Illinois Public Telecommunications Ass'n v. Federal Communications Commission ( 2014 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued April 4, 2014                  Decided June 13, 2014
    No. 13-1059
    ILLINOIS PUBLIC TELECOMMUNICATIONS ASSOCIATION,
    PETITIONER
    v.
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION AND UNITED
    STATES OF AMERICA,
    RESPONDENTS
    AT&T, INC. AND VERIZON,
    INTERVENORS
    Consolidated with 13-1083, 13-1149
    On Petitions for Review of an Order of
    the Federal Communications Commission
    Michael W. Ward argued the cause for petitioners Illinois
    Public Telecommunications Association and Payphone
    Association of Ohio, Inc. Keith J. Roland argued the cause
    for petitioner Independent Payphone Association of New
    York. With them on the briefs were Albert H. Kramer,
    Donald J. Evans, and Daniel S. Blynn.
    2
    Sarah E. Citrin, Counsel, Federal Communications
    Commission, argued the cause for respondents. With her on
    the brief were William J. Baer, Assistant Attorney General,
    U.S. Department of Justice, Robert B. Nicholson and Shana
    M. Wallace, Attorneys, Suzanne M. Tetreault, Deputy General
    Counsel, Federal Communications Commission, Jacob M.
    Lewis, Associate General Counsel, and Richard K. Welch,
    Deputy Associate General Counsel. Joel Marcus, Attorney,
    Federal Communications Commission, entered              an
    appearance.
    Aaron M. Panner argued the cause for intervenors. With
    him on the brief were Gary L. Phillips, Michael E. Glover,
    and Christopher M. Miller.
    Before: KAVANAUGH and WILKINS, Circuit Judges, and
    SILBERMAN, Senior Circuit Judge.
    Opinion for       the   Court   filed   by   Circuit   Judge
    KAVANAUGH.
    KAVANAUGH, Circuit Judge: Once upon a time, the only
    way to call home from a roadside rest stop or neighborhood
    diner was to use a payphone. Some payphones were owned
    by independent payphone providers. Other payphones were
    owned by Bell Operating Companies. The Bell Operating
    Companies also happened to own the local phone lines. To
    ensure fair competition in the payphone market, Congress
    prohibited Bell Operating Companies from exploiting their
    control over the local phone lines to discriminate against other
    payphone providers in the upstream payphone market.
    Specifically, Congress prohibited Bell Operating Companies
    from subsidizing their own payphones or charging
    discriminatory rates to competitor payphone providers. See
    
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    . This case concerns the remedies available
    3
    for violations of that prohibition – in particular, whether
    independent payphone providers who were charged excessive
    rates by Bell Operating Companies are entitled to refunds or
    instead are entitled only to prospective relief in the form of
    lower rates.
    We conclude that Congress granted discretion to the
    Federal Communications Commission to determine whether
    refunds would be required in those circumstances and that the
    Commission reasonably exercised that discretion here.
    I
    Petitioners are trade associations representing
    independent payphone providers in Illinois, New York, and
    Ohio. Since the mid-1980s, independent payphone providers
    have competed with Bell Operating Companies in the
    consumer payphone market.          At first, Bell Operating
    Companies had a built-in advantage. In addition to operating
    some payphones, Bell Operating Companies owned the local
    phone lines that provide service to all payphones. An
    independent payphone provider was thus “both a competitor
    and a customer” of the local Bell Operating Company. Davel
    Communications, Inc. v. Qwest Corp., 
    460 F.3d 1075
    , 1081
    (9th Cir. 2006). And that Bell Operating Company could
    exploit its control over the local phone lines by charging
    lower service rates to its own payphones or higher service
    rates to independent payphone providers. See New England
    Public Communications Council, Inc. v. FCC, 
    334 F.3d 69
    ,
    71 (D.C. Cir. 2003).
    To prevent unfair competition in the payphone market,
    Congress included a payphone services provision in the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996. See Pub. L. No. 104-104,
    § 151(a), 
    110 Stat. 56
    , 106. That provision, codified as a new
    4
    Section 276 of the Communications Act of 1934, states that a
    Bell Operating Company may not “subsidize its payphone
    service directly or indirectly” or “prefer or discriminate in
    favor of its payphone service.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (a). To
    implement those statutory proscriptions, Congress directed
    the FCC to prescribe regulations governing Bell Operating
    Company rates. See 
    id.
