Endeavor Partners Fund, LLC v. Cmsnr. IRS ( 2019 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued October 23, 2019           Decided November 26, 2019
    No. 18-1275
    ENDEAVOR PARTNERS FUND, LLC AND DELTA CURRENCY
    TRADING, LLC, TAX MATTERS PARTNER,
    APPELLANTS
    v.
    COMMISSIONER OF INTERNAL REVENUE,
    APPELLEE
    Consolidated with 18-1276, 18-1277, 18-1278
    On Appeal from the Decisions
    of the United States Tax Court
    Adrienne B. Koch argued the cause for appellants. With
    her on the briefs were David L. Katsky, Elias M. Zuckerman,
    and Haley E. Adams.
    Francesca Ugolini, Attorney, U.S. Department of
    Justice, argued the cause for appellee. With her on the brief
    was Judith A. Hagley, Attorney.
    Before: ROGERS and GRIFFITH, Circuit Judges, and
    WILLIAMS, Senior Circuit Judge.
    2
    Opinion for the Court filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    WILLIAMS.
    Concurring opinion filed by Circuit Judge ROGERS.
    WILLIAMS, Senior Circuit Judge: Andrew Beer was in the
    tax shelter business. His enterprise (referred to by the parties
    as “the Delta Group” or “Bricolage”) sold customers the chance
    to claim large, artificial losses to offset their income and reduce
    their taxes. Partnerships controlled by Beer bought pairs of
    currency option trades from Deutsche Bank. Each option trade
    within the pair amounted to a bet on whether a target currency
    would appreciate or depreciate within a week. Together, the
    two options in each pair yielded a net gain or loss of zero.
    Whichever trade won generated a large gain for a
    partnership in one year; the losing trade created a
    corresponding loss in a subsequent year. Partnerships enjoy
    pass through status, meaning that partners (not the partnership)
    are liable for the organization’s taxes and enjoy any tax
    benefits. See 26 U.S.C. § 701. In this case, an accommodating
    party absorbed the partnerships’ gains, while Beer’s customers
    took advantage of the losses. See Endeavor Partners Fund,
    LLC v. Comm’r, 
    115 T.C.M. 1540
    , 
    2018 WL 3203127
    ,
    at *4 (T.C. 2018) (describing rules “allegedly” enabling the
    accommodating party to “defease” the gains).
    This case involves three sets of trades in November and
    December, 2001, generating $144 million in losses a year later.
    See 
    id. at *14.
    By the fall of 2002, the government had gotten
    wise to this type of tax shelter and scared off Beer’s customers,
    see Endeavor Partners Fund, LLC, 
    2018 WL 3203127
    , at *14;
    J.A. 2184, and accordingly Beer used the losses for himself,
    though he evidently needed only $40 million of the total. See
    J.A. 2185.
    3
    The Tax Court found that these transactions lacked
    economic substance—that they were shams designed to look
    like real world trades without any of the risk or concomitant
    opportunity for profit.
    Though the option trades nominally cost tens of millions
    of dollars each, Deutsche Bank financed almost all the scheme
    on credit. According to the Tax Court’s findings, the parties
    structured the transactions to guarantee that, regardless of
    which trade “won,” the options always paid an amount exactly
    equal to the costs of the Deutsche Bank loan. One half of an
    option pair paid out in Danish kroner, while the other paid out
    in euros.
    These two currencies are functionally the same; the former
    was then, and is now, “pegged” to the latter. But currency
    markets are not perfectly efficient and, apparently, the
    currencies did not move identically on the open market. To
    avoid any residual risk that the krone and the euro might
    fluctuate relative to one another, the Tax Court found, Deutsche
    Bank and the partnerships agreed in advance to use seven-day
    forward exchange rates to convert the euro or krone winnings
    into the currency necessary to pay off the Deutsche Bank loan.
    See Endeavor Partners Fund, LLC, 
    2018 WL 3203127
    , at *8,
    *10, *12, *19. This meant that the trades posed zero risk: No
    matter which option trade won, the partnerships knew they
    would receive exactly enough money to pay off the Deutsche
    Bank loans.
    On appeal, the partnerships primarily contest the Tax
    Court’s conclusion that the parties agreed in advance on the
    exact rates to be used in determining earnings and losses under
    the option agreements, together with a related evidentiary
    point. Because the Tax Court did not clearly err in that
    conclusion—or in any other material respect—we affirm.
