at 1080.
    Though agreeing that “court[s] should not
    eliminate the distinction between professional and college sports,” I also
    disagreed that the vacated remedy would have done so.
    Id. at 1082
    n.4.
    As a practical matter, the remedy that survived appeal required nothing of
    the NCAA, which had already adopted a more generous adjustment to the
    grant-in-aid limit by permitting schools to offer any D1 recruit an athletic
    scholarship up to the COA, irrespective of whether his or her NIL was or
    could be used or licensed.
    18 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    In December 2015, the district court certified three
    injunctive relief classes comprised of (i) FBS football players,
    (ii) D1 men’s basketball players, and (iii) D1 women’s
    basketball players. Each subclass consists of student-athletes
    who have received or will receive a full grant-in-aid during
    the pendency of this litigation.
    Nearly a year after our decision in O’Bannon II, the
    NCAA sought judgment on the pleadings, invoking res
    judicata. It argued that O’Bannon II “requires nothing more
    of the NCAA than that it permit its member schools to
    provide student-athletes with their full education-related
    [COA].” Because the NCAA had already amended its rules
    to satisfy that requirement, it reasoned that any post-
    O’Bannon antitrust challenges to its compensation rules must
    fail. The district court denied the motion. It explained that
    Student-Athletes, unlike the O’Bannon plaintiffs, had
    challenged, among other things, limits on non-cash,
    education-related benefits. It acknowledged the possibility
    that O’Bannon forecloses a type of relief—lifting restrictions
    on cash payments untethered to educational expenses—but
    declined to read it more broadly than that.
    Cross-motions for summary judgment followed. The
    district court again rejected the NCAA’s preclusion
    arguments. As to the merits, it adopted, at the parties’
    request, the market definition from O’Bannon I: the market
    for a college education or, alternatively, student-athletes’
    labor. It then granted Student-Athletes summary judgment at
    the Rule of Reason’s first step, as the NCAA did not
    meaningfully dispute that the challenged rules have
    anticompetitive effects in the relevant markets. At the Rule
    of Reason’s second step, it determined that the NCAA had
    raised triable issues as to whether its rules have the
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    19
    procompetitive effect(s) of maintaining the popularity of its
    elite college basketball and football products or integrating
    student-athletes into the wider campus community. Last, the
    district court found that Student-Athletes had proffered
    sufficient evidence to support their two proposed LRAs:
    (i) allowing individual conferences, but not the NCAA, to
    regulate student-athlete compensation; or (ii) enjoining
    NCAA rules that restrict both non-cash education-related
    benefits and benefits that are incidental to athletic
    participation.
    D. The District Court’s Decision
    After a ten-day bench trial, the district court entered
    judgment for Student-Athletes, in part. The court concluded
    that NCAA limits on education-related benefits are
    unreasonable restraints of trade, and accordingly enjoined
    those limits; however, the court declined to hold that NCAA
    limits on compensation unrelated to education likewise
    violate section 1. 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1109
    .
    1. Determination that O’Bannon Is Not Preclusive
    At the outset of its conclusions of law, the district court
    again declined to dismiss the case on res judicata grounds.
    Id. at 1092–96.
    It identified “material factual differences”
    between O’Bannon and the Alston litigation,
    id. at 1095,
    including in the identity of class members and the rules and
    rights at issue, see
    id. at 1093–94
    (explaining that “[t]he crux
    of the O’Bannon case was the right to student-athletes’
    NIL[s],” whereas “[t]he conduct at issue here is not connected
    to NIL rights” but to limits on above-COA compensation and
    benefits);
    id. at 1094
    (noting that challenged rules either did
    20 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    not exist or have “materially changed” since O’Bannon). The
    district court then proceeded to its Rule of Reason analysis.
    2. The Relevant Market
    To begin, the district court accepted Student-Athletes’
    trial theory narrowing the relevant market to one in which
    Student-Athletes sell their “labor in the form of athletic
    services” to schools in exchange for athletic scholarships and
    other payments permitted by the NCAA.
    Id. at 1067,
    1097.
    3. Anticompetitive Effects
    Next, the court reiterated its summary judgment finding
    of “significant anticompetitive effects in the relevant market.”
    Id. at 1067,
    1097. It relied on Student-Athletes’ economic
    analyses reflecting that schools, as buyers of athletic services,
    exercise monopsony power to artificially cap compensation
    at a level that is not commensurate with student-athletes’
    value.
    Id. at 1068.
    Based on these analyses, it also found
    that, but for the challenged restraints, schools would offer
    recruits compensation that more closely correlates with their
    talent.
    Id. at 1068–69,
    1098.
    The district court also highlighted additional trial
    evidence demonstrating the challenged rules’ anticompetitive
    effects. This included testimony that, in 2013, the Power
    Five began to urge the NCAA to loosen its compensation
    restrictions based on a concern that existing rules
    incongruously allowed schools to spend on virtually anything,
    including palatial athletic facilities and seven-figure coaches’
    salaries, except direct financial support for student-athletes.
    Id. at 1068–69.
    In the district court’s view, the Power Five’s
    concerns constituted further proof that, absent the NCAA’s
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.             21
    rules, student-athletes would receive higher compensation.
    Id. at 1069.
    Although the NCAA granted the Power Five
    autonomy to create new forms of compensation and to
    expand previously available compensation and benefits in
    2015, the district court observed that these conferences
    remain constrained by “overarching NCAA limits” that cap
    compensation at an artificially low level.
    Id. 4. Procompetitive
    Effect
    The district court then turned to the NCAA’s asserted
    procompetitive justifications. In pertinent part, the NCAA
    argued that the challenged rules implement “amateurism,”
    which drives consumer interest in college sports because
    “consumers ‘value amateurism.’”8
    Id. at 1070
    (internal
    citation omitted). The district court accepted this justification
    with respect to the NCAA’s limits on cash compensation
    untethered to education, but not as to its limits on non-cash
    education-related benefits.
    Id. at 1082
    –83, 1101–02.
    As a preliminary matter, the district court found no proof
    that the challenged rules directly foster consumer demand.
    Id. at 1070
    . It acknowledged the NCAA’s theory that its
    rules safeguard “amateurism” for consumers’ benefit, but the
    8
    This justification is the only one raised on appeal. The district court
    rejected the NCAA’s other proffered justification (abandoned on appeal):
    The challenged rules purportedly enhance student-athletes’ college
    education by integrating them into the wider campus community.
    Id. at 1083–86,
    1102–03. The district court declined to find that the
    challenged rules improve academic performance or prevent a social
    “wedge” between athletes and non-athletes.
    Id. at 1083–85,
    1102–03. To
    the contrary, it found that the challenged rules foster resentment by
    permitting expenditures on “frills, like extravagant athletes-only
    facilities.”
    Id. at 1085–86,
    1103.
    22 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    meaning of that term eluded the court.9 See
    id. at 1070–71
    (noting former SEC commissioner’s testimony that he “do[es
    not] even know what [amateurism] means” (internal citation
    omitted)). Though the NCAA defined amateurism during the
    litigation as “‘not paying’ the participants,”
    id. at 1071
    (internal citation omitted), the district court observed that this
    purported pay-for-play prohibition is riddled with exceptions.
    See
    id. at 1071
    –74.
    After cataloguing the long list of above-COA payments
    that the NCAA permits, the court then reached two
    conclusions: (i) the challenged rules “do not follow any
    coherent definition of amateurism . . . or even ‘pay,’” and
    (ii) these payments (many of which post-date O’Bannon)
    have not diminished demand for college sports, which
    “remain[] exceedingly popular and revenue-producing.”
    Id. at 1074.
    On the question of consumer demand, the district court
    found Student-Athletes’ evidence regarding the effect (or lack
    thereof) of above-COA compensation on demand more
    compelling than the NCAA’s. For instance, in the battle of
    economic experts, the district court found the NCAA’s only
    demand expert, Dr. Kenneth Elzinga, unreliable because he
    failed to study “standard measures of consumer demand, such
    as revenues, ticket sales, or ratings,” but instead relied on
    interviews with NCAA affiliates introduced to him by
    9
    The NCAA’s “Principle of Amateurism” provides that student-
    athletes’ “participation should be motivated primarily by education and by
    the physical, mental and social benefits to be derived,” that their
    “participation in intercollegiate athletics is an avocation,” and that they
    “should be protected from exploitation by professional and commercial
    enterprises.”
    Id. at 1070
    (internal citation omitted).
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   23
    defense counsel.
    Id. at 1075
    . The district court further found
    his analysis irrelevant as he refused to study consumer
    response to historical changes in compensation levels based
    on the false premise that the NCAA’s amateurism rules have
    not materially changed over time.
    Id. By contrast,
    the district court credited Student-Athletes’
    expert Dr. Daniel Rascher’s demand analysis, which was
    based on two natural experiments and, in some respects,
    corroborated by defense witnesses.
    Id. at 1076–78,
    1100.
    The first experiment—comparing consumer demand before
    and after the August 2015 increase to the grant-in-aid limit,
    which resulted in “thousands of class members receiving
    significant” above-COA payments, including SAF and AEF
    distributions—demonstrated “no negative impact on
    consumer demand.”
    Id. at 1076.
    In fact, Dr. Rascher found
    that revenues from D1 basketball and FBS football, “one of
    the best economic measures of consumer demand,” have
    increased since 2015.
    Id. at 1076–77;
    see also
    id. at 1078
    (noting corroborating testimony by an NCAA Rule 30(b)(6)
    witness and a Big 12 Rule 30(b)(6) witness). The second
    experiment—comparing demand before and after the
    University of Nebraska (of the Big Ten) began providing
    athletes up to $7,500 in post-eligibility education-related
    aid—likewise did not demonstrably reduce interest in
    Nebraska sports or FBS football and D1 basketball more
    broadly.
    Id. at 1077
    –78.
    
    The district court also found Student-Athletes’ survey
    expert, Dr. Hal Poret, considerably more persuasive than the
    NCAA’s, Dr. Bruce Isaacson.
    Id. at 1078
    –80, 
    1100–01.
