BNP Paribas Energy Trading GP v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission ( 2014 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued November 8, 2013           Decided February 21, 2014
    No. 12-1242
    BNP PARIBAS ENERGY TRADING GP,
    FORMERLY KNOWN AS FORTIS ENERGY MARKETING &
    TRADING GP,
    PETITIONER
    v.
    FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION,
    RESPONDENT
    PSEG ENERGY RESOURCES & TRADE LLC, ET AL.,
    INTERVENORS
    On Petitioner for Review of Order of the
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    Gordon J. Smith argued the cause for petitioner. With
    him on the briefs was Matthew T. Rick.
    Ira Megdal was on the briefs for intervenor South Jersey
    Resources Group, LLC in support of petitioner. Marc J. Fink
    entered an appearance.
    Samuel Soopper, Attorney, Federal Energy Regulatory
    Commission, argued the cause for respondent. With him on
    the brief were David L. Morenoff, Acting General Counsel,
    2
    and Robert H. Solomon, Solicitor. Judith A. Albert, Attorney,
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, entered an
    appearance.
    Michael J. Thompson argued the cause for intervenors
    Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Company, LLC, et al. With
    him on the briefs were David S. Shaffer, David A. Glenn,
    James H. Byrd, and James H. Jeffries, IV.
    Before: TATEL, Circuit Judge, and WILLIAMS and
    RANDOLPH, Senior Circuit Judges.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    WILLIAMS.
    WILLIAMS, Senior Circuit Judge: Two firms receiving
    gas storage service in the Washington Storage Field ceased
    taking service and “released” their storage rights to petitioner
    BNP Paribas Energy Trading GP and intervenor South Jersey
    Resources Group, LLC. (Since they are similarly situated and
    advance the same arguments, we’ll refer to the new customers
    collectively as “Paribas” or “the replacement shippers.”) At
    the time of the release, the departing customers exercised their
    contract rights to buy back so-called “base gas” from the
    field’s operator, Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Company,
    LLC (“Transco”). Base gas is necessary in such a field to
    maintain pressure and thus enable users to extract “top gas”
    for shipment to its next destination. Transcontinental Gas
    Pipe Line Corp., 125 FERC ¶ 63,020 at P 123 (2008) (“ALJ
    Decision”). The buy-back was at contractually agreed low
    prices reflecting the era (mid-1970s to early-1980s) when the
    original customers had supplied the base gas. Given the buy-
    back, Transco had to make new purchases to replenish its base
    gas so as to maintain service at the levels prevailing before the
    replacement.
    3
    At the time of the exiting customers’ departure, the
    historic customers who remained, and the new replacement
    customers, disputed whether the cost of the new base gas
    should be charged entirely to the replacement shippers
    (“incremental pricing”) or should be charged to all shippers in
    proportion to their usage (“rolled-in pricing”). In a decision
    purporting to apply the familiar “cost causation” principle, the
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission chose incremental
    pricing. Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corp., 130 FERC
    ¶ 61,043 at P 33 (2010) (“Order”); Transcontinental Gas Pipe
    Line Corp., 139 FERC ¶ 61,002 at PP 64-68 (2012) (“Order
    on Rehearing”). As we’ll see, the Commission failed to offer
    an intelligible explanation of how its decision manifested the
    cost causation principle. It particularly failed to explain how
    or why or in what sense the historic customers’ continued
    demand did not share, pro rata, in causing the need for the
    new base gas, or, to put the same issue in terms that the
    Commission often treats as equivalent, how or why or in what
    sense the historic customers did not share proportionately in
    the benefits provided by the new base gas. And it brushed off
    with a terse “not relevant” Paribas’s invocation of a seemingly
    parallel set of the Commission’s own decisions. Accordingly,
    we vacate and remand, explaining in detail below.
    * * *
    In 1975, at the outset of the field’s operation, shippers
    intending to use it agreed with Transco on a means of
    supplying the necessary base gas. The shippers permitted
    Transco to take gas that they were otherwise entitled to
    purchase, in a quantity proportionate to each shipper’s future
    storage rights in the field. Transco paid for the gas and held
    title to it. But the agreement entitled each customer to
    repurchase its share of the base gas on terminating service at
    the field. Transco enlarged the field several times between
    1975 and 1981, each time buying gas that the new shippers
    4
    had been entitled to take themselves, and each time giving
    those shippers the right to repurchase the gas at historic cost
    on terminating service. On all such occasions Transco’s costs
    were rolled into the rate base. Order on Rehearing, 139 FERC
    at PP 3-4.
    In the late 1990s Transco filed an amended tariff that
    obliged it to meet any new base gas needs on its own, and to
    maintain enough base gas to support the field’s total top gas.