     § 276(b)(1)(C). And to ensure that
    state laws would not undermine the statutory proscriptions,
    Congress provided that “[t]o the extent that any State
    requirements are inconsistent with the Commission’s
    regulations, the Commission’s regulations on such matters
    shall preempt such State requirements.” Id. § 276(c). 1
    The FCC and the payphone industry have traveled a long
    and winding road in implementing Section 276. We recount
    here only those developments relevant to this case. 2
    In 1996, the FCC issued an initial set of orders
    implementing Section 276. Those orders required Bell
    Operating Companies to file tariffs demonstrating that the
    rates they charged to independent payphone providers
    complied with the requirements of Section 276. The FCC
    directed Bell Operating Companies to file those tariffs with
    state regulatory commissions by January 1997. The FCC
    1
    The full text of Section 276 is reprinted as an appendix to this
    opinion.
    2
    Our prior Section 276 cases describe the implementation of
    the provision in greater detail. See AT&T Corp. v. FCC, 
    363 F.3d 504
     (D.C. Cir. 2004); New England Public Communications
    Council, Inc. v. FCC, 
    334 F.3d 69
     (D.C. Cir. 2003); Global
    Crossing Telecommunications, Inc. v. FCC, 
    259 F.3d 740
     (D.C.
    Cir. 2001); American Public Communications Council v. FCC, 
    215 F.3d 51
     (D.C. Cir. 2000); MCI Telecommunications Corp. v. FCC,
    
    143 F.3d 606
     (D.C. Cir. 1998); Illinois Public Telecommunications
    Association v. FCC, 
    117 F.3d 555
     (D.C. Cir. 1997).
    5
    directed the state regulatory commissions to review the tariffs
    for compliance with Section 276 based on a pricing standard
    known as the “new services test.” State commissions that
    were unable to review the tariffs could order Bell Operating
    Companies in their states to instead file tariffs with the FCC.
    See Order on Reconsideration, Implementation of the Pay
    Telephone Reclassification and Compensation Provisions of
    the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 FCC Rcd. 21,233,
    21,308 ¶ 163 (1996); Report and Order, Implementation of the
    Pay Telephone Reclassification and Compensation Provisions
    of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 11 FCC Rcd. 20,541,
    20,614-15 ¶¶ 146, 147 (1996).
    In Wisconsin, independent payphone providers
    challenged the rates charged by Bell Operating Companies as
    unlawful under Section 276. In 2002, in response to the
    Wisconsin litigation, the FCC issued additional guidance on
    the pricing standard that state commissions must apply in
    determining whether Bell Operating Company rates comply
    with Section 276. See Order Directing Filings, Wisconsin
    Public Service Commission, 17 FCC Rcd. 2051, 2065-71
    ¶¶ 43-65 (2002). The FCC’s new guidance led a number of
    states to conclude that Bell Operating Companies had been
    charging excessive rates. Bell Operating Companies in those
    states thus had to (and did) reduce their rates going forward.
    But the independent payphone providers sought more than
    just prospective relief. They argued that they were entitled to
    refunds dating back to 1997.          Some state regulatory
    commissions and courts agreed and granted full refunds.
    Other states granted partial refunds. Some states granted no
    refunds. See Declaratory Ruling and Order, Implementation
    of the Pay Telephone Reclassification and Compensation
    Provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 28 FCC
    Rcd. 2615, 2621 ¶ 11 & n.37 (2013) (Refund Order).
    6
    Three state proceedings are relevant here. In Illinois, the
    state commission and state courts declined to order refunds
    primarily because of the filed-rate doctrine, which prohibits
    retroactive revisions to rates that a government regulatory
    body has approved. See Illinois Public Telecommunications
    Association v. Illinois Commerce Commission, No. 1-04-0225
    (Ill. App. Ct. Nov. 23, 2005). In New York, the state
    commission and state courts have thus far declined to grant
    refunds but have left the question open pending resolution of
    the independent payphone providers’ petition in this case. See
    Independent Payphone Association of New York, Inc. v.
    Public Service Commission of New York, 
    774 N.Y.S.2d 197
    (N.Y. App. Div. 2004). And in Ohio, the state commission
    awarded partial refunds but the state commission and state
    courts denied the request for refunds back to 1997 based on
    the filed-rate doctrine and state procedural grounds. See
    Payphone Association of Ohio v. Public Utilities Commission
    of Ohio, 
    849 N.E.2d 4
     (Ohio 2006).