    Dr. Isaacson asked respondents why they watch college
    sports and listed “amateurs and/or not paid” as one possible
    reason, but failed to indicate that “amateurs” means “not
    24 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    paid” or to otherwise define “amateurs,” thus “render[ing] the
    responses hopelessly ambiguous.”
    Id. at 1078
    . 
    Moreover, he
    measured only consumer preference and conceded that he did
    not attempt to study behavior.
    Id. at 1079
    . By contrast,
    Dr. Poret tested behavior and found that consumers would
    continue to view or attend college athletics (at the same rate)
    even if eight types of compensation that the NCAA currently
    prohibits or limits were individually implemented.
    Id. at 1079
    –80. The district court credited this conclusion.
    Id. at 1079
    –80 & n.24.
    Testimony by NCAA lay witnesses that “student” status
    drives demand also failed to persuade the district court of a
    connection between the challenged compensation regime and
    demand.
    Id. at 1082
    , 1101. It reasoned that “student-athletes
    would continue to be students in the absence of the
    challenged rules,”
    id. at 1082,
    relying on O’Bannon II’s
    observation that higher education “would still be available to
    student-athletes if they were paid some compensation in
    addition to their athletic scholarships,”
    id. at 1101
    (quoting
    O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1073
    ). It also underscored the
    absence of evidence that the NCAA had promulgated its rules
    based on demand analyses.
    Id. at 1080,
    1100–01.
    Despite finding the NCAA’s procompetitive theory
    largely unpersuasive, the district court “credit[ed] the
    importance to consumer demand of maintaining a distinction
    between college sports and professional sports.”
    Id. at 1082
    .
    The court then found that some NCAA rules—the COA limit
    on the grant-in-aid, limits on compensation unrelated to
    education, and limits on cash awards for graduating or other
    academic achievements—serve that purpose by precluding
    “unlimited payments unrelated to education, akin to salaries
    seen in professional sports leagues.”
    Id. at 1082
    –83; see also
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   25
    id. at 1101
    –02. But the court concluded that limits on “non-
    cash education-related benefits,” such as post-eligibility
    graduate scholarships or tutoring, do not have that effect; it
    reasoned that such benefits “could not be confused with a
    professional athlete’s salary” and would only “emphasize that
    the recipients are students.”
    Id. at 1083.
    5. Less Restrictive Alternative
    At the Rule of Reason’s third step, the district court
    considered whether three potential alternatives to the
    challenged restraints were less restrictive but virtually as
    effective in preventing “demand-reducing unlimited
    compensation indistinguishable from that observed in
    professional sports.”
    Id. at 1086.
    The district court rejected
    two proposed LRAs, both of which would have permitted
    individual conferences to limit above-COA compensation,
    but would have otherwise invalidated either (i) all NCAA
    compensation limits or (ii) NCAA limits on education-related
    compensation and existing caps on benefits incidental to
    athletics participation, such as healthcare, pre-season
    expenses, and athletic participation awards.
    Id. at 1086–87.
    The district court found that both these alternatives would
    enable professional-style cash payments, thus threatening the
    distinction between college and professional sports.
    Id. at 1087
    . 
    The court acknowledged the possibility that
    conferences could “discover” demand-preserving
    compensation levels.
    Id. But it
    rejected these LRAs to avoid
    demand-reducing “miscalculations” during “the inevitable
    trial-and-error phase.”
    Id. 26 IN
    RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    The district court then identified a viable LRA:
    (1) allow the NCAA to continue to limit
    grants-in-aid at not less than the [COA];
    (2) allow the [NCAA] to continue to limit
    compensation and benefits unrelated to
    education; (3) enjoin NCAA limits on most
    compensation and benefits that are related to
    education, but allow it to limit education-
    related academic or graduation awards and
    incentives, as long as the limits are not lower
    than its limits on athletic performance awards
    now or in the future.10
    Id. The court
    enumerated specific education-related benefits
    that the NCAA would be unable to prohibit or limit under the
    LRA: “computers, science equipment, musical instruments
    and other items not currently included in the [COA] but
    nonetheless related to the pursuit of various academic
    studies”; post-eligibility scholarships for undergraduate,
    graduate, and vocational programs at any school; tutoring;
    study-abroad expenses; and paid post-eligibility internships.
    Id. at 1088.
    The district court explained that this LRA would permit
    some NCAA regulation of cash graduation or academic
    awards because these payments could otherwise morph into
    professional-like salaries.
    Id. It instructed
    that the cap on
    such awards should not fall below the existing limit on
    aggregate athletic participation awards (currently, $5,600), as
    receipt of the latter “has been shown not to decrease
    10
    The district court found that the current aggregate limit on such
    awards is $5,600.
    Id. at 1072
    , 
    1099.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    27
    consumer demand and not to be inconsistent with the
    NCAA’s understanding of amateurism.”
    Id. Under this
    LRA, individual conferences may continue to limit all
    payment types because “no individual conference dominates
    nearly the entire market, like the NCAA does.”
    Id. The district
    court further reasoned that this LRA would not
    “greatly impact[]” the NCAA’s “latitude to superintend
    college sports,” as it “would affect only a small fraction of
    [its] rulemaking jurisdiction.”
    Id. The district
    court concluded that this LRA would be
    virtually as effective as the challenged rules at preserving
    student-athletes’ status as students (and thus demand),
    analogizing it to the LRA affirmed in O’Bannon II: Both
    require the NCAA to permit members “to cover legitimate
    education-related costs.”
    Id. at 1105
    (citing O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1075
    ). Finally, it determined that, far from
    resulting in significantly increased costs, the LRA’s
    elimination of a category of rules would decrease the
    NCAA’s enforcement costs.
    Id. at 1090–91,
    1105.
    6. Remedy
    The district court implemented this LRA via a permanent
    injunction. See In re NCAA Athletic Grant-In-Aid Cap
    Antitrust Litig., 
    2019 WL 1593939
    (N.D. Cal. Mar. 8, 2019).
    The injunction provides that the parties may move to modify
    its list of education-related benefits and that the NCAA may
    move to incorporate a definition of compensation and benefits
    that are “related to education” if it chooses to adopt one.
    Id. at *1.
    It also allows the NCAA to regulate how its members
    provide education-related benefits. Id.; see also 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1107
    (“[T]he NCAA could require schools
    to pay for these items directly or to reimburse student-athletes
    28 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    for [equipment] expenses if adequate proof of purchase is
    shown.”). The court reiterated that NCAA members remain
    free to independently restrict pay. 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1109
    . And it stayed the injunction pending resolution of a
    timely appeal.
    Id. at 1110.
    E. Post-Appeal Developments
    After the NCAA timely appealed, California enacted the
    Fair Pay to Play Act (the “FPP Act”). See Cal. S.B. 206
    (Sept. 30, 2019), Cal. Educ. Code § 67456. The FPP Act
    requires the NCAA and its member institutions to permit
    student-athletes enrolled in California colleges and
    universities to earn compensation from the use of their NILs.
    Id. § 67456(a),
    (g). It takes effect on January 1, 2023.
    Id. § 67456(h).
    In response to the FPP Act, the NCAA created a working
    group that has recommended permitting NIL benefits so long
    as they are tethered to education and otherwise preserve the
    distinction between college and professional sports
    recognized in O’Bannon II. See Fed. and State Leg. Working
    Grp. Report 4 (Oct. 23, 2019), available at
    https://tinyurl.com/working-grp-report. In recent testimony
    before the Senate Commerce Subcommittee on
    Manufacturing, Trade and Consumer Protection, NCAA
    President Dr. Mark Emmert denied that the NCAA would be
    “taking any action that is contrary to the position advocated
    by the NCAA or accepted by the Ninth Circuit with respect
    to the type of NIL payments that were at issue in the
    O’Bannon case[.]” See Test. of Dr. Mark Emmert 6 (Feb. 11,
    2020), available at https://tinyurl.com/Emmert-Test-y.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    29
    II
    The application of stare decisis and res judicata are
    questions of law that we review de novo. See In re Watts,
    
    298 F.3d 1077
    , 1079 (9th Cir. 2002); Media Rights Techs.,
    Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 
    922 F.3d 1014
    , 1020 (9th Cir. 2019).
    We review factual findings for clear error and legal
    conclusions de novo. See O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1061
    .
    Under clear error review, we must “accept the district court’s
    findings of fact unless we are left with the definite and firm
    conviction that a mistake has been committed.”
    Id. (quoting FTC
    v. BurnLounge, Inc., 
    753 F.3d 878
    , 883 (9th Cir. 2014));
    see also United States v. Alexander, 
    106 F.3d 874
    , 877 (9th
    Cir. 1997) (“We must not reverse as long as the findings are
    plausible in light of the record viewed in its entirety[.]”). In
    other words, a decision is not clearly erroneous unless it
    “strike[s] us as wrong with the force of a five-week-old,
    unrefrigerated dead fish.” Prete v. Bradbury, 
    438 F.3d 949
    ,
    968 n.23 (9th Cir. 2006) (internal citation omitted).
    Last, “[w]e review a district court’s decision to grant a
    permanent injunction for an abuse of discretion”; the “factual
    findings underpinning the award” for clear error; and the
    “rulings of law relied upon by the district court in awarding
    injunctive relief” de novo. Ollier v. Sweetwater Union High
    Sch. Dist., 
    768 F.3d 843
    , 867 (9th Cir. 2014) (internal
    citations and quotation marks omitted).
    30 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    III
    The district court correctly concluded O’Bannon II did
    not foreclose this litigation as a matter of stare decisis and res
    judicata.
    A
    Stare decisis binds “today’s Court” to “yesterday’s
    decisions.” Danielson v. Inslee, 
    945 F.3d 1096
    , 1097 (9th
    Cir. 2019) (quoting Kimble v. Marvel Entm’t, LLC, 
    135 S. Ct. 2401
    , 2409 (2015)). “In determining whether [we are] bound
    by an earlier decision,” we consider “not only the rule
    announced, but also the facts giving rise to the dispute, other
    rules considered and rejected and the views expressed in
    response to any dissent or concurrence.” Hart v. Massanari,
    
    266 F.3d 1155
    , 1170 (9th Cir. 2001). “Insofar as there may
    be factual differences between the current case” and
    O’Bannon II, we “must determine whether those differences
    are material to the application of the rule or allow the
    precedent to be distinguished on a principled basis.”