    Because storage at the Washington field is fully subscribed,
    the need to purchase new gas would arise from the departure
    of an historic customer (assuming it took away its share of the
    base gas) followed by the arrival of a replacement shipper
    (which, with the end of the prior system, would not be
    providing its share of the base gas). On the other hand, an
    historic shipper’s termination of service and repurchase of
    base gas, with no replacement shipper stepping in, would not
    in itself automatically require Transco to secure new base gas.
    
    Id. at PP
    7-9.
    Events in 2005 and 2006 triggered what appear to be the
    first applications of the new requirement that Transco
    purchase base gas outside the old purchase-repurchase
    arrangement. Two historic shippers, PSEG Energy Resources
    and Trade LLC and South Jersey Gas Company, “released”
    their Washington field rights to the replacement shippers now
    before us and exercised their right to repurchase their share of
    the base gas at historic cost—roughly $0.89 per dekatherm.
    At the time of repurchase the price of gas was roughly $6 per
    dekatherm. 
    Id. at PP
    11-12.
    Transco responded by proposing a new, bifurcated tariff.
    The historic shippers would continue to pay a “rolled-in” rate
    reflecting their proportionate share of the low-cost historic
    base gas. Paribas, however, would pay an “incremental rate”
    reflecting the cost of 3.4 million dekatherms of additional gas,
    5
    most of which would have been unnecessary in the absence of
    replacement shippers. 
    Id. at P
    12-13. (According to FERC
    staff, 1.32 million dekatherms would have been needed even
    without the replacement customers. ALJ Decision, 125 FERC
    at PP 101-02). The parties eventually settled all issues except
    for the rate applicable to Paribas.
    An administrative law judge rejected the proposal after
    finding that Transco failed to meet its burden to show that the
    proposed rate was just and reasonable. 
    Id. at P
    180. The ALJ
    observed that since “all base gas as a whole serves the top gas
    capacity and deliverability needs of all customers as a whole,
    it is impossible to attribute any portion of base gas to any one
    or more customers in any way other than pro rata according
    to each customer’s top gas volume.” 
    Id. at P
    129. And
    “[w]hen base gas is injected or withdrawn, the top gas
    capacity and deliverability needs of all customers are affected
    equally.” 
    Id. at P
    130. As statements of physical reality,
    these propositions are, so far as appears, undisputed. And the
    ALJ noted specifically that consultations by Transco with the
    remaining historic customers might well have led them to take
    less gas and thus to require acquisition of less replacement
    base gas. 
    Id. at P
    133. Thus the ALJ concluded that the
    newly purchased gas was “as crucial to meeting the needs of
    [Transco’s] existing customers as it was to meeting the needs
    of [Paribas],” 
    id. at P
    138, and that “no one customer’s top gas
    allotment can be said to ‘cause’ more base gas cost than any
    other customer’s,” 
    id. at P
    129.
    In the orders under review, the Commission reversed and
    approved Transco’s rate filing, with reasoning that we will
    analyze below.
    6
    * * *
    We review the Commission’s ratemaking decisions under
    the APA’s familiar arbitrary and capricious standard.
    Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corp. v. FERC, 
    518 F.3d 916
    , 919 (D.C. Cir. 2008). That standard requires us to ensure
    that the Commission “considered the relevant factors and
    articulated a rational connection between the facts found and
    the choice made.” 
    Id. (quoting Nat’l
    Ass’n of Clean Air
    Agencies v. EPA, 
    489 F.3d 1221
    , 1228 (D.C. Cir. 2007)). Part
    of that requirement of course requires the Commission to
    provide an adequate explanation before it treats similarly
    situated parties differently. Petroleum Commc’ns, Inc. v.
    FCC, 
    22 F.3d 1164
    , 1172 (D.C. Cir. 1994).
    The Natural Gas Act requires that rates be just and
    reasonable and not unduly discriminatory.            15 U.S.C.
    § 717c(a)-(b). The Commission has “added flesh to these bare
    statutory bones” through adoption of the “cost causation”
    principle, which requires that rates “reflect to some degree the
    costs actually caused by the customer who must pay them.”
    K N Energy, Inc. v. FERC, 
    968 F.2d 1295
    , 1300 (D.C. Cir.
    1992). This typically translates into a process of “comparing
    the costs assessed against a party to the burdens imposed or
    benefits drawn by that party.” Midwest ISO Transmission
    Owners v. FERC, 
    373 F.3d 1361
    , 1368 (D.C. Cir. 2004). The
    flip side of the principle is that the Commission generally may
    not single out a party for the full cost of a project, or even
    most of it, when the benefits of the project are diffuse. See
    Illinois Commerce Comm’n v. FERC, 
    576 F.3d 470
    , 476 (7th
    Cir. 2009); Pac. Gas & Elec. Co. v. FERC, 
    373 F.3d 1315
    ,
    1320-21 (D.C. Cir. 2004).