    Having failed to gain retrospective relief through state
    regulatory or judicial proceedings, independent payphone
    providers from Illinois, New York, and Ohio sought a
    declaratory ruling from the FCC. See 
    47 C.F.R. § 1.2
    (authority to issue declaratory rulings). They asked the
    Commission to declare that Section 276 created an absolute
    entitlement to refunds dating back to 1997 and that the state
    commissions and courts had violated federal law by denying
    relief. The Commission rejected that position. After
    considering the text, history, and purpose of Section 276, the
    Commission concluded that states “may, but are not required
    to, order refunds” for periods dating back to 1997 in which a
    7
    Bell Operating Company did not have compliant rates in
    effect. Refund Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 2639 ¶ 47. 3
    The independent payphone providers filed petitions for
    review in this Court. See 
    28 U.S.C. § 2342
    (1); 
    47 U.S.C. § 402
    (a).     We assess the FCC’s ruling under the
    Administrative Procedure Act. We must determine whether
    the decision was “arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion,
    or otherwise not in accordance with law.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A).
    II
    The independent payphone providers challenge the
    FCC’s decision on three primary grounds. They contend that
    the Refund Order violates Section 276(a), violates Section
    276(c), and constitutes an arbitrary and capricious exercise of
    the FCC’s discretion. We consider those arguments in turn.
    A
    The independent payphone providers first contend that
    the FCC’s Refund Order unambiguously violates Section
    276(a). That provision says that a Bell Operating Company
    “shall not subsidize its payphone service directly or indirectly
    from its telephone exchange service operations or its
    3
    The dispute here concerns only retrospective relief. As the
    FCC noted, “no party to this proceeding is contending today that
    the payphone line rates are currently out of compliance with”
    Section 276 “or otherwise inconsistent with federal law; rather, the
    sole question is whether certain states improperly denied refunds.”
    Declaratory Ruling and Order, Implementation of the Pay
    Telephone Reclassification and Compensation Provisions of the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, 28 FCC Rcd. 2615, 2635 ¶ 41
    (2013) (Refund Order).
    8
    exchange access operations” and “shall not prefer or
    discriminate in favor of its payphone service.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (a). In the independent payphone providers’ view,
    Section 276(a) establishes an absolute entitlement to refunds
    for periods in which the statute was violated.
    The problem for the independent payphone providers is
    that Congress said nothing of the sort. In cases where a Bell
    Operating Company violates the proscriptions established by
    Section 276(a), the statute does not say whether only
    prospective relief is in order, or whether retrospective relief is
    also required. In particular, Section 276(a) does not say that
    refunds are required, or that refunds are not required, or
    anything at all about refunds. Rather, as this Court has
    previously recognized, Section 276(a) is “silent regarding the
    mechanism the FCC should adopt to ensure that the statute’s
    requirements are carried out.”               Global Crossing
    Telecommunications, Inc. v. FCC, 
    259 F.3d 740
    , 744 (D.C.
    Cir. 2001).
    Section 276(a)’s silence on refunds is telling given that
    Congress has expressly specified refund remedies in other
    sections of the Communications Act of 1934 and related
    statutes. See 47 U.S.C §§ 228(f)(1), 543(c)(1)(C); see also
    
    15 U.S.C. § 5711
    (a)(2)(I). Indeed, several of those provisions
    originated in statutes enacted shortly before the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, an indication that Congress
    in 1996 was fully capable of specifying a refund remedy when
    it wanted to require one. See Telephone Disclosure and
    Dispute Resolution Act, § 101, Pub. L. No. 102-556, 
    106 Stat. 4181
    , 4185 (1992); Cable Television Consumer Protection
    and Competition Act of 1992, § 3(a), Pub. L. No. 102-385,
    
    106 Stat. 1460
    , 1468. Congress’s decision not to include a
    refund remedy in Section 276 thus suggests that it intended to
    leave remedial discretion with the Commission.            That
    9
    interpretation is consistent with the general principle that
    agencies ordinarily have wide discretion to shape remedies for
    statutory violations. See AT&T Co. v. FCC, 
    454 F.3d 329
    ,
    334 (D.C. Cir. 2006).
    In sum, Section 276(a) does not speak to the refund
    question. And one of the first principles of administrative law
    is that “if the statute is silent or ambiguous with respect to the
    specific issue,” the only question for the court is whether the
    agency’s interpretation of that statute is reasonable. City of
    Arlington v. FCC, 
    133 S. Ct. 1863
    , 1868 (2013) (quoting
    Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. NRDC, 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 843 (1984)).
