Transm. Agency of Northern CA v. FERC ( 2010 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued October 21, 2010           Decided December 10, 2010
    No. 09-1213
    TRANSMISSION AGENCY OF NORTHERN CALIFORNIA,
    PETITIONER
    v.
    FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION,
    RESPONDENT
    CITY OF REDDING, CALIFORNIA, ET AL.,
    INTERVENORS
    Consolidated with Nos. 09-1216, 09-1217,
    09-1245, 09-1246, 09-1247
    On Petitions for Review of Orders
    of the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    Michael Postar and Harvey L. Reiter argued the cause for
    petitioners. With them on the briefs were Bhaveeta K. Mody,
    Jon R. Stickman, Abigail Briggerman, Sean M. Neal, John
    McCaffrey, Peter J. Scanlon, and Jason T. Gray. Lisa S. Gast,
    Matthew R. Rudolphi, and Marie D. Zosa entered appearances.
    2
    Joseph B. Nelson, Deborah A. Swanstrom, and Lodie D.
    White were on the briefs for intervenors Imperial Irrigation
    District and City of Los Angeles Department of Water and
    Power in support of petitioners.
    Samuel Soopper, Attorney, Federal Energy Regulatory
    Commission, argued the cause for respondent. With him on the
    brief were Thomas R. Sheets, General Counsel, and Robert H.
    Solomon, Solicitor.
    Daniel J. Shonkwiler argued the cause for intervenors
    California Independent System Operator Corporation and
    Southern California Edison Company in support of respondent.
    With him on the brief were Nancy J. Saracino, Roger E.
    Collanton, Jennifer R. Hasbrouck, Erin K. Moore, and Mark R.
    Huffman. Erin K. Moore and Mark D. Patrizio entered
    appearances.
    Before: GINSBURG, HENDERSON and ROGERS, Circuit
    Judges.
    Opinion for the Court by Circuit Judge ROGERS.
    3
    ROGERS, Circuit Judge: Various municipalities1 petition for
    review of two Federal Energy Regulatory Commission orders
    conditionally approving the California Independent System
    Operator (“CAISO”)’s proposal to create an Integrated
    Balancing Authority Area (“IBAA”) by combining the
    Sacramento Municipal Utility District (“SMUD”) and the
    Turlock Irrigation District (“Turlock”) for the purpose of pricing
    transactions. We deny the petitions for review.
    I.
    The court has recently summarized much of the pertinent
    background in Sacramento Municipal Utility District v. FERC,
    
    616 F.3d 520
    , 523-24 (D.C. Cir. 2010), a related case. Following
    the Commission’s promulgation of Order No. 888, which called
    for nationwide deregulation of electricity transmission and
    encouraged public utilities to participate in regional transmission
    organizations and independent system operators, the California
    legislature in 1996 created the CAISO to operate transmission
    and other ancillary services on parts of the California electric
    power system. In response to the 2000 California energy crisis,
    the CAISO, at the Commission’s behest, began redesigning the
    California electricity market to foster greater reliability and
    1
    Petitioners are the Sacramento Municipal Utility District, the
    Turlock Irrigation District, the Modesto Irrigation District, the City of
    Redding, the City of Santa Clara d/b/a Silicon Valley Power, and the
    Transmission Agency of Northern California (“TANC”), a joint
    exercise of powers agency partially comprised of the other petitioners.
    Petitioners are considered “municipalities” under the Federal Power
    Act, see 
    16 U.S.C. § 796
    (7). This is also true for municipal
    intervenors (“Municipals”), such as the Imperial Irrigation District and
    the City of Los Angeles Department of Water and Power. For ease of
    reference, the opinion does not identify individual parties.
    4
    economic efficiency on its system.2 In 2008, the CAISO filed
    proposed revisions to its existing tariff and the Market Redesign
    and Technology Upgrade Tariff, which it described as “a
    comprehensive redesign of the California electricity markets . . .
    aimed at enhancing reliability and increasing the efficient
    utilization of the CAISO Controlled Grid.”                CAISO,
    Amendments to MRTU Tariff Provisions, at 1, Docket No.
    ER08-1113-000 (June 17, 2008) (“IBAA Proposal”). The
    amended tariff would: (1) implement locational marginal
    pricing3; (2) implement a full network model of the transmission
    system to improve dispatch efficiency; (3) include day-ahead and
    real-time energy markets; and (4) ensure that day-ahead
    schedules are physically feasible. The Commission has
    approved the market redesign in a series of orders, two of which
    concern the CAISO’s IBAA Proposal and are challenged here.