    Id. at 1172;
    see also In re Osborne, 
    76 F.3d 306
    , 309 (9th Cir.
    1996) (explaining that decisions “furnish[] the rule for the
    determination of a subsequent case involving identical or
    similar material facts” (internal citation omitted)).
    Antitrust decisions are particularly fact-bound. The
    Supreme Court has long emphasized that the Rule of Reason
    “contemplate[s]” “case-by-case adjudication.” See Leegin
    Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 
    551 U.S. 877
    ,
    899 (2007); see also Maple Flooring Mfrs.’ Ass’n v. United
    States, 
    268 U.S. 563
    , 579 (1925) (“[E]ach case arising under
    the Sherman Act must be determined upon the particular facts
    disclosed by the record, and . . . opinions in those cases must
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   31
    be read in the light of their facts”); Phillip Areeda & Herbert
    Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust
    Principles and Their Application, ¶ 1205c3 (4th ed. 2018)
    (“Continuing contracts in restraint of trade,” are “typically
    subject to continuing reexamination,” and “even a judicial
    holding that a particular agreement is lawful does not
    immunize it from later suit or preclude its reexamination as
    circumstances change.”).
    O’Bannon II was a decision of “limited scope,” which the
    panel majority summarized as follows:
    [W]e reaffirm that NCAA regulations are
    subject to antitrust scrutiny and must be tested
    in the crucible of the Rule of Reason. . . .
    [T]he NCAA is not above the antitrust laws,
    and courts cannot and must not shy away from
    requiring the NCAA to play by the Sherman
    Act’s rules. In this case, the NCAA’s rules
    have been more restrictive than necessary to
    maintain its tradition of amateurism in support
    of the college sports market. The Rule of
    Reason requires that the NCAA permit its
    schools to provide up to the [COA] to their
    student athletes. It does not require 
    more. 802 F.3d at 1079
    (emphasis added).
    In arguing that the last two sentences of this passage
    foreclose the current litigation, the NCAA ignores the
    inherently fact-dependent nature of a Rule of Reason
    analysis, which evaluates dynamic market conditions and
    consumer preferences; the panel majority’s manifest effort to
    limit its decision to the record before it; and the majority’s
    32 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    mandate that courts must continue to subject NCAA rules,
    including those governing compensation, to antitrust scrutiny.
    See
    id. at 1064
    (“The amateurism rules’ validity must be
    proved, not presumed.”).
    Far from straying outside O’Bannon II’s bounds, the
    district court here sought to toe the line that the panel
    majority drew. The court uncapped education-related
    benefits, but left in place NCAA limits on compensation
    unrelated to education, consistent with the majority’s
    observation that “student-athletes remain amateurs as long as
    any money paid to them goes to cover legitimate educational
    expenses.”
    Id. at 1075
    (emphasis added); see also
    id. at 1076
    (vacating injunction only insofar as it forced NCAA to permit
    “cash payments untethered to . . . education expenses”).
    The district court meaningfully and properly distinguished
    O’Bannon II from the current litigation as a narrow challenge
    to restrictions on NIL compensation. See
    id. at 1052
    (introducing challenged rules as those that “prohibit student-
    athletes from being paid for the use of their [NILs]”);
    id. at 1055
    (stating that the “gravamen of O’Bannon’s complaint
    was that the NCAA’s amateurism rules, insofar as they
    prevented student-athletes from being compensated for the
    use of their NILs, were an illegal restraint of trade”);
    id. at 1073
    n.17 (“The correct inquiry under the Rule of Reason
    is: What procompetitive benefits are served by the NCAA’s
    existing rule banning NIL payments?”). Additionally, the
    proposed LRAs in O’Bannon were expressly limited to
    “licensing revenue generated from the use” of student-
    athletes’ NILs. See O’Bannon 
    I, 7 F. Supp. 3d at 1007
    . By
    contrast, this action more broadly targets the “interconnected
    set of NCAA rules that limit the compensation [student-
    athletes] may receive in exchange for their athletic services.”
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   33
    
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1062
    . And Student-Athletes
    sought LRAs that would uncap above-COA compensation,
    regardless whether their NILs have, will, or could generate
    any revenue that would fund such compensation. See
    id. at 1086.
    The NCAA’s argument that it should not incur antitrust
    liability for relaxing its compensation limits since O’Bannon
    is not persuasive. The district court rightly concluded that
    this argument misses the mark: “It is the fact that the prices
    of student-athlete compensation are fixed, as opposed to the
    amount at which these prices are fixed, that renders the
    agreements at issue anticompetitive.”
    Id. at 1095
    (citing
    O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1071
    (“It is no excuse that the
    prices fixed are themselves reasonable.”) (quoting Catalano,
    Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 
    446 U.S. 643
    , 647 (1980))).
    Additionally, the NCAA’s concession that it has relaxed
    its compensation limits since O’Bannon only underscores that
    the instant litigation is materially factually different from
    O’Bannon. Indeed, as Student-Athletes argue, the changes to
    compensation limits since O’Bannon “alter the factual
    assumption that drove the result in O’Bannon: they show that
    non-education-related cash payments in excess of the [COA]
    are no longer a ‘quantum leap’ from current NCAA
    practice[.]” See O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1078
    (“The
    difference between offering student-athletes education-related
    compensation and offering them cash sums untethered to
    educational expenses is not minor; it is a quantum leap.”)).
    In O’Bannon II, the majority addressed only two types of
    above-COA allowances: Pell Grants and prize money for
    tennis recruits. See
    id. at 1058–59.
    It distinguished Pell
    Grants, which are “intended for education-related expenses,”
    34 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    from “pure cash compensation” for athletic performance.
    Id. at 1078
    n.24. And it declared that “award money from
    outside athletic events implicates amateurism differently than
    allowing schools to pay student-[athletes] directly.”
    Id. at 1077
    n.21. Neither of these above-COA allowances is
    analogous to the post-O’Bannon II forms of
    compensation—provided by schools and unrelated to
    education—that the district court cited to support its
    conclusion that the NCAA, contrary to its theory of
    amateurism, does provide at least some “pay for play.” See
    
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1071
    –74. For example, the court
    found that, after the O’Bannon record closed, student-athletes
    have received, inter alia, athletic participation awards in the
    form of Visa gift cards,11 SAF disbursements in the thousands
    of dollars to pay for loss-of-value insurance,12 and personal
    expenses unrelated to education.
    Id. at 1095
    . Based on these
    innovations, the court fairly concluded that the compensation
    landscape has meaningfully changed since O’Bannon. See
    id. at 1094
    .
    In sum, because O’Bannon II “was decided on a narrow
    set of facts that are distinguishable from the present case,” we
    “decline to adopt” the NCAA’s “broad interpretation” of that
    decision. United States v. Silver, 
    245 F.3d 1075
    , 1079 (9th
    Cir. 2001).
    11
    Visa gift cards function like cash, even if the NCAA declines to
    admit as much.
    12
    The NCAA characterizes this insurance as a “legitimate expense to
    protect against the risk of loss that could be incurred during athletic
    competition,” but the legitimacy of these payments is irrelevant here.
    What matters, for stare decisis purposes, is that the O’Bannon II panel had
    no occasion to consider whether such payments accord with the NCAA’s
    conception of amateurism.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.      35
    B
    Res judicata, also known as “claim preclusion,” “bars a
    party in successive litigation from pursuing claims that ‘were
    raised or could have been raised in [a] prior action.’” Media
    Rights 
    Techs., 922 F.3d at 1020
    (internal citation omitted). It
    applies when there is: (i) an identity of claims between the
    prior and subsequent actions; (ii) a final judgment on the
    merits; and (iii) identity or privity between the parties.
    Id. at 1020–21.
    The NCAA bears the burden of proving all three
    elements.
    Id. at 1021.
    The NCAA fails to carry its burden
    with respect to the first element.
    “Claim preclusion does not apply to claims that were not
    in existence and could not have been sued upon . . . when the
    allegedly preclusive action was initiated.”
    Id. (internal citation
    omitted). That bright-line rule is dispositive here.
    Because Student-Athletes’ antitrust claim “arose from events
    that occurred after” the O’Bannon record closed in August
    2014—that is, the above-described proliferation of
    permissible above-COA payments alongside a growth in
    revenues from FBS football and D1 basketball—it is “not
    barred.” Howard v. City of Coos Bay, 
    871 F.3d 1032
    , 1040
    (9th Cir. 2017); see also Harkins Amusement Enters., Inc. v.
    Harry Nace Co., 
    890 F.2d 181
    , 183 (9th Cir. 1989) (“Failure
    to gain relief for one period of time does not mean that the
    plaintiffs will necessarily fail for a different period of time”);
    California v. Chevron Corp., 
    872 F.2d 1410
    , 1415 (9th Cir.
    1989) (providing that “conduct of the parties since the first
    36 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    judgment[] must be considered” in connection with
    successive antitrust suits).13
    IV
    The district court properly granted judgment on the
    Student-Athletes’ Sherman Act § 1 claim. The Sherman Act
    prohibits, inter alia, agreements “in restraint of” interstate
    trade or commerce. 15 U.S.C. § 1. The Supreme Court has
    interpreted section 1 “as ‘outlaw[ing] only unreasonable
    restraints’ of trade.” See In re Nat’l Football League’s
    Sunday Ticket Antitrust Litig., 
    933 F.3d 1136
    , 1149 (9th Cir.
    2019) (alteration in original) (quoting State Oil Co. v. Khan,
    
    522 U.S. 3
    , 10 (1997)). “[W]hen considering agreements
    among entities involved in league sports, such as here, [we]
    must determine whether the restriction is unreasonable under
    the [R]ule of [R]eason.”