    Whatever the policy virtues of the independent payphone
    providers’ position, we will not read into the statute a
    mandatory provision that Congress declined to supply. See
    ANTONIN SCALIA & BRYAN A. GARNER, READING LAW: THE
    INTERPRETATION OF LEGAL TEXTS 93 (2012) (omitted-case
    canon). We instead conclude that FCC has discretion to fill
    Section 276’s gap with a reasonable approach to the refund
    question. Cf. Global Crossing, 
    259 F.3d at 744-45
    ; Illinois
    Public Telecommunications Association v. FCC, 
    117 F.3d 555
    , 567-68 (D.C. Cir. 1997). And for reasons explained in
    greater depth below, the Commission’s decision was
    reasonable. 4
    4
    In their reply brief, the independent payphone providers
    contend that the FCC’s discretion is constrained by Section 206 of
    the Communications Act, which provides that a carrier violating the
    Act “shall be liable to the person or persons injured thereby for the
    full amount of damages sustained.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 206
    . By failing to
    raise this issue until their reply brief, the independent payphone
    providers forfeited the argument. We therefore do not consider it.
    See Lake Carriers’ Association v. EPA, 
    652 F.3d 1
    , 10 n.9 (D.C.
    Cir. 2011).
    10
    B
    The independent payphone providers next contend that
    the Refund Order contravenes Section 276(c). That provision
    says that “[t]o the extent that any State requirements are
    inconsistent with the Commission’s regulations, the
    Commission’s regulations on such matters shall preempt such
    State requirements.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (c). The independent
    payphone providers argue that the FCC’s 2013 Refund Order
    permits refunds dating back to April 1997, and that any state
    decision denying refunds is “inconsistent with the
    Commission’s regulations” and preempted. 
    Id.
    That argument rests on a misreading of the FCC’s Refund
    Order. The Commission repeatedly explained that states
    “may, but are not required to, order refunds” for any period in
    which Bell Operating Companies charged non-compliant
    rates. Refund Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 2639 ¶ 47 (emphases
    added); see 
    id.
     at 2636 ¶ 42 n.178 (same); 
    id.
     at 2640 ¶ 49
    (same). Put differently, the fact that states may order refunds
    does not mean that states must order refunds. Therefore, a
    state commission or state court decision that considers a
    Section 276 claim and denies refunds – as happened in the
    three states at issue here – is not inconsistent with the FCC’s
    regulations and is not preempted. See 
    id.
     at 2634-35 ¶¶ 40-
    41. That conclusion is further buttressed by the deference that
    this Court affords to the FCC’s reasonable interpretations of
    its own regulations. See Auer v. Robbins, 
    519 U.S. 452
    , 461
    (1997); Global Crossing, 
    259 F.3d at 746
    .
    In a twist on their Section 276(c) preemption argument,
    the independent payphone providers contend that the FCC’s
    reliance on state refund determinations constitutes an
    unlawful subdelegation of federal authority to the States. As
    an initial matter, states do not require any subdelegation of
    11
    authority from the FCC to adjudicate federal statutory claims.
    In our federal system, state tribunals have the constitutional
    authority and duty to apply federal statutes and determine
    statutorily appropriate remedies. See U.S. Const. art. VI, cl.
    2; Burt v. Titlow, 
    134 S. Ct. 10
    , 15 (2013) (“State courts are
    adequate forums for the vindication of federal rights.”);
    Tafflin v. Levitt, 
    493 U.S. 455
    , 470 (1990) (Scalia, J.,
    concurring) (“As Congress made no provision concerning the
    remedy, the federal and the state courts have concurrent
    jurisdiction.”) (alteration omitted). Indeed, the independent
    payphone providers do not contest the FCC’s decision to have
    state regulatory commissions determine whether Bell
    Operating Company rates comply with Section 276 in the first
    instance. See Oral Arg. at 3:41-4:07. They object only to the
    FCC’s decision not to override state decisions denying
    refunds in particular cases. But Congress said nothing about
    who should decide whether to award refunds for violations of
    Section 276. That statutory silence sets this case apart from
    United States Telecom Association v. FCC, 
    359 F.3d 554
    (D.C. Cir. 2004), the leading example of an unlawful
    subdelegation relied upon by the independent payphone
    providers. In the statutory provision at issue in that case,
    Congress had expressly directed “the Commission” to make
    certain determinations. 