    4
    ***
    On a variety of grounds Congress allows taxpayers the
    benefit of various deductions, exclusions, and credits. See, e.g.,
    26 U.S.C. § 165 (permitting taxpayers to deduct losses). These
    provisions tempt some taxpayers into engaging in transactions
    that appear to follow the letter of the law but lack any real
    economic substance.
    We review the Tax Court’s conclusions that the paired
    currency option trades amount to shams “in the same manner
    and to the same extent as decisions of the district courts in civil
    actions tried without a jury.” 26 U.S.C. § 7482(a)(1). This
    means we examine legal conclusions de novo and factual
    determinations for clear error. See Green Gas Del. Statutory
    Tr. v. Comm’r, 
    903 F.3d 138
    , 142 (D.C. Cir. 2018). We may
    overturn the Tax Court’s fact findings only if we come to a
    “definite and firm conviction that a mistake has been
    committed.” United States v. U.S. Gypsum Co., 
    333 U.S. 364
    ,
    395 (1948).
    The Tax Court relied for legal principles on our decision
    in Horn v. Commissioner, 
    968 F.2d 1229
    (D.C. Cir. 1992),
    requiring that to treat a transaction as a sham the IRS must show
    that it possessed neither (1) any objectively reasonable
    potential for profit nor (2) any “other legitimate nontax
    business purposes,” 
    id. at 1238;
    see also 
    id. (identifying “risk
    allocation” as one such alternative nontax business purpose);
    Endeavor Partners Fund, LLC, 
    2018 WL 3203127
    , at *17–18
    (relying on Horn). Looking beyond this case, we note that
    Congress established its own test in a 2010 amendment to the
    Internal Revenue Code, see 26 U.S.C. § 7701(o); Health Care
    and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010, Pub. L. No. 111-
    152, § 1409, 124 Stat. 1029, 1068–69 (2010), to be applied
    prospectively only, see 
    id. at 1070.
                                    5
    The partnerships argue that the Commissioner bore the
    burden of proof at trial. But the Tax Court correctly ruled that
    “the allocation of the burden of proof in these cases is
    immaterial” because the governing standard was the
    preponderance of the evidence. Endeavor Partners Fund, LLC,
    
    2018 WL 3203127
    , at *17; see Blodgett v. Comm’r, 
    394 F.3d 1030
    , 1039 (8th Cir. 2005). Under a preponderance standard,
    once both parties have produced their respective evidence, the
    side with the more persuasive case prevails. See 
    Blodgett, 394 F.3d at 1039
    . As a result, the parties sensibly focus on the facts:
    if the Tax Court’s factual findings were free of reversible error,
    the judgment of sham transaction is inevitable.
    The Tax Court did not clearly err when it concluded the
    parties fixed the forward exchange rates, ensuring that they
    could predict the precise amount that the winning and losing
    trades would pay—and ensuring that the trades had no ex ante
    profit potential and lacked any “other legitimate nontax
    business purposes,” 
    Horn, 968 F.2d at 1238
    . The court relied
    primarily on three items of evidence.
    First, it found that the partnerships and Deutsche Bank
    “exchanged spreadsheets” that included the mutually agreed
    rate “for converting kroner to euro” and “kroner and euro into
    dollars.” Endeavor Partners Fund, LLC, 
    2018 WL 3203127
    ,
    at *9, *10, *12.
    Second, when Deutsche Bank closed the three 2001 trades,
    it did not use the prevailing market exchange rates. See
    Appellant Br. 47 (admitting that “Deutsche Bank may not have
    used any of the actual spot rates in effect on the settlement
    dates”). Instead, Deutsche Bank settled the trades using the
    same rates listed in the spreadsheets they exchanged.
    Third, not once did the partnerships object to the use of the
    fixed exchange rate instead of the prevailing market spot rate.
    6
    See Endeavor Partners Fund, LLC, 
    2018 WL 3203127
    , at *19.
    The Delta Group’s contemporary silence about Deutsche
    Bank’s use of a pre-agreed exchange rate strongly indicates that
    the parties agreed to fix the krone-euro rate for purposes of
    determining option outcomes, eliminating whatever risk (and
    potential for profit) might have otherwise existed. And at least
    two other similar sets of trades in which Beer’s affiliates
    engaged in 2000 also recorded no profit or loss. See 
    id. at *6–
    8; J.A. 1999, 2358, 2634.