    Id. at 1150
    n.5; see also O’Bannon
    
    II, 802 F.3d at 1069
    (“[T]he appropriate rule is the Rule of
    Reason.”).
    As applied here, under the Rule of Reason’s “three-step
    framework:” (1) Student-Athletes “bear[] the initial burden of
    showing that the restraint produces significant
    13
    In support of its res judicata argument, the NCAA cites the
    O’Bannon II majority’s discussion of the “danger” of “future plaintiffs”
    pursuing “essentially the same claim again and again.” If anything, the
    cited discussion cuts against the NCAA. The majority predicted that
    future challenges to the district court’s $5,000 cap on deferred NIL
    payments would ultimately result in student-athletes, “captur[ing] the full
    value of their NIL” and the NCAA’s transformation into a minor league.
    O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1079
    . Far from enshrining the majority’s
    decision as the last word on the legality of NCAA compensation rules, this
    hypothetical rests on the premise that res judicata would not have blocked
    such challenges.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   37
    anticompetitive effects within a relevant market”; (2) if they
    carry that burden, the NCAA “must come forward with
    evidence of the restraint’s procompetitive effects”; and
    (3) Student-Athletes “must then show that any legitimate
    objectives can be achieved in a substantially less restrictive
    manner.” O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1070
    (quoting Tanaka v.
    Univ. of S. Cal., 
    252 F.3d 1059
    , 1063 (9th Cir. 2001)).
    Throughout this analysis, we remain mindful that, although
    “the NCAA is not above the antitrust laws,”
    id. at 1079
    ,
    courts are not “free to micromanage organizational rules or to
    strike down largely beneficial market restraints,”
    id. at 1075.
    Accordingly, a court must invalidate a restraint and replace it
    with an LRA only if the restraint is “patently and inexplicably
    stricter than is necessary to accomplish all of its
    procompetitive objectives.”
    Id. at 1075
    .
    A
    The district court properly concluded that the Student-
    Athletes carried their burden at the first step of the Rule of
    Reason. The district court found that the NCAA’s rules have
    “significant anticompetitive effects in the relevant market”
    for Student-Athletes’ labor on the gridiron and the court. See
    
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1070
    (“[B]ecause elite student-
    athletes lack any viable alternatives to [D1], they are forced
    to accept, to the extent they want to attend college and play
    sports at an elite level after high school, whatever
    compensation is offered to them by [D1] schools, regardless
    of whether any such compensation is an accurate reflection of
    the competitive value of their athletic services.”). These
    findings “have substantial support in the record,” O’Bannon
    
    II, 802 F.3d at 1070
    ; see 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1067
    –70,
    and the NCAA does not dispute them, see O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1072
    .
    38 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    B
    The NCAA does, however, quarrel with the district
    court’s analysis at the Rule of Reason’s second step, where
    the NCAA bears a “heavy burden” of “competitively
    justify[ing]” its undisputed “deviation from the operations of
    a free market.” Bd. of 
    Regents, 468 U.S. at 113
    ; see also
    O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1064
    (explaining that the NCAA is
    not entitled to a presumption that its restraints are
    procompetitive). On appeal, the NCAA advances a single
    procompetitive justification: The challenged rules preserve
    “amateurism,” which, in turn, “widen[s] consumer choice” by
    maintaining a distinction between college and professional
    sports.
    “Improving customer choice is procompetitive.” Paladin
    Assocs., Inc. v. Mont. Power Co., 
    328 F.3d 1145
    , 1157 (9th
    Cir. 2003); see also O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1072
    (“[A]
    restraint that broadens choices can be procompetitive.”).
    Thus, the district court properly “credit[ed] the importance to
    consumer demand of maintaining a distinction between
    college and professional sports.” 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1082
    .14
    14
    Writing in support of Student-Athletes, amici assert that courts may
    not consider a restraint’s procompetitive benefits in a market outside the
    market deemed relevant for the purpose of evaluating a restraint’s
    anticompetitive effects. That proposition is not settled. See 
    Paladin, 328 F.3d at 1157
    n.11 (acknowledging the “theory that procompetitive
    effects in a separate market cannot justify anticompetitive effects in the
    market . . . under analysis” (citing United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc.
    
    405 U.S. 596
    , 610 (1972)). The O’Bannon II panel had no occasion to
    address it, as the parties there limited their dispute to whether the
    challenged rules, as a factual matter, preserved consumer demand. 
    See 802 F.3d at 1072
    –74. So, too, here: The parties have agreed that the
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.              39
    The district court concluded, however, that only some of
    the challenged rules serve that procompetitive purpose: limits
    on above-COA payments unrelated to education, the COA
    cap on athletic scholarships, and certain restrictions on cash
    academic or graduation awards and incentives.
    Id. at 1101–02
    (recognizing that removal of these restrictions
    could result in unlimited cash payments akin to professional
    salaries). It explained that the remaining rules—those
    restricting “non-cash education-related benefits”—do nothing
    to foster or preserve demand because “[t]he value of such
    benefits, like a scholarship for post-eligibility graduate school
    tuition, is inherently limited to its actual value, and could not
    be confused with a professional athlete’s salary.”
    Id. at 1083.
    The record amply supports these findings. The district
    court reasonably relied on demand analyses, survey evidence,
    and NCAA testimony indicating that caps on non-cash,
    education-related benefits have no demand-preserving effect
    and, therefore, lack a procompetitive justification. See
    id. at 1076
    –80.
    First, Dr. Rascher’s and Dr. Noll’s demand analyses
    demonstrate that the NCAA has loosened its restrictions on
    above-COA, education-related benefits since O’Bannon
    without adversely affecting consumer demand. These
    benefits include SAF and AEF distributions to cover fifth-
    and sixth-year aid, postgraduate scholarships, tutoring,
    relevant market is the market for Student-Athletes’ labor, while the market
    to be assessed for pro-competitive effects is the market for college sports.
    Thus, the issue is not presented in this case. Because the issue raised by
    amici is “not properly before us,” we express no view on its merits, and
    leave it for another day. Pres. Coal., Inc. v. Pierce, 
    667 F.2d 851
    , 862
    (9th Cir. 1982).
    40 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    international student fees, educational supplies, academic
    achievement or graduation awards, graduate school exam
    fees, and fees for internship programs.
    Id. at 1072
    n.15.
    Second, Student-Athletes’ survey evidence reflects that
    individually implementing seven types of education-related
    benefits—limited or forbidden under the challenged rules—
    would not diminish the survey respondents’ viewership or
    attendance.15
    Third, NCAA witnesses confirmed that the NCAA set
    limits on education-related benefits without consulting any
    demand studies. See
    id. at 1080
    (“Indeed, [Kevin] Lennon,
    who has worked for the NCAA for more than thirty years,
    testified that he does not recall any instance in which any
    study on consumer demand was considered by the NCAA
    membership when making rules about compensation”); see
    also
    id. at 1074
    (“Defendants have not provided any cogent
    explanation for why the NCAA generally prohibits financial
    aid for graduate school at another institution, or for why the
    Senior Scholar Awards are limited in quantity and amount.”).
    Notwithstanding this evidence, the NCAA accuses the
    district court of straying from a purported “judicial
    consensus” that the NCAA expands consumer choice by
    enforcing an amateurism principle under which student-
    athletes “must not be paid” a penny over the COA. This
    sweeping procompetitive justification—the “Not One Penny”
    15
    These benefits were: an academic incentive payment with a
    maximum value of $10,000, a graduation incentive payment with a
    maximum value of $10,000, a post-eligibility undergraduate scholarship,
    a work-study payment, off-season expenses, a graduate school scholarship
    for the COA, and a post-eligibility study-abroad scholarship.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    41
    standard, in Dr. Noll’s parlance—lacks support in both
    precedent and the record.
    Although both Board of Regents and O’Bannon II define
    amateurism to exclude payment for athletic performance,
    neither purports to immortalize that definition as a matter of
    law. In fact, O’Bannon II recognizes that Board of Regents’
    discussion of amateurism is 
    “dicta.” 802 F.3d at 1063
    . And
    to the extent the O’Bannon II majority accepted the NCAA’s
    conception of amateurism, it did so based on the record,
    which demonstrated a “concrete procompetitive effect,”
    id. at 1073
    , of limiting above-COA “NIL cash payments
    untethered to [students’] education expenses,”
    id. at 1076
    .
    The record in this case, by contrast, reflects no such
    concrete procompetitive effect of limiting non-cash,
    education-related benefits. Instead, the record supports a
    much narrower conception of amateurism that still gives rise
    to procompetitive effects: Not paying student-athletes
    “unlimited payments unrelated to education, akin to salaries
    seen in professional sports leagues” is what makes them
    “amateurs.” 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1083
    . The district
    court credited NCAA testimony that college sports resonates
    with fans because they are not professionalized, and that “if
    the college game looks to be professional sports, [fewer]
    people will watch it.”
    Id. at 1082
    (internal citations omitted).
    But the court reasonably declined to adopt the Not One Penny
    standard based on considerable evidence that college sports
    have retained their distinctive popularity despite an increase
    in permissible forms of above-COA compensation and
    benefits.
    In defense of its expansive conception of amateurism, the
    NCAA relies on its survey of 1,100 college sports fans,
    42 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    reflecting that 31.7 percent watch college sports because,
    inter alia, they “like the fact that college players are amateurs
    and/or are not paid.” The NCAA claims that the district court
    rejected this survey on “baseless grounds.” But it disregards
    the court’s primary and most compelling reason for
    dismissing this evidence: The survey results reflect, at most,
    a consumer preference for “amateurism,” but do not capture
    the effects (if any) that the tested compensation scenarios
    would have on consumer behavior. See
    id. at 1079
    (“Dr. Isaacson acknowledged that measuring consumer
    preferences is ‘not the same thing’ as measuring future
    consumer behavior, and that he did not do any work to
    measure any relationship between the two.” (internal citation
    omitted)). The NCAA does not deny this flaw in its survey
    evidence.