    359 F.3d at 565
     (emphasis added).
    As the FCC correctly explained here, “Nothing in section 276
    requires that the Commission be the arbiter of specific refund
    disputes.” Refund Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 2635 ¶ 41. We
    therefore reject the subdelegation claim.
    C
    Because the FCC’s interpretation in the Refund Order is
    not inconsistent with Section 276(a) or Section 276(c), the
    only remaining question is whether the Commission’s
    approach was arbitrary or capricious. See Chevron, 
    467 U.S. 12
    at 844. That is not a high bar for the FCC to clear. As this
    Court explained in another Section 276 case: “Although the
    enforcement regime chosen by the Commission may not be
    the only one possible, we must uphold it as long as it is a
    reasonable means of implementing the statutory
    requirements.” Global Crossing, 
    259 F.3d at 745
    .
    Here, the FCC readily satisfied that deferential standard.
    The Commission reasonably concluded that “states, as part of
    their tariff review responsibilities, are well-positioned to
    resolve refund disputes arising from the tariffs they review.”
    Refund Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 2636 ¶ 42. The FCC
    recognized that it was not adopting a “single, federal policy”
    governing refunds and that some state-to-state variation
    would naturally result. 
    Id.
     at 2636 ¶ 42 n.178; see 
    id.
     at 2640
    ¶ 48. Moreover, an independent payphone provider can opt
    for a federal decisionmaker by suing a Bell Operating
    Company for a Section 276 violation in federal court. See 
    47 U.S.C. § 207
    . And of course, a party who believes that a state
    court has misapplied federal law can ultimately seek review
    of the state court judgment in the U.S. Supreme Court. See
    U.S. Const. art. III, §§ 1, 2; 
    28 U.S.C. § 1257
    . The Illinois
    independent payphone providers unsuccessfully sought to do
    just that. See 
    549 U.S. 1205
     (2007) (denying certiorari).
    The independent payphone providers contend that the
    FCC’s approach is arbitrary and capricious because it leads to
    refund determinations that vary from state to state. But there
    is nothing inherently arbitrary or capricious about state-to-
    state variation, especially in the administration of a statute
    based in part on cooperative federalism – that is, a statute that
    relies in part on states to implement federal law. See
    generally Heather K. Gerken, Federalism as the New
    Nationalism: An Overview, 123 YALE L.J. 1889 (2014); Abbe
    R. Gluck, Our [National] Federalism, 123 YALE L.J. 1996
    13
    (2014). As this Court has explained, the Communications Act
    establishes a “system of dual state and federal regulation over
    telephone service” that recognizes states’ traditional role in
    the rate regulation process.          New England Public
    Communications Council, Inc. v. FCC, 
    334 F.3d 69
    , 75 (D.C.
    Cir. 2003) (quoting Louisiana Public Service Commission v.
    FCC, 
    476 U.S. 355
    , 360 (1986)); see 
    47 U.S.C. §§ 151
    ,
    152(b); see also City of Rancho Palos Verdes v. Abrams, 
    544 U.S. 113
    , 128 (2005) (Breyer, J., concurring)
    (Communications Act based on “cooperative federalism”
    framework). The Act authorizes the FCC to preempt state
    law in certain areas, and the FCC has exercised that authority
    by requiring states to review Bell Operating Company tariffs
    under a uniform national pricing standard. See New England
    Public, 
    334 F.3d at 75-78
    . But there is nothing arbitrary or
    capricious about the FCC’s decision not to further exercise its
    preemptive power to dictate a uniform national answer to the
    refund question, especially given the backdrop of state
    involvement in the ratemaking process. Cf. Batterton v.
    Francis, 
    432 U.S. 416
    , 430 (1977) (federal agency can defer
    to local definition of “unemployment” in administering joint
    federal-state welfare program).
    The independent payphone providers object in particular
    to states’ invocation of the filed-rate doctrine – the prohibition
    on retroactively changing approved rates. But the filed-rate
    doctrine has long been “a central tenet of telecommunications
    law,” so it hardly seems unreasonable or arbitrary for the FCC
    to allow states to invoke that doctrine. TON Services, Inc. v.