    The partnerships attack the court’s finding of an agreement
    on rate-fixing, pointing to the testimony of Andrew Beer, the
    man behind the whole scheme. Beer had offered an innocent
    explanation of the Deutsche Bank spreadsheets, saying that
    they didn’t represent an agreed forward exchange rate with
    which to settle the trades, but rather a projection “to ensure that
    the trades were priced in such a way that any profit or loss
    would result from [a] change [in the market] and not from an
    error in pricing in the first instance.” See Appellant Br. 18
    (paraphrasing Beer’s testimony at J.A. 2173–74). We’re far
    from confident we understand what Beer meant to convey. But
    the account, if believed, would support an inference that
    Deutsche Bank’s use of the forward exchange rate to settle the
    trades, rather than the spot rate, was pure accident and a
    deviation from the parties’ plans. See Endeavor Partners
    Fund, LLC, 
    2018 WL 3203127
    , at *19.
    But the Tax Court did not credit Beer’s testimony. Id.; see
    106 Ltd. v. Comm’r, 
    684 F.3d 84
    , 92 (D.C. Cir. 2012) (noting
    that the Tax Court’s “credibility determinations are entitled to
    the greatest deference” (quotation and citation omitted)).
    Indeed, it pointed to a highly implausible assumption
    underlying Beer’s account: “Mr. Beer’s testimony presupposes
    that Deutsche Bank erred in this way, not once, but every time
    it closed a Delta options trade.” Endeavor Partners Fund,
    LLC, 
    2018 WL 3203127
    , at *19.
    7
    This leads us to the partnerships’ claim of a faulty
    evidentiary ruling. The Tax Court went on to note that the
    partnerships did not call “the most logical witness to testify
    about Deutsche Bank’s trading practices,” namely someone
    “from Deutsche Bank.” 
    Id. The court
    observed “from this we
    infer that such testimony would not have been helpful to them.”
    
    Id. As the
    partnerships see it, the court thus drew an
    impermissible adverse inference from the absence of a
    Deutsche Bank witness. And—they argue—this error is fatal,
    because the court needed that inference to reach the conclusion
    that the parties rigged the rates.
    But studying the court’s analysis, we conclude that any
    error was harmless.
    Under the common law formulation, a fact finder
    (typically, a jury) may but need not draw an adverse inference
    from the absence of a witness “if a party has it [1] peculiarly
    within his power to produce witnesses whose testimony would
    [2] elucidate the transaction.” United States v. Young, 
    463 F.2d 934
    , 939 (D.C. Cir. 1972) (quoting Graves v. United States, 
    150 U.S. 118
    , 121 (1893)).
    The likely Deutsche Bank witnesses clearly had the
    potential to “elucidate the transaction”—they could directly
    address the question whether the rate-rigging had been
    intentional or accidental. 
    Id. So the
    pertinent questions are
    whether the witnesses were “peculiarly within [the
    partnership’s] power” and, if not, whether the Tax Court’s
    conclusion rested materially on the adverse inference.
    On the facts of this case, neither the partnerships nor the
    Commissioner peculiarly controlled Deutsche Bank’s
    employees. The partnerships’ business relationship with
    Deutsche Bank had long since withered, and the government’s
    non-prosecution agreement with the Bank did not, by itself,
    8
    place its employees within the government’s power. See
    United States v. Tarantino, 
    846 F.2d 1384
    , 1404 (D.C. Cir.
    1988) (“[N]o automatic inference of exclusive government
    control arises from the fact that witnesses are acting as
    government informants, or from a grant of immunity from
    prosecution.” (citations omitted) (emphasis added)). But see
    Burgess v. United States, 
    440 F.2d 226
    , 232 (D.C. Cir. 1970)
    (concluding that “[t]he testimony showed a relationship
    between the Government and the informer which placed it
    peculiarly within the power of the Government to produce
    him”); United States v. Williams, 
    113 F.3d 243
    , 246 n.2 (D.C.
    Cir. 1997) (construing Burgess as “alleviat[ing] the need for the
    defense to seek a witness by subpoena” to secure a missing-
    witness instruction).
    Some courts have relaxed the common law standard and
    dropped the requirement that the party against whom an
    inference is drawn have the witness “peculiarly within his
    power,” thus giving the fact finder fairly broad discretion to
    draw an inference and to choose the party against whom it is to
    be drawn. See, e.g., Wilson v. Merrell Dow Pharm. Inc., 
    893 F.2d 1149
    , 1152 (10th Cir. 1990) (“When an absent witness is
    equally available to both parties, either party is open to the
    inference that the missing testimony would have been adverse
    to it.”); United States v. Erb, 
    543 F.2d 438
    , 444 (2d Cir. 1976)
    (“[T]he weight of authority in this circuit and the more logical
    view is that the failure to produce (a witness equally available
    to both sides) is open to an inference against both parties.”