    The district court offered another sound reason to reject
    the NCAA’s survey evidence: The survey’s use of the phrase
    “amateurs and/or not paid” made its responses “hopelessly
    ambiguous.”
    Id. at 1078
    . 
    In so finding, the district court did
    not, as the NCAA complains, “inject ambiguity into a
    commonplace term.” Amateurism does not have a fixed
    definition, as NCAA officials themselves have conceded.
    See, e.g.,
    id. at 1070–71
    (“Mike Slive, who served as
    commissioner of the SEC, one of the Power Five, . . . testified
    that amateurism is ‘just a concept that I don’t even know
    what it means. I really don’t.’” (internal citation omitted));
    see also O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1083
    (Thomas, C.J.,
    dissenting) (referring to amateurism as a “nebulous concept
    prone to ever-changing definition”). Survey respondents who
    selected “amateurs and/or not paid” may have very well
    equated amateurism with student status, irrespective of
    whether those students receive compensation for athletics.
    See 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1082
    (acknowledging defense
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    43
    witness testimony that “consumers’ perception that student-
    athletes are, in fact, students” drives consumer demand for
    D1 basketball and FBS football). Given this lack of clarity,
    the district court reasonably concluded that the NCAA’s
    survey results were of limited evidentiary value.
    Finally, the district court properly considered whether the
    challenged rules themselves, rather than hypothetical
    alternatives, have procompetitive benefits. As both parties
    recognize, the proper “inquiry under the Rule of Reason is:
    What procompetitive benefits are served by the NCAA’s
    [challenged] rule[s]?” See O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1073
    n.17. As we have recounted, the district court gave reasoned
    consideration to the procompetitive effects achieved by each
    type of challenged rule, ultimately concluding that the NCAA
    “sufficiently show[ed] a procompetitive effect of some
    aspects of the challenged compensation scheme,” but not all.
    
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1103
    (emphasis added). By
    contrast, in O’Bannon, the district court erred at step two
    because it considered the procompetitive benefits of
    hypothetical limits on large amounts of compensation. See
    O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1073
    n.17 (“During the second step,
    the district court could only consider the benefits of the
    NCAA’s existing rule prohibiting NIL payments—it could
    not consider the potential benefits of an alternative rule (such
    as capping large payments).”). Here, the NCAA has
    conceded that its rules, in part, “prevent the receipt of
    unlimited pay” unrelated to education. Dr. Isaacson also
    acknowledged that the challenged rules prohibit unlimited
    pay. Thus, the court did not err in assessing whether such
    rules have procompetitive effects.
    In short, the district court fairly found that NCAA
    compensation limits preserve demand to the extent they
    44 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    prevent unlimited cash payments akin to professional salaries,
    but not insofar as they restrict certain education-related
    benefits.16
    C
    At the Rule of Reason’s third step, it is Student-Athletes’
    burden to “make a strong evidentiary showing” that their
    proposed LRAs to the challenged scheme “are viable.”
    Id. at 1074.
    “[T]o be viable,” an alternative “must be ‘virtually
    as effective’ in serving the procompetitive purposes of the
    NCAA’s current rules, and ‘without significantly increased
    cost.’”
    Id. (quoting Cty.
    of Tuolumne v. Sonora Cmty. Hosp.,
    
    236 F.3d 1148
    , 1159 (9th Cir. 2001)). Where “a restraint is
    patently and inexplicably stricter than is necessary to
    accomplish all of its procompetitive objectives, an antitrust
    court can and should invalidate it and order it replaced with
    [an LRA].”
    Id. at 1075
    .
    The LRA identified by the district court would prohibit
    the NCAA from (i) capping certain education-related
    16
    The NCAA asserts that the district court proceeded from the
    “simply fictional” premise that the dividing line between student-athletes
    and professionals is that the latter may receive “unlimited pay.” In
    context, the district court was using the term “unlimited pay” as shorthand
    for payments that run the risk of eroding consumer perception of student-
    athletes as students—that is, cash payments unrelated to education and
    akin to professional salaries. The NCAA’s own expert used that
    shorthand in surveying consumer attitudes toward an “unlimited payments
    scenario,” where “a college could pay a student-athlete any amount it
    wanted to, without any limit, for playing college sports.”
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.               45
    benefits17 and (ii) limiting academic or graduation awards or
    incentives below the maximum amount that an individual
    athlete may receive in athletic participation awards, while
    (iii) permitting individual conferences to set limits on
    education-related benefits. See 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1087
    . The district court did not clearly err in determining
    that this LRA would be “‘virtually as effective’ in serving the
    procompetitive purposes of the NCAA’s current rules,” and
    may be implemented without “significantly increased cost.”
    See O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1074
    (internal citation omitted).
    1
    The district court reasonably concluded that uncapping
    certain education-related benefits would preserve consumer
    demand for college athletics just as well as the challenged
    rules do. Such benefits are easily distinguishable from
    professional salaries, as they are “connect[ed] to education”;
    “their value is inherently limited to their actual costs”; and
    “they can be provided in kind, not in cash.” Alston, 375 F.
    Supp. 3d at 1102. And, as already detailed, the record
    furnishes ample support for the district court’s finding that
    the provision of education-related benefits has not and will
    not repel college sports fans.
    17
    Those benefits are the following: “computers, science equipment,
    musical instruments and other tangible items not included in the cost of
    attendance calculation but nonetheless related to the pursuit of academic
    studies; post-eligibility scholarships to complete undergraduate or
    graduate degrees at any school; scholarships to attend vocational school;
    tutoring; expenses related to studying abroad that are not included in the
    cost of attendance calculation; and paid post-eligibility internships.” In re
    NCAA Athletic Grant-In-Aid Cap Antitrust Litig., 
    2019 WL 1593939
    ,
    at *1.
    46 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    The district court drew an apt analogy between the LRA
    upheld in O’Bannon II and the LRA it identified here: Both
    athletic scholarships for the COA and education-related
    benefits “cover legitimate education-related costs.”
    Id. at 1105
    . Indeed, in affirming the district court’s order insofar
    as it raised the grant-in-aid cap to the COA, the O’Bannon II
    panel noted Dr. Emmert’s testimony that this alternative
    would not harm demand “because all the money given to
    students would be going to cover their ‘legitimate costs’ to
    attend school.” O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1075
    . In reference
    to this litigation, Dr. Emmert similarly announced the
    NCAA’s approval of the court’s order to the extent that it
    would foster competition among conferences and schools
    “over who can provide the best educational experience”—“an
    inherently good thing.” Associated Press, Emmert: Ruling
    reinforced fundamentals of NCAA, ESPN, Apr. 4, 2019,
    available at https://tinyurl.com/emmert-NCAA/.
    Dr. Emmert’s comment is consistent with the record. As
    in O’Bannon II, the NCAA presented no evidence that
    demand will suffer if schools are free to reimburse education-
    related expenses of inherently limited value. Indeed, its
    evidence was to the contrary. For instance, in testifying about
    a University of Nebraska program that permits student-
    athletes to receive up to $7,500 in post-eligibility aid (for
    study-abroad expenses, scholarships, and internships), the
    University’s former chancellor conceded that such benefits
    “relate to the educational enterprise” and, thus, do not erode
    demand. When asked about the propriety of above-COA
    compensation, the current MAC commissioner similarly
    testified that the “key” is “linking” payments to the “pursuit
    of the educational opportunities of the individual involved.”
    The LRA fashioned by the district court achieves that link.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    47
    In light of this evidence, the district court reasonably
    concluded that market competition in connection with
    education-related benefits will only reinforce consumers’
    perception of student-athletes as students, thereby preserving
    demand. See 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1089
    (observing that
    NCAA’s “own witnesses” testified that “consumer demand
    for [D1] basketball and FBS football is driven largely by
    consumers’ perception that student-athletes are, in fact,
    students”).
    Moreover, no evidence in the record substantiates the
    NCAA’s concerns that certain benefits permissible under the
    LRA, if uncapped, will become vehicles for payments that are
    virtually indistinguishable from a professional’s salary.
    These concerns are premised on an unreasonably expansive
    reading of the injunction, including its requirement that the
    NCAA permit reimbursement for “tangible items not
    included in the [COA] calculation but nonetheless related to
    the pursuit of academic studies.” In re NCAA Athletic Grant-
    In-Aid Cap Antitrust Litig., 
    2019 WL 1593939
    , at *1. We
    construe injunctions in “context” and “so as to avoid . . .
    absurd result[s].” Gathright v. City of Portland, 
    439 F.3d 573
    , 581 (9th Cir. 2006). The context here makes plain that
    it “cannot have been the district court’s intent,”
    id., for uncapped
    benefits to be vehicles for unlimited cash payments.
    Instead, it expressly envisioned “non-cash education-related
    benefits” for “legitimate education-related costs,” not luxury
    cars or expensive musical instruments for students who are
    not studying music. 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1105
    (emphasis added). Thus, properly construed, the injunction
    does not permit the type of unlimited cash payments asserted
    by the NCAA. Further, as the district court properly
    concluded, it is doubtful that a consumer could mistake a
    post-eligibility internship for a professional athlete’s salary,
    48 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    where the former is necessarily divorced from participation
    in college athletics.
    The NCAA’s challenges to the evidence underlying this
    LRA are likewise unavailing. To be sure, neither the survey
    nor Dr. Rascher’s observations regarding the Nebraska
    program purport to reflect the effect that nationwide
    education-related benefits, implemented in the aggregate,
    would have on consumer demand. But the district court did
    not rely exclusively on this evidence. Under the deferential
    standard of review required here, we must examine the record
    “in its entirety.” 
    Alexander, 106 F.3d at 877
    . The NCAA
    fails to explain why the cumulative evidence, which included
    demand analyses regarding the growth of NCAA revenue
    alongside the expansion of SAF and AEF payments for
    education-related expenses, was insufficient.