    Qwest Corp., 
    493 F.3d 1225
    , 1236 (10th Cir. 2007); see
    Arizona Grocery Co. v. Atchison, Topeka & Santa Fe Railway
    Co., 
    284 U.S. 370
    , 390 (1932). Moreover, the filed-rate
    doctrine does not present an insuperable barrier to refunds or
    otherwise negate the FCC’s position that refunds are
    permitted in individual cases. Indeed, the FCC expressly
    14
    recognized that several states have granted refunds
    notwithstanding the filed-rate doctrine. See Refund Order, 28
    FCC Rcd. at 2640 ¶ 48 (citing Indiana and South Carolina
    commission decisions).
    In sum, we see nothing unreasonable about how the FCC
    filled the statutory gap and exercised its discretion.
    III
    As an alternative, the independent payphone providers
    have sought refunds through a less direct route. They asked
    the FCC to order Bell Operating Companies to disgorge
    certain payments that those companies had received from
    long-distance carriers (not from independent payphone
    providers). The independent payphone providers would not
    benefit directly from such a disgorgement order. But they
    believed that such an order would induce Bell Operating
    Companies to pay refunds to the independent payphone
    providers as a way to avoid complying with the disgorgement
    order. The FCC declined to issue the requested order. The
    independent payphone providers renew the claim in this
    Court. But they lack Article III standing to pursue their claim
    in this Court.
    In Section 276, Congress ordered the FCC to “establish a
    per call compensation plan to ensure that all payphone service
    providers are fairly compensated for each and every
    completed intrastate and interstate call using their payphone.”
    
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A). That provision responded to the
    development of long-distance access codes and 800 numbers
    that allowed callers to use payphones without depositing
    coins, thereby depriving payphone operators of revenue. The
    FCC issued a rule requiring the long-distance carriers who
    benefited from such “dial-around” calls to compensate
    15
    payphone providers. Sprint Communications Co. v. APCC
    Services, Inc., 
    554 U.S. 269
    , 271-72 (2008); see also 
    47 U.S.C. § 226
    ; 
    47 C.F.R. § 64.1300
    .
    Of relevance here, the FCC stated that the eligibility of
    Bell Operating Companies to receive “dial-around”
    compensation from long-distance carriers depended on the
    Bell Operating Companies’ compliance with Section 276.
    See Refund Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 2633-34 ¶ 38. Bell
    Operating Companies, believing their rates compliant with
    Section 276, began collecting dial-around compensation from
    long-distance carriers in 1997. But as explained above, some
    states later concluded that Bell Operating Companies’ rates
    had not actually been compliant with Section 276 in the
    several years after 1997.       The independent payphone
    providers asked the FCC to order Bell Operating Companies
    to forfeit the payments they had received from the long-
    distance carriers during those years to the Government. The
    Commission declined to issue such an order. See 
    id.
     at 2633-
    34 ¶ 38 n.161.
    We do not reach the merits of the independent payphone
    providers’ petitions for review on that issue because they lack
    Article III standing to challenge that aspect of the
    Commission’s decision.          To establish standing, the
    independent payphone providers must show an injury-in-fact
    caused by the Commission’s conduct and redressable by this
    Court. See Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife, 
    504 U.S. 555
    , 560-
    61 (1992). Here, the independent payphone providers assert
    an injury-in-fact: “paying years of excessive charges caused
    by” the Bell Operating Companies’ “failure to have . . .
    compliant rates.” Pet’rs Br. 34; see Oral Arg. at 14:37-14:40
    (“the injury is the overcharging of rates”). But that injury is
    not redressable by this Court. Even if we ordered the FCC to
    do exactly what the independent payphone providers seek –
    16
    order Bell Operating Companies to disgorge the payments
    they received from long-distance carriers – the independent
    payphone providers would not receive any of that money.
    Rather, Bell Operating Companies would forfeit the money to
    the Government. See App. 847; Oral Arg. at 13:37-13:39.
    That would do nothing to redress the injury suffered by the
    independent payphone providers as a result of the allegedly
    excessive rates charged to them by Bell Operating
    Companies.      Cf. Steel Co. v. Citizens for a Better
    Environment, 
    523 U.S. 83
    , 106 (1998) (no standing where
    plaintiff “seeks not remediation of its own injury” that has
    abated but rather general “vindication of the rule of law”).
    The independent payphone providers respond with a
    rather creative theory of redressability. They suggest that Bell
    Operating Companies would rather accede to their demand for
    refunds than disgorge the supposedly larger amount of dial-
    around compensation collected from long-distance carriers.