    In a critical section of its Order on Rehearing the
    Commission set out to explain its “Consistency with Cost
    Causation Principle.” Order on Rehearing, 139 FERC at PP
    7
    64-68. It saw the case as “present[ing] alternative methods of
    analyzing cost causation, depending upon whether the focus is
    on the pipeline’s operations or on the events enabling each
    customer to join the system.” 
    Id. at P
    64. It acknowledged
    the validity of the ALJ’s finding that because the field was
    operated on an integrated basis, “all base gas injected into the
    field serves the top gas deliverability needs of all . . .
    customers, regardless of when each shipper joined the
    system.” 
    Id. But in
    its “alternative” view of causation, the
    Commission saw the exiting historic shippers’ releases to the
    replacement shippers as “the ‘most immediate and proximate’
    cause” of the need to buy new base gas, as those releases
    obligated Transco to provide service to the replacement
    shippers for the remaining terms of the exiting shippers’
    contracts. 
    Id. at P
    65.
    On its face, this alternative focus on the exiting shippers’
    release doesn’t seem to support the Commission’s idea that
    the replacement shippers’ demand is the cause of the need for
    the additional 3.4 million dekatherms of base gas. It still
    places the replacement shippers in the position of any new
    customer whose demand, coupled with that of the prior
    customers, necessitates some new investment. Thus the
    Commission’s characterization of both alternative views as
    “factually accurate,” 
    id. at P
    66, seems highly questionable.
    Having reached this point of supposed indeterminacy, the
    Commission went on to say that accordingly the weight to be
    given each theory of “cause” should turn on “equitable
    factors,” 
    id., which it
    identified primarily as the fact of the
    historic shippers’ having “provided essential support [for
    Transco’s developing the field] by providing the necessary
    base gas out of their gas purchase entitlements during a period
    of severe gas shortages,” 
    id. at P
    67.
    8
    By way of background, three observations about cost
    causation are relevant. First, the cost causation principle
    generally calls for giving the same treatment to new and
    continuing customers, based on a straightforward economic
    rationale. Where “all customers cause the incurrence of the
    costs . . . , whether by adding or merely continuing their
    usage,” Nat’l Ass’n of Regulatory Util. Comm’rs v. FERC,
    
    475 F.3d 1277
    , 1285 (D.C. Cir. 2007); Town of Norwood v.
    FERC, 
    962 F.2d 20
    , 24 n.1 (D.C. Cir. 1992), assignment of
    the costs to all customers (both continuing and new) forces
    each set “to weigh the marginal benefits of the capacity to
    them against the marginal costs they impose on society by
    continuing to make demands.”          1 Alfred Kahn, The
    Economics of Regulation 140 (1988); Southeastern Michigan
    Gas Co. v. FERC, 
    133 F.3d 34
    , 41 (D.C. Cir. 1998) (citing
    Kahn); cf. PJM Interconnection, LLC, 128 FERC ¶ 61,157 at
    P 102 (2009) (recognizing, on the supply side, equivalence
    between new entrants and existing suppliers).
    Second, the cost causation principle itself manifests a
    kind of equity. This is most obvious when we frame the
    principle (as we and the Commission often do) as a matter of
    making sure that burden is matched with benefit. See, e.g.,
    Midwest ISO Transmission 
    Owners, 373 F.3d at 1368
    ;
    Southeastern Michigan Gas 
    Co., 133 F.3d at 41
    (as “every
    shipper is economically marginal, the costs of increased
    demand may equitably be attributed to every user”).
    Third, despite those propositions, we have recognized
    that equitable factors (independent of those inherent in the
    cost causation principle itself) may on occasion trump that
    principle. Town of 
    Norwood, 962 F.2d at 24
    n.1.
    Notwithstanding the Commission’s undoubted power to
    rest on “equitable” principles, its moves here reveal two flaws.
    First, as we saw above, its basis for imputing an exclusive or
    9
    even primary causal role to the replacement shippers’ demand
    is uncertain at best. Thus its chosen bridge to reliance on
    “equity” is shaky. Second, the Commission doesn’t explain
    why the historic shippers’ earlier support for the project
    (which left them entitled to buy back their gas and resell it at
    current prices) gives them a special equitable claim in
    perpetuity. Equity’s conscience is famously “as long as the
    chancellor’s foot”; to reconcile its use with the APA’s
    rejection of arbitrariness requires both that the justification for
    shifting to “equity” and the reasons that make an outcome
    equitable be set forth with clarity and logic. They are missing
    here, and the Commission doesn’t really advance its judgment
    that the replacement shippers’ demand can be viewed as the
    sole cause of the base gas need by pinning on that demand the
    undefined label “immediate and proximate cause.”
