Verizon v. FCC ( 2014 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued September 9, 2013          Decided January 14, 2014
    No. 11-1355
    VERIZON,
    APPELLANT
    v.
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION,
    APPELLEE
    INDEPENDENT TELEPHONE & TELECOMMUNICATIONS
    ALLIANCE, ET AL.,
    INTERVENORS
    Consolidated with 11-1356
    On Petition For Review and Notice of Appeal
    of an Order of the Federal Communications Commission
    Helgi C. Walker argued the cause for appellant/petitioner
    Verizon. With her on the briefs were Eve Klindera Reed,
    William S. Consovoy, Brett A. Shumate, Walter E. Dellinger,
    Anton Metlitsky, Samir C. Jain, Carl W. Northrup, Michael
    Lazarus, Andrew Morentz, Michael E. Glover, William H.
    Johnson, Stephen B. Kinnaird, and Mark A. Stachiw. John T.
    Scott III and Edward Shakin entered appearances.
    2
    Stephen B. Kinnaird, Carl W. Northrup, Michael Lazarus,
    Andrew Morentz, and Mark A. Stachiw were on the briefs for
    appellants/petitioners MetroPCS Communications, Inc., et al.
    John P. Elwood, Sam Kazman, Randolph May, and Ilya
    Shapiro were on the brief for amici curiae The Competitive
    Enterprise Institute, et al. in support of appellant/petitioner.
    Russell P. Hanser, Bryan N. Tramont, and Quentin Riegel
    were on the brief for amicus curiae National Association of
    Manufacturers in support of appellant/petitioner.
    Kenneth T. Cuccinelli, II, Attorney General, Office of the
    Attorney General for the Commonwealth of Virginia, E.
    Duncan Getchell, Jr., Solicitor General, and Wesley G. Russell,
    Jr., Deputy Attorney General, were on the brief for amici
    curiae The Commonwealth of Virginia, et al. in support of
    appellant/petitioner.
    Sean A. Lev, General Counsel, Federal Communications
    Commission, argued the cause for appellee/respondent. With
    him on the briefs were Catherine G. O’Sullivan and Nickolai
    G. Levin, Attorneys, U.S. Department of Justice, Peter
    Karanjia, Deputy General Counsel, Federal Communications
    Commission, Jacob M. Lewis, Associate General Counsel, and
    Joel Marcus and Matthew J. Dunne, Counsel. Robert J.
    Wiggers, Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice, R. Craig
    Lawrence, Assistant U.S. Attorney, and Richard K. Welch,
    Deputy Associate General Counsel, Federal Communications
    Commission, entered appearances.
    Pantelis Michalopoulos argued the cause for intervenors.
    With him on the brief were Stephanie A. Roy, Andrew W. Guhr,
    Henry Goldberg, David C. Bergmann, Kurt Matthew Rogers,
    and Brendan Daniel Kasper. Markham C. Erickson, Jeffrey J.
    3
    Binder, Harold J. Feld and James B. Ramsay entered
    appearances.
    Sean H. Donahue and David T. Goldberg were on the brief
    for amici curiae Reed Hundt, et al. in support of
    appellee/respondent.
    E. Joshua Rosenkranz, Gabriel M. Ramsey, Thomas J.
    Gray, and Christina Von der Ahe were on the brief for amici
    curiae Venture Capital Investors in support of
    appellee/respondent.
    Andrew Jay Schwartzman was on the brief for amicus
    curiae Tim Wu in support of appellee/respondent.
    John Blevins was on the brief for amici curiae Internet
    Engineers     and    Technologists    in    support     of
    appellee/respondent.
    Kevin S. Bankston and Emma J. Llansó were on the brief
    for amici curiae The Center for Democracy and Technology, et
    al. in support of appellee/respondent.
    Before: ROGERS and TATEL, Circuit Judges, and
    SILBERMAN, Senior Circuit Judge.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge TATEL.
    Opinion concurring in part and dissenting in part filed by
    Senior Circuit Judge SILBERMAN.
    TATEL, Circuit Judge: For the second time in four years,
    we are confronted with a Federal Communications
    Commission effort to compel broadband providers to treat all
    Internet traffic the same regardless of source—or to require, as
    4
    it is popularly known, “net neutrality.” In Comcast Corp. v.
    FCC, 
    600 F.3d 642
    (D.C. Cir. 2010), we held that the
    Commission had failed to cite any statutory authority that
    would justify its order compelling a broadband provider to
    adhere to open network management practices. After Comcast,
    the Commission issued the order challenged here—In re
    Preserving the Open Internet, 25 F.C.C.R. 17905 (2010) (“the
    Open Internet Order”)—which imposes disclosure,
    anti-blocking, and anti-discrimination requirements on
    broadband providers. As we explain in this opinion, the
    Commission has established that section 706 of the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996 vests it with affirmative
    authority to enact measures encouraging the deployment of
    broadband infrastructure. The Commission, we further hold,
    has reasonably interpreted section 706 to empower it to
    promulgate rules governing broadband providers’ treatment of
    Internet traffic, and its justification for the specific rules at
    issue here—that they will preserve and facilitate the “virtuous
    circle” of innovation that has driven the explosive growth of
    the Internet—is reasonable and supported by substantial
    evidence. That said, even though the Commission has general
    authority to regulate in this arena, it may not impose
    requirements that contravene express statutory mandates.
    Given that the Commission has chosen to classify broadband
    providers in a manner that exempts them from treatment as
    common carriers, the Communications Act expressly prohibits
    the Commission from nonetheless regulating them as such.
    Because the Commission has failed to establish that the
    anti-discrimination and anti-blocking rules do not impose per
    se common carrier obligations, we vacate those portions of the
    Open Internet Order.
    5
    I.
    Understanding this case requires an understanding of the
    Internet, the Internet marketplace, and the history of the
    Commission’s regulation of that marketplace.
    Four major participants in the Internet marketplace are
    relevant to the issues before us: backbone networks, broadband
    providers, edge providers, and end users. Backbone networks
    are interconnected, long-haul fiber-optic links and high-speed
    routers capable of transmitting vast amounts of data. See In re
    Verizon Communications Inc. and MCI, Inc. Applications for
    Approval of Transfer of Control, 20 F.C.C.R. 18433, 18493
    ¶ 110 (2005). Internet users generally connect to these
    networks—and, ultimately, to one another—through local
    access providers like petitioner Verizon, who operate the
    “last-mile” transmission lines. See Open Internet Order, 25
    F.C.C.R. at 17908, 17915 ¶¶ 7, 20. In the Internet’s early days,
    most users connected to the Internet through dial-up
    connections over local telephone lines. See In re Inquiry
    Concerning High-Speed Access to the Internet Over Cable and
    Other Facilities, 17 F.C.C.R. 4798, 4802–03 ¶ 9 (2002)
    (“Cable Broadband Order”). Today, access is generally
    furnished      through     “broadband,”      i.e.,   high-speed
    communications technologies, such as cable modem service.
    See In re Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced
    Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a
    Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 25 F.C.C.R. 9556, 9557,
    9558–59 ¶¶ 1, 4 (2010) (“Sixth Broadband Deployment
    Report”); 47 U.S.C. § 1302(d)(1). Edge providers are those
    who, like Amazon or Google, provide content, services, and
    applications over the Internet, while end users are those who
    consume edge providers’ content, services, and applications.
    See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17910 ¶ 13. To pull
    the whole picture together with a slightly oversimplified
    6
    example: when an edge provider such as YouTube transmits
    some sort of content—say, a video of a cat—to an end user,
    that content is broken down into packets of information, which
    are carried by the edge provider’s local access provider to the
    backbone network, which transmits these packets to the end
    user’s local access provider, which, in turn, transmits the
    information to the end user, who then views and hopefully
    enjoys the cat.
    These categories of entities are not necessarily mutually
    exclusive. For example, end users may often act as edge
    providers by creating and sharing content that is consumed by
    other end users, for instance by posting photos on Facebook.
    Similarly, broadband providers may offer content,
    applications, and services that compete with those furnished by
    edge providers. See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17915
    ¶ 20.
    Proponents of net neutrality—or, to use the Commission’s
    preferred term, “Internet openness”—worry about the
    relationship between broadband providers and edge providers.
    They fear that broadband providers might prevent their
    end-user subscribers from accessing certain edge providers
    altogether, or might degrade the quality of their end-user
    subscribers’ access to certain edge providers, either as a means
    of favoring their own competing content or services or to
    enable them to collect fees from certain edge providers. Thus,
    for example, a broadband provider like Comcast might limit its
    end-user subscribers’ ability to access the New York Times
    website if it wanted to spike traffic to its own news website, or
    it might degrade the quality of the connection to a search
    website like Bing if a competitor like Google paid for
    prioritized access.
    7
    Since the advent of the Internet, the Commission has
    confronted the questions of whether and how it should regulate
    this communications network, which, generally speaking, falls
    comfortably within the Commission’s jurisdiction over “all
    interstate and foreign communications by wire or radio.” 47
    U.S.C. § 152(a). One of the Commission’s early efforts
    occurred in 1980, when it adopted what is known as the
    Computer II regime. The Computer II rules drew a line
    between “basic” services, which were subject to regulation
    under Title II of the Communications Act of 1934 as common
    carrier services, see 47 U.S.C. §§ 201 et seq., and “enhanced”
    services, which were not. See In re Amendment of Section
    64.702 of the Commission’s Rules and Regulations, 77
    F.C.C.2d 384, 387 ¶¶ 5–7 (1980) (“Second Computer
    Inquiry”). What distinguished “enhanced” services from
    “basic” services was the extent to which they involved the
    processing of information rather than simply its transmission.
    
    Id. at 420–21
    ¶¶ 96–97. For example, the Commission
    characterized telephone service as a “basic” service, see 
    id. at 419
    ¶ 94, because it involved a “pure” transmission that was
    “virtually transparent in terms of its interaction with customer
    supplied information,” 
    id. at 420
    ¶ 96. Services that involved
    “computer processing applications . . . used to act on the
    content, code, protocol, and other aspects of the subscriber’s
    information”—a definition that encompassed the services
    needed to connect an end user to the Internet—constituted
    enhanced services. 
    Id. at 420
    ¶ 97.
    By virtue of their designation as common carriers,
    providers of basic services were subject to the duties that apply
    to such entities, including that they “furnish . . . communication
    service upon reasonable request,” 47 U.S.C. § 201(a), engage
    in no “unjust or unreasonable discrimination in charges,
    practices, classifications, regulations, facilities, or services,”
    
    id. § 202(a),
    and charge “just and reasonable” rates, 
    id. 8 §
    201(b). Although the Commission applied no such
    restrictions to purveyors of enhanced services, it imposed
    limitations on certain entities, like AT&T, which owned the
    transmission facilities over which enhanced services would be
    provided. Second Computer Inquiry, 77 F.C.C.2d at 473–74
    ¶¶ 228–29. These restrictions included, most significantly,
    requirements that such entities offer enhanced services only
    through a completely separate corporate entity and that they
    offer their transmissions facilities to other enhanced service
    providers on a common carrier basis. 
    Id. For more
    than twenty years, the Commission applied some
    form of the Computer II regime to Internet services offered
    over telephone lines, then the predominant way in which most
    end users connected to the Internet. See, e.g., In re Appropriate
    Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over
    Wireline Facilities, 17 F.C.C.R. 3019, 3037–40 ¶¶ 36–42
    (2002). Telephone companies that provided the actual wireline
    facilities over which information was transmitted were limited
    in the manner in which they could provide the enhanced
    services necessary to permit end users to access the Internet. 
    Id. at 3040
    ¶ 42. They were also required to permit third-party
    Internet Service Providers (ISPs), such as America Online, to
    access their wireline transmission facilities on a common
    carrier basis. 
    Id. It was
    against this background that Congress passed the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, 110
    Stat. 56. Tracking the Computer II distinction between basic
    and enhanced services, the Act defines two categories of
    entities: telecommunications carriers, which provide the
    equivalent of basic services, and information-service
    providers, which provide the equivalent of enhanced services.
    47 U.S.C. § 153(24), (50), (51), (53); see National Cable &
    Telecommunications Ass’n v. Brand X Internet Services, 545
    
    9 U.S. 967
    ,    976–77    (2005).    The     Act    subjects
    telecommunications carriers, but not information-service
    providers, to Title II common carrier regulation. 47 U.S.C.
    § 153(53); Brand 
    X, 545 U.S. at 975
    –76.
    Pursuant to the Act, and paralleling its prior practice under
    the Computer II regime, the Commission then classified
    Digital Subscriber Line (DSL) services—broadband Internet
    service       furnished      over       telephone        lines—as
    “telecommunications services.” See In re Deployment of
    Wireline Services Offering Advanced Telecommunications
    Capability, 13 F.C.C.R. 24012, 24014, 24029–30 ¶¶ 3, 35–36
    (1998) (“Advanced Services Order”). DSL services, the
    Commission concluded, involved pure transmission
    technologies, and so were subject to Title II regulation. 
    Id. at 24030–31
    ¶ 35. A DSL provider could exempt its Internet
    access services, but not its transmission facilities themselves,
    from Title II common carrier restrictions only by operating
    them through a separate affiliate (i.e., a quasi-independent
    ISP). 
    Id. at 24018
    ¶ 13.
    Four years later, however, the Commission took a
    different approach when determining how to regulate
    broadband service provided by cable companies. Instead of
    viewing cable broadband providers’ transmission and
    processing of information as distinct services, the Commission
    determined that cable broadband providers—even those that
    own and operate the underlying last-mile transmission
    facilities—provide a “single, integrated information service.”
    Cable Broadband Order, 17 F.C.C.R. at 4824 ¶ 41. Because
    cable broadband providers were thus not telecommunications
    carriers at all, they were entirely exempt from Title II
    regulation. 
    Id. at 4802
    ¶ 7.
    10
    In National Cable & Telecommunications Ass’n v. Brand
    X Internet Services, 
    545 U.S. 967
    (2005), the Supreme Court
    upheld the Commission’s classification of cable broadband
    providers. The Court concluded that the Commission’s ruling
    represented a reasonable interpretation of the 1996
    Telecommunications Act’s ambiguous provision defining
    telecommunications service, see 
    id. at 991–92,
    and that the
    Commission’s determination was entitled to deference
    notwithstanding its apparent inconsistency with the agency’s
    prior interpretation of that statute, see 
    id. at 981,
    1000–01.
    Following Brand X, the Commission classified other types
    of broadband providers, such as DSL and wireless, which
    includes those offering broadband Internet service for cellular
    telephones, as information service providers exempt from Title
    II’s common carrier requirements. See In re Appropriate
    Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over
    Wireline Facilities, 20 F.C.C.R. 14853, 14862 ¶ 12 (2005)
    (“2005 Wireline Broadband Order”); In re Appropriate
    Regulatory Treatment for Broadband Access to the Internet
    Over Wireless Networks, 22 F.C.C.R. 5901, 5901–02 ¶ 1
    (2007) (“Wireless Broadband Order”); In re United Power
    Line Council’s Petition for Declaratory Ruling Regarding the
    Classification of Broadband over Power Line Internet Access
    Service as an Information Service, 21 F.C.C.R. 13281, 13281
    ¶ 1 (2006). Despite calls to revisit these classification orders,
    see, e.g., Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 18046
    (concurring statement of Commissioner Copps), the
    Commission has yet to overrule them.
    But even as the Commission exempted broadband
    providers from Title II common carrier obligations, it left open
    the possibility that it would nonetheless regulate these entities.
    In the Cable Broadband Order, for example, the Commission
    sought comment on whether and to what extent it should utilize
    11
    the powers granted it under Title I of the Communications Act
    to impose restrictions on cable broadband providers. Cable
    Broadband Order, 17 F.C.C.R. at 4842 ¶ 77. Subsequently, in
    conjunction with the 2005 Wireline Broadband Order, the
    Commission issued a Policy Statement in which it signaled its
    intention to “preserve and promote the open and
    interconnected nature of the public Internet.” In re Appropriate
    Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over
    Wireline Facilities, 20 F.C.C.R. 14986, 14988 ¶ 4 (2005). The
    Commission announced that should it “see evidence that
    providers of telecommunications for Internet access or
    IP-enabled services are violating these principles,” it would
    “not hesitate to take action to address that conduct.” 2005
    Wireline Broadband Order, 20 F.C.C.R. at 14904 ¶ 96.
    The Commission did just that when, two years later,
    several subscribers to Comcast’s cable broadband service
    complained that the company had interfered with their use of
    certain peer-to-peer networking applications. See In re Formal
    Complaint of Free Press and Public Knowledge Against
    Comcast Corp. for Secretly Degrading Peer-to-Peer
    Applications, 23 F.C.C.R. 13028 (2008) (“Comcast Order”).
    Finding that Comcast’s impairment of these applications had
    “contravene[d] . . . federal policy,” 
    id. at 13052
    ¶ 43, the
    Commission ordered the company to adhere to a new approach
    for managing bandwidth demand and to disclose the details of
    that approach, 
    id. at 13059–60
    ¶ 54. The Commission justified
    its order as an exercise of what courts term its “ancillary
    jurisdiction,” see 
    id. at 13034–41
    ¶¶ 14–22, a power that flows
    from the broad language of Communications Act section 4(i).
    See 47 U.S.C. § 154(i) (“The Commission may perform any
    and all acts, make such rules and regulations, and issue such
    orders, not inconsistent with this chapter, as may be necessary
    in the execution of its functions.”); see generally American
    Library Ass’n v. FCC, 
    406 F.3d 689
    , 700–03 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
    12
    We have held that the Commission may exercise such ancillary
    jurisdiction where two conditions are met: “(1) the
    Commission’s general jurisdictional grant under Title I covers
    the regulated subject and (2) the regulations are reasonably
    ancillary to the Commission’s effective performance of its
    statutorily mandated responsibilities.” American Library
    