    Order Conditionally Accepting Tariff Changes and Directing
    Compliance Filing, 
    124 FERC ¶ 61,271
     (Sept. 19, 2008)
    (“Order”); Order on Rehearing and Clarification, 
    128 FERC ¶ 61,103
     (July 30, 2009) (“Rehearing Order”).
    2
    “An [Independent System Operator (“ISO”)] is an
    independent company that has operational control, but not ownership,
    of the transmission facilities owned by member utilities. ISOs provide
    open access to the regional transmission system to all electricity
    generators at rates established in a single, unbundled, grid-wide tariff
    . . . .” NRG Power Mktg., LLC v. Maine Pub. Utils. Comm’n, 
    130 S. Ct. 693
    , 697 n.1 (2010) (ellipsis in original) (citation and internal
    quotation marks omitted).
    3
    Under a locational marginal price rate design, energy prices
    vary by location and time in order to reflect the cost of energy,
    including the cost of transmission losses and congestion, at each
    location on the CAISO-controlled grid. Sacramento Mun., 
    616 F.3d at 524-25
    . As such, “prices are designed to reflect the least-cost of
    meeting an incremental megawatt-hour of demand at each location on
    the grid.” 
    Id. at 524
    .
    5
    According to the CAISO, the “most important objective” of
    its proposal was to “protect CAISO ratepayers from unjust and
    unreasonable prices that may result in the absence of the CAISO
    having accurate information . . . to verify the location of external
    resources.” IBAA Proposal at 2. The CAISO’s inability to
    verify the location of external resources stemmed from
    California’s and the Pacific Northwest’s electricity transmission
    infrastructure. The California-Oregon Intertie, which delivers
    electricity from the Pacific Northwest to central California, is
    comprised of three 500 kilovolt power lines that run parallel to
    each other. The first line, the California-Oregon Transmission
    Project (“COTP”), runs from the Captain Jack substation in
    Oregon to the Tesla substation in central California, ending at the
    Olinda substation. TANC is a participant in, and the project
    manager of, the COTP. The COTP is generally located within
    the SMUD balancing authority area and is not part of the
    CAISO-controlled grid. The remaining two lines, known
    collectively as the Pacific AC Intertie (“PACI”) and at times
    referred to individually as “PACI-P” and “PACI-W,” run from
    the Malin substation in Oregon to the Tracy substation in central
    California, ending at the Round Mountain substation. The PACI
    is physically located within the geographic area of the CAISO-
    controlled grid, although the CAISO is not an owner of the
    PACI. The Captain Jack substation and the Malin substation are
    electrically connected; likewise the Tesla substation and the
    Tracy substation are electrically connected. The basic structure
    6
    of the California-Oregon Intertie looks like this:
    The IBAA Proposal focuses on SMUD and Turlock, two
    independent but interconnected “balancing authority areas,” see
    Sacramento Mun., 
    616 F.3d at
    524 n.2, that draw power from the
    Pacific Northwest over the California-Oregon Intertie when
    purchasing this power is cheaper than generating it locally.
    Together they have twelve interconnections with the CAISO-
    controlled grid. The CAISO was concerned that it would be
    unable to model power flows and calculate locational marginal
    prices accurately for these entities due to “parallel flows,” also
    known as “unscheduled flows.” Although a “scheduled” or
    “contract” flow is planned between two points over a specific
    path, the power does not always flow over the scheduled route if
    there are other paths; it flows over the path of least resistance,
    creating a parallel flow. In some instances, as in the California-
    Oregon Intertie, the presence of parallel lines means that when
    a scheduled flow occurs there will necessarily be an unscheduled
    flow over parallel lines.
    The CAISO’s proposed solution in the IBAA Proposal was
    two-fold. It first combined SMUD and Turlock into a single
    IBAA for purposes of the full network model. And, second, to
    7
    rectify concerns regarding market manipulation and to model the
    IBAA connection points more accurately, the IBAA Proposal
    used a “single hub” approach whereby one default proxy price
    would be selected for all twelve connection points: All imports
    into the CAISO system from the IBAA would be priced as if
    they originated at the Captain Jack substation in Oregon; all
    exports from the CAISO system to the IBAA would be priced at
    a hypothetical “SMUD hub.” Alternatively, SMUD and Turlock
    or future IBAA entities could enter into individual market
    efficiency enhancement agreements (“MEEAs”) with the CAISO
    to receive a more accurate pricing structure upon providing the
    CAISO with information allowing it to verify the location and
    operation of the resources used to carry out interchange
    transactions between the CAISO-controlled grid and the IBAA.