    (quotation and citations omitted)); United States v. Cotter, 
    60 F.2d 689
    , 692 (2d Cir. 1932) (Hand, J.) (“When both sides fail
    to call a witness who knows something of the facts, their
    conduct, like anything else they do, is a circumstance which a
    jury may use.”); State v. Greer, 
    922 N.W.2d 312
    , ¶¶ 18–19
    (Wis. Ct. App. 2018) (unpublished).
    9
    We have given conflicting signals about whether control
    over a missing witness is required for a fact finder to draw an
    inference. Compare 
    Young, 463 F.2d at 943
    (“But in the in-
    between case where each side has the physical capacity to
    locate and produce the witness, and it is debatable which side
    might more naturally have been expected to call the witness,
    there may be latitude for the judge to leave the matter to debate
    without an instruction, simply permitting each counsel to argue
    to the jury concerning the ‘natural’ inference of fact to be
    drawn.”), with United States v. Norris, 
    873 F.2d 1519
    , 1522
    (D.C. Cir. 1989) (“Exclusivity or peculiarity of power to
    produce is [] one of two necessary predicates for entitlement to
    the missing witness instruction.” (emphasis added)).
    In at least one case involving an agency, we have reversed
    the National Labor Relations Board when it applied the adverse
    inference against a party that did not control the witness. Bufco
    Corp. v. NLRB, 
    147 F.3d 964
    , 971 (D.C. Cir. 1998). In the
    course of our (brief) analysis, we also noted that the Board’s
    decision conflicted with its own precedent on the subject. 
    Id. This multiplicity
    of viewpoints suggests the possibility
    that we should, in reviewing agency decisions, adopt a rule that
    saves agencies from undue risk of reversal due to their potential
    failure to estimate correctly what circuit will review a particular
    decision. Besides reducing the risk of inadvertent error, such a
    rule would prevent agencies from having to adopt different
    evidentiary rules depending on the circuit (or, indeed, multiple
    circuits) in which an appeal may lie. At least where good
    arguments exist for and against permitting the inference, we
    might allow an agency leeway to choose its own path.
    Though lodged under Article I, the Tax Court is—in one
    relevant respect—unusual: Congress has specifically directed
    us to review that court in the “same manner and to the same
    extent as decisions of the district courts in civil actions tried
    10
    without a jury.” 26 U.S.C. § 7482(a)(1). This indicates that,
    even if we were to adopt the rule discussed above generally, we
    would still have to apply our circuit’s case law to Tax Court
    decisions rather than Tax Court precedent. See generally Dang
    v. Comm’r, 
    83 T.C.M. 1627
    , 
    2002 WL 977368
    , at *3
    (T.C. 2002) (concluding, in an unpublished, non-binding
    memorandum opinion, that “no adverse inference is warranted”
    if “a witness is equally available to both parties”).
    In the end, however, we need not resolve the permissibility
    of the inference nor the governing source of law on that issue.
    The error, if any, was harmless. See 
    Young, 463 F.2d at 940
    (applying harmless error analysis). No reader of the Tax
    Court’s analysis of Beer’s testimony in the full context of the
    documentary evidence can seriously doubt that its observation
    about the lack of Deutsche Bank witnesses was only a matter
    of gilding the lily. Cf. William Shakespeare, King John, act 4,
    sc. 2 (“To gild refined gold, to paint the lily . . . Is wasteful and
    ridiculous excess.”). Indeed, examining the record we do not
    believe any reasonable fact finder would have needed to rely
    on an adverse inference to tip the scales in the Commissioner’s
    favor. The court had before it a pattern of trades that occurred
    on at least five different dates (the three in late 2001 at issue in
    this appeal and two others in 2000). On all five occasions, the
    partnerships turned not a smidgeon of profit or loss. See J.A.
    1999, 2358, 2634. And by Beer’s admission the Delta Group
    never objected to Deutsche Bank’s failure to use the market
    spot rates to close the trades in 2001. See J.A. 2579–80 (stating
    surprise at learning that the trades did not use the spot rates).
    Given this sustained pattern of repeated, zero-profit-or-loss
    transactions, the Tax Court had—and asserted—ample reason
    to conclude that Beer and Deutsche Bank arranged their scheme
    to eliminate all risk. Indeed, the pattern evidence was the thrust
    of the Tax Court’s analysis. See Endeavor Partners Fund,
    LLC, 
    2018 WL 3203127
    , at *19. As the evidence appeared to
    the court to tilt overwhelmingly in favor of the Commissioner,
    11
    the partnerships’ failure to dig themselves out of the hole by
    calling Deutsche Bank witnesses must naturally have suggested
    that the partnerships saw no prospect of help in that quarter.