    Ass’n, 406 F.3d at 691
    –92.
    In Comcast, we vacated the Commission’s order, holding
    that the agency failed to demonstrate that it possessed authority
    to regulate broadband providers’ network management
    
    practices. 600 F.3d at 644
    . Specifically, we held that the
    Commission had identified no grant of statutory authority to
    which the Comcast Order was reasonably ancillary. 
    Id. at 661.
    The Commission had principally invoked statutory provisions
    that, though setting forth congressional policy, delegated no
    actual regulatory authority. 
    Id. at 651–58.
    These provisions, we
    concluded, were insufficient because permitting the agency to
    ground its exercise of ancillary jurisdiction in policy
    statements alone would contravene the “‘axiomatic’ principle
    that ‘administrative agencies may [act] only pursuant to
    authority delegated to them by Congress.’” 
    Id. at 654
    (alteration in original) (quoting American Library 
    Ass’n, 406 F.3d at 691
    ). We went on to reject the Commission’s
    invocation of a handful of other statutory provisions that,
    although they could “arguably be read to delegate regulatory
    authority,” 
    id. at 658,
    provided no support for the precise order
    at issue, 
    id. at 658–61.
    While the Comcast matter was pending, the Commission
    sought comment on a set of proposed rules that, with some
    modifications, eventually became the rules at issue here. See In
    re Preserving the Open Internet, 24 F.C.C.R. 13064 (2009). In
    support, it relied on the same theory of ancillary jurisdiction it
    had asserted in the Comcast Order. See 
    id. at 13099
    ¶¶ 83–85.
    13
    But after our decision in Comcast undermined that theory, the
    Commission sought comment on whether and to what extent it
    should reclassify broadband Internet services as
    telecommunications services. See In re Framework for
    Broadband Internet Service, 25 F.C.C.R. 7866, 7867 ¶ 2
    (2010). Ultimately, however, rather than reclassifying
    broadband, the Commission adopted the Open Internet Order
    that Verizon challenges here. See 25 F.C.C.R. 17905.
    The Open Internet Order establishes two sets of
    “prophylactic rules” designed to “incorporate longstanding
    openness principles that are generally in line with current
    practices.” 25 F.C.C.R. at 17907 ¶ 4. One set of rules applies to
    “fixed” broadband providers—i.e., those furnishing residential
    broadband service and, more generally, Internet access to end
    users “primarily at fixed end points using stationary
    equipment.” 
    Id. at 17934
    ¶ 49. The other set of requirements
    applies to “mobile” broadband providers—i.e., those
    “serv[ing] end users primarily using mobile stations,” such as
    smart phones. 
    Id. The Order
    first imposes a transparency requirement on
    both fixed and mobile broadband providers. 
    Id. at 17938
    ¶ 56.
    They must “publicly disclose accurate information regarding
    the network management practices, performance, and
    commercial terms of [their] broadband Internet access
    services.” 
    Id. at 17937
    ¶ 54 (fixed providers); see also 
    id. at 17959
    ¶ 98 (mobile providers).
    Second, the Order imposes anti-blocking requirements on
    both types of broadband providers. It prohibits fixed
    broadband providers from “block[ing] lawful content,
    applications, services, or non-harmful devices, subject to
    reasonable network management.” 
    Id. at 17942
    ¶ 63. Similarly,
    the Order forbids mobile providers from “block[ing]
    14
    consumers from accessing lawful websites” and from
    “block[ing] applications that compete with the provider’s
    voice or video telephony services, subject to reasonable
    network management.” 
    Id. at 17959
    ¶ 99. The Order defines
    “reasonable network management” as practices designed to
    “ensur[e] network security and integrity,” “address[] traffic
    that is unwanted by end users,” “and reduc[e] or mitigat[e] the
    effects of congestion on the network.” 
    Id. at 17952
    ¶ 82. The
    anti-blocking rules, the Order explains, not only prohibit
    broadband providers from preventing their end-user
    subscribers from accessing a particular edge provider
    altogether, but also prohibit them “from impairing or
    degrading particular content, applications, services, or
    non-harmful devices so as to render them effectively
    unusable.” 
    Id. at 17943
    ¶ 66.
    Third, the Order imposes an anti-discrimination
    requirement on fixed broadband providers only. Under this
    rule, such providers “shall not unreasonably discriminate in
    transmitting lawful network traffic over a consumer’s
    broadband Internet access service. Reasonable network
    management shall not constitute unreasonable discrimination.”
    
    Id. at 17944
    ¶ 68. The Commission explained that
    “[u]se-agnostic discrimination”—that is, discrimination based
    not on the nature of the particular traffic involved, but rather,
    for example, on network management needs during periods of
    congestion—would generally comport with this requirement.
    
    Id. at 17945–46
    ¶ 73. Although the Commission never
    expressly said that the rule forbids broadband providers from
    granting preferred status or services to edge providers who pay
    for such benefits, it warned that “as a general matter, it is
    unlikely that pay for priority would satisfy the ‘no
    unreasonable discrimination’ standard.” 
    Id. at 17947
    ¶ 76.
    Declining to impose the same anti-discrimination requirement
    on mobile providers, the Commission explained that
    15
    differential treatment of such providers was warranted because
    the mobile broadband market was more competitive and more
    rapidly evolving than the fixed broadband market, network
    speeds and penetration were lower, and operational constraints
    were higher. See 
    id. at 17956–57
    ¶¶ 94–95.
    As authority for the adoption of these rules, the
    Commission invoked a plethora of statutory provisions. See 
    id. at 17966–81
    ¶¶ 115–37. In particular, the Commission relied
    on section 706 of the 1996 Telecommunications Act, which
    directs it to encourage the deployment of broadband
    telecommunications capability. See 47 U.S.C. § 1302(a), (b).
    According to the Commission, the rules furthered this statutory
    mandate by preserving unhindered the “virtuous circle of
    innovation” that had long driven the growth of the Internet.
    Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17910–11 ¶ 14; see 
    id. at 17968,
    17972 ¶¶ 117, 123. Internet openness, it reasoned, spurs
    investment and development by edge providers, which leads to
    increased end-user demand for broadband access, which leads
    to increased investment in broadband network infrastructure
    and technologies, which in turn leads to further innovation and
    development by edge providers. 
    Id. at 17910–11
    ¶ 14. If, the
    Commission continued, broadband providers were to disrupt
    this “virtuous circle” by “[r]estricting edge providers’ ability to
    reach end users, and limiting end users’ ability to choose which
    edge providers to patronize,” they would “reduce the rate of
    innovation at the edge and, in turn, the likely rate of
    improvements to network infrastructure.” 
    Id. at 17911
    ¶ 14.
    Two members of the Commission dissented. As they saw
    it, the Open Internet Order rules not only exceeded the
    Commission’s lawful authority, but would also stifle rather
    than encourage innovation. See Open Internet Order, 25
    F.C.C.R. at 18049–81 (Dissenting Statement of Commissioner
    16
    McDowell); 
    id. at 18084–98
    (Dissenting Statement of
    Commissioner Baker).
    Verizon filed a petition for review of the Open Internet
    Order pursuant to 47 U.S.C. § 402(a) as well as a notice of
    appeal pursuant to 47 U.S.C. § 402(b). Because “we plainly
    have jurisdiction by the one procedural route or the other,” “we
    need not decide which is the more appropriate vehicle for our
    review.” Cellco Partnership v. FCC, 
    700 F.3d 534
    , 541 (D.C.
    Cir. 2012) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    Verizon challenges the Open Internet Order on several
    grounds, including that the Commission lacked affirmative
    statutory authority to promulgate the rules, that its decision to
    impose the rules was arbitrary and capricious, and that the rules
    contravene statutory provisions prohibiting the Commission
    from treating broadband providers as common carriers. In Part
    II, we consider Verizon’s attacks on the Commission’s
    affirmative statutory authority and its justification for
    imposing these rules. We consider the common carrier issue in
    Part III. Given our disposition of the latter issue, we have no
    need to address Verizon’s additional contentions that the Order
    violates the First Amendment and constitutes an
    uncompensated taking.
    Before beginning our analysis, we think it important to
    emphasize that although the question of net neutrality
    implicates serious policy questions, which have engaged
    lawmakers, regulators, businesses, and other members of the
    public for years, our inquiry here is relatively limited.
    “Regardless of how serious the problem an administrative
    agency seeks to address, . . . it may not exercise its authority in
    a manner that is inconsistent with the administrative structure
    that Congress enacted into law.” Ragsdale v. Wolverine World
    Wide, Inc., 
    535 U.S. 81
    , 91 (2002) (internal quotation marks
    17
    omitted). Accordingly, our task as a reviewing court is not to
    assess the wisdom of the Open Internet Order regulations, but
    rather to determine whether the Commission has demonstrated
    that the regulations fall within the scope of its statutory grant of
    authority.
    II.
    The Commission cites numerous statutory provisions it
    claims grant it the power to promulgate the Open Internet
    Order rules. But we start and end our analysis with section 706
    of the 1996 Telecommunications Act, which, as we shall
    explain, furnishes the Commission with the requisite
    affirmative authority to adopt the regulations.
    Section 706(a) provides:
    The Commission and each State commission with
    regulatory jurisdiction over telecommunications
    services shall encourage the deployment on a
    reasonable and timely basis of advanced
    telecommunications capability to all Americans
    (including, in particular, elementary and secondary
    schools and classrooms) by utilizing, in a manner
    consistent with the public interest, convenience, and
    necessity, price cap regulation, regulatory
    forbearance, measures that promote competition in
    the local telecommunications market, or other
    regulating methods that remove barriers to
    infrastructure investment.
    47 U.S.C. § 1302(a). Section 706(b), in turn, requires the
    Commission to conduct a regular inquiry “concerning the
    availability of advanced telecommunications capability.” 
    Id. § 1302(b).
    It further provides that should the Commission find
    that “advanced telecommunications capability is [not] being
    18
    deployed to all Americans in a reasonable and timely fashion,”
    it “shall take immediate action to accelerate deployment of
    such capability by removing barriers to infrastructure
    investment and by promoting competition in the
    telecommunications market.” 
    Id. The statute
    defines
    “advanced telecommunications capability” to include
    “broadband telecommunications capability.” 
    Id. § 1302(d)(1).
    Verizon contends that neither subsection (a) nor (b) of
    section 706 confers any regulatory authority on the
    Commission. As Verizon sees it, the two subsections amount
    to nothing more than congressional statements of policy.
    Verizon further contends that even if either provision grants
    the Commission substantive authority, the scope of that grant is
    not so expansive as to permit the Commission to regulate
    broadband providers in the manner that the Open Internet
    Order rules do. In addressing these questions, we apply the
    familiar two-step analysis of Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural
    Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    (1984). As the
    Supreme Court has recently made clear, Chevron deference is
    warranted even if the Commission has interpreted a statutory
    provision that could be said to delineate the scope of the
    agency’s jurisdiction. See City of Arlington v. FCC, 
    133 S. Ct. 1863
    , 1874 (2013). Thus, if we determine that the
    Commission’s interpretation of section 706 represents a
    reasonable resolution of a statutory ambiguity, we must defer
    to that interpretation. See 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842
    –43. The
    Chevron inquiry overlaps substantially with that required by
    the Administrative Procedure Act (APA), pursuant to which
    we must also determine whether the Commission’s actions
    were “arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or
    otherwise not in accordance with law.” 5 U.S.C. § 706(2)(A);
    see National Ass’n of Regulatory Utility Commissioners v.
    Interstate Commerce Commission, 
    41 F.3d 721
    , 726–27 (D.C.
    Cir. 1994).
    19
    A.
    This is not the first time the Commission has asserted that
    section 706(a) grants it authority to regulate broadband
    providers. Advancing a similar argument in Comcast, the
    Commission contended that section 706(a) provided a
    statutory hook for its exercise of ancillary jurisdiction.
    Although we thought that section 706(a) might “arguably be
    read to delegate regulatory authority to the Commission,” we
    concluded that the Commission could not rely on this provision
    to justify the Comcast Order because it had previously
    determined, in the still-binding Advanced Services Order, that
    the provision “‘does not constitute an independent grant of
    authority.’” 
    Comcast, 600 F.3d at 658
    (quoting Advanced
    Services Order, 13 F.C.C.R. at 24047 ¶ 77). We rejected the
    Commission’s claim that the Advanced Services Order
    concluded only that section 706(a) granted it no forbearance
    authority—authority to relieve regulated entities of statutory
    obligations to which they would otherwise be subject, see 47
    U.S.C. § 160—over and above that given it elsewhere in the
    Communications Act. 
    Comcast, 600 F.3d at 658
    . Indeed, the
    Advanced Services Order was clearly far broader, explicitly
    declaring: “section 706(a) does not constitute an independent
    grant of forbearance authority or of authority to employ other
    regulating methods.” Advanced Services Order, 13 F.C.C.R. at
    24044 ¶ 69 (emphasis added). Because the Commission had
    “never questioned, let alone overruled, that understanding of
    section 706,” we held that it “remain[ed] bound” by its prior
    interpretation. 
    Comcast, 600 F.3d at 659
    .
    But the Commission need not remain forever bound by the
    Advanced Services Order’s restrictive reading of section
    706(a). “An initial agency interpretation is not instantly carved
    in stone.” 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 863
    . The APA’s requirement of
    reasoned decision-making ordinarily demands that an agency
    20
    acknowledge and explain the reasons for a changed
    interpretation. See FCC v. Fox Television Stations, Inc., 
    556 U.S. 502
    , 515 (2009) (“An agency may not . . . depart from a
    prior policy sub silentio or simply disregard rules that are still
    on the books.”); Brand 
    X, 545 U.S. at 981
    (“Unexplained
    inconsistency is, at most, a reason for holding an interpretation
    to be an arbitrary and capricious change from agency practice
    under the Administrative Procedure Act.”). But so long as an
    agency “adequately explains the reasons for a reversal of
    policy,” its new interpretation of a statute cannot be rejected
    simply because it is new. Brand 
    X, 545 U.S. at 981
    . At the time
    we issued our Comcast opinion, the Commission failed to
    satisfy this requirement, as its assertion that section 706(a)
    gave it regulatory authority represented, at that point, an
    attempt to “‘depart from a prior policy sub silentio.’” 
    Comcast, 600 F.3d at 659
    (quoting 
    Fox, 556 U.S. at 515
    ).
    In the Open Internet Order, however, the Commission has
    offered a reasoned explanation for its changed understanding
    of section 706(a). To be sure, the Open Internet Order evinces
    a palpable reluctance to accept this court’s interpretation of the
    Advanced Services Order, as the Commission again attempts
    to reconcile its current understanding of section 706(a) with its
    prior interpretation. See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    17969 ¶ 119 (characterizing the Advanced Services Order as
    being “consistent with [the Commission’s] present
    understanding”). Of course, such reluctance hardly makes the
    Commission’s decision unreasonable, as it is free to express its
    disagreement with this court’s holdings. After all, even a
    federal agency is entitled to a little pride. Moreover, although
    the Open Internet Order inaccurately describes the Advanced
    Services Order’s actual conclusion, it does describe what the
    Order likely should have concluded. Specifically, the
    Advanced Services Order’s rejection of section 706(a) as a
    source of substantive authority rested almost entirely on the
    21
    notion that a contrary interpretation would somehow permit the
    Commission to evade express statutory commands forbidding
    it from using its forbearance authority in certain circumstances.
    See Advanced Services Order, 13 F.C.C.R. at 24045–46 ¶¶ 72–
    73. This makes little sense. By the same reasoning, one might
    say that Article I of the Constitution gives Congress no
    substantive authority because Congress might otherwise be
    able to use that authority in a way that violates the Ex Post
    Facto Clause. The Open Internet Order characterizes the
    Advanced Services Order as simply “disavowing a reading of
    Section 706(a) that would allow the agency to trump specific
    mandates of the Communications Act,” thus honoring “the
    interpretive canon that ‘[a] specific provision . . . controls one[]
    of more general application.’” Open Internet Order, 25
    F.C.C.R. at 17969 ¶¶ 118–119 (quoting Bloate v. United
    States, 
    559 U.S. 196
    , 207 (2010)). Perhaps the Commission
    should have more openly acknowledged that it was not actually
    describing the Advanced Services Order, but instead rewriting
    it in a more logical manner. In this latter task, however, the
    Commission succeeded: its reinterpretation of the Advanced
    Services Order was more reasonable than the Advanced
    Services Order itself.
    In any event—and more important for our purposes—the
    Commission expressly declared: “To the extent that the
    Advanced Services Order can be construed as having read
    Section 706(a) differently, we reject that reading of the statute
    for the reasons discussed in the text.” Open Internet Order, 25
    F.C.C.R. at 17969 ¶ 119 n.370. Setting forth those “reasons” at
    some length, the Commission analyzed the statute’s text, its
    legislative history, and the resultant scope of the Commission’s
    authority, concluding that each of these considerations
    supports the view that section 706(a) constitutes an affirmative
    grant of regulatory authority. 
    Id. at 17969–70
    ¶¶ 119–121. In
    these circumstances, and contrary to Verizon’s contentions, we
    22
    have no basis for saying that the Commission “casually
    ignored prior policies and interpretations or otherwise failed to
    provide a reasoned explanation” for its changed interpretation.
    Cablevision Systems Corp. v. FCC, 
    649 F.3d 695
    , 710 (D.C.
    Cir. 2011) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    The question, then, is this: Does the Commission’s current
    understanding of section 706(a) as a grant of regulatory
    authority represent a reasonable interpretation of an ambiguous
    statute? We believe it does.
    Recall that the provision directs the Commission
    to “encourage the deployment . . . of advanced
    telecommunications capability . . . by utilizing . . . price cap
    regulation, regulatory forbearance, measures that promote
    competition in the local telecommunications market, or other
    regulating methods that remove barriers to infrastructure
    investment.” 47 U.S.C. § 1302(a). As Verizon argues, this
    language could certainly be read as simply setting forth a
    statement of congressional policy, directing the Commission to
    employ “regulating methods” already at the Commission’s
    disposal in order to achieve the stated goal of promoting
    “advanced telecommunications” technology. But the language
    can just as easily be read to vest the Commission with actual
    authority to utilize such “regulating methods” to meet this
    stated goal. As the Commission put it in the Open Internet
    Order, one might reasonably think that Congress, in directing
    the Commission to undertake certain acts, “necessarily
    invested the Commission with the statutory authority to carry
    out those acts.” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17969
    ¶ 120.
    Section 706(a)’s reference to state commissions does not
    foreclose such a reading. Observing that the statute applies to
    both “[t]he Commission and each State commission with
    23
    regulatory jurisdiction over telecommunications services,” 47
    U.S.C. § 1302(a) (emphasis added), Verizon contends that
    Congress would not be expected to grant both the FCC and
    state commissions the regulatory authority to encourage the
    deployment of advanced telecommunications capabilities. But
    Congress has granted regulatory authority to state
    telecommunications commissions on other occasions, and we
    see no reason to think that it could not have done the same here.
    See, e.g., 
    id. § 251(f)
    (granting state commissions the authority
    to exempt rural local exchange carriers from certain
    obligations imposed on other incumbents); 
    id. § 252(e)
    (requiring all interconnection agreements between incumbent
    local exchange carriers and entrant carriers to be approved by a
    state commission); see also AT & T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities
    Board, 
    525 U.S. 366
    , 385–86 (1999) (describing the
    Commission’s power and responsibility to dictate the manner
    in which state commissions exercise such authority). Thus,
    Congress has not “directly spoken” to the question of whether
    section 706(a) is a grant of regulatory authority simply by
    mentioning state commissions in that grant. 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842
    .
    This case, moreover, is a far cry from FDA v. Brown &
    Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    529 U.S. 120
    (2000), on which
    Verizon principally relies. There, the Supreme Court held that
    “Congress ha[d] clearly precluded the [Food and Drug
    Administration] from asserting jurisdiction to regulate tobacco
    products.” 
    Id. at 126.
    The Court emphasized that the FDA had
    not only completely disclaimed any authority to regulate
    tobacco products, but had done so for more than eighty years,
    and that Congress had repeatedly legislated against this
    background. See 
    id. at 143–59.
    The Court also observed that
    the FDA’s newly adopted conclusion that it did in fact have
    authority to regulate this industry would, given its findings
    regarding the effects of tobacco products and its authorizing
    24
    statute, logically require the agency to ban such products
    altogether, a result clearly contrary to congressional policy. See
    