    The CAISO explained that the elements of its single hub,
    default pricing point proposal were justified by and “result[ed]
    directly from the limited type and amount of information the
    CAISO expects to receive from the IBAA [e]ntities.” IBAA
    Proposal at 5. The Commission agreed, concluding that “by
    using a more accurate representation of the locations of external
    resources used to implement interchange transactions in the
    CAISO’s full network model the IBAA [P]roposal will help to
    ensure that interchange transactions from the SMUD and Turlock
    balancing authority areas are appropriately valued for purposes
    of managing congestion on the CAISO-controlled grid, and
    reduce the likelihood of significant differences between
    scheduled flows and actual flows.” Order ¶ 5. Accordingly, the
    Commission found the CAISO tariff, as amended by the IBAA
    Proposal, was “just and reasonable” under the Federal Power Act
    (“FPA”), 16 U.S.C. § 824d, but conditioned its approval on the
    modification of the IBAA Proposal in several ways, including
    that the CAISO address potential over-collection for charges
    based upon losses of energy during transmission due to the
    modeling of parallel flows, specify in its tariff the information to
    8
    be provided for establishing MEEAs, and treat such information
    as confidential. See Order ¶¶ 6 & n.6, 8. The CAISO satisfied
    the conditions in additional filings and the Commission denied
    rehearing, rejecting various challenges, some of which are
    renewed in the pending petitions. See Rehearing Order ¶ 1.
    II.
    Petitioners challenge the Commission’s jurisdiction to
    review and approve a tariff amendment governing the pricing of
    electricity in the CAISO market, and also contend that the
    Commission’s acceptance of the IBAA Proposal amending the
    CAISO tariff was neither a reasonable exercise of its discretion
    under the FPA nor supported by substantial evidence of record.
    The court “review[s] [the Commission’s] orders under the
    arbitrary and capricious standard and uphold[s] [the
    Commission’s] factual findings if supported by substantial
    evidence.” Am. Gas Ass’n v. FERC, 
    593 F.3d 14
    , 19 (D.C. Cir.
    2010) (citation and quotation marks omitted). The court must
    affirm the Commission’s orders “so long as [the Commission]
    examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a . . . rational
    connection between the facts found and the choice made. In
    matters of ratemaking, our review is highly deferential, as
    [i]ssues of rate design are fairly technical and, insofar as they are
    not technical, involve policy judgments that lie at the core of the
    regulatory mission.” Alcoa Inc. v. FERC, 
    564 F.3d 1342
    , 1347
    (D.C. Cir. 2009) (second, third, and fourth alterations and ellipsis
    in original) (citations and internal quotation marks omitted).
    Nonetheless, the Commission must respond to objections and
    address contrary evidence in more than a cursory fashion. See
    NorAm Gas Transmission Co. v. FERC, 
    148 F.3d 1158
    , 1163-65
    (D.C. Cir. 1998). In reviewing the Commission’s assertion of
    jurisdiction under the FPA and its interpretation of a
    Commission-approved contract, the court applies the familiar
    9
    two-step analysis under Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. NRDC, 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 842-44 (1984). See S. Cal. Edison Co. v. FERC, 
    502 F.3d 176
    , 181 (D.C. Cir. 2007); Transmission Agency of N. Cal. v.
    FERC, 
    495 F.3d 663
    , 673 (D.C. Cir. 2007) (“TANC”).
    A.
    Jurisdiction. FPA Section 201(f) provides that “[n]o
    provision in . . . subchapter [II regulating electric utility
    companies engaged in interstate commerce] shall apply to, or be
    deemed to include . . . any political subdivision of a State . . . or
    any agency, authority, or instrumentality of . . . the foregoing . .
    . unless such provision makes specific reference thereto.” 
    16 U.S.C. § 824
    (f). Section 205 requires the Commission to ensure
    that the rates and charges “made, demanded, or received by any
    public utility” are “just and reasonable.” 
    Id.
     § 824d(a). Section
    201(e), in turn, defines “public utility” to be “any person who
    owns or operates facilities subject to the jurisdiction of the
    Commission.” Id. § 824(e). The court has concluded that by
    these provisions “Congress has . . . specifically exempted
    governmental entities from subchapter II of the FPA.” TANC,
    
    495 F.3d at 674
    .