    The failings of the Commission’s approach here are
    underscored by its non-response to a specific point that
    Paribas raised in the administrative proceedings. There it
    argued that the Commission’s decision was inconsistent with
    its application of cost causation to an analogous case in the
    electricity sector, namely when integration of a new electricity
    generator requires upgrades to the transmission network.
    Paribas says that in that case the Commission does not permit
    transmission operators to mechanically assign the cost of the
    upgrade to the generator that precipitated the expense, but
    instead requires consideration of the benefits to all parties on
    the integrated system. See, e.g., Midwest Indep. Transmission
    Sys. Operator, Inc. & the Midwest ISO Transmission Owners,
    129 FERC ¶ 61,060 at PP 53-56 (2009); Order No. 2003-A,
    Standardization of Generator Interconnection Agreements &
    Procedures, 106 FERC ¶ 61,220 at PP 585-86 (2004); Re
    Public Service Co. of Colorado, 62 FERC ¶ 61,013, 61,061
    (1993). It inquires whether the upgrade benefits all users of
    the grid or just the additional generator, and does not “require
    the Generator to bear costs incurred for the development of
    10
    equipment that benefits all users of the network.” Entergy
    Services, Inc. v. FERC, 
    391 F.3d 1240
    , 1243 (D.C. Cir. 2004).
    Yet when Paribas pointed out the apparent inconsistency
    between FERC’s action here and its management of the
    electricity sector, the Commission brushed it off as “not
    relevant to this case.” Order on Rehearing, 139 FERC at P
    77; see FERC Br. 21. Such an opaque dismissal of an analogy
    falls well short of the APA’s requirement that the Commission
    “provide an adequate explanation to justify treating similarly
    situated parties differently,” Comcast Corp. v. FCC, 
    526 F.3d 763
    , 769 (D.C. Cir. 2008); accord Am. Min. Cong. v. EPA,
    
    907 F.2d 1179
    , 1191 (D.C. Cir. 1990).
    Whatever the reason for rejecting the analogy from
    electricity regulation (if there is one), it cannot be that the
    distinctions between gas and electricity, or between the
    Natural Gas Act and the Federal Power Act, ipso facto put an
    electricity analysis out of court. We have routinely relied on
    the two statutes’ rough equivalence, looking to natural gas
    analogs when assessing electricity regulation and vice-versa.
    Transmission Access Policy Study Grp. v. FERC, 
    225 F.3d 667
    , 686 (D.C. Cir. 2000) (applying principles of natural gas
    regulation to electricity); Am. Gas Ass’n v. FERC, 
    912 F.2d 1496
    , 1506 (D.C. Cir. 1990) (applying principles of electricity
    regulation to natural gas). To be clear, we are not suggesting
    that the Commission must always regulate the natural gas and
    electricity industries identically. Indeed, it often does not.
    E.g., Re Northeast Utilities Service Co., 62 FERC ¶ 61,294,
    62,923 (Mar. 26, 1993). FERC may point to distinguishing
    facts or established policy, but it may not dismiss a material
    argument out-of-hand.
    Transco, intervening in support of the Commission,
    appears to suggest that any error is immaterial because even in
    the case of a network upgrade the Commission permits
    incremental rates in certain circumstances. Transco Br. 27-28.
    11
    Even assuming those circumstances to be present here, the
    Commission’s reliance on the exception would have given
    Paribas a chance to argue against its applicability. But the
    Commission’s outright dismissal of Paribas’s analogy
    provides no rationale for us to review.
    In short, the Commission has failed to offer a reasoned
    basis for its conclusion.
    * * *
    Although we find that the Commission’s response to
    Paribas’s contentions was arbitrary and capricious, we do not
    mean to suggest that on remand the Commission is to ignore
    the complex history of the Washington field. The historic
    shippers have consistently refrained from leaving the field and
    reaping the potential windfall from exercising their contingent
    option to purchase their share of the base gas. By so
    refraining, they annually incur, as a cost of continuing to take
    service, the foregone return on the proceeds of selling that
    gas. It may be that the Commission could, consistent with
    regarding all shippers as causing the need for the purchase of
    additional base gas in proportion to their use of the field,
    nevertheless require the replacement shippers to pay the
    incremental cost, while allowing the historic shippers to pay
    the previously calculated rate and continue to forego the
    annualized return from exercise of their buy-back option. If
    this analysis is correct, such a rate treatment could subject all
    shippers to similar incentives for similar use of the field. As
    the Commission did not broach such an analysis, it would
    obviously be inappropriate for us to adopt it. SEC v. Chenery
    Corp., 
    318 U.S. 80
    , 87 (1943). But we cannot affirm on the
    basis of a Commission rationale that fails to respond to critical
    arguments raised before the agency. Accordingly, the
    Commission’s order is
    12
    Vacated and remanded.