    id. at 135–43.
    Furthermore, the Court reasoned, if Congress
    had intended to “delegate a decision of such economic and
    political significance” to the agency, it would have done so far
    more clearly. 
    Id. at 160.
    The circumstances here are entirely different. Although
    the Commission once disclaimed authority to regulate under
    section 706(a), it never disclaimed authority to regulate the
    Internet or Internet providers altogether, nor is there any
    similar history of congressional reliance on such a disclaimer.
    To the contrary, as recounted above, see supra at 7–9, when
    Congress passed section 706(a) in 1996, it did so against the
    backdrop of the Commission’s long history of subjecting to
    common carrier regulation the entities that controlled the
    last-mile facilities over which end users accessed the Internet.
    See, e.g., Second Computer Inquiry, 77 F.C.C.2d at 473–74
    ¶¶ 228–29. Indeed, one might have thought, as the
    Commission originally concluded, see Advanced Services
    Order, 13 F.C.C.R. at 24029–30 ¶ 35, that Congress clearly
    contemplated that the Commission would continue regulating
    Internet providers in the manner it had previously. Cf. Brand 
    X, 545 U.S. at 1003
    (Breyer, J., concurring) (concluding that the
    Commission’s decision to exempt cable broadband providers
    from Title II regulation was “perhaps just barely” within the
    scope of the agency’s “statutorily delegated authority”); 
    id. at 1005
    (Scalia, J., dissenting) (arguing that Commission’s
    decision “exceeded the authority given it by Congress”). In
    fact, section 706(a)’s legislative history suggests that Congress
    may have, somewhat presciently, viewed that provision as an
    affirmative grant of authority to the Commission whose
    existence would become necessary if other contemplated
    grants of statutory authority were for some reason unavailable.
    The Senate Report describes section 706 as a “necessary
    25
    fail-safe” “intended to ensure that one of the primary
    objectives of the [Act]—to accelerate deployment of advanced
    telecommunications capability—is achieved.” S. Rep. No.
    104-23 at 50–51. As the Commission observed in the Open
    Internet Order, it would be “odd . . . to characterize Section
    706(a) as a ‘fail-safe’ that ‘ensures’ the Commission’s ability
    to promote advanced services if it conferred no actual
    authority.” 25 F.C.C.R. at 17970 ¶ 120.
    Verizon directs our attention to a number of bills
    introduced in Congress subsequent to the passage of the 1996
    Act that, if enacted, would have imposed requirements on
    broadband providers similar to those embodied in the
    Commission’s Open Internet Order. See, e.g., Internet
    Non-Discrimination Act of 2006, S. 2360, 109th Cong. (2006).
    Such subsequent legislative history, however, provides “‘an
    unreliable guide to legislative intent.’” North Broward
    Hospital District v. Shalala, 
    172 F.3d 90
    , 98 (D.C. Cir. 1999)
    (quoting Chapman v. United States, 
    500 U.S. 453
    , 464 n.4
    (1991)). Moreover, even assuming that Congress’s failure to
    impose such restrictions would itself cast light on Congress’s
    understanding of the Commission’s power to do so, any such
    inferences would be largely countered by Congress’s similar
    failure to adopt a proposed resolution that would have
    specifically disapproved of the Commission’s promulgation of
    the Open Internet Order. See H.J. Res. 37, 112th Cong. (2011).
    These conflicting pieces of subsequent failed legislation tell us
    little if anything about the original meaning of the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996.
    Thus, although regulation of broadband Internet
    providers certainly involves decisions of great “economic and
    political significance,” Brown & 
    Williamson, 529 U.S. at 160
    ,
    we have little reason given this history to think that Congress
    could not have delegated some of these decisions to the
    26
    Commission. To be sure, Congress does not, as Verizon
    reminds us, “hide elephants in mouseholes.” Whitman v.
    American Trucking Ass’ns, Inc., 
    531 U.S. 457
    , 468 (2001). But
    FCC regulation of broadband providers is no elephant, and
    section 706(a) is no mousehole.
    Of course, we might well hesitate to conclude that
    Congress intended to grant the Commission substantive
    authority in section 706(a) if that authority would have no
    limiting principle. See 
    Comcast, 600 F.3d at 655
    (rejecting
    Commission’s understanding of its authority that “if accepted
    . . . would virtually free the Commission from its congressional
    tether”); cf. 
    Whitman, 531 U.S. at 472
    –73 (discussing the
    nondelegation doctrine). But we are satisfied that the scope of
    authority granted to the Commission by section 706(a) is not so
    boundless as to compel the conclusion that Congress could
    never have intended the provision to set forth anything other
    than a general statement of policy. The Commission has
    identified at least two limiting principles inherent in section
    706(a). See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17970 ¶ 121.
    First, the section must be read in conjunction with other
    provisions of the Communications Act, including, most
    importantly, those limiting the Commission’s subject matter
    jurisdiction to “interstate and foreign communication by wire
    and radio.” 47 U.S.C. § 152(a). Any regulatory action
    authorized by section 706(a) would thus have to fall within the
    Commission’s subject matter jurisdiction over such
    communications—a limitation whose importance this court
    has recognized in delineating the reach of the Commission’s
    ancillary jurisdiction. See American Library 
    Ass’n, 406 F.3d at 703
    –04. Second, any regulations must be designed to achieve a
    particular purpose: to “encourage the deployment on a
    reasonable and timely basis of advanced telecommunications
    capability to all Americans.” 47 U.S.C. § 1302(a). Section
    706(a) thus gives the Commission authority to promulgate only
    27
    those regulations that it establishes will fulfill this specific
    statutory goal—a burden that, as we trust our searching
    analysis below will demonstrate, is far from “meaningless.”
    Dissenting Op. at 7.
    B.
    Section 706(b) has a less tortured history. Until shortly
    before the Commission issued the Open Internet Order, it had
    never considered whether the provision vested it with any
    regulatory authority. The Commission had no need to do so
    because prior to that time it had made no determination that
    advanced telecommunications technologies, including
    broadband Internet access, were not “being deployed to all
    Americans in a reasonable and timely fashion,” the
    prerequisite for any purported invocation of authority to “take
    immediate action to accelerate deployment of such capability”
    under section 706(b). 47 U.S.C. § 1302(b).
    In July 2010, however, the Commission concluded that
    “broadband deployment to all Americans is not reasonable and
    timely.” Sixth Broadband Deployment Report, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    9558 ¶ 2. This conclusion, the Commission recognized,
    represented a deviation from its five prior assessments. 
    Id. at 9558
    ¶ 2 & n.8. According to the Commission, the change was
    driven by its decision to raise the minimum speed threshold
    qualifying as broadband. 
    Id. at 9558
    ¶ 4. “Broadband,” as
    defined in the 1996 Telecommunications Act, is Internet
    service furnished at speeds that “enable[] users to originate and
    receive high-quality voice, data, graphics, and video
    telecommunications using any technology.” 47 U.S.C.
    § 1302(d)(1). In 1999, the Commission found this requirement
    satisfied by services “having the capability of supporting . . . a
    speed . . . in excess of 200 kilobits per second (kbps) in the last
    mile.” In re Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced
    Telecommunications Capability to All Americans in a
    28
    Reasonable and Timely Fashion, 14 F.C.C.R. 2398, 2406 ¶ 20
    (1999). The Commission chose this threshold because it was
    “enough to provide the most popular forms of broadband—to
    change web pages as fast as one can flip through the pages of a
    book and to transmit full-motion video.” 
    Id. That said,
    the
    Commission recognized that technological developments
    might someday require it to reassess the 200 kbps threshold. 
    Id. at 2407–08
    ¶ 25.
    In the Sixth Broadband Deployment Report, the
    Commission decided that day had finally arrived. The
    Commission explained that consumers now regularly use their
    Internet connections to access high-quality video and expect to
    be able at the same time to check their email and browse the
    web. Sixth Broadband Deployment Report, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    9562–64 ¶¶ 10–11. Two hundred kbps, the Commission
    determined, “simply is not enough bandwidth” to permit such
    uses. 
    Id. at 9562
    ¶ 10. The Commission thus adopted a new
    threshold more appropriate to current consumer behavior and
    expectations: four megabytes per second (mbps) for end users
    to download content from the Internet—twenty times as fast as
    the prior threshold—and one mbps for end users to upload
    content. 
    Id. at 9563
    ¶ 11.
    Applying this new benchmark, the Commission found that
    “roughly 80 million American adults do not subscribe to
    broadband at home, and approximately 14 to 24 million
    Americans do not have access to broadband today.” Sixth
    Broadband Deployment Report, 25 F.C.C.R. at 9574 ¶ 28.
    Given these figures and the “ever-growing importance of
    broadband to our society,” the Commission was unable to find
    “that broadband is being reasonably and timely deployed”
    within the meaning of section 706(b). 
    Id. This conclusion,
    it
    explained, triggered section 706(b)’s mandate that the
    Commission “take immediate action to accelerate
    29
    deployment.” 
    Id. at 9558
    ¶ 3 (quoting 47 U.S.C. § 1302(b))
    (internal quotation marks omitted).
    Subsequently, in the Open Internet Order the Commission
    made clear that this statutory provision does not limit the
    Commission to using other regulatory authority already at its
    disposal, but instead grants it the power necessary to fulfill the
    statute’s mandate. See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    17972 ¶ 123. Emphasizing the provision’s “shall take
    immediate action” directive, the Commission concluded that
    section 706(b) “provides express authority” for the rules it
    adopted. 
    Id. Contrary to
    Verizon’s arguments, we believe the
    Commission has reasonably interpreted section 706(b) to
    empower it to take steps to accelerate broadband deployment if
    and when it determines that such deployment is not
    “reasonable and timely.” To be sure, as with section 706(a), it
    is unclear whether section 706(b), in providing that the
    Commission “shall take immediate action to accelerate
    deployment of such capability by removing barriers to
    infrastructure investment and by promoting competition in the
    telecommunications market,” vested the Commission with
    authority to remove such barriers to infrastructure investment
    and promote competition. 47 U.S.C. § 1302(b). But the
    provision may certainly be read to accomplish as much, and
    given such ambiguity we have no basis for rejecting the
    Commission’s determination that it should be so understood.
    See 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842
    –43. Moreover, as discussed
    above with respect to section 706(a), see supra at 24–27,
    nothing in the regulatory background or the legislative history
    either before or after passage of the 1996 Telecommunications
    Act forecloses such an understanding. We think it quite
    reasonable to believe that Congress contemplated that the
    Commission would regulate this industry, as the agency had in
    30
    the past, and the scope of any authority granted to it by section
    706(b)—limited, as it is, both by the boundaries of the
    Commission’s subject matter jurisdiction and the requirement
    that any regulation be tailored to the specific statutory goal of
    accelerating broadband deployment—is not so broad that we
    might hesitate to think that Congress could have intended such
    a delegation.
    Verizon makes two additional arguments regarding the
    Commission’s interpretation of section 706(b), both of which
    we can dispose of in relatively short order.
    First, Verizon contends that if section 706(b) gives the
    Commission any regulatory authority, that authority must be
    understood in conjunction with section 706(c), which directs
    the Commission to “compile a list of geographical areas that
    are not served by any provider of advanced
    telecommunications capability.” 47 U.S.C. § 1302(c). Thus,
    Verizon claims, any regulations that the Commission might
    adopt pursuant to section 706(b) may not “reach beyond any
    particular ‘geographical areas that are not served’ by any
    broadband provider and apply throughout the country.”
    Verizon’s Br. 33 (emphasis omitted). By its own terms,
    however, section 706(c) describes simply “part of the inquiry”
    that section 706(b) requires the Commission to conduct
    concerning broadband deployment. 47 U.S.C. § 1302(c)
    (emphasis added). It nowhere purports to delineate all aspects
    of that inquiry. Nor does it limit the actions that the
    Commission may take if, in the course of that inquiry, it
    determines that broadband deployment has not been
    “reasonable and timely.”
    Second, Verizon asserts that the Sixth Broadband
    Deployment Report’s finding that triggered section 706(b)’s
    grant of regulatory authority “arbitrarily contravened five prior
    31
    agency determinations of reasonable and timely deployment.”
    Verizon’s Br. 33. The timing of the Commission’s
    determination is certainly suspicious, coming as it did closely
    on the heels of our rejection in Comcast of the legal theory on
    which the Commission had until then relied to establish its
    authority over broadband providers. But questionable timing,
    by itself, gives us no basis to reject an otherwise reasonable
    finding. Beyond its general assertion that the Commission’s
    finding was “arbitrar[y],” Verizon offers no specific reason for
    thinking that the Commission’s logical and carefully reasoned
    determination was illegitimate. We can see none.
    C.
    This brings us, then, to Verizon’s alternative argument
    that even if, as we have held, sections 706(a) and 706(b) grant
    the Commission affirmative authority to promulgate rules
    governing broadband providers, the specific rules imposed by
    the Open Internet Order fall outside the scope of that authority.
    The Commission’s theory, to reiterate, is that its regulations
    protect and promote edge-provider investment and
    development, which in turn drives end-user demand for more
    and better broadband technologies, which in turn stimulates
    competition among broadband providers to further invest in
    broadband. See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17910–
    11, 17970 ¶¶ 14, 120. Thus, the Commission claims, by
    preventing broadband providers from blocking or
    discriminating against edge providers, the rules “encourage the
    deployment on a reasonable and timely basis of advanced
    telecommunications capability to all Americans,” 47 U.S.C.
    § 1302(a), and “accelerate deployment of such capability,” 
    id. § 1302(b),
    by removing “barriers to infrastructure investment”
    and promoting “competition,” 
    id. § 1302(a),
    (b). See Open
    Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17968, 17972 ¶¶ 117, 123. That
    is, contrary to the dissent, see Dissenting Op. at 2–7, the
    Commission made clear—and Verizon appears to
    32
    recognize—that the Commission found broadband providers’
    potential disruption of edge-provider traffic to be itself the sort
    of “barrier” that has “the potential to stifle overall investment
    in Internet infrastructure,” and could “limit competition in
    telecommunications markets.” Open Internet Order, 25
    F.C.C.R. at 17970 ¶ 120.
    Verizon mounts a twofold challenge to this rationale. It
    argues that the Open Internet Order regulations will not, as the
    Commission claims, meaningfully promote broadband
    deployment, and that even if they do advance this goal, the
    manner in which they do so is too attenuated from this statutory
    purpose to fall within the scope of authority granted by either
    statutory provision.
    We begin with the second, more strictly legal, question of
    whether, assuming the Commission has accurately predicted
    the effect of these regulations, it may utilize the authority
    granted to it in sections 706(a) and 706(b) to impose
    regulations of this sort on broadband providers. As we have
    previously acknowledged, “in proscribing . . . practices with
    the statutorily identified effect, an agency might stray so far
    from the paradigm case as to render its interpretation
    unreasonable, arbitrary, or capricious.” National Cable &
    Telecommunications Ass’n v. FCC, 
    567 F.3d 659
    , 665 (D.C.
    Cir. 2009). Here, Verizon has given us no reason to conclude
    that the Open Internet Order’s requirements “stray” so far
    beyond the “paradigm case” that Congress likely contemplated
    as to render the Commission’s understanding of its authority
    unreasonable. The rules not only apply directly to broadband
    providers, the precise entities to which section 706 authority to
    encourage broadband deployment presumably extends, but
    also seek to promote the very goal that Congress explicitly
    sought to promote. Because the rules advance this statutory
    goal of broadband deployment by first promoting
    33
    edge-provider innovations and end-user demand, Verizon
    derides the Commission’s justification as a “triple-cushion
    shot.” Verizon’s Br. 28. In billiards, however, a triple-cushion
    shot, although perhaps more difficult to complete, counts the
    same as any other shot. The Commission could reasonably
    have thought that its authority to promulgate regulations that
    promote broadband deployment encompasses the power to
    regulate broadband providers’ economic relationships with
    edge providers if, in fact, the nature of those relationships
    influences the rate and extent to which broadband providers
    develop and expand their services for end users. See
    