    Petitioners, joined by intervenor Municipals, contend that
    the Commission exceeded its jurisdiction in approving the IBAA
    Proposal because FPA Section 201(f) “unequivocally exempts”
    governmental entities from the Commission’s rate-setting
    authority under FPA Sections 205 and 206, 
    id.,
     and their
    voluntary participation in such markets does not give the
    Commission authority to regulate their rates, Bonneville Power
    Admin. v. FERC, 
    422 F.3d 908
    , 924 (9th Cir. 2005). The
    Commission rejected this challenge, concluding that approving
    the IBAA Proposal was within its “core authority” for four
    principal reasons: (1) the amended CAISO tariff applied only to
    scheduled transactions that affect the CAISO-controlled grid and
    the IBAA Proposal “establishes only the rates, terms and
    10
    conditions for sales in the CAISO’s market”; (2) in National
    Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners v. FERC, 
    475 F.3d 1277
     (D.C. Cir. 2007) (“NARUC”), the court upheld the
    Commission’s authority to regulate all aspects of wholesale
    energy sales; (3) an IBAA entity’s voluntary choice to participate
    in the CAISO market includes a choice to operate under the
    CAISO tariff; and (4) Bonneville, which addressed the
    Commission’s authority to order refunds under FPA Section 206,
    does not limit the Commission’s jurisdiction here because it was
    not ordering a non-jurisdictional entity to issue a refund. See
    Rehearing Order ¶¶ 20-25. Petitioners and Municipals maintain
    that these four bases for exercising jurisdiction impermissibly
    focus on the nature of the transactions and not the identity of the
    sellers. As noted, the court affords Chevron deference to the
    Commission’s interpretation of its jurisdiction under the FPA.
    See TANC, 
    495 F.3d at 673
    .
    Although the jurisdictional line was more easily drawn when
    the electricity world was “neatly divided into spheres of retail
    versus wholesale sales, and local distribution versus transmission
    facilities,” the “unbundling” of services and the general
    restructuring of electricity markets in the last two decades has
    made line-drawing more complex. Transmission Access Policy
    Study Group v. FERC, 
    225 F.3d 667
    , 691 (D.C. Cir. 2000).
    Rather than allowing the mere presence of a governmental entity
    to defeat the Commission’s assertion of jurisdiction over a public
    utility, the court has accepted that jurisdictional and non-
    jurisdictional entities are regularly integrated co-participants in
    modern power markets. Thus, in NARUC, 
    475 F.3d at 1281
    ,
    where facilities were jointly owned by private firms and states,
    the court held that the Commission’s “assertion of jurisdiction
    over specified transactions, even though affecting the conduct of
    the [state] owner(s) with respect to its facilities, is not per se an
    exercise of jurisdiction over the facility,” observing that the
    contract modifications mandated by Order No. 888 forced non-
    11
    jurisdictional owners to permit certain transactions to occur over
    the jointly owned facility. 
    Id. at 1281-82
    . The court observed
    that the Commission was “exercising jurisdiction only over
    ‘interconnections to a “distribution” facility when the facility is
    included in a public utility’s Commission-filed [Open Access
    Transmission Tariff] and the interconnection is for the purpose
    of facilitating a jurisdictional wholesale sale of electric energy.’”
    
    Id. at 1282
     (emphasis added in opinion) (quoting Order No.
    2003-A, 
    106 FERC ¶ 61,220
     (2004), at 31,
    075 P 730
    ). Likewise,
    “[the Commission] may analyze and consider the rates of non-
    jurisdictional utilities to the extent that those rates affect
    jurisdictional transactions.” TANC, 
    495 F.3d at 671
     (citation and
    quotation marks omitted).
    In Sacramento Municipal, 
    616 F.3d 520
    , the court rejected
    a challenge to the Commission’s jurisdiction to approve the
    initial, pre-IBAA Proposal phases of the CAISO’s market
    redesign, including its decision to implement locational marginal
    pricing. The Imperial Irrigation District argued in that case that
    the Commission exceeded its authority in assessing marginal loss
    charges to transactions involving Imperial’s use of transmission
    ownership rights, i.e., contractual entitlements to use facilities it
    owns within the CAISO balancing authority area. See 
    id.
     at 535-
    36. The Commission responded by making clear that marginal
    loss charges would be applied “only to transactions that . . .
    involve injections and withdrawals from the [CAISO] grid and
    could not be assessed where the [transmission ownership rights]
    holder has no point of interface with the [CAISO].” 