    But it also rendered the allusion to these witnesses (and any
    possible error) harmless.
    The partnerships contend the pattern of no-profit-or-loss
    trades cannot provide evidence of an agreement to rig the rates
    “unless (at a minimum) it could not be explained by anything
    else.” Appellant Br. 47. Not so. Under a preponderance
    standard, what matters is that the Tax Court could reasonably
    find that rate rigging (rather than Beer’s account) was the more
    probable explanation for the highly suspicious pattern, not that
    it was irrefutable. None of the cases to which the partnerships
    cite, see 
    id. at n.25,
    demands that we overturn the Tax Court’s
    sensible conclusion. See, e.g., Smith v. Reitman, 
    389 F.2d 303
    ,
    304 (D.C. Cir. 1967) (concluding that there must be “some
    basis in the record or in common experience to warrant” an
    inference based on res ipsa loquitur (emphasis added)
    (quotation and citation omitted)).
    Finally, the partnerships argue that their trades possessed
    an independent business purpose, aside from offsetting taxes:
    Before the Commissioner started cracking down on the
    practice, the Delta Group had planned to profit from the tax
    losses by transactions in its tax shelter business. (Ultimately,
    instead of selling the losses, Beer used them for himself when
    he ran out of customers.) This seems a splendid new example
    of chutzpah. The business purpose test looks to whether a
    transaction has any purpose independent of the resulting tax
    savings. If profits from marketing tax losses could be viewed
    as “independent,” the sham transaction rule would apply only
    to unsophisticated creators of sham transactions (a small group,
    we suspect).
    * * *
    12
    The judgment of the Tax Court is
    Affirmed.
    ROGERS, Circuit Judge, concurring: I write only to
    elaborate on how a finding that there was an agreement on the
    exchange rates eliminated the profit potential of the trades.
    As the court explains, one option in a pair would pay out
    in kroner and the other would pay out in euros. Op. at 3.
    Equally important, however, is that the premium loan for the
    option that paid out kroner needed to be repaid in kroner, and
    the premium loan for the option that paid out in euros needed
    to be repaid in euros. The fact that the premium loans needed
    to be repaid in different currencies explains why the rate
    agreement eliminated any profit potential. Putting aside the
    negligible payout from the losing option, the partnerships
    needed to use the payout from the winning option to pay the
    premium loans for both the winning option and the losing
    option. Because the two options’ premium loans had to be
    repaid in different currencies, the partnerships needed to make
    a currency exchange in order to repay one of the premium
    loans. That currency exchange is the possible source of profit
    potential, and by agreeing on that exchange rate the
    partnerships and Deutsche Bank eliminated any profit potential
    from these trades. See Tax Ct. Op. 17–18; see also Appellants’
    Br. 11–12; Appellee Br. 13–15.
    Appellants emphasize that if there were no agreement to
    fix the exchange rates that would be used when the winning
    option paid out and the partnerships repaid the premium loans,
    then how far the payouts would go toward covering the loans
    would depend upon the actual movements of the euro and
    krone against each other during the week between the trade
    date and the settlement date. Appellants’ Br. 11. How far those
    payouts would go toward covering the premium loans would
    also depend upon movements of the euro and krone against the
    U.S. dollar (because appellants’ books reflect U.S. dollar
    values) during both that initial week and the remaining life of
    the investment until the smaller payout on the losing option was
    made. 
    Id. at 11–12.
    In their view, the Tax Court’s finding of
    2
    rate “rigging” is unsupported by substantial evidence, thus
    making clear the potential for profit as the deals were
    structured.
    For example, if the krone-denominated loan were the
    winning loan and the euro-denominated loan were the losing
    loan, then the partnerships would receive a large payout in
    kroner and would need to use that payout to repay a loan in
    kroner and a loan in euros. To repay the latter, the partnerships
    would need to exchange their remaining kroner (after repaying
    the krone-denominated loan) for euros. Depending on the
    exchange rate between the krone and the euro, the krone payout
    could exceed the euro loan amount, resulting in a gain; or it
    may fall short of the euro loan amount, resulting in a loss; or it
    may exactly equal the euro loan amount, resulting in neither
    profit nor loss. By fixing the rates, the partnerships and
    Deutsche Bank ensured that the winning payout exactly
    equaled the premium loans for both options, and thereby
    eliminated the possibility of profit or loss attendant to this
    currency exchange.