    Thus, in the independent payphone providers’ view, an FCC
    disgorgement order would in turn induce Bell Operating
    Companies to resolve their refund dispute with the
    independent payphone providers and thereby redress the
    independent payphone providers’ injury. The independent
    payphone providers offer nothing beyond sheer speculation to
    support their bank-shot approach. And it is well-established
    that a “merely speculative” theory of redressability does not
    suffice to create Article III standing. Sprint, 
    554 U.S. at 273
    (internal quotation marks omitted); see Lujan, 
    504 U.S. at 560-61
    ; Linda R.S. v. Richard D., 
    410 U.S. 614
    , 617-18
    (1973); cf. Illinois Public Telecommunications Association v.
    Illinois Commerce Commission, No. 1-04-0225 (Ill. App. Ct.
    Nov. 23, 2005) (same conclusion on state law).
    Because the independent payphone providers have not
    demonstrated Article III standing with respect to their dial-
    17
    around compensation claim, we lack jurisdiction to adjudicate
    that portion of their petitions for review.
    ***
    We have carefully considered all of the independent
    payphone providers’ arguments. We deny the petitions in part
    and dismiss the remainder for lack of jurisdiction.
    So ordered.
    18
    APPENDIX
    § 276. Provision of payphone service
    (a) Nondiscrimination safeguards
    After the effective date of the rules prescribed pursuant to
    subsection (b) of this section, any Bell operating company
    that provides payphone service –
    (1) shall not subsidize its payphone service directly
    or indirectly from its telephone exchange service
    operations or its exchange access operations; and
    (2) shall not prefer or discriminate in favor of its
    payphone service.
    (b) Regulations
    (1) Contents of regulations
    In order to promote competition among payphone
    service providers and promote the widespread
    deployment of payphone services to the benefit of the
    general public, within 9 months after February 8, 1996,
    the Commission shall take all actions necessary
    (including any reconsideration) to prescribe regulations
    that –
    (A) establish a per call compensation plan to ensure
    that all payphone service providers are fairly
    compensated for each and every completed intrastate and
    interstate call using their payphone, except that
    emergency calls and telecommunications relay service
    calls for hearing disabled individuals shall not be subject
    to such compensation;
    (B) discontinue the intrastate and interstate carrier
    access charge payphone service elements and payments
    in effect on February 8, 1996, and all intrastate and
    interstate payphone subsidies from basic exchange and
    19
    exchange access revenues, in favor of a compensation
    plan as specified in subparagraph (A);
    (C) prescribe a set of nonstructural safeguards for
    Bell operating company payphone service to implement
    the provisions of paragraphs (1) and (2) of subsection (a)
    of this section, which safeguards shall, at a minimum,
    include the nonstructural safeguards equal to those
    adopted in the Computer Inquiry-III (CC Docket No. 90-
    623) proceeding;
    (D) provide for Bell operating company payphone
    service providers to have the same right that independent
    payphone providers have to negotiate with the location
    provider on the location provider’s selecting and
    contracting with, and, subject to the terms of any
    agreement with the location provider, to select and
    contract with, the carriers that carry interLATA calls
    from their payphones, unless the Commission determines
    in the rulemaking pursuant to this section that it is not in
    the public interest; and
    (E) provide for all payphone service providers to
    have the right to negotiate with the location provider on
    the location provider’s selecting and contracting with,
    and, subject to the terms of any agreement with the
    location provider, to select and contract with, the carriers
    that carry intraLATA calls from their payphones.
    (2) Public interest telephones
    In the rulemaking conducted pursuant to paragraph
    (1), the Commission shall determine whether public
    interest payphones, which are provided in the interest of
    public health, safety, and welfare, in locations where
    there would otherwise not be a payphone, should be
    maintained, and if so, ensure that such public interest
    payphones are supported fairly and equitably.
    20
    (3) Existing contracts
    Nothing in this section shall affect any existing
    contracts between location providers and payphone
    service providers or interLATA or intraLATA carriers
    that are in force and effect as of February 8, 1996.
    (c) State preemption
    To the extent that any State requirements are inconsistent
    with the Commission’s regulations, the Commission’s
    regulations on such matters shall preempt such State
    requirements.
    (d) “Payphone service” defined
    As used in this section, the term “payphone service”
    means the provision of public or semi-public pay telephones,
    the provision of inmate telephone service in correctional
    institutions, and any ancillary services.