    Id. at 536
    (ellipsis and second alteration in original) (citation and internal
    quotation marks omitted). The court upheld the Commission’s
    assertion of jurisdiction:
    Far from compelling Imperial [Irrigation District] to
    become a participating transmission owner of
    California ISO, [the Commission] merely permitted the
    12
    ISO to charge Imperial for the costs incurred by the ISO
    when Imperial conducts transactions that cause
    transmission losses on the ISO’s grid.               The
    Commission’s proper exercise of its power to regulate
    California ISO’s rates was not transformed into a
    violation of its statutory jurisdiction by dint of its
    incidental effect on Imperial.
    
    Id.
     The Commission was not charging Imperial to use its own
    facilities; rather, the charges stemmed solely from Imperial’s use
    of CAISO-controlled facilities and attendant services. 
    Id. at 537
    .
    The court noted a similar distinction had been drawn in Michigan
    Public Power Agency v. FERC, 
    405 F.3d 8
    , 13 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
    The same reasoning controls here. In denying rehearing, the
    Commission emphasized that “[t]he IBAA Proposal is . . .
    limited, only applying to scheduled transactions that impact the
    CAISO-controlled grid.” Rehearing Order ¶ 21. And “since the
    IBAA Proposal only applies to scheduled transactions that
    impact the CAISO-controlled grid, only a party that chooses to
    use the CAISO-controlled grid is affected.” Id. ¶ 23. In short,
    “the IBAA Proposal establishes only the rates, terms and
    conditions for sales in the CAISO’s markets.” Id. ¶ 25.
    Although petitioners and Municipals would distinguish
    Sacramento Municipal because the IBAA Proposal’s regulation
    of the rate at which non-jurisdictional entities may sell energy to
    the CAISO is not, in their view, an “incidental effect” of
    regulating jurisdictional entities, the fact remains that the
    Commission is only regulating the CAISO’s actions and the
    manner in which it calculates rates on the CAISO-controlled
    grid. Petitioners’ and Municipals’ rates are not the object of the
    Commission’s Orders, and the Commission does not purport to
    interfere impermissibly with the manner in which these
    municipalities calculate their own rates. See NARUC, 
    475 F.3d at 1280
    . In the highly integrated and complex California energy
    13
    market, the Commission’s regulation of a jurisdictional entity,
    such as the CAISO, “may, of course, impinge as a practical
    matter on the behavior of non-jurisdictional ones.” 
    Id.
     But, as
    in Sacramento Municipal, this is not a basis for concluding that
    the Commission has exceeded its jurisdiction under the FPA.
    Contrary to petitioners’ position, neither the Ninth Circuit’s
    opinion in Bonneville nor this court’s opinion in TANC preclude
    the Commission from asserting jurisdiction over the IBAA
    Proposal. Bonneville simply holds that the Commission may not
    order a non-jurisdictional entity to issue a refund, 
    422 F.3d at 920
    , and, more critically, the Commission is not regulating
    petitioners’ rates; it is regulating only the CAISO’s. Indeed,
    Bonneville distinguishes a circumstance in which the
    Commission orders the CAISO, as opposed to a governmental
    entity, “to operate the market in a different fashion or to set a
    market-clearing price for power on a going-forward basis.” 
    Id.
    For the same reason, the Commission does not run afoul of the
    prohibition in Bonneville, adopted by this court in TANC, that the
    Commission’s “refund authority under the FPA is ultimately
    determined by the ‘identities of the sellers subject to the refund
    order.’” TANC, 
    495 F.3d at 674
     (quoting Bonneville, 
    422 F.3d at 911
    ).
    Petitioners and Municipals also miss the mark in faulting the
    Commission for justifying its assertion of jurisdiction on non-
    jurisdictional entities’ voluntary participation in the CAISO
    market. In denying rehearing the Commission was not
    suggesting that it was asserting jurisdiction by agreement; rather,
    the Commission was illustrating that governmental entities are
    affected by the IBAA Proposal only insofar as they choose to
    transact within the CAISO-controlled grid. See Rehearing Order
    ¶ 22. Thus, petitioners’ and Municipals’ reliance on Columbia
    Gas Transmission Corp. v. FERC, 
    404 F.3d 459
    , 463 (D.C. Cir.
    2005), is misplaced.