    And though the record does not reflect whether an athlete
    has ever received $5,600 in aggregate athletic participation
    awards, the district court reasonably concluded that
    permitting student-athletes to receive up to that amount in
    academic or graduation awards and incentives will not erode
    consumer demand. See 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1072
    (citing Dr. Elzinga’s testimony that a player on a successful
    team could obtain $5,600 in cumulative awards under
    existing rules). The district court had before it (and fairly
    credited) evidence that demand would withstand even higher
    caps on such awards and incentives. See
    id. at 1080
    (discussing Student-Athletes’ survey, which indicated that
    consumers would continue to view and attend college sports
    events even if student-athletes received academic or
    graduation incentive payments of up to $10,000); see also
    id. at 1074
    , 1102, n.42 (observing that NCAA’s 30(b)(6) witness
    was unable to explain the NCAA’s reason for limiting Senior
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.             49
    Scholar-Athlete Awards to two students per year and a value
    of $10,000). The NCAA’s objection to the $5,600 cap rings
    especially hollow considering that it does not cap individual
    academic or graduation awards drawn from the AEF or SAF.
    See
    id. at 1072
    n.15.18
    Finally, the NCAA contends that the district court
    engaged in improper judicial price setting by tying the cap on
    academic and graduation awards and incentives to the cap on
    aggregate athletic participation awards. The Supreme Court
    has remarked that courts are “ill suited” to identify terms of
    dealing between competitors, including a product’s “proper
    price.” Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
    Trinko, LLP, 
    540 U.S. 398
    , 408 (2004). But the district court
    did not fix the value of these academic awards: The task of
    setting their value to protect demand, by adjusting the
    aggregate value of athletic participation awards, remains in
    the NCAA’s court. See 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1107
    .
    2
    The district court did not clearly err in finding that this
    LRA will not result in significantly increased costs. The
    district court reasoned that enjoining NCAA caps on most
    education-related benefits will actually save the NCAA
    resources that it would have otherwise spent on enforcing
    18
    The $5,600 cap on academic achievement awards and the $5,000
    cap on deferred NIL compensation that the panel majority struck down in
    O’Bannon II may be “remarkably close” as a numerical matter, but they
    are different where it counts: Unlike deferred NIL compensation,
    academic achievement awards are plainly education-related and, thus,
    reinforce the demand-preserving perception of student-athletes as students.
    50 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    those caps.
    Id. at 1090.
    Commonsense supports that
    determination, as does the record.
    Moreover, though the injunction permits the NCAA to
    regulate, to an extent, academic and graduation awards and
    incentives, and conferences to regulate all education-related
    benefits, there is no reason to believe that such regulation, if
    pursued, will result in significantly increased costs. The
    NCAA does not dispute that it and its conferences have
    existing rulemaking and enforcement infrastructure to
    achieve such regulation. See
    id. at 1090
    n.32 (noting
    NCAA’s recent creation of enforcement body to adjudicate
    violations of “complex” NCAA rules, including the
    “prioritiz[ation of] academics and the well-being of college
    athletes” (internal citation omitted); see also
    id. (noting that
    conferences are legislative bodies under the Bylaws).
    The court’s findings at step three are supported by the
    record, and certainly not clearly erroneous.
    V
    The final question remaining is whether the district
    court’s injunction goes too far or not far enough in enjoining
    the NCAA’s unlawful conduct. In the NCAA’s view, the
    injunction is impermissibly vague, in violation of Federal
    Rule of Civil Procedure 65(d) (“Rule 65(d)”), and usurps the
    association’s role as the “superintend[ent]” of college sports,
    O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1074
    . On cross-appeal, Student-
    Athletes urge that the district court should have enjoined all
    NCAA compensation limits, including those on payments
    untethered to education. In our view, the district court struck
    the right balance in crafting a remedy that both prevents
    anticompetitive harm to Student-Athletes while serving the
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   51
    procompetitive purpose of preserving the popularity of
    college sports. Thus, we neither vacate nor broaden the
    injunction, but affirm.
    A
    Rule 65(d) reflects the “basic principle” that “those
    against whom an injunction is issued should receive fair and
    precisely drawn notice of what the injunction actually
    prohibits.” Fortyune v. Am. Multi-Cinema, Inc., 
    364 F.3d 1075
    , 1086–87 (9th Cir. 2004) (internal citation omitted).
    “[W]e will not set aside injunctions under Rule 65(d) ‘unless
    they are so vague that they have no reasonably specific
    meaning.’”
    Id. at 1087
    (internal citation omitted). The
    challenged injunction clears this hurdle.
    The district court enjoined the NCAA from limiting
    enumerated “compensation and benefits related to
    education,” In re NCAA Athletic Grant-In-Aid Cap Antitrust
    Litig., 
    2019 WL 1593939
    , at *1 (listing computers, science
    equipment, musical instruments, etc.). The NCAA does not
    claim confusion as to the meaning of any of these items.
    Instead, it stakes its Rule 65(d) objection on the injunction’s
    reference to “other tangible items not included in the [COA]
    but nonetheless related to the pursuit of academic studies.”
    Id. When read
    in context, following a list of specific types of
    education-related equipment, this language is reasonably
    specific. And unlike in Columbia Pictures Industries, Inc. v.
    Fung, a copyright infringement case on which the NCAA
    relies, the injunction here does not make cryptic reference to
    “general[]” or “wide[spread]” understanding and knowledge
    of technical terms. 
    710 F.3d 1020
    , 1048 (9th Cir. 2013).
    52 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    Nor did the district court impermissibly wrest control of
    college sports from the NCAA by empowering itself to
    determine the types of benefits that qualify as “related to”
    education, instead of “leaving th[at] task” to “the institutions
    experienced in and responsible for providing education.” The
    NCAA does not (nor can it reasonably) dispute that the
    benefits enumerated in the injunction are plainly related to
    academics. What is more, the injunction invites the NCAA
    to promulgate a definition of “related to education,” based on
    its institutional expertise, subject to the court’s approval. See
    In re NCAA Athletic Grant-In-Aid Cap Antitrust Litig., 
    2019 WL 1593939
    , at *1. This allowance does not constitute
    judicial usurpation by a long shot.
    In sum, we uphold the injunction against the NCAA’s
    challenges.
    B
    If the district court had concluded, as Student-Athletes
    contend, that NCAA limits on compensation unrelated to
    education unreasonably restrain trade, then it should have
    enjoined those limits. See 15 U.S.C. §§ 4, 25 (conferring
    jurisdiction on federal courts to “prevent and restrain
    violations” of antitrust law ); see also Ford Motor Co. v.
    United States, 
    405 U.S. 562
    , 577–78 (1972) (“Antitrust relief
    should unfetter a market from anticompetitive conduct.”
    (emphasis added)). The problem for Student-Athletes is that
    the court did not conclude as much; instead, it determined
    that NCAA limits on education-related compensation are the
    only challenged rules that flunk the Rule of Reason.
    Although the district court found that all the challenged
    rules have an anticompetitive effect, Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    53
    at 1067–70, a finding of anticompetitive harm at step one
    does not end the inquiry. A defendant may escape antitrust
    liability despite inflicting harm if a court determines that the
    restraint has a procompetitive effect, and a proposed LRA
    eliminating that restraint is not viable. See, e.g., O’Bannon
    
    II, 802 F.3d at 1070
    , 1076–79 (finding that rules prohibiting
    NIL compensation had significant anticompetitive effects, but
    vacating portion of injunction requiring deferred
    compensation for NILs after concluding that this alternative
    was not a viable LRA).
    As previously stated, the district court concluded, at step
    two, that the NCAA satisfied its burden of showing that
    “[r]ules that prevent unlimited payments”—“unrelated to
    education” and “akin to salaries seen in professional sports
    leagues”—serve the procompetitive end of distinguishing
    college from professional sports. 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1083
    . And at step three, it rejected Student-Athletes
    proposed LRAs, which would have eliminated such limits,
    reasoning:
    [A]t least some conferences would allow their
    schools to offer student-athletes unlimited
    cash payments that are unrelated to education.
    Such payments could be akin to those
    observed in professional sports leagues.
    Payments of that nature could diminish the
    popularity of college sports as a product
    distinct from professional sports.
    Id. at 1087
    . 
    Contrary to Student-Athletes’ understanding, this
    analysis reflects the judgment that limits on cash
    compensation unrelated to education do not, on this record,
    54 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    constitute anticompetitive conduct and, thus, may not be enjoined.
    This judgment was adequately reasoned and rests on
    neither factual nor legal error.          The district court
    acknowledged the theoretical possibility that “conference
    officials, as rational economic actors, would not act contrary
    to their members’ aggregate economic interests” by paying
    demand-reducing levels of compensation.
    Id. But it
    reasonably perceived a risk of “miscalculations” by
    conferences during an “inevitable trial-and-error phase.”
    Id. The district
    court did not clearly err in declining to assume
    that conferences, in reality, would act rationally.
    The record indicates that the Power Five schools have
    exercised their autonomy in recent years to expand benefits
    unrelated to education and that conferences and schools have
    provided largely discretionary SAF and AEF payments for a
    wide range of expenses unrelated to education—both without
    harming consumer demand. But the district court reasonably
    concluded that this evidence may not reliably indicate that
    individual conferences would regulate payments in a demand-
    preserving manner absent any restrictions: The autonomy
    structure permits the Power Five to collectively adopt
    compensation-related legislation, in line with O’Bannon II’s
    guidance that some degree of “mutual agreement” is
    necessary to make the college sports product available. 
    See 802 F.3d at 1069
    (quoting Bd. of 
    Regents, 468 U.S. at 102
    ).
    And the NCAA currently limits the use of SAF funds to
    payments that are distinguishable from a professional’s salary
    in that they “meet[] financial needs that arise in conjunction
    with participation in intercollegiate athletics, enrollment in
    academic curriculum or to recognize academic achievement.”
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.             55
    Student-Athletes’ claims of legal error are likewise
    unpersuasive. They cite no support for their position that a
    court “should not simply import the [LRA] as its injunction.”
    Indeed, O’Bannon II holds otherwise: “Where, as here, a
    restraint is patently and inexplicably stricter than is necessary
    to accomplish all of its procompetitive objectives, an antitrust
    court can and should invalidate it and order it replaced with
    a [viable LRA].”