    Cablevision, 649 F.3d at 709
    (holding that Commission had
    not impermissibly “reached beyond the paradigm case” in
    “interpreting a statute focused on the provision of satellite
    programming to authorize terrestrial withholding regulations,”
    because cable companies’ ability to withhold terrestrial
    programming would, in turn, discourage potential competitors
    from entering the market to provide satellite programming)
    (internal quotation marks omitted).
    Whether the Commission’s assessment of the likely
    effects of the Open Internet Order deserves credence presents
    a slightly more complex question. Verizon attacks the
    reasoning and factual support underlying the Commission’s
    “triple-cushion shot” theory, advancing these arguments both
    as an attack on the Commission’s statutory interpretation and
    as an APA arbitrary and capricious challenge. Given that these
    two arguments involve similar considerations, we address
    them together. In so doing, “we must uphold the Commission’s
    factual determinations if on the record as a whole, there is such
    relevant evidence as a reasonable mind might accept as
    adequate to support [the] conclusion.” Secretary of Labor,
    MSHA v. Federal Mine Safety & Health Review Comm’n, 
    111 F.3d 913
    , 918 (D.C. Cir. 1997) (internal quotation marks
    omitted); see 5 U.S.C. § 706(2)(E). We evaluate the
    34
    Commission’s reasoning to ensure that it has “examine[d] the
    relevant data and articulate[d] a satisfactory explanation for its
    action including a rational connection between the facts found
    and the choice made.” National Fuel Gas Supply Corp. v.
    FERC, 
    468 F.3d 831
    , 839 (D.C. Cir. 2006) (quoting Motor
    Vehicle Manufacturers Ass’n of U.S. v. State Farm Mutual
    Auto Insurance Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 43 (1983)) (internal
    quotation marks omitted). When assessing the reasonableness
    of the Commission’s conclusions, we must be careful not to
    simply “‘substitute [our] judgment for that of the agency,’”
    especially when the “agency’s predictive judgments about the
    likely economic effects of a rule” are at issue. National
    Telephone Cooperative Ass’n v. FCC, 
    563 F.3d 536
    , 541 (D.C.
    Cir. 2009) (quoting State 
    Farm, 463 U.S. at 43
    ). Under these
    standards, the Commission’s prediction that the Open Internet
    Order regulations will encourage broadband deployment is, in
    our view, both rational and supported by substantial evidence.
    To begin with, the Commission has more than adequately
    supported and explained its conclusion that edge-provider
    innovation leads to the expansion and improvement of
    broadband infrastructure. The Internet, the Commission
    observed in the Open Internet Order, is, “[l]ike electricity and
    the computer,” a “‘general purpose technology’ that enables
    new methods of production that have a major impact on the
    entire economy.” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17909
    ¶ 13. Certain innovations—the lightbulb, for example—create
    a need for infrastructure investment, such as in power
    generation facilities and distribution lines, that complement
    and further drive the development of the initial innovation and
    ultimately the growth of the economy as a whole. See Timothy
    F. Bresnahan & M. Trajtenberg, General purpose
    technologies: ‘Engines of Growth’? 65 J. ECONOMETRICS 83,
    84 (1995), cited in Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17909
    ¶ 13 n.12; see also Amicus Br. of Internet Engineers and
    35
    Technologists 17 (citing Hearing on Internet Security Before
    the H. Comm. on Science, Space, and Technology, 103d Cong.
    (Mar. 22, 1994) (written testimony of Dr. Vinton G. Cerf)).
    The rise of streaming online video is perhaps the best and
    clearest example the Commission used to illustrate that the
    Internet constitutes one such technology: higher-speed
    residential Internet connections in the late 1990s “stimulated”
    the development of streaming video, a service that requires
    particularly high bandwidth, “which in turn encouraged
    broadband providers to increase network speeds.” Open
    Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17911 ¶ 14 n.23. The
    Commission’s emphasis on this connection between
    edge-provider innovation and infrastructure development is
    uncontroversial. Indeed, in its comments to the Commission,
    Verizon, executing a triple-cushion shot of its own,
    acknowledged:
    [T]he social and economic fruits of the Internet
    economy are the result of a virtuous cycle of
    innovation and growth between that ecosystem
    and the underlying infrastructure—the
    infrastructure enabling the development and
    dissemination of Internet-based services and
    applications, with the demand and use of those
    services . . . driving improvements in the
    infrastructure which, in turn, support further
    innovations in services and applications.
    Verizon Comments at 42, Docket No. 09-191 (Jan. 14, 2010)
    (internal quotation marks omitted).
    The Commission’s finding that Internet openness fosters
    the edge-provider innovation that drives this “virtuous cycle”
    was likewise reasonable and grounded in substantial evidence.
    Continued innovation at the edge, the Commission explained,
    36
    “depends upon low barriers to innovation and entry by edge
    providers,” and thus restrictions on edge providers’ “ability to
    reach end users . . . reduce the rate of innovation.” Open
    Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17911 ¶ 14. This conclusion
    finds ample support in the economic literature on which the
    Commission relied, see, e.g., Joseph Farrell & Philip J. Weiser,
    Modularity, Vertical Integration, and Open Access Policies:
    Towards a Convergence of Antitrust and Regulation in the
    Internet Age, 17 HARV. J. L. & TECH. 85, 95 (2003), cited in
    Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17911 ¶ 14 n.25, as well
    as in history and the comments of several edge providers. For
    one prominent illustration of the relationship between
    openness and innovation, the Commission cited the invention
    of the World Wide Web itself by Sir Tim Berners-Lee, who,
    although not working for an entity that operated the underlying
    network, was able to create and disseminate this enormously
    successful innovation without needing to make any changes to
    previously developed Internet protocols or securing “any
    approval from network operators.” Open Internet Order, 25
    F.C.C.R. at 17910 ¶ 13 (citing, inter alia, TIM BERNERS-LEE,
    WEAVING THE WEB 16 (2000)). It also highlighted the
    comments of Google and Vonage—both innovative edge
    providers—who emphasized the importance of the Internet’s
    open design to permitting new content and services to develop
    at the edge. 
    Id. at 17911
    ¶ 14 n.24 & n.25. The record amassed
    by the Commission contains many similar examples, and
    Verizon has given us no basis for questioning the
    Commission’s determination that the preservation of Internet
    openness is integral to achieving the statutory objectives set
    forth in Section 706. See 
    id. at 17910–11,
    17968, 17972 ¶¶ 14,
    117, 123.
    Equally important, the Commission has adequately
    supported and explained its conclusion that, absent rules such
    as those set forth in the Open Internet Order, broadband
    37
    providers represent a threat to Internet openness and could act
    in ways that would ultimately inhibit the speed and extent of
    future broadband deployment. First, nothing in the record gives
    us any reason to doubt the Commission’s determination that
    broadband providers may be motivated to discriminate against
    and among edge providers. The Commission observed that
    broadband providers—often the same entities that furnish end
    users with telephone and television services—“have incentives
    to interfere with the operation of third-party Internet-based
    services that compete with the providers’ revenue-generating
    telephone and/or pay-television services.” Open Internet
    Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17916 ¶ 22. As the Commission noted,
    Voice-over-Internet-Protocol (VoIP) services such as Vonage
    increasingly serve as substitutes for traditional telephone
    services, 
    id., and broadband
    providers like AT&T and Time
    Warner have acknowledged that online video aggregators such
    as Netflix and Hulu compete directly with their own “core
    video subscription service,” 
    id. at 17917
    ¶ 22 & n.54; see also
    
    id. at 17918
    ¶ 23 n.60 (finding that a study concluding that
    cable companies had sought to exclude networks that
    competed with the companies’ own affiliated channels, see
    Austan Goolsbee, Vertical Integration and the Market for
    Broadcast and Cable Television Programming, Paper for the
    Federal Communications Commission 31–32 (Sept. 5, 2007),
    “provides empirical evidence that cable providers have acted in
    the past on anticompetitive incentives to foreclose rivals”).
    Broadband providers also have powerful incentives to accept
    fees from edge providers, either in return for excluding their
    competitors or for granting them prioritized access to end
    users. See 
    id. at 17918
    –19 ¶¶ 23–24. Indeed, at oral argument
    Verizon’s counsel announced that “but for [the Open Internet
    Order] rules we would be exploring those commercial
    arrangements.” Oral Arg. Tr. 31. And although broadband
    providers might not adopt pay-for-priority agreements or other
    similar arrangements if, according to the Commission’s
    38
    analysis, such agreements would ultimately lead to a decrease
    in end-user demand for broadband, the Commission explained
    that the resultant harms to innovation and demand will largely
    constitute “negative externalities”: any given broadband
    provider will “receive the benefits of . . . fees but [is] unlikely
    to fully account for the detrimental impact on edge providers’
    ability and incentive to innovate and invest.” Open Internet
    Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17919–20 ¶ 25 & n.68. Although
    Verizon dismisses the Commission’s assertions regarding
    broadband providers’ incentives as “pure speculation,”
    Verizon’s Br. 52, see also Dissenting Op. at 15, those
    assertions are, at the very least, speculation based firmly in
    common sense and economic reality.
    Moreover, as the Commission found, broadband providers
    have the technical and economic ability to impose such
    restrictions. Verizon does not seriously contend otherwise. In
    fact, there appears little dispute that broadband providers have
    the technological ability to distinguish between and
    discriminate against certain types of Internet traffic. See Open
    Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17923 ¶ 31 (broadband
    providers possess “increasingly sophisticated network
    management tools” that enable them to “make fine-grained
    distinction in their handling of network traffic”). The
    Commission also convincingly detailed how broadband
    providers’ position in the market gives them the economic
    power to restrict edge-provider traffic and charge for the
    services they furnish edge providers. Because all end users
    generally access the Internet through a single broadband
    provider, that provider functions as a “‘terminating
    monopolist,’” 
    id. at 17919
    ¶ 24 n.66, with power to act as a
    “gatekeeper” with respect to edge providers that might seek to
    reach its end-user subscribers, 
    id. at 17919
    ¶ 24. As the
    Commission reasonably explained, this ability to act as a
    “gatekeeper” distinguishes broadband providers from other
    39
    participants in the Internet marketplace—including prominent
    and potentially powerful edge providers such as Google and
    Apple—who have no similar “control [over] access to the
    Internet for their subscribers and for anyone wishing to reach
    those subscribers.” 
    Id. at 17935
    ¶ 50.
    To be sure, if end users could immediately respond to any
    given broadband provider’s attempt to impose restrictions on
    edge providers by switching broadband providers, this
    gatekeeper power might well disappear. Cf. Open Internet
    Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17935 ¶ 51 (declining to impose similar
    rules on “dial-up Internet access service because telephone
    service has historically provided the easy ability to switch
    among competing dial-up Internet access services”). For
    example, a broadband provider like Comcast would be unable
    to threaten Netflix that it would slow Netflix traffic if all
    Comcast subscribers would then immediately switch to a
    competing broadband provider. But we see no basis for
    questioning the Commission’s conclusion that end users are
    unlikely to react in this fashion. According to the Commission,
    “end users may not know whether charges or service levels
    their broadband provider is imposing on edge providers vary
    from those of alternative broadband providers, and even if they
    do have this information may find it costly to switch.” 
    Id. at 17921
    ¶ 27. As described by numerous commenters, and
    detailed more thoroughly in a Commission report compiling
    the results of an extensive consumer survey, the costs of
    switching include: “early termination fees; the inconvenience
    of ordering, installation, and set-up, and associated deposits or
    fees; possible difficulty returning the earlier broadband
    provider’s equipment and the cost of replacing incompatible
    customer-owned equipment; the risk of temporarily losing
    service; the risk of problems learning how to use the new
    service; and the possible loss of a provider-specific email
    address or website.” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    40
    17924–25 ¶ 34 (footnotes omitted) (citing, inter alia, Federal
    Communications Commission, Broadband Decisions: What
    Drives Consumers to Switch—Or Stick With—Their
    Broadband Internet Provider (FCC Working Paper, Dec.
    2010),     available    at   hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/
    attachmatch/DOC-303264A1.pdf).            Moreover,        the
    Commission emphasized, many end users may have no option
    to switch, or at least face very limited options: “[a]s of
    December 2009, nearly 70 percent of households lived in
    census tracts where only one or two wireline or fixed wireless
    firms provided” broadband service. 
    Id. at 17923
    ¶ 32. As the
    Commission concluded, any market power that such
    broadband providers might have with respect to end users
    would only increase their power with respect to edge providers.
    