    14
    Municipals fare no better in responding that the IBAA
    Proposal is not limited to the CAISO-controlled grid because it
    incorporates prices at Captain Jack outside of the grid and makes
    reference to modeling “external” resources. Although the
    CAISO’s full network model uses proxies and data from outside
    the CAISO-controlled grid, the IBAA Proposal sets rates only for
    transactions on the CAISO-controlled grid. Moreover, the
    Commission may properly “analyze and consider the rates of
    non-jurisdictional utilities to the extent that those rates affect
    jurisdictional transactions.” TANC, 
    495 F.3d at 671
     (citation and
    quotation marks omitted).
    B.
    Existing Contracts. The Amended Owners Coordinated
    Operation Agreement (“Agreement”) between Pacific Gas and
    Electric Company (“PG&E”), participants in the California-
    Oregon Transmission Project (“COTP”), and participants in the
    Western Area Power Administration addresses the joint
    operation of the California-Oregon Intertie, the three-line parallel
    system comprised of the COTP (between Captain Jack and
    Tesla) and the dual PACI-P and PACI-W lines (between Malin
    and Tracy). Because the Agreement governed different subject
    matter than the IBAA Proposal, the Commission rejected the
    argument that approval of the IBAA Proposal violated the
    Agreement. See Order ¶¶ 246-255; Rehearing Order ¶¶ 254-260.
    Petitioners and the Commission agree that the Mobile-Sierra4
    doctrine prohibits the Commission from approving the IBAA
    Proposal if it impinges upon rights protected under the
    Agreement. The issue, then, is whether the Commission’s
    determination that the Agreement and IBAA Proposal do not
    conflict was reasonable.
    4
    See United Gas Pipe Line Co. v. Mobile Gas Serv.
    Corp., 
    350 U.S. 332
     (1956); Fed. Power Comm’n v. Sierra Pac.
    Power Co., 
    350 U.S. 348
     (1956).
    15
    A variation of the two-step Chevron analysis frames the
    arbitrary and capricious review. See Entergy Servs., Inc. v.
    FERC, 
    568 F.3d 978
    , 981-82 (D.C. Cir. 2009). The court “first
    consider[s] de novo whether [the Agreement] unambiguously
    addresses the matter at issue. If so, the language of the
    Agreement controls for [the court] must give effect to the
    unambiguously expressed intent of the parties.” S. Cal. Edison,
    
    502 F.3d at 181
     (citation and internal quotation marks omitted).
    Familiar contract interpretation principles apply.            Thus,
    ambiguity arises where an agreement “is reasonably susceptible
    of different constructions or interpretations.” Iberdrola
    Renewables, Inc. v. FERC, 
    597 F.3d 1299
    , 1304 (D.C. Cir. 2010)
    (citation and quotation marks omitted). Further, “[i]n construing
    tariffs, courts and agencies must look to the four corners of the
    tariff and consider the entire instrument as a whole.” Consol.
    Gas Transmission Corp. v. FERC, 
    771 F.2d 1536
    , 1545 (D.C.
    Cir. 1985). And “[t]he purposes for which a tariff was imposed
    should be considered . . . for ‘to decide the question of the scope
    of [a] tariff without consideration of the factors and purposes
    underlying the terminology employed would make the process
    of adjudication little more than an exercise in semantics.” 
    Id.
    (second alteration in original) (quoting United States v. W. Pac.
    R.R., 
    352 U.S. 59
    , 67 (1956)).
    Section 5 of the Agreement provides:
    This Agreement governs the coordinated operation of
    the PACI and COTP. It is the intent of the Parties to
    maintain the System as coordinated facilities to benefit
    its Transfer Capability. Except as to the use of the
    Tesla ByPass provided under this Agreement and as
    necessary to perform curtailment sharing obligations
    under Section 11 of this Agreement, no Party provides
    or shall be required to provide any transmission or other
    electric service to another Party under this Agreement.
    16
    Section 8.4 provides, in pertinent part, that
    [t]he System shall be operated as a coordinated three-
    line transmission system. No Party shall be charged
    any rate and PG&E shall not be charged any
    transmission loss for any power, which flows over the
    System or over the Tesla ByPass. . . . Except to the
    extent necessary for sharing Curtailments, no Party
    shall have a right under this Agreement to have any of
    its power delivered on or otherwise have the use of
    transmission facilities owned by another Party.
    Although the CAISO agreed to “honor” the Agreement, see
    Order ¶ 247, the extent to which the Agreement restricts the
    CAISO is unclear. Insofar as it is binding, the Commission
    concluded that the Agreement, which provides for shared use,
    coordinated operation, maintenance, and planning of the
    California-Oregon Intertie, “does not concern how energy is
    priced once it enters the CAISO-controlled grid” and therefore
    presents no conflict with the IBAA Proposal. 