    Id. at 1075
    (emphasis added).
    Finally, Student-Athletes argue that the NCAA may no
    longer rely on O’Bannon II’s conclusion that NCAA limits on
    cash payments untethered to education are critical to
    preserving the distinction between college and professional
    sports now that it has “endorse[d]” the very “same NIL
    benefits” at issue there. This argument is premature. As it
    stands, the NCAA has not endorsed cash compensation
    untethered to education; instead, it has undertaken to comply
    with the FPP Act in a manner that is consistent with
    O’Bannon II—that is, by loosening its restrictions to permit
    NIL benefits that are “tethered to education.” Fed. and State
    Leg. Working Grp. Report 4 (Oct. 23, 2019), available at
    https://tinyurl.com/working-grp-report; see also Test. of
    Dr. Mark Emmert 6 (Feb. 11, 2020), available at
    https://tinyurl.com/Emmert-Test-y. Accordingly, we disagree
    that the NCAA’s response to the FPP Act militates in favor
    of enjoining all NCAA compensation limits.19
    19
    Student-Athletes further contend that the FPP Act and similar
    proposed legislation in other states indicate a “consensus” that student-
    athletes’ receipt of payments unrelated to education will not dampen
    consumer interest in college sports. However, the Act’s legislative history
    suggests that concerns about fundamental fairness, rather than
    considerations regarding demand, drove its enactment. See, e.g., S.B. 206
    Assembly Floor Analysis 2 (Sept. 4, 2019), available at
    https://tinyurl.com/SB-206-AFA.
    56 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    VI
    To repeat my observation in O’Bannon II: “The national
    debate about amateurism in college sports is important. But
    our task as appellate judges is not to resolve it. Nor could we.
    Our task is simply to review the district court judgment
    through the appropriate lens of antitrust law and under the
    appropriate standard of review.” O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1083
    (Thomas, C.J., concurring in part and dissenting in
    part).
    For the foregoing reasons, we hold that the district court
    properly concluded that NCAA limits on education-related
    benefits do not “play by the Sherman Act’s rules.”
    Id. at 1079
    . Accordingly, we affirm its liability determination
    and injunction in all respects.
    AFFIRMED.
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   57
    M. SMITH, Circuit Judge, concurring:
    Because I am bound by our decision in O’Bannon v.
    NCAA (O’Bannon II), 
    802 F.3d 1049
    (9th Cir. 2015), I join
    the panel opinion in full. I write separately to express
    concern that the current state of our antitrust law reflects an
    unwitting expansion of the Rule of Reason inquiry in a way
    that deprives the young athletes in this case (Student-
    Athletes) of the fundamental protections that our antitrust
    laws were meant to provide them.
    Student-Athletes are talented, hardworking individuals
    who have dedicated their young lives to excelling in specific
    sports. As amici describe, Student-Athletes work an average
    of 35–40 hours per week on athletic duties during their
    months-long athletic seasons, and most work similar hours
    during the off-season to stay competitive. At the same time,
    most of them do their best to succeed academically, managing
    to devote on average another 40 hours per week to classes
    and study. Nevertheless, their coaches and others in the
    Division 1 ecosystem make sure that Student-Athletes put
    athletics first, which makes it difficult for them to compete
    for academic success with students more focused on
    academics. They are often forced to miss class, to neglect
    their studies, and to forego courses whose schedules conflict
    with the sports in which they participate. In addition to
    lessening their chances at academic success because of the
    time they must devote to their sports obligations, Student-
    Athletes are often prevented from obtaining internships or
    part-time paying jobs, and, as a result, often lack both income
    and marketable work experience. Meanwhile, the grueling
    hours and physical demands of college sports carry
    significant health risks, such as sleep deprivation, stress,
    broken bones, and even potential brain damage. Despite their
    58 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    best efforts, however, fewer than 5% of Student-Athletes will
    ever play at a professional level, and most of those lucky few
    will stay in the pros only a few short years. In short, the
    college years are likely the only years when young Student-
    Athletes have any realistic chance of earning a significant
    amount of money or achieving fame as a result of their
    athletic skills.
    For all their dedication, labor, talent, and personal
    sacrifice, Student-Athletes go largely uncompensated. They
    may receive tuition for an academic experience that they
    cannot take full advantage of, minimal living expenses, and
    some lavish perks that do nothing for their present or future
    financial security. However, that is not because their athletic
    services have little value. On the contrary, the NCAA and
    Division 1 universities make billions of dollars from ticket
    sales, television contracts, merchandise, and other fruits that
    directly flow from the labors of Student-Athletes. A number
    of Division 1 head football coaches take home multimillion-
    dollar salaries that exceed those of many NFL coaches.
    Moreover, contrary to the NCAA’s representations about the
    importance of “amateurism,” the evidence in this case shows
    that college sports viewership has only increased since we
    reduced some limitations on student-athlete compensation in
    O’Bannon II. See Panel Op. at 11–13.
    My reaction to our application of federal antitrust law to
    the case of the Student-Athletes is similar Justice Alito’s
    reaction to the majority’s view in Collins v. Virginia,
    584 U.S. ___, 
    138 S. Ct. 1663
    (2018). Said he: “An ordinary
    person of common sense would react to the Court’s decision
    the way Mr. Bumble famously responded when told about a
    legal rule that did not comport with the reality of everyday
    life. If that is the law, he exclaimed, ‘the law is a ass—a
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   59
    idiot.’”
    Id. at 1681
    (Alito, J., dissenting) (quoting C.
    Dickens, Oliver Twist 277 (1867)).
    The treatment of Student-Athletes is not the result of free
    market competition. To the contrary, it is the result of a
    cartel of buyers acting in concert to artificially depress the
    price that sellers could otherwise receive for their services.
    Our antitrust laws were originally meant to prohibit exactly
    this sort of distortion.
    The Sherman Act and related antitrust laws were designed
    to preserve our economic freedom. United States v. Topco
    Assocs., Inc., 
    405 U.S. 596
    , 610 (1972). Under those laws,
    the freedom guaranteed each and every
    business, no matter how small, is the freedom
    to compete—to assert with vigor, imagination,
    devotion, and ingenuity whatever economic
    muscle it can muster. Implicit in such
    freedom is the notion that it cannot be
    foreclosed with respect to one sector for the
    economy because certain private citizens or
    groups believe that such foreclosure might
    promote greater competition in a more
    important sector of the economy.
    Id. The Sherman
    Act thus “protect[s] the economic freedom
    of participants in the relevant market.” Am. Ad Mgmt., Inc.
    v. Gen. Tel. Co. of Cal., 
    190 F.3d 1051
    , 1057 (9th Cir. 1999)
    (quoting Associated Gen. Contractors of Cal., Inc. v. Cal.
    State Council of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
    , 538 (1983)).
    Those protections extend to sellers of goods and services—
    such as Student-Athletes—to the same extent they do buyers,
    consumers, or competitors. Mandeville Island Farms, Inc. v.
    60 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    Am. Crystal Sugar Co., 
    334 U.S. 219
    , 235 (1948). “The Act
    is comprehensive in its terms and coverage, protecting all
    who are made victims of the forbidden practices by
    whomever they may be perpetrated.”
    Id. (emphasis added).
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act, at issue here, prohibits
    agreements that unreasonably restrain trade. 15 U.S.C. § 1;
    Standard Oil Co. of N.J. v. United States, 
    221 U.S. 1
    , 58
    (1911). In evaluating alleged violations of Section 1 that fall
    outside the bounds of several now-established per se rules,
    courts apply the Rule of Reason to determine the effect of a
    given restraint on competition. “[T]he inquiry mandated by
    the Rule of Reason is whether the challenged agreement is
    one that promotes competition or one that suppresses
    competition.” Nat’l Soc’y of Prof’l Eng’rs v. United States,
    
    435 U.S. 679
    , 691 (1978). Importantly, it is not the purpose
    of the Rule of Reason analysis “to decide whether a policy
    favoring competition is in the public interest, or in the interest
    of the members of an industry. Subject to exceptions defined
    by statute, that policy decision has been made by the
    Congress.”
    Id. at 692.
    The Rule of Reason entails a three-step analysis, of which
    the starting point is to identify the market in which the
    restraint occurs. See Big Bear Lodging Ass’n v. Snow
    Summit, Inc., 
    182 F.3d 1096
    , 1104–05 (9th Cir. 1999). At
    Step One, the “plaintiff bears the initial burden of showing
    that the restraint produces significant anticompetitive effects
    within” that market. O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1070
    (quoting
    Tanaka v. Univ. of S. Cal., 
    252 F.3d 1059
    , 1063 (9th Cir.
    2001)). If the plaintiff meets that burden, at Step Two, “the
    defendant must come forward with evidence of the restraint’s
    procompetitive effects.”
    Id. (quoting Tanaka,
    252 F.3d at
    1063). Finally, at Step Three, “the plaintiff must . . . show
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   61
    that any legitimate objectives can be achieved in a
    substantially less restrictive manner.”
    Id. (quoting Tanaka,
    252 F.3d at 1063).
    Despite confining the Step One analysis of
    anticompetitive effects to the defined market, courts have not
    consistently limited the scope of the Step Two analysis in the
    same way. Some, including our court, have permitted
    defendants to offer procompetitive effects in a collateral
    market as justification for anticompetitive effects in the
    defined market. In NCAA v. Board of Regents of Univ. of
    Oklahoma (Board of Regents), 
    468 U.S. 85
    (1984), for
    example, the Supreme Court considered whether preserving
    demand for tickets to live college football games could justify
    anticompetitive restraints in the market for live college
    football television.
    Id. at 95–96,
    115–17. The district court
    defined the relevant market at Step One as “live college
    football television.”
    Id. at 95.
    The NCAA had restrained
    competition in this market by fixing the price of telecasts,
    negotiating exclusive contracts with two television networks,
    and artificially limiting the number of televised games.
    Id. at 96.
    Among other alleged procompetitive justifications, all
    of which the Court ultimately rejected, the NCAA argued that
    its television plan promoted consumer demand for live
    attendance at college football games.