    Id. The dissent
    focuses on this latter aspect of the
    Commission’s reasoning, arguing at some length that the
    Commission’s failure to expressly find that broadband
    providers have market power with respect to end users is “fatal
    to its attempt to regulate.” Dissenting Op. at 12. But Verizon
    has never argued that the Commission’s failure to make a
    market power finding somehow rendered its understanding of
    its statutory authority unreasonable or its decision arbitrary and
    capricious. Verizon does fleetingly mention the market power
    issue once in its opening brief, asserting as part of its First
    Amendment claim that Turner Broadcasting System, Inc. v.
    FCC, 
    520 U.S. 180
    (1997)—in which the Supreme Court,
    applying intermediate scrutiny, upheld a congressional statute
    compelling cable companies to carry local broadcast television
    stations, 
    id. at 185—is
    distinguishable in part because, unlike
    the Commission here, Congress had found “evidence of
    ‘considerable and growing market power.’” Verizon Br. 46
    (quoting 
    Turner, 520 U.S. at 197
    ). But to say, as Verizon does,
    that an allegedly speech-infringing regulation violates the First
    41
    Amendment because of the absence of a market condition that
    would increase the need for that regulation is hardly to say that
    the absence of this market condition renders the regulation
    wholly irrational. Verizon’s bare citation to a Justice
    Department submission—relied upon by the dissent, see
    Dissenting Op. at 11, 14–15—is even less on point, as that
    submission simply advised the Commission to take care to
    avoid stifling incentives for broadband investment; it never
    asserted, as the dissent does, that such market power is required
    for broadband providers to have the economic clout to restrict
    edge-provider traffic in the first place. See Department of
    Justice Comments at 28, Docket No. 09-51 (Jan. 14, 2010).
    Indeed, when pressed at oral argument to embrace our
    dissenting colleague’s position, Verizon’s counsel failed to do
    so, stating only that it was “possible” that if the Commission
    had made a market power finding, the Order could be justified.
    Oral Arg. Tr. 10. As we “do not sit as [a] self-directed board[]
    of legal inquiry and research,” and Verizon “has made no
    attempt to address the issue,” the argument is clearly forfeited.
    Carducci v. Regan, 
    714 F.2d 171
    , 177 (D.C. Cir. 1983).
    In any event, it seems likely that the reason Verizon never
    advanced this argument is that the Commission’s failure to find
    market power is not “fatal” to its theory. Broadband providers’
    ability to impose restrictions on edge providers does not
    depend on their benefiting from the sort of market
    concentration that would enable them to impose substantial
    price increases on end users—which is all the Commission said
    in declining to make a market power finding. See Open
    Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17923 ¶ 32 & n.87; see also
    Department of Justice & Federal Trade Commission,
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 4.1 (2010) (defining product
    markets and market power in terms of a firm’s ability to raise
    prices for consumers). Rather, broadband providers’ ability to
    impose restrictions on edge providers simply depends on end
    42
    users not being fully responsive to the imposition of such
    restrictions. See supra at 39. If the dissent believes that
    broadband providers’ ability to restrict edge-provider traffic
    without having their end users react would itself represent an
    exercise of market power, then the dissent’s dispute with the
    Commission’s reasoning appears to be largely semantic: the
    Commission expressly found that end users are not responsive
    in this fashion even if it never used the term “market power” in
    doing so. See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17924–25
    ¶ 34.
    Furthermore, the Commission established that the threat
    that broadband providers would utilize their gatekeeper ability
    to restrict edge-provider traffic is not, as the Commission put it,
    “merely theoretical.” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    17925 ¶ 35. In support of its conclusion that broadband
    providers could and would act to limit Internet openness, the
    Commission pointed to four prior instances in which they had
    done just that. These involved a mobile broadband provider
    blocking online payment services after entering into a contract
    with a competing service; a mobile broadband provider
    restricting the availability of competing VoIP and streaming
    video services; a fixed broadband provider blocking VoIP
    applications; and, of course, Comcast’s impairment of
    peer-to-peer file sharing that was the subject of the Comcast
    Order. See 
    id. Although some
    of these incidents may not have
    involved “adjudicated findings of misconduct,” as Verizon
    asserts, Verizon’s Br. 50, that hardly means that no record
    evidence supports the Commission’s conclusion that the
    incidents had in fact occurred. Likewise, the fact that we
    vacated the Comcast Order—rendering it, according to
    Verizon, a “legal nullity,” Verizon’s Br. 51—did not require
    the Commission to entirely disregard the underlying conduct
    that produced that order. In Comcast, we held that the
    Commission had failed to cite any statutory authority that
    43
    justified its order, not that Comcast had never impaired Internet
    traffic. See 
    Comcast, 600 F.3d at 644
    . Nor, finally, did the
    Commission’s invocation of these examples demonstrate that
    it was attempting to “impose an ‘industry-wide solution for a
    problem that exists only in isolated pockets.’” Verizon’s Br. 51
    (quoting Associated Gas Distributors v. FERC, 
    824 F.2d 981
    ,
    1019 (D.C. Cir. 1987)). Rather, as the Commission explained,
    these incidents—which occurred “notwithstanding the
    Commission’s adoption of open Internet principles,”
    Commission enforcement proceedings against those who
    violated those principles, and specific Commission orders
    “requir[ing] certain broadband providers to adhere to open
    Internet obligations,” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    17926–27 ¶ 37—buttressed the agency’s conclusion that
    broadband providers’ incentives and ability to restrict Internet
    traffic could produce “[w]idespread interference with the
    Internet’s openness” in the absence of Commission action, 
    id. at 17927
    ¶ 38. Such a “problem” is doubtless “industry-wide.”
    Associated Gas 
    Distributors, 824 F.2d at 1019
    .
    Finally, Verizon argues that the Open Internet Order rules
    will necessarily have the opposite of their intended effect
    because they will “harm innovation and deter investment by
    increasing costs, foreclosing potential revenue streams, and
    restricting providers’ ability to meet consumers’ evolving
    needs.” Verizon’s Br. 52; see also Dissenting Op. at 14–16. In
    essence, Verizon believes that any stimulus to edge-provider
    innovation, as well as any consequent demand for broadband
    infrastructure, produced by the Open Internet Order will be
    outweighed by the diminished incentives for broadband
    infrastructure investment caused by the new limitations on
    business models broadband providers may employ to reap a
    return on their investment. As Verizon points out, two
    members of the Commission agreed that the rules would be
    counterproductive, and several commenters contended that
    44
    certain regulations of broadband providers would run the risk
    of stifling infrastructure investment. See Open Internet Order,
    25 F.C.C.R. at 18054–56 (Dissenting Statement of
    Commissioner McDowell); 
    id. at 18088–91
    (Dissenting
    Statement of Commissioner Baker); Verizon Comments at 40–
    86, Docket No. 09-191 (Jan. 14, 2010); MetroPCS Comments
    at 24–35, Docket No. 09-191 (Jan 14, 2010); see also Open
    Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17931 ¶ 42 n.143 (discussing
    the comments of the Department of Justice and Federal Trade
    Commission).
    The record, however, also contains much evidence
    supporting the Commission’s conclusion that, “[b]y
    comparison to the benefits of [its] prophylactic measures, the
    costs associated with the open Internet rules . . . are likely
    small.” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17928 ¶ 39. This
    is, in other words, one of those cases—quite frequent in this
    circuit—where “the available data do[] not settle a regulatory
    issue and the agency must then exercise its judgment in moving
    from the facts and probabilities on the record to a policy
    conclusion.” State 
    Farm, 463 U.S. at 52
    . Here the Commission
    reached its “policy conclusion” by emphasizing, among other
    things, (1) the absence of evidence that similar restrictions of
    broadband providers had discouraged infrastructure
    investment, and (2) the strength of the effect on broadband
    investment that it anticipated from edge-provider innovation,
    which would benefit both from the preservation of the
    “virtuous circle of innovation” created by the Internet’s
    openness and the increased certainty in that openness
    engendered by the Commission’s rules. Open Internet Order,
    at 17928–31 ¶¶ 40–42. In so doing, the Commission has
    offered “a rational connection between the facts found and the
    choice made,” State 
    Farm, 463 U.S. at 52
    (internal quotation
    marks omitted), and Verizon has given us no persuasive reason
    to question that judgment.
    45
    III.
    Even though section 706 grants the Commission authority
    to promote broadband deployment by regulating how
    broadband providers treat edge providers, the Commission
    may not, as it recognizes, utilize that power in a manner that
    contravenes any specific prohibition contained in the
    Communications Act. See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    17969 ¶ 119 (reiterating the Commission’s disavowal of “a
    reading of Section 706(a) that would allow the agency to trump
    specific mandates of the Communications Act”); see also D.
    Ginsberg & Sons, Inc. v. Popkin, 
    285 U.S. 204
    , 208 (1932)
    (“General language of a statutory provision, although broad
    enough to include it, will not be held to apply to a matter
    specifically dealt with in another part of the same enactment.”).
    According to Verizon, the Commission has done just that
    because the anti-discrimination and anti-blocking rules
    “subject[] broadband Internet access service . . . to common
    carriage regulation, a result expressly prohibited by the Act.”
    Verizon’s Br. 14.
    We think it obvious that the Commission would violate
    the Communications Act were it to regulate broadband
    providers as common carriers. Given the Commission’s
    still-binding decision to classify broadband providers not as
    providers of “telecommunications services” but instead as
    providers of “information services,” see supra at 9–10, such
    treatment would run afoul of section 153(51): “A
    telecommunications carrier shall be treated as a common
    carrier under this [Act] only to the extent that it is engaged in
    providing telecommunications services.” 47 U.S.C. § 153(51);
    see also Wireless Broadband Order, 22 F.C.C.R. at 5919 ¶ 50
    (concluding that a “service provider is to be treated as a
    common carrier for the telecommunications services it
    provides, but it cannot be treated as a common carrier with
    46
    respect to other, non-telecommunications services it may offer,
    including information services”). Likewise, because the
    Commission has classified mobile broadband service as a
    “private” mobile service, and not a “commercial” mobile
    service, see Wireless Broadband Order, 22 F.C.C.R. at 5921
    ¶ 56, treatment of mobile broadband providers as common
    carriers would violate section 332: “A person engaged in the
    provision of a service that is a private mobile service shall not,
    insofar as such person is so engaged, be treated as a common
    carrier for any purpose under this [Act].” 47 U.S.C.
    § 332(c)(2); see 
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 538
    (“[M]obile-data
    providers are statutorily immune, perhaps twice over, from
    treatment as common carriers.”).
    Insisting it has transgressed neither of these prohibitions,
    the Commission begins with the rather half-hearted argument
    that the Act referred to in sections 153(51) and 332 is the
    Communications Act of 1934, and that when the Commission
    utilizes the authority granted to it in section 706—enacted as
    part of the 1996 Telecommunications Act—it is not acting
    “under” the 1934 Act, and thus is “not subject to the statutory
    limitations on common-carrier treatment.” Commission’s Br.
    68. But section 153(51) was also part of the 1996
    Telecommunications Act. And regardless, “Congress
    expressly directed that the 1996 Act . . . be inserted into the
    Communications Act of 1934.” AT & T 
    Corp., 525 U.S. at 377
    (citing Telecommunications Act of 1996 § 1(b)). The
    Commission cannot now so easily escape the statutory
    prohibitions on common carrier treatment.
    Thus, we must determine whether the requirements
    imposed by the Open Internet Order subject broadband
    providers to common carrier treatment. If they do, then given
    the manner in which the Commission has chosen to classify
    broadband providers, the regulations cannot stand. We apply
    47
    Chevron’s deferential standard of review to the interpretation
    and application of the statutory term “common carrier.” See
    
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 544
    . After first discussing the history and
    use of that term, we turn to the issue of whether the
    Commission’s interpretation of “common carrier”—and its
    conclusion that the Open Internet Order’s rules do not
    constitute common carrier obligations—was reasonable.
    A.
    Offering little guidance as to the meaning of the term
    “common carrier,” the Communications Act defines that
    phrase, somewhat circularly, as “any person engaged as a
    common carrier for hire.” 47 U.S.C. § 153(11). Courts and the
    Commission have therefore resorted to the common law to
    come up with a satisfactory definition. See FCC v. Midwest
    Video Corp., 
    440 U.S. 689
    , 701 n.10 (1979) (“Midwest Video
    II”).
    In the Nineteenth Century, American courts began
    imposing certain obligations—conceptually derived from the
    traditional legal duties of innkeepers, ferrymen, and others who
    served the public—on companies in the transportation and
    communications industries. See 
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 545
    . As the
    Supreme Court explained in Interstate Commerce Commission
    v. Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Co., 
    145 U.S. 263
    , 275 (1892),
    “the principles of the common law applicable to common
    carriers . . . demanded little more than that they should carry for
    all persons who applied, in the order in which the goods were
    delivered at the particular station, and that their charges for
    transportation should be reasonable.” Congress subsequently
    codified these duties, first in the 1887 Interstate Commerce
    Act, ch. 104, 24 Stat. 379, then the Manns-Elkins Act of 1910,
    ch. 309, 36 Stat. 539, and, most relevant here, the
    Communications Act of 1934, ch. 652, 48 Stat. 1064. See
    