    Id.
     Viewing
    section 5 to “denote[] the scope of the Agreement,” the
    Commission concluded that the prohibition on charges in section
    8.4 was limited to the coordinated operation and maintenance of
    the PACI and COTP. Id. ¶ 248; see also Rehearing Order ¶ 225.
    Petitioners contend that section 8.4 unambiguously
    precludes the CAISO from “charg[ing] any rate . . . for any
    power, which flows over the System.” As they see it, section 8.4
    “reflects the Parties’ intent to shield one another from charges
    that might otherwise be imposed as a result of their coordinated
    operations, even where the power flows through the CAISO-
    controlled grid.” Reply Br. 8. But section 8.4 must be read in
    conjunction with section 5, as they are both part of a single
    agreement. See Consol. Gas Transmission, 
    771 F.2d at 1545
    .
    On its face the Agreement does not concern the manner in which
    17
    the CAISO sets rates in its own market. Although section 8.4
    refers broadly to “any rate” for power flowing over the system,
    the reach of this provision cannot extend beyond the scope of the
    Agreement itself, which is stated in section 5.
    Seeking to avoid the effect of section 5, petitioners maintain
    that the Commission has erroneously presumed a conflict
    between the two sections. But the Commission simply read one
    section in light of the other. See Order ¶ 248. In addition, the
    Commission’s interpretation is consistent with the Agreement’s
    general purpose, see Consol. Gas Transmission, 
    771 F.2d at 1545
    , to ensure the combination of the three power lines (COTP,
    PACI-P, PACI-W) does not result in parallel flow charges to the
    Parties, which they would otherwise incur. Indeed, petitioners
    acknowledge that “[t]he Agreement prohibits the Parties from
    assessing each other for ‘any’ such power flows.” Reply Br. 8.
    The IBAA Proposal does not permit a party to the Agreement to
    charge another party for flows over the three-line system. It is
    irrelevant, as the Commission maintains, that the PACI is part of
    the CAISO grid.
    Petitioners relatedly contend that the Commission’s
    adjustment of the IBAA Proposal to prevent potential
    overcollection of losses, see Order ¶¶ 106, 252, shows that the
    Commission is permitting losses to be charged for parallel flows
    in violation of the Agreement. The Commission directed the
    CAISO to remove these charges, however, in order to avoid
    having COTP customers that transact in the CAISO market pay
    the cost due to losses of energy during transmission reflected in
    the Captain Jack locational marginal price in addition to the same
    cost reflected in the existing COTP tariff. See Order ¶ 106.
    Such action has no relation to whether the parties to the
    Agreement may charge one another for parallel flows on the
    California-Oregon Intertie. The Commission acknowledged that
    section 8.4 of the Agreement “provides that parties cannot charge
    18
    a rate for these [parallel] flows.” Order ¶ 252. But its decision
    to direct the CAISO “to revise the IBAA proposal to address any
    potential overcollection of losses,” 
    id.,
     does not indicate that a
    failure to remove these loss charges would have violated the
    Agreement. The Commission explained that “the IBAA
    proposal will not charge any rate for these flows over and above
    what it is doing under the current tariff.” 
    Id.
     (emphasis added).
    On rehearing, the Commission stated that it did not find such
    pricing to be prohibited by the Agreement. See Rehearing Order
    ¶ 258. The Commission’s position on appeal, that “this
    adjustment was to make the [IBAA] rate consistent with other
    rate tariffs, not the Coordinated Operation Agreement,” is thus
    supported by the record. Resp’t Br. 40.
    Because section 5 defines the scope of the Agreement to
    govern only the joint operation of the three power lines
    comprising the California-Oregon Intertie, and section 8.4 is
    properly read in light of section 5, the Commission reasonably
    concluded that the Agreement only prohibits the parties to the
    Agreement from charging each other for unscheduled use of
    another’s lines associated with parallel flows and does not reach
    the IBAA Proposal, which concerns the CAISO’s ability to set
    rates within its own market.
    C.
    Discrimination. FPA Section 205, in addition to requiring
    that all rates and charges be “just and reasonable,” provides:
    No public utility shall, with respect to any transmission
    or sale subject to the jurisdiction of the Commission,
    (1) make or grant any undue preference or advantage to
    any person or subject any person to any undue
    prejudice or disadvantage, or (2) maintain any
    unreasonable difference in rates, charges, service,
    19
    facilities, or in any other respect, either as between
    localities or as between classes of service.