    Id. at 115.
    The Court
    rejected this argument for three reasons: (1) individual
    schools could protect live attendance at the specific game
    being televised by negotiating a regional blackout, without
    acting in concert with other schools; (2) no evidence
    supported the NCAA’s theory that limiting televised games
    actually promoted live attendance, especially since games
    would still be broadcast at all hours of the day; and (3) the
    NCAA’s live attendance theory was “not based on a desire to
    maintain the integrity of college football as a distinct and
    62 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    attractive product, but rather on a fear that . . . ticket sales for
    most college games are unable to compete in a free
    market”—“a justification that is inconsistent with the basic
    policy of the Sherman Act.”
    Id. at 115–17.
    The Supreme
    Court did not, however, say that the live attendance
    justification failed because courts categorically cannot
    consider procompetitive benefits outside the defined market.
    Our relevant precedents follow a similar analysis. In
    O’Bannon II, we held that preserving consumer demand for
    college sports was a legitimate procompetitive justification
    for anticompetitive restraints on compensation for student-
    athletes’ names, images, and likenesses in the market among
    colleges for student-athletes’ 
    services. 802 F.3d at 1069
    –73.
    The district court had defined the relevant market at Step One
    as the “college education market,” “wherein colleges compete
    for the services of athletic recruits by offering them
    scholarships and various amenities, such as coaching and
    facilities.”
    Id. at 1070
    . The NCAA had restrained
    competition in this market by preventing member schools
    from paying student athletes for the use of their names,
    images, and likenesses.
    Id. Contrary to
    two of the NCAA’s
    proffered justifications, we accepted the district court’s
    factual determinations that the restraint did “not promote
    competitive balance,” and did “not increase output in the
    college education market.”
    Id. at 1072
    . We also rejected the
    NCAA’s argument that, by preserving the character of
    college sports, the restraint “‘widen[ed]’ the choices
    ‘available to athletes.’”
    Id. (quoting Board
    of 
    Regents, 468 U.S. at 102
    ). “As the district court found, it is primarily
    ‘the opportunity to earn a higher education’ that attracts
    athletes to college sports rather than professional sports, and
    that opportunity would still be available to student-athletes if
    they were paid some compensation in addition to their
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    63
    athletic scholarships.”
    Id. at 1073.
    Yet, without tying the
    Step 2 analysis to the “college education market,” we held
    that the NCAA had demonstrated that the restraint served the
    procompetitive purpose of preserving “the amateur nature of
    collegiate sports [that] increases their appeal to consumers.”
    Id. Accordingly, we
    proceeded to Rule of Reason Step Three,
    wherein we upheld the district court’s less restrictive
    alternative of allowing grant-in-aid up to the full cost of
    attendance, but we vacated the district court’s less restrictive
    alternative of allowing “small” amounts of deferred cash
    compensation as incompatible with amateurism.
    Id. at 1074–79.
    Other courts, however, have rejected procompetitive
    justifications outside of the defined market. For example, in
    Smith v. Pro Football, Inc., 
    593 F.2d 1173
    (D.C. Cir. 1978),
    a former NFL player challenged rules governing the draft of
    graduating college players under which “no team was
    permitted to negotiate prior to the draft with any [eligible]
    player . . . and no team could negotiate with (or sign) any
    player selected by another team in the draft.”
    Id. at 1176.
    The D.C. Circuit affirmed the finding that the draft had
    anticompetitive effects. The draft eliminated competition by
    “inescapably forc[ing] each seller of football services to deal
    with one, and only one buyer, robbing the seller, as in any
    monopsonistic market, of any real bargaining power.”
    Id. at 1185.
    At Step Two of the Rule of Reason analysis, the NFL
    asserted that the draft rules were procompetitive because they
    promoted “competitive balance” among the league’s teams,
    in turn “producing better entertainment for the public, higher
    salaries for the players, and increased financial security for
    the clubs.”
    Id. at 1186.
    The court rejected those justifications
    64 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    because they did not have procompetitive effects in the
    market for players’ services. “The draft is ‘procompetitive,’
    if at all, in a very different sense from that in which it is
    anticompetitive.”
    Id. “[W]hile [the
    draft] may heighten
    athletic competition and thus improve the entertainment
    product offered to the public, [it] does not increase
    competition in the economic sense of encouraging others to
    enter the market and to offer the product at lower cost.”
    Id. The court
    concluded that the draft’s anticompetitive and
    procompetitive effects were “not comparable,” and thus it
    was “impossible to ‘net them out’ in the usual rule-of-reason
    balancing.”
    Id. Despite its
    ruling in Board of Regents, the Supreme Court
    has not squarely addressed the proper scope of the Step Two
    analysis. And, although we conducted a similar analysis in
    O’Bannon II, neither have we. In my view, the underlying
    purpose of the Sherman Act—promoting competition—
    counsels in favor of conducting a more limited Rule of
    Reason analysis, as the court in Smith did. Realistically, the
    Rule of Reason analysis is judicially administrable only if it
    is confined to the single market identified from the outset. If
    the purpose of the Rule of Reason is to determine whether a
    restraint is net procompetitive or net anticompetitive,
    accepting procompetitive effects in a collateral market
    disrupts that balancing. It weakens antitrust protections by
    permitting defendants to rely on a broader array of
    justifications that promote competition, if at all, in collateral
    markets where the restraint under analysis does not occur.
    Jurists faced with weighing the anticompetitive effects in
    one market with the procompetitive effects in another cannot
    simply “net them out” mathematically. 
    Smith, 593 F.2d at 1186
    . Rather, courts employing a cross-market analysis
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.   65
    must—implicitly or explicitly—make value judgments by
    determining whether competition in the collateral market is
    more important than competition in the defined market. As
    the Supreme Court has warned, this is not what the antitrust
    laws invite courts to do. “If a decision is to be made to
    sacrifice competition in one portion of the economy for
    greater competition in another portion this too is a decision
    that must be made by Congress and not by private forces or
    by the courts. Private forces are too keenly aware of their own
    interests in making such decisions and courts are ill-equipped
    and ill-situated for such decisionmaking.” 
    Topco, 405 U.S. at 611
    .
    Consider this case. The district court accepted the
    relevant market as that for Student-Athletes’ “labor in the
    form of athletic services in men’s and women’s Division I
    basketball and FBS football,” in which Student-Athletes “sell
    their athletic services to the schools that participate in
    Division I basketball and FBS football in exchange for
    grants-in-aid and other benefits and compensation permitted
    by NCAA rules.” In re NCAA Athletic Grant-In-Aid Cap
    Antitrust Litig. (Alston), 
    375 F. Supp. 3d 1058
    , 1067 (N.D.
    Cal. 2019). At Step One, the district court found that
    Student-Athletes had established significant anticompetitive
    effects in the market for their athletic services. The court
    concluded that the NCAA rules “have the effect of artificially
    compressing and capping student-athlete compensation and
    reducing competition for student-athlete recruits by limiting
    the compensation offered in exchange for their athletic
    services.”
    Id. at 1068.
    At Step Two, the court did not limit its consideration to
    the procompetitive effects of the compensation limits in the
    market for Student-Athletes’ athletic services. Rather, it
    66 IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.
    found that certain of the compensation limits are
    procompetitive because they drive consumer demand for
    college sports by distinguishing collegiate from professional
    athletics.
    Id. at 1083.
    In other words, the court found that
    limiting Student-Athletes’ pay in the market for their services
    was justified because that restraint drove demand for the
    distinct product of college sports in the consumer market for
    sports entertainment. The court did not require that the
    NCAA prove that this impact on consumer demand had a
    corollary procompetitive impact on the market for Student-
    Athletes’ services, that it “increase[d] output” or “‘widen[ed]’
    the choices ‘available to athletes.’” O’Bannon 
    II, 802 F.3d at 1072
    (quoting Board of 
    Regents, 468 U.S. at 102
    ). The
    court did not require that the NCAA prove its compensation
    rules, within the defined market, “increase competition in the
    economic sense of encouraging others to enter the market to
    offer the product at lower cost.” 
    Smith, 593 F.2d at 1186
    . It
    was enough for the NCAA to meet its Step Two burden that
    it could show (however feebly) a procompetitive effect in a
    collateral market.
    Although the district court correctly applied our
    precedents, the result of this analysis seems to erode the very
    protections a Sherman Act plaintiff has the right to enforce.
    Here, Student-Athletes are quite clearly deprived of the fair
    value of their services. 
    Alston, 375 F. Supp. 3d at 1068
    . As
    the district court found, while the NCAA and its conferences
    generate billions in revenue from college sports, they “have
    monopsony power to restrain student-athlete compensation in
    any way and at any time they wish, without any meaningful
    risk of diminishing their market dominance.”
    Id. at 1063
    ,
    1070. Under the Rule of Reason analysis we affirm today, so
    long as the NCAA cites consumer demand for college sports,
    we allow it to artificially suppress competition for collegiate
    IN RE NCAA ATHLETIC GRANT-IN-AID CAP ANTITRUST LITIG.    67
    athletes’ services by limiting their compensation. Instead of
    requiring the NCAA to explain how those limits promote
    schools’ competition for athletes, we leave Student-Athletes
    with little recourse under the antitrust laws. Student-Athletes
    are thus denied the freedom to compete and, in turn, “of
    compensation they would receive in the absence of the
    restraints.”
    Id. at 1068.
    Our Rule of Reason framework has shifted toward this
    cross-market analysis without direct consideration or a robust
    justification. It may be that scholars or litigants can develop
    a purely economic, mathematically-defensible method for
    cross-market analysis that does not depend on policy
    judgments that our antitrust laws never meant to delegate to
    the courts. But we do not currently have such a method, and
    it may equally be the case that no such method is possible or
    desirable.
    Lacking a robust justification, I fear that our cross-market
    Rule of Reason analysis frustrates the very purpose of the
    antitrust laws, in this case to the great detriment of Student-
    Athletes. I hope our court will reconsider this issue in a case
    that squarely raises it.