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 545
    –46.
    48
    Although the nature and scope of the duties imposed on
    common carriers have evolved over the last century, see, e.g.,
    Orloff v. FCC, 
    352 F.3d 415
    , 418–21 (D.C. Cir. 2003)
    (discussing the implications of the relaxation of the tariff-filing
    requirement), the core of the common law concept of common
    carriage has remained intact. In National Association of
    Regulatory Utility Commissioners v. FCC, 
    525 F.2d 630
    , 642
    (D.C. Cir. 1976) (“NARUC I”), we identified the basic
    characteristic that distinguishes common carriers from
    “private” carriers—i.e., entities that are not common
    carriers—as “[t]he common law requirement of holding
    oneself out to serve the public indiscriminately.” “[A] carrier
    will not be a common carrier,” we further explained, “where its
    practice is to make individualized decisions, in particular
    cases, whether and on what terms to deal.” 
    Id. at 641.
    Similarly, in National Association of Regulatory Utility
    Commissioners v. FCC, 
    533 F.2d 601
    , 608 (1976) (“NARUC
    II”), we concluded that “the primary sine qua non of common
    carrier status is a quasi-public character, which arises out of the
    undertaking to carry for all people indifferently.” (Internal
    quotation marks omitted).
    For our purposes, perhaps the seminal case applying this
    notion of common carriage is Midwest Video II. At issue in
    Midwest Video II was a set of regulations compelling cable
    television systems to operate a minimum number of channels
    and to hold certain channels open for specific 
    users. 440 U.S. at 692
    –93. Cable operators were barred from exercising any
    discretion over who could use those latter channels and what
    those users could transmit. They were also forbidden from
    charging users any fee for some of the channels and limited to
    charging an “appropriate” fee for the remaining channels. 
    Id. at 693–94.
    Because at that time the Commission had no express
    statutory authority over cable systems, it sought to justify these
    49
    rules as ancillary to its authority to regulate broadcasting. 
    Id. at 696–99.
    Rejecting this argument, the Supreme Court held that the
    Commission had no power to regulate cable operators in this
    fashion. The Court reasoned that if the Commission sought to
    exercise such ancillary jurisdiction over cable operators on the
    basis of its authority over broadcasters, it must also respect the
    specific statutory limits of that authority, as “without reference
    to the provisions of the Act directly governing broadcasting,
    the Commission’s jurisdiction . . . would be unbounded.”
    Midwest Video 
    II, 440 U.S. at 706
    . Congress had expressly
    prohibited the Commission from regulating broadcasters as
    common carriers, a limitation that must then, according to the
    Court, also extend to cable operators. 
    Id. at 707.
    And the
    challenged regulations, the Court held, “plainly impose
    common-carrier obligations on cable operators.” 
    Id. at 701.
    In
    explaining this conclusion, the Court largely reiterated the
    nature of the obligations themselves: “Under the rules, cable
    systems are required to hold out dedicated channels on a
    first-come, nondiscriminatory basis. Operators are prohibited
    from determining or influencing the content of access
    programming. And the rules delimit what operators may
    charge for access and use of equipment.” 
    Id. at 701–02
    (internal citations omitted).
    In Cellco, we recently confronted the similar question of
    whether a Commission regulation compelling mobile
    telephone companies to offer data roaming agreements to one
    another on “commercially reasonable” terms impermissibly
    regulated these providers as common 
    carriers. 700 F.3d at 537
    .
    From the history and decisions surveyed above, we distilled
    “several basic principles” that guide our analysis here. 
    Id. at 547.
    First, “[i]f a carrier is forced to offer service
    indiscriminately and on general terms, then that carrier is being
    50
    relegated to common carrier status.” 
    Id. We also
    clarified,
    however, that “there is an important distinction between the
    question whether a given regulatory regime is consistent with
    common carrier or private carrier status, and the Midwest
    Video II question whether that regime necessarily confers
    common carrier status.” 
    Id. (internal citations
    omitted). Thus,
    “common carriage is not all or nothing—there is a gray area in
    which although a given regulation might be applied to common
    carriers, the obligations imposed are not common carriage per
    se.” 
    Id. In this
    “space between per se common carriage and per
    se private carriage,” we continued, “the Commission’s
    determination that a regulation does or does not confer
    common carrier status warrants deference.” 
    Id. Given these
    principles, we concluded that the data
    roaming rule imposed no per se common carriage requirements
    because it left “substantial room for individualized bargaining
    and discrimination in terms.” 
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 548
    . The rule
    “expressly permit[ted] providers to adapt roaming agreements
    to ‘individualized circumstances without having to hold
    themselves out to serve all comers indiscriminately on the
    same or standardized terms.’” 
    Id. That said,
    we cautioned that
    were the Commission to apply the “commercially reasonable”
    standard in a restrictive manner, essentially elevating it to the
    traditional common carrier “just and reasonable” standard, see
    47 U.S.C. § 201(b), the rule might impose obligations that
    amounted to common carriage per se, a claim that could be
    brought in an “as applied” challenge. 
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 548
    –
    49.
    B.
    The Commission’s explanation in the Open Internet
    Order for why the regulations do not constitute common
    carrier obligations and its defense of those regulations here
    largely rest on its belief that, with respect to edge providers,
    51
    broadband providers are not “carriers” at all. Stating that an
    entity is not a common carrier if it may decide on an
    individualized basis “‘whether and on what terms to deal’ with
    potential customers,” the Commission asserted in the Order
    that “[t]he customers at issue here are the end users who
    subscribe to broadband Internet access services.” Open
    Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17950–51 ¶ 79 (quoting
    NARUC 
    I, 525 F.2d at 641
    ) (emphasis added). It explained that
    because broadband providers would remain able to make
    “individualized decisions” in determining on what terms to
    deal with end users, the Order permitted the providers the
    “flexibility to customize service arrangements for a particular
    customer [that] is the hallmark of private carriage.” 
    Id. at 17951
    ¶ 79. Here, the Commission reiterates that “as long as [a
    broadband provider] is not required to serve end users
    indiscriminately, rules regarding blocking or charging edge
    providers do not create common carriage.” Commission’s
    Br. 61. We disagree.
    It is true, generally speaking, that the “customers” of
    broadband providers are end users. But that hardly means that
    broadband providers could not also be carriers with respect to
    edge providers. “Since it is clearly possible for a given entity to
    carry on many types of activities, it is at least logical to
    conclude that one may be a common carrier with regard to
    some activities but not others.” NARUC 
    II, 533 F.2d at 608
    .
    Because broadband providers furnish a service to edge
    providers, thus undoubtedly functioning as edge providers’
    “carriers,” the obligations that the Commission imposes on
    broadband providers may well constitute common carriage per
    se regardless of whether edge providers are broadband
    providers’ principal customers. This is true whatever the nature
    of the preexisting commercial relationship between broadband
    providers and edge providers. In contending otherwise, the
    Commission appears to misunderstand the nature of the inquiry
    52
    in which we must engage. The question is not whether, absent
    the Open Internet Order, broadband providers would or did act
    as common carriers with respect to edge providers; rather, the
    question is whether, given the rules imposed by the Open
    Internet Order, broadband providers are now obligated to act
    as common carriers. See Midwest Video 
    II, 440 U.S. at 701
    –02.
    In support of its understanding of common carriage, the
    Commission first invokes section 201(a), which provides that
    it is the “duty of every common carrier . . . to furnish . . .
    communication service upon reasonable request therefor.” 47
    U.S.C. § 201(a). No one disputes that a broadband provider’s
    transmission of edge-provider traffic to its end-user
    subscribers represents a valuable service: an edge provider like
    Amazon wants and needs a broadband provider like Comcast
    to permit its subscribers to use Amazon.com. According to the
    Commission, however, because edge providers generally do
    not “request” service from broadband providers, and may have
    no direct relationship with end users’ local access providers,
    broadband providers cannot be common carriers with respect
    to such edge providers. But section 201(a) describes a “duty”
    of a common carrier, not a prerequisite for qualifying as a
    common carrier in the first place. More important, the Open
    Internet Order imposes this very duty on broadband providers:
    given the Open Internet Order’s anti-blocking and
    anti-discrimination requirements, if Amazon were now to
    make a request for service, Comcast must comply. That is,
    Comcast must now “furnish . . . communication service upon
    reasonable request therefor.” 47 U.S.C. § 201(a).
    Similarly flawed is the Commission’s argument that
    because the Communications Act defines a “common carrier”
    as a “common carrier for hire,” 47 U.S.C. § 153(11) (emphasis
    added), a common carrier relationship may exist only with
    respect to those customers who purchase service from the
    53
    carrier. As Verizon aptly puts it in response, the fact that
    “broadband providers . . . generally have not charged edge
    providers for access or offered them differentiated services . . .
    has no legal significance because the avowed purpose of the
    rules is to deny providers the discretion to do so now and in the
    future.” Verizon’s Reply Br. 5 n.3. In other words, but for the
    Open Internet Order, broadband providers could freely impose
    conditions on the nature and quality of the service they furnish
    edge providers, potentially turning certain edge
    providers—currently able to “hire” their service for free—into
    paying customers. The Commission may not claim that the
    Open Internet Order imposes no common carrier obligations
    simply because it compels an entity to continue furnishing
    service at no cost.
    Likewise, the Commission misses the point when it
    contends that because the Communications Act “imposes
    non-discrimination requirements on many entities that are not
    common carriers,” the Order’s requirements cannot
    “transform[] providers into common carriers.” Commission’s
    Br. 66–67. In support, the Commission cites 47 U.S.C.
    § 315(b), which requires that broadcasters charge political
    candidates nondiscriminatory rates if broadcasters permit them
    to use their stations, as well as 47 U.S.C. § 548(c)(2)(B), which
    prohibits satellite programming vendors owned in part or in
    whole by a cable operator from discriminating against other
    cable operators in the delivery of programming. Commission’s
    Br. 66–67. But Congress has no statutory obligation to avoid
    imposing common carrier obligations on those who might not
    otherwise operate as common carriers, and thus the extent to
    which the cited provisions might regulate those entities as such
    is irrelevant. The Commission, on the other hand, has such an
    obligation with respect to entities it has classified as statutorily
    exempt from common carrier treatment, and the issue here is
    whether it has nonetheless “relegated [those entities], pro
    54
    tanto, to common-carrier status.” Midwest Video 
    II, 440 U.S. at 700
    –01.
    In these respects, Midwest Video II is indistinguishable.
    The Midwest Video II cable operators’ primary “customers”
    were their subscribers, who paid to have programming
    delivered to them in their homes. There, as here, the
    Commission’s regulations required the regulated entities to
    carry the content of third parties to these customers—content
    the entities otherwise could have blocked at their discretion.
    Moreover, much like the rules at issue here, the Midwest Video
    II regulations compelled the operators to hold open certain
    channels for use at no cost—thus permitting specified
    programmers to “hire” the cable operators’ services for free.
    Given that the cable operators in Midwest Video II were
    carriers with respect to these third-party programmers, we see
    no basis for concluding that broadband providers are not
    similarly carriers with respect to third-party edge providers.
    The Commission advances several grounds                 for
    distinguishing Midwest Video II. None is convincing.
    The Commission asserts that, unlike in Midwest Video II,
    here the content is delivered to end users only when an end user
    requests it—i.e., by clicking on a link to an edge provider’s
    website. But the same was essentially true in Midwest Video II:
    cable companies’ customers would not actually receive the
    content on the dedicated public access channels unless they
    chose to watch those channels. The access requested by the
    programmers in Midwest Video II, like the access requested by
    edge providers here, is the ability to have their communications
    transmitted to end-user subscribers if those subscribers so
    desire.
    55
    Nor, contrary to the Commission’s contention, is it at all
    relevant that in Midwest Video II only a limited number of
    cable channels were available, while in this case the number of
    edge providers a broadband provider could serve is unlimited.
    Whether an entity qualifies as a carrier does not turn on how
    much content it is able to carry or the extent to which other
    content might be crowded out. A short train is no more a carrier
    than a long train, or even a train long enough to serve every
    possible customer.
    Finally, Midwest Video II cannot be distinguished on the
    basis that the Court there emphasized the degree to which the
    Commission’s rules impinged on cable operators’ “editorial
    discretion,” and “transferred control” over the content
    transmitted. Commission’s Br. 65. The Court made two related
    points regarding editorial discretion, neither of which helps the
    Commission. First, it observed that the need to protect editorial
    discretion was one reason Congress forbade common carrier
    treatment of broadcasters in the first place, a rationale that also
    applied to cable operators, thus confirming the Court’s
    decision to extend that statutory prohibition to the
    Commission’s attempt to exercise its ancillary jurisdiction
    over such entities. Midwest Video 
    II, 440 U.S. at 700
    , 706–08.
    Here, whatever might be the justifications for prohibiting
    common carrier treatment of “information service” providers
    and “commercial” mobile service providers, such treatment is
    undoubtedly prohibited. See 47 U.S.C. §§ 153(51), 332(c)(2).
    Second, the Court emphasized that, unlike the regulations
    approved in United States v. Midwest Video Corp., 
    406 U.S. 649
    (1972) (“Midwest Video I”)—which required certain cable
    companies to create their own programming and maintain
    facilities for local production, 
    id. at 653–55—the
    regulations in
    Midwest Video II “transferred control of the content of access
    cable channels from cable operators to members of the public.”
    Midwest Video 
    II, 440 U.S. at 700
    . The Court’s point was
    56
    simply that the Midwest Video I regulations had created no
    common carrier obligations because they had imposed no
    obligation on cable operators to provide carriage to any third
    party. By giving third parties “control” over the transmissions
    that cable operators carried, however, the Midwest Video II
    regulations did. The regulations here accomplish the very same
    sort of transfer of control: whereas previously broadband
    providers could have blocked or discriminated against the
    content of certain edge providers, they must now carry the
    content those edge providers desire to transmit. The only
    remaining question, then, is whether the Open Internet Order’s
    rules have so limited broadband providers’ control over edge
    providers’ transmissions that the regulations constitute
    common carriage per se. It is to that question that we now turn.
    C.
    We have little hesitation in concluding that the
    anti-discrimination obligation imposed on fixed broadband
    providers has “relegated [those providers], pro tanto, to
    common carrier status.” Midwest Video 
    II, 440 U.S. at 700
    –01.
    In requiring broadband providers to serve all edge providers
    without “unreasonable discrimination,” this rule by its very
    terms compels those providers to hold themselves out “to serve
    the public indiscriminately.” NARUC 
    I, 525 F.2d at 642
    .
    Having relied almost entirely on the flawed argument that
    broadband providers are not carriers with respect to edge
    providers, the Commission offers little response on this point.
    In its briefs, the Commission contends only that if the Open
    Internet Order imposes common carriage requirements, so too
    would the regulations at issue in United States v. Southwestern
    Cable Co., 
    392 U.S. 157
    (1968), which the Supreme Court
    declined to strike down. Southwestern Cable involved a
    Commission rule that, among other things, compelled cable
    operators to transmit the signals of local broadcasters when
    57
    cable operators imported the competing signals of other
    broadcasters into the local service area. 
    Id. at 161.
    Such a rule
    is plainly distinguishable from the Open Internet Order’s
    anti-discrimination rule because the Southwestern Cable
    regulation imposed no obligation on cable operators to hold
    their facilities open to the public generally, but only to certain
    specific broadcasters if and when the cable operators acted in
    ways that might harm those broadcasters. As the Court later
    explained in Midwest Video II, the Southwestern Cable rule
    “was limited to remedying a specific perceived evil,” and “did
    not amount to a duty to hold out facilities indifferently for
    public 
    use.” 440 U.S. at 706
    n.16. The Open Internet Order’s
    anti-discrimination provision is not so limited, as the
    compelled carriage obligation applies in all circumstances and
    with respect to all edge providers.
    Significantly for our purposes, the Commission never
    argues that the Open Internet Order’s “no unreasonable
    discrimination” standard somehow differs from the
    nondiscrimination standard applied to common carriers
    generally—the argument that salvaged the data roaming
    requirements in Cellco. In a footnote in the Order itself, the
    Commission suggested that it viewed the rule’s allowance for
    “reasonable network management” as establishing treatment
    that was somehow inconsistent with per se common carriage.
    See Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17951 ¶ 79 n.251. But
    the Commission has forfeited this argument by failing to raise
    it in its briefs here. See 
    Comcast, 600 F.3d at 660
    ; Roth v. U.S.
    DOJ, 
    642 F.3d 1161
    , 1181 (D.C. Cir. 2011).
    In any event, the argument is without merit. The Order
    defines the “reasonable network management” concept as
    follows: “A network management practice is reasonable if it is
    appropriate and tailored to achieving a legitimate network
    management purpose, taking into account the particular
    58
    network architecture and technology of the broadband Internet
    access service.” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17952
    ¶ 82. This provision, the Commission explained, would permit
    broadband providers to do two things, neither of which conflict
    with per se common carriage. First, “the reasonable network
    management” exception would permit broadband providers to
    “address[] traffic that is unwanted by end users . . . such as by
    providing services or capabilities consistent with an end user’s
    choices regarding parental controls or security capabilities.”
    
    Id. Because the
    relevant service broadband providers furnish to
    edge providers is the ability to access end users if those end
    users so desire, a limited exception permitting end users to
    direct broadband providers to block certain traffic by no means
    detracts from the common carrier nature of the obligations
    imposed on broadband providers. Second, the Order defines
    “reasonable network management” to include practices
    designed to protect the network itself by “addressing traffic
    that is harmful to the network” and “reducing or mitigating the
    effects of congestion.” 
    Id. at 17952
    ¶ 82. As Verizon correctly
    points out, however, this allowance “merely preserves a
    common carrier’s traditional right to ‘turn[] away [business]
    either because it is not of the type normally accepted or
    because the carrier’s capacity has been exhausted.’” Verizon’s
    Br. 20 (quoting NARUC 
    I, 525 F.2d at 641
    ). Railroads have no
    obligation to allow passengers to carry bombs on board, nor
    need they permit passengers to stand in the aisles if all seats are
    taken. It is for this reason that the Communications Act bars
    common carriers from engaging in “unjust or unreasonable
    discrimination,” not all discrimination. 47 U.S.C. § 202
    (emphasis added).
    The Commission has provided no basis for concluding
    that in permitting “reasonable” network management, and in
    prohibiting merely “unreasonable” discrimination, the Order’s
    standard of “reasonableness” might be more permissive than
    59
    the quintessential common carrier standard. See 
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 548
    (characterizing the “just and reasonable” standard
    as being that “applicable to common carriers”). To the extent
    any ambiguity exists regarding how the Commission will apply
    these rules in practice, we think it is best characterized as
    ambiguity as to how the common carrier reasonableness
    standard applies in this context, not whether the standard
    applied is actually the same as the common carrier standard.
    Unlike the data roaming requirement at issue in Cellco, which
    set forth a “commercially reasonable” standard, see 
    id. at 537,
    the language of the Open Internet Order’s anti-discrimination
    rule mirrors, almost precisely, section 202’s language
    establishing the basic common carrier obligation not to “make
    any unjust or unreasonable discrimination.” 47 U.S.C. § 202.
    Indeed, confirming that the two standards are equivalent, the
    Commission responded to commenters who argued that the
    “no unreasonable discrimination” requirement was too vague
    by quoting another commenter who observed that
    “[s]eventy-five years of experience have shown [the
    ‘unreasonable’ qualifier in Section 202] to be both
    administrable and indispensable to the sound administration of
    the nation’s telecommunications laws.” Open Internet Order,
    25 F.C.C.R. at 17949 ¶ 77 n.240. Moreover, unlike the data
    roaming rule in Cellco—which spelled out “sixteen different
    factors plus a catchall . . . that the Commission must take into
    account in evaluating whether a proffered roaming agreement
    is commercially reasonable,” thus building into the standard
    “considerable flexibility,” 
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 548
    —the Open
    Internet Order makes no attempt to ensure that its
    reasonableness standard remains flexible. Instead, with respect
    to broadband providers’ potential negotiations with edge
    providers, the Order ominously declares: “it is unlikely that
    pay for priority would satisfy the ‘no unreasonable
    discrimination’ standard.” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    17947 ¶ 76. If the Commission will likely bar broadband
    60
    providers from charging edge providers for using their service,
    thus forcing them to sell this service to all who ask at a price of
    $0, we see no room at all for “individualized bargaining.”
    
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 548
    .
    Whether the Open Internet Order’s anti-blocking rules,
    applicable to both fixed and mobile broadband providers,
    likewise establish per se common carrier obligations is
    somewhat less clear. According to Verizon, they do because
    they deny “broadband providers discretion in deciding which
    traffic from . . . edge providers to carry,” and deny them
    “discretion over carriage terms by setting a uniform price of
    zero.” Verizon’s Br. 16–17. This argument has some appeal.
    The anti-blocking rules establish a minimum level of service
    that broadband providers must furnish to all edge providers:
    edge providers’ “content, applications [and] services” must be
    “effectively []usable.” Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. at
    17943 ¶ 66. The Order also expressly prohibits broadband
    providers from charging edge providers any fees for this
    minimum level of service. 
    Id. at 17943
    –44 ¶ 67. In requiring
    that all edge providers receive this minimum level of access for
    free, these rules would appear on their face to impose per se
    common carrier obligations with respect to that minimum level
    of service. See Midwest Video 
    II, 440 U.S. at 701
    n.9 (a carrier
    may “operate as a common carrier with respect to a portion of
    its service only”).
    At oral argument, however, Commission counsel asserted
    that “[i]t’s not common carriage to simply have a basic level of
    required service if you can negotiate different levels with
    different people.” Oral Arg. Tr. 86. This contention rests on the
    fact that under the anti-blocking rules broadband providers
    have no obligation to actually provide any edge provider with
    the minimum service necessary to satisfy the rules. If, for
    example, all edge providers’ “content, applications [and]
    61
    services” are “effectively usable,” Open Internet Order, 25
    F.C.C.R. at 17943 ¶ 66, at download speeds of, say, three
    mbps, a broadband provider like Verizon could deliver all edge
    providers’ traffic at speeds of at least four mbps. Viewed this
    way, the relevant “carriage” broadband providers furnish
    might be access to end users more generally, not the minimum
    required service. In delivering this service, so defined, the
    anti-blocking rules would permit broadband providers to
    distinguish somewhat among edge providers, just as
    Commission counsel contended at oral argument. For example,
    Verizon might, consistent with the anti-blocking rule—and
    again, absent the anti-discrimination rule—charge an edge
    provider like Netflix for high-speed, priority access while
    limiting all other edge providers to a more standard service. In
    theory, moreover, not only could Verizon negotiate separate
    agreements with each individual edge provider regarding the
    level of service provided, but it could also charge
    similarly-situated edge providers completely different prices
    for the same service. Thus, if the relevant service that
    broadband providers furnish is access to their subscribers
    generally, as opposed to access to their subscribers at the
    specific minimum speed necessary to satisfy the anti-blocking
    rules, then these rules, while perhaps establishing a lower limit
    on the forms that broadband providers’ arrangements with
    edge providers could take, might nonetheless leave sufficient
    “room for individualized bargaining and discrimination in
    terms” so as not to run afoul of the statutory prohibitions on
    common carrier treatment. 
    Cellco, 700 F.3d at 548
    .
    Whatever the merits of this view, the Commission
    advanced nothing like it either in the underlying Order or in its
    briefs before this court. Instead, it makes no distinction at all
    between the anti-discrimination and anti-blocking rules,
    seeking to justify both types of rules with explanations that, as
    we have explained, are patently insufficient. We are unable to
    62
    sustain the Commission’s action on a ground upon which the
    agency itself never relied. Lacson v. Department of Homeland
    Security, 
    726 F.3d 170
    , 177 (D.C. Cir. 2013); see also United
    States v. Southerland, 
    486 F.3d 1355
    , 1360 (D.C. Cir. 2007)
    (“argument[s] . . . raised for the first time at oral argument [are]
    forfeited”). Nor may we defer to a reading of a statutory term
    that the Commission never offered. Shieldalloy Metallurgical
    Corp. v. Nuclear Regulatory Comm’n, 
    624 F.3d 489
    , 495 (D.C.
    Cir. 2010).
    The disclosure rules are another matter. Verizon does not
    contend that these rules, on their own, constitute per se
    common carrier obligations, nor do we see any way in which
    they would. Also, because Verizon does not direct its First
    Amendment or Takings Clause claims against the disclosure
    obligations, we have no need to address those contentions here.
    Verizon does argue that the disclosure rules are not
    severable, insisting that if the anti-discrimination and
    anti-blocking rules fall so too must the disclosure
    requirements. We disagree. “Whether the offending portion of
    a regulation is severable depends upon the intent of the agency
    and upon whether the remainder of the regulation could
    function sensibly without the stricken provision.” MD/DC/DE
    Broadcasters Ass’n v. FCC, 
    236 F.3d 13
    , 22 (D.C. Cir. 2001)
    (emphasis omitted). At oral argument, Commission counsel
    explained that the rules function separately, Oral Arg. Tr. 81–
    82, and we are satisfied that the Commission would have
    adopted the disclosure rules absent the rules we now vacate,
    which, we agree, operate independently. See Davis County
    Solid Waste Management v. EPA, 
    108 F.3d 1454
    , 1457–59
    (D.C. Cir. 1997) (finding promulgated standard to be severable
    where EPA asserted in rehearing petition that, contrary to its
    position at oral argument, the standards could stand alone).
    63
    IV.
    For the forgoing reasons, although we reject Verizon’s
    challenge to the Open Internet Order’s disclosure rules, we
    vacate both the anti-discrimination and the anti-blocking rules.
    See Northern Air Cargo v. U.S. Postal Service, 
    674 F.3d 852
    ,
    860–61 (D.C. Cir. 2012) (appropriateness of vacatur dependent
    on whether “(1) the agency’s decision is so deficient as to raise
    serious doubts whether the agency can adequately justify its
    decision at all; and (2) vacatur would be seriously disruptive or
    costly”); 
    Comcast, 600 F.3d at 661
    (vacating the Comcast
    Order). We remand the case to the Commission for further
    proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    So ordered.
    SILBERMAN, Senior Circuit Judge, concurring in part and
    dissenting in part: I am in general agreement with the majority’s
    conclusion that the Open Internet Order impermissibly subjects
    broadband providers to treatment as common carriers, but I
    disagree with the majority’s conclusion that § 706 otherwise
    provides the FCC with affirmative statutory authority to
    promulgate these rules. I also think the Commission’s reasoning
    violates the Administrative Procedure Act. These differences are
    important since the majority opinion suggests possible
    regulatory modifications that might circumvent the prohibition
    against common carrier treatment.
    I.
    The Commission’s net neutrality regulation is purportedly
    designed to promote innovation among edge providers who, in
    turn, provide Internet user experience, thereby increasing user
    demand for broadband service and, ultimately, encouraging
    broadband providers to invest in infrastructure development to
    meet that demand. Open Internet Order, 25 F.C.C.R. 17905,
    17907 ¶ 13 (2010). Verizon describes this theory as a “triple
    cushion shot.” As I will show, whatever its logic, it is based on
    a faulty factual premise. But my first disagreement with the
    Commission, and the majority, is to the claimed statutory
    authority.
    I quite agree with the majority that the relevant statutory
    language is § 706 of the Communications Act. 47 U.S.C. §
    1302. Although the FCC purports to rely on a scatter shot of
    other provisions of the statute, as well as § 706, none of those
    other provisions truly bear on the issue. “Emanations from the
    penumbra” may once have served to justify constitutional
    interpretation, but it hasn’t caught on as legitimate statutory
    interpretation. I also agree with the majority – and disagree with
    Verizon – that § 706 is a grant of positive regulatory authority,
    but it doesn’t come close to sanctioning the Commission’s
    regulation.
    2
    The statute directs the Commission to “encourage the
    deployment on a reasonable and timely basis of advanced
    telecommunications capability to all Americans . . . by utilizing
    . . . price cap regulation, regulatory forbearance, measures that
    promote competition in the local telecommunications market, or
    other regulating methods that remove barriers to infrastructure
    investment.” 47 U.S.C. § 1302(a).1
    The FCC contends for, and the majority grants, Chevron
    deference as to the interpretation of this language. I don’t
    disagree that Chevron is called for, but Chevron “is not a wand
    by which courts can turn an unlawful frog into a legitimate
    prince.” Associated Gas Distributors v. F.E.R.C., 
    824 F.2d 981
    ,
    1001 (D.C. Cir. 1987).
    The key words obviously are “measures that promote
    competition in the local telecommunications market or other
    regulating methods that remove barriers to infrastructure
    investment.” Those are the words that grant actual authority. Yet
    the Commission does not ground its regulation on this language.
    Indeed, both the Commission and the majority conflate these
    two clauses, though they have distinct functions. “Promoting
    competition in the telecommunications market” implies a
    regulation that encourages broadband providers to compete with
    each other, head-to-head, on price and quality. Removing
    “barriers to infrastructure investment,” on the other hand, does
    not necessarily require any increased competition in the
    1
    Because § 706(b) contains almost the same language, it is
    unnecessary to discuss these two provisions separately. See 47 U.S.C.
    § 1302(b) (The Commission “shall take immediate action . . . by
    removing barriers to infrastructure investment and by promoting
    competition in the telecommunications market.”).
    3
    telecommunications market.2 For example, if a particular
    broadband provider were a monopolist, then by regulating its
    prices, the Commission might encourage it to expand supply to
    increase profits, rather than artificially restrict supply so as to
    charge supracompetitive rates. Such a regulation would not
    increase competition, but it would at least potentially remove a
    barrier to investment. This is, essentially, the theory that the
    Commission purportedly relies on: If the Commission
    theoretically could spur demand for broadband, the Commission
    would encourage further infrastructure investment regardless of
    head-to-head competition. Thus, it is on the “removing barriers”
    clause, primarily,3 that the Order must stand or fall. Yet, the
    Commission never actually identifies any practices of the
    broadband providers as “barriers to investment” – not once in
    over 100 pages – probably because it would be so far fetched an
    interpretation of those words.
    Nor does the Commission state (or argue in its brief),
    contrary to the majority’s opinion, that the “triple cushion shot”
    – the means by which the Commission hopes to stimulate
    demand for better broadband – is designed to increase
    competition in the broadband market. See Majority Op. at 31-32
    (citing 25 F.C.C.R. at 17910-11, 17970 ¶¶ 14, 120). Paragraph
    2
    An example of a paradigmatic barrier to infrastructure investment
    would be state laws that prohibit municipalities from creating their
    own broadband infrastructure to compete against private companies.
    See Klint Finley, Why Your City Should Compete With Google’s
    Super-Speed Internet, WIRED, May 28, 2013,
    http://www.wired.com/wiredenterprise/2013/05/community-fiber/.
    3
    The transparency rules at least have the added benefit of
    facilitating consumer choice by providing information, which could
    lead to greater competition in the broadband market.
    4
    14 makes no reference to competition,4 and paragraph 120 does
    not refer to competition between broadband providers in the
    local telecommunications market – which is the statutory
    objective. Indeed, paragraph 120 indicates that the
    Commission’s objective is to protect the edge providers (not in
    4
    The Internet’s openness is critical to these outcomes,
    because it enables a virtuous circle of innovation in which
    new uses of the network – including new content,
    applications, services, and devices – lead to increased end-
    user demand for broadband, which drives network
    improvements, which in turn lead to further innovative
    network uses. Novel, improved, or lower-cost offerings
    introduced by content, application, service, and device
    providers spur end-user demand and encourage broadband
    providers to expand their networks and invest in new
    broadband technologies. Streaming video and e-commerce
    applications, for instance, have led to major network
    improvements such as fiber to the premises, VDSL, and
    DOCSIS 3.0. These network improvements generate new
    opportunities for edge providers, spurring them to innovate
    further. Each round of innovation increases the value of the
    Internet for broadband providers, edge providers, online
    businesses, and consumers. Continued operation of this
    virtuous circle, however, depends upon low barriers to
    innovation and entry by edge providers, which drive end-
    user demand. Restricting edge providers’ ability to reach end
    users, and limiting end users’ ability to choose which edge
    providers to patronize, would reduce the rate of innovation
    at the edge and, in turn, the likely rate of improvements to
    network infrastructure. Similarly, restricting the ability of
    broadband providers to put the network to innovative uses
    may reduce the rate of improvements to network
    infrastructure.
    25 F.C.C.R. at 17910-11 ¶ 14.
    5
    the telecommunications market) from content competition with
    the broadband providers.5
    Indeed, the Commission frankly admits its purpose is much
    wider than the statutory objectives. It claims it must regulate
    broadly, so as to “protect[] consumer choice, free expression,
    end-user control, and the ability to innovate without
    permission,” 25 F.C.C.R. at 17949 ¶ 78, which certainly
    5
    In directing the Commission to “encourage the deployment
    on a reasonable and timely basis of advanced
    telecommunications capability to all Americans . . . by
    utilizing . . . price cap regulation, regulatory forbearance,
    measures that promote competition in the local
    telecommunications market, or other regulating methods
    that remove barriers to infrastructure investment,” Congress
    necessarily invested the Commission with the statutory
    authority to carry out those acts. Indeed, the relevant Senate
    Report explained that the provisions of Section 706 are
    “intended to ensure that one of the primary objectives of the
    [1996 Act] – to accelerate deployment of advanced
    telecommunications capability – is achieved,” and stressed
    that these provisions are “a necessary fail-safe” to guarantee
    that Congress’s objective is reached. It would be odd indeed
    to characterize Section 706(a) as a “fail-safe” that “ensures”
    the Commission’s ability to promote advanced services if it
    conferred no actual authority. Here, under our reading,
    Section 706(a) authorizes the Commission to address
    practices, such as blocking VoIP communications,
    degrading or raising the cost of online video, or denying end
    users material information about their broadband service,
    that have the potential to stifle overall investment in Internet
    infrastructure and limit competition in telecommunications
    markets.
    25 F.C.C.R. at 17970 ¶ 120 (emphasis added).
    6
    indicates a Commission objective that exceeds the statutory
    authority granted in § 706.
    The majority takes the statutory language even further; it
    states that the Commission’s
    authority to promulgate regulations that promote
    broadband deployment encompasses the power to
    regulate broadband providers’ economic relationships
    with edge providers if, in fact, the nature of those
    relationships influences the rate and extent to which
    broadband providers develop and expand services for
    end users.
    Majority Op. at 33. So much for the terms “promote competition
    in the local telecommunications market” or “remove barriers to
    infrastructure investment.” Presto, we have a new statute
    granting the FCC virtually unlimited power to regulate the
    Internet. This reading of § 706, as we said in Comcast Corp. v.
    FCC, “would virtually free the Commission from its
    congressional tether.” 
    600 F.3d 642
    , 655 (D.C. Cir. 2010). The
    limiting principles the majority relies on are illusory.
    The majority claims that the Commission cannot exceed its
    subject-matter jurisdiction over “interstate and foreign
    communication by wire and radio.” 25 F.C.C.R. at 17970 ¶ 121
    (citing 47 U.S.C. § 152(a)). This is obviously true, but it is not
    a limitation on the Commission's interpretation of this specific
    statutory provision. The question is not whether the statute
    permits the Commission to do absolutely anything – of course
    it does not – but, rather, whether § 706 contains any intrinsic
    limitations. If the Commission’s subject matter jurisdiction is a
    “limiting principle,” then we might as well call the First
    Amendment a limiting principle, for surely the Commission
    could not censor the Internet, even if doing so did somehow
    increase broadband deployment.
    7
    According to the majority, the Commission is also
    restrained because it may only regulate pursuant to § 706 if it
    does so to achieve a particular purpose: to “encourage the
    deployment on a reasonable and timely basis of advanced
    telecommunications capability to all Americans.” 25 F.C.C.R.
    at 17970 ¶ 121 (citing 47 U.S.C. § 1302(a)). This is an almost
    meaningless limitation, as demonstrated by the Open Internet
    Order itself. The Commission’s theory is that an open Internet
    will spur demand for broadband infrastructure. 
    Id. at 17907
    ¶ 3.
    But any regulation that, in the FCC’s judgment might arguably
    make the Internet “better,” could increase demand. I do not see
    how this “limitation” prevents § 706 from being carte blanche
    to issue any regulation that the Commission might believe to be
    in the public interest.
    To sum up, § 706 requires the Commission to identify a
    “barrier[] to infrastructure investment” or a measure that
    “promote[s] competition” in the broadband market – which it
    has not.
    II.
    Verizon alternatively argues that, even assuming that §
    706 grants the Commission its claimed authority, the regulation
    is arbitrary and capricious because its findings – such as they are
    – lack substantial evidence. I agree. Although we are not faced
    with a formal adjudication which would be judged by substantial
    evidence on a closed record, factual determinations that underly
    regulations must still be premised on demonstrated – and
    reasonable – evidential support. See Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n
    of U.S., Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 43
    (1983).
    The Commission purports to fear that broadband providers
    might discriminate against, or even block, the Internet traffic of
    specific edge providers or classes of edge providers, perhaps
    8
    because broadband providers offer some competing services or
    because they might charge certain edge providers for premium
    services. The majority puts it even more starkly, asserting that
    the Commission found that “broadband providers have the
    technical and economic ability to impose . . . restrictions” on
    edge providers. Majority Op. at 38 (emphasis added). But the
    Commission never actually made such a finding. Its conclusions
    are littered with “may,” “if,” and “might.” For example,
    according to the Commission, a broadband provider:
    •    “may have economic incentives to block or
    otherwise disadvantage specific edge providers”
    •    “might use this power to benefit its own or
    affiliated offerings at the expense of unaffiliated
    offerings”
    •    “may act to benefit edge providers that have paid
    it to exclude rivals”
    •    “may have incentives to increase revenues by
    charging edge providers”6
    •    “might withhold or decline to expand capacity in
    order to ‘squeeze’ non-prioritized traffic”
    25 F.C.C.R. at 17915-22 ¶¶ 21-29. To be sure, the majority
    correctly observes that we should defer to an agency’s
    “predictive judgments as to the economic effect of a rule,”
    National Telephone Cooperative Ass’n v. FCC, 
    563 F.3d 536
    ,
    541 (D.C. Cir. 2009), but deference to such a judgment must be
    based on some logic and evidence, not sheer speculation. That
    6
    In this case, Verizon has indicated it does wish to explore two-
    sided pricing (charging both edge providers and consumers).
    9
    a party “may” do something is hardly a finding – at least in
    American law – that a party has done or will do something.
    Moreover, whether or not the “triple cushion shot” theory is
    rational economics (and I have my doubts), it rests, as I have
    noted, on a false factual premise – that the evidence supports a
    finding that broadband providers across the board, in all
    markets, enjoy sufficient economic clout to take the above
    actions.
    The Commission asserts – and the majority accepts – that
    broadband providers act as “gatekeepers” because each one has
    a so-called “terminating monopoly” over access to particular end
    users. These are terms, largely invented,7 the economic
    significance of which the Commission does not explain. All
    7
    My research has not revealed any use of the phrase “terminating
    monopoly” outside of the context of these proceedings before the
    FCC. It does not appear to be an accepted economic term. A
    “gatekeeper,” on the other hand, is an intermediary between a
    consumer and an upstream seller. And a consumer’s willingness to
    switch to another available supplier depends on the prospective benefit
    measured against the transaction costs (how many blocks am I willing
    to walk, or how many phone calls am I willing to make?).
    Recent literature suggests that gatekeepers may sometimes
    exercise market power against upstream suppliers even when the
    gatekeeper does not have enough market share to exercise downstream
    market power against consumers. See, e.g., Grimes, Warren S., Buyer
    Power and Retail Gatekeeper Power: Protecting Competition and the
    Atomistic Seller, 72 ANTITRUST L. J. 563, 580 (2005). One example
    would be if I purchase my groceries at a particular store, any food
    supplier who wishes to sell to me probably must do so through that
    particular store because I am unlikely to switch grocery stores over a
    single product. Regardless of any contemporary debates over the
    differences between buyer power and seller power, one thing is clear:
    The gatekeeper effect is a tool that facilitates the exercise of market
    power over sellers; it is not market power itself.
    10
    retail stores, for instance, are “gatekeepers.” The term is thus
    meaningful only insofar as the gatekeeper by means of a
    powerful economic position vis-a-vis consumers gains leverage
    over suppliers.8 The Commission made no effort to construct an
    analytic framework to measure this supposed gateway advantage
    – it is a rather slippery concept – nor did it adduce evidence to
    establish the economic power it would supposedly afford all
    broadband providers against all edge providers.
    Without broadband provider market power, consumers, of
    course, have options; they can go to another broadband provider
    if they want to reach particular edge providers or if their
    connections to particular edge providers have been degraded.
    The Commission implicitly recognizes this, because it justifies
    exempting dial-up Internet providers from the Order by noting
    that “telephone service has historically provided the easy ability
    to switch among competing dial-up Internet access services.” 25
    F.C.C.R. at 17935 ¶ 51. The Commission also exempts
    “backbone” Internet providers – which interconnect between
    broadband providers – obviously for the same reason. On the
    other hand, the Commission asserts that broadband customers
    may have few alternatives or they may be locked into long-term
    8
    The Commission treats each individual edge provider as
    analogous to an upstream seller in a retail context. But it seems more
    plausible that consumers consider “Internet access” to be the product
    that they are buying, and that large product creates greater incentives
    to switch to another provider. Although the Commission has argued
    that consumers will perceive a slow connection to a particular edge
    provider as indicative of a problem with that edge provider, rather than
    as a problem with the quality of Internet access provided by the
    broadband provider, 25 F.C.C.R. at 17921 ¶ 27, the Commission
    presents no evidence to support that conclusion. Indeed, edge
    providers have a strong incentive to inform consumers if their
    connections are being degraded. Moreover, the transparency rule,
    which we uphold, makes this outcome almost impossible.
    11
    contracts with early-termination fees. To be sure, some difficulty
    switching broadband providers is certainly a factor that might
    contribute to a firm’s having market power, but that itself is not
    market power. There are many industries in which switching
    between competitors is not instantly achieved, but those
    industries may still be heavily disciplined by competitive forces
    because consumers will switch unless there are real barriers. By
    pointing to potential difficulties consumers may encounter
    switching broadband providers, the Commission is simply
    implying that broadband providers have market power (market
    power lite?), without actually examining if and where they do.
    Although Verizon was reluctant to concede that even if a
    broadband provider had market power that would authorize the
    Commission to take action under § 706 – presumably because
    it challenged any regulatory authority under § 706 – it did bring
    to our attention a Justice Department submission, discussed
    infra, that emphasized the necessity of the Commission limiting
    its regulatory initiatives to the control of broadband market
    power. Ex Parte Submission of the U.S. DOJ at 28, Docket No.
    09-51 (Jan. 4, 2010). My discussion of market power reflects my
    view (and apparently the Justice Department’s) of what evidence
    would be adequate to support the Commission’s rule. In any
    event, Verizon certainly challenged the factual basis of the
    Commission’s “gateway” conclusion, so I don’t think the
    existence vel non of market power is really a different
    consideration. See Majority Op. at 40-41.
    The majority does contend that four possible instances of
    broadband providers restricting users’ access to certain edge
    providers are sufficient evidence of broadband providers’
    “incentives and ability to restrict Internet traffic.” Majority Op.
    at 43. That the Commission was able to locate only four
    potential examples of such conduct is, frankly, astonishing. In
    such a large industry where, as Verizon notes, billions of
    connections are formed between users and edge providers each
    12
    year, one would think there should be ample examples of just
    about any type of conduct. But even if examples of such conduct
    were more numerous, it would still not be evidence that
    broadband providers are economically capable of restricting
    consumer choice. And, as the Commission noted, there are
    potentially efficient, pro-consumer reasons that an individual
    broadband provider might wish to restrict access to some edge
    providers. See 25 F.C.C.R. at 17921 ¶ 28 n.80 (“Economics
    literature recognizes that access charges could be harmful under
    some circumstances and beneficial under others. . . . [T]he
    economic literature on two-sided markets is at an early stage of
    development.”). The Commission’s anecdotes then do not show
    that any broadband providers are capable of actually causing the
    harm about which the Commission is concerned.
    My view, then, is that the Commission’s failure to conduct
    a market power analysis is fatal to its attempt to regulate,
    because it means that there is inadequate evidence to support the
    lynchpin of the Commission’s economic theory. The
    Commission actually recognized that a finding of market power
    would enhance its theory. 25 F.C.C.R. at 17923 ¶ 32. Indeed!
    But such a finding would, of course, have to be made market to
    market (indeed the statute specifically references local
    telecommunications markets), and if so, it would be a finding of
    a barrier to broadband investment without the mental gymnastics
    of the triple cushion shot. If one (or two) broadband providers
    have market power in any particular market and thereby could
    raise prices while restricting supply, the Commission could well
    conclude that was a barrier to broadband investment.
    Of course, before the Commission could determine whether
    a particular broadband provider possesses market power, it
    would have to first define the relevant market. Instead, the
    Commission, in this case, simply cited a 2009 study that found
    that “nearly 70 percent of households lived in census tracts
    where only one or two wireline or fixed wireless firms provided
    13
    advertised download speeds of at least 3 Mbps and upload
    speeds of at least 768 Kbps.” 25 F.C.C.R. at 17923 ¶ 32. Why
    are these speeds relevant? Because the Commission has
    previously, as part of its statutory duty to assess the state of
    broadband deployment, defined “broadband” to mean download
    speeds of at least 4 Mbps and upload speeds of at least 1 Mbps.
    Sixth Broadband Deployment Report, 25 F.C.C.R. 9556, 9559
    ¶ 5 (2010). According to the Commission, it is the minimum
    speed necessary to stream high quality video while
    simultaneously browsing the Internet and using email. 
    Id. I don’t
    dispute the legitimacy of that definition. Yet, while the
    Commission is free to rely on technical considerations in
    defining the statutory term “broadband,” such considerations are
    irrelevant when it comes to defining the market in economic
    terms. A broadband provider offering a 2 Mbps connection is
    not, according to the FCC, really offering broadband. But it is
    quite likely that consumers, in deciding which Internet service
    to purchase, will compare products at varying speeds and price
    points. Slower service providers can still exert competitive
    pressure on faster service providers. So, too, can mobile
    broadband providers. Before the Commission can conclude that
    a market is concentrated, it must first define that market. It has
    made no effort to do so.
    The Commission, moreover, does not address whether the
    trend in the broadband market is towards more or less
    competition. Obviously the deployment of broadband
    infrastructure is a capital-intensive process, and it should not be
    surprising if, during a period of expansion, some areas are
    served by fewer competitors than others. But there is no
    evidence in the record suggesting that broadband providers are
    carving up territory or avoiding head-to-head competition. At
    least anecdotally, the opposite seems to be true. Google has now
    entered the broadband market as a direct competitor:
    14
    Google’s ultra-high-speed Internet service may finally
    be scaring the big Internet providers into action.
    Following Google’s announcement that it will expand
    into Austin, Texas, AT&T announced it will offer fiber
    Internet in the city, and Time Warner Cable announced
    it would offer citywide wireless Internet service.
    But smaller companies are also trying to head off
    Google before the company even makes an
    announcement in their communities. This week, for
    example, the Lawrence, Kansas-based Internet
    provider Wicked Broadband began taking pre-orders
    for a residential fiber Internet service with speeds to
    rival Google Fiber’s.
    Klint Finley, Google Fiber Spurs Mom-and-Pop Net Providers
    T o o ,      W I R E D ,     A p r .   2 6 ,     2 0 1 3 ,
    http://www.wired.com/wiredenterprise/2013/04/google-fiber-
    wicked/.
    The Commission apparently wanted to avoid a disciplined
    inquiry focused on market power, notwithstanding the warning
    it received from the Justice Department less than a year before
    the regulation issued – which, as I noted, Verizon cited – a
    warning that unless the FCC’s focus was on market power, any
    regulation could actually discourage broadband development,
    thus frustrating the statutory objective:
    Although enacting some form of regulation to prevent
    certain providers from exercising monopoly power
    may be tempting with regard to . . . areas [served by
    only one or two broadband providers], care must be
    taken to avoid stifling the infrastructure investments
    needed to expand broadband access. In particular, price
    regulation would be appropriate only where necessary
    to protect consumers from the exercise of monopoly
    15
    power and where such regulation would not stifle
    incentives to invest in infrastructure deployment.
    Ex Parte Submission of the U.S. DOJ at 28, Docket No. 09-51
    (Jan. 4, 2010).
    The Commission did postulate one other economic theory
    supposedly establishing a “barrier to infrastructure investment”
    that does not depend on the broadband providers possessing
    market power. It argued, essentially, that innovation among edge
    providers is a public good in that every broadband provider
    benefits from an open Internet, but each broadband provider has
    an individual incentive to charge edge providers for service
    because, if broadband providers were to forego that revenue
    stream, they would be unable to internalize all of the supposed
    benefits to innovation. 25 F.C.C.R. at 17919 ¶ 25. In short, the
    Commission speculates that the Open Internet Order prevents
    a classic “tragedy of the commons”– a situation in which each
    economic actor, behaving in his own self-interest, contributes to
    the destruction of a public good. See Garrett Hardin, The
    Tragedy of the Commons, 162 SCIENCE 1243 (1968). In such a
    situation, each actor would be better off if a central regulator
    prevented them from doing what would be in their private
    interest if they were acting unilaterally. Again, however, the
    Commission fails to make any real economic findings regarding
    whether these rules are actually necessary to prevent such a
    situation. As such, it is the sheerest of fanciful speculation.
    Indeed, if a tragedy of the commons were likely in the
    broadband market, then one would expect Verizon and other
    broadband providers to support the Open Internet Order,
    because such a situation would be economically harmful to them
    in the long run. By the same token, when firms oppose, on
    antitrust grounds, the merger of competing firms, it is generally
    a reliable indicator that the merger is pro-competitive. See Frank
    H. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 18
    16
    (1984) (“When a business rival brings suit, it is often safe to
    infer that the arrangement is beneficial to consumers.”). Firms
    can generally be relied upon to know their own best interest.
    Perhaps most troubling, the Commission fails to appreciate
    the long-term impact of its own regulations. An unwarranted
    government interference in a functioning market is likely to
    persist indefinitely, whereas a failure to intervene, even when
    regulation would be helpful, is likely to be only temporarily
    harmful because new innovations are constantly undermining
    entrenched industrial powers. See 
    id. at 3
    (“[J]udicial errors that
    tolerate baleful practices are self-correcting while erroneous
    condemnations are not.”); Tim Wu, THE MASTER SWITCH 11
    (2010) (“But as we have said, that which is centralized also
    eventually becomes a target for assault[.]”).
    Nevertheless, the Commission justifies its aggressive,
    prophylactic regulation by asserting that the negative
    consequences of regulation (preserving the status quo) are likely
    to be minor, while the consequences of allowing the broadband
    market to evolve without regulation could be drastic and
    permanent. 25 F.C.C.R. at 17909 ¶ 12. I think this is quite
    wrong, but in any event, the agency’s judgment about the
    propriety of leaping before looking cannot displace the judgment
    of Congress which, in enacting § 706, did not so broadly
    empower the Commission. Rather, Congress required the
    agency to identify an actual barrier to infrastructure investment
    or a threat to competition, and the agency must have evidence
    that the barrier or threat exists.
    III.
    Because the Open Internet Order obviously imposes
    common carrier obligations on broadband providers, I join
    generally the opinion of the Court with respect to Part III.
    Indeed, even noted proponents of “net neutrality” acknowledge
    17
    as much: “[N]et neutrality is the twenty-first century’s version
    of common carriage. . . . In the case of the Internet, common
    carriage under the name of net neutrality amounts to an FCC
    rule that bans any degree of blocking individual sites, [or]
    transmission of data.” Tim Wu, THE MASTER SWITCH 236
    (2010).
    I have, however, one quibble with the majority’s analysis of
    the anti-blocking rules. Although ultimately concluding that the
    anti-blocking rules are unlawful, the majority says that whether
    those rules “likewise establish per se common carrier
    obligations is somewhat less clear.” Majority Op. at 60.
    Although the Order states that, under the anti-blocking rules,
    broadband providers may not degrade content so as to make it
    “effectively unusable,” the majority supposes that a broadband
    provider might voluntarily choose to offer service that is faster
    than the anti-blocking rules require, i.e., faster than the
    minimum speed necessary to make each edge provider
    effectively usable by consumers. By exceeding the minimum
    level of service, the majority suggests, the broadband providers
    would have wide latitude to engage in individualized bargaining,
    which might take this rule outside of common carriage per se.
    My concern with this hypothesis is that the phrase “effectively
    unusable” is subject to manipulation. I think it should mean that
    whatever speed is generally offered to most edge providers is the
    minimum necessary to be effectively usable. After all, it is
    artificial to distinguish between what is “effective” and what
    consumers expect. If a faster speed were to become standard, we
    would likely consider a slower speed to be effectively unusable.
    Thus, while there is a possibility that a “fast lane” Internet
    service might be offered on a non-common carriage basis, the
    service that most users receive under this rule would still have
    to be offered as common carriage, at a regulated price of zero.
    In any event, as the majority recognizes, the Commission did not
    18
    make this argument, so the anti-blocking rules must fall.9
    ***
    This regulation essentially provides an economic preference
    to a politically powerful constituency, a constituency that, as is
    true of typical rent seekers, wishes protection against market
    forces. The Commission does not have authority to grant such
    a favor.
    9
    I do think that the transparency rules rest on firmer ground. The
    Commission is required to make triennial reports to Congress on
    “market entry barriers” in information services, 47 U.S.C. § 257, and
    requiring disclosure of network management practices appears to be
    reasonably ancillary to that duty. I also agree with the majority’s
    conclusion that the disclosure rules are severable from the anti-
    discrimination and anti-blocking rules.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 11-1355

Filed Date: 1/14/2014

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 3/3/2016

Authorities (29)

Cablevision Systems Corp. v. Federal Communications ... , 649 F.3d 695 ( 2011 )

Chapman v. United States , 111 S. Ct. 1919 ( 1991 )

At&T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board , 119 S. Ct. 721 ( 1999 )

Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc. , 121 S. Ct. 903 ( 2001 )

National Cable & Telecommunications Assn. v. Brand X ... , 125 S. Ct. 2688 ( 2005 )

Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, ... , 104 S. Ct. 2778 ( 1984 )

Secretary of Labor, Mine Safety and Health Administration v.... , 111 F.3d 913 ( 1997 )

Food & Drug Administration v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco ... , 120 S. Ct. 1291 ( 2000 )

Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States, Inc. v. State ... , 103 S. Ct. 2856 ( 1983 )

Louis A. Carducci v. Donald T. Regan, Secretary, U.S. ... , 714 F.2d 171 ( 1983 )

North Broward Hospital District v. Shalala , 172 F.3d 90 ( 1999 )

Interstate Com. Commiss. v. B. & O. RAILROAD , 12 S. Ct. 844 ( 1892 )

associated-gas-distributors-v-federal-energy-regulatory-commission-air , 824 F.2d 981 ( 1987 )

national-association-of-regulatory-utility-commissioners-v-federal , 533 F.2d 601 ( 1976 )

Orloff v. Federal Communications Commission , 352 F.3d 415 ( 2003 )

Federal Communications Commission v. Fox Television ... , 129 S. Ct. 1800 ( 2009 )

Turner Broadcasting System, Inc. v. Federal Communications ... , 117 S. Ct. 1174 ( 1997 )

davis-county-solid-waste-management-and-energy-recovery-special-service , 108 F.3d 1454 ( 1997 )

D. Ginsberg & Sons, Inc. v. Popkin , 52 S. Ct. 322 ( 1932 )

United States v. Southerland, Shawn , 486 F.3d 1355 ( 2007 )

View All Authorities »