    16 U.S.C. § 824d(b). To this end, upon finding that a rate is
    “unjust, unreasonable, unduly discriminatory or preferential,” the
    Commission is required to “determine the just and reasonable
    rate, charge, classification, rule, regulation, practice, or contract
    to be thereafter observed and in force, and shall fix the same by
    order.” Id. § 824e(a). “A rate is not ‘unduly’ preferential or
    ‘unreasonably’ discriminatory if the utility can justify the
    disparate effect.” Ark. Elec. Energy Consumers v. FERC, 
    290 F.3d 362
    , 367 (D.C. Cir. 2002); see also Elec. Consumers Res.
    Council v. FERC, 
    747 F.2d 1511
    , 1515 (D.C. Cir. 1984). The
    court will not find a Commission determination to be unduly
    discriminatory if the entity claiming discrimination is not
    similarly situated to others. Sacramento Mun. Util. Dist. v.
    FERC, 
    474 F.3d 797
    , 802 (D.C. Cir. 2007).
    In filing a revision to a tariff, the public utility bears the
    ultimate burden of demonstrating that the rate is not unduly
    discriminatory. See Elec. Consumers, 
    747 F.2d at 1515
    . Yet
    “[o]nly upon a [Section 205] complainant’s showing that a rate
    design has different effects on similarly situated customers does
    the burden shift to the respondent [public utility] to justify those
    disparities.” Sw. Elec. Coop., Inc. v. FERC, 
    347 F.3d 975
    , 981
    (D.C. Cir. 2003). If the Commission determines the rate is not
    unduly discriminatory, as it did here, then petitioner-
    complainants bear the burden of “demonstrat[ing] that [the
    Commission’s] policy judgments are arbitrary or capricious, a
    heavy burden indeed.” Transmission Access, 225 F.3d at 714.
    This framework was made clear in Sacramento Municipal, 
    616 F.3d at 537-38
    , where the court rejected the contention that the
    Commission erroneously conflated the burden of proof when it
    “properly placed the initial burden of showing that the tariff
    proposal [wa]s just and reasonable on [the CAISO] . . . [t]hen,
    20
    after finding that the [CAISO] had established that it was ‘just
    and reasonable’ . . . [,] simply found that Imperial had failed to
    controvert that conclusion.” Petitioners likewise overlook the
    shifting burdens and the standard of review in suggesting that the
    Commission impermissibly advances a post hoc argument on
    appeal, that petitioners failed to show the rates were unduly
    discriminatory, when the Commission had placed the initial
    burden on the CAISO to justify the tariff amendment, see, e.g.,
    Order ¶ 208; Rehearing Order ¶ 221.
    On the merits, petitioners contend that combining SMUD
    and Turlock into an IBAA constituted unreasonable and undue
    discrimination, in violation of FPA Section 205, 16 U.S.C.
    § 824d. Rejecting this view, the Commission credited the
    CAISO’s identification of six factors distinguishing SMUD and
    Turlock from other balancing authority areas, finding that
    “unique circumstances” justified the consolidation for purposes
    of the CAISO’s market redesign. See Order ¶¶ 208-216;
    Rehearing Order ¶¶ 216-226. Petitioners now complain that the
    Commission failed to provide a reasoned response to evidence
    and objections advanced by parties, see NorAm, 
    148 F.3d at 1163-65
    , but the record is to the contrary.
    In response to petitioners’ objection to placing weight on the
    number, rather than the size, of the connections between two
    parallel systems, the Commission noted that the proposed “IBAA
    does, in fact, have several large interconnection points, including
    Tracy,” making the SMUD-Turlock IBAA “highly
    interconnected with the CAISO with respect to the number, size,
    and distance between its interconnections with the CAISO-
    controlled grid.” Order ¶ 212; see also Rehearing Order ¶ 218.
    Additional statements defeat petitioners’ claim that the
    Commission did not conclude SMUD and Turlock connections
    were more significant than other areas. The Commission noted
    that the “sheer number of interconnections and the extent of the
    21
    parallel flows combined with its imbedded position within the
    CAISO grid” make the SMUD-Turlock IBAA the “most highly
    integrated interface with the CAISO.” Order ¶ 212. The
    Commission also contrasted the IBAA’s twelve interconnection
    points with the next largest balancing authority area, the Los
    Angeles Department of Water and Power, which has only four
    points. See 
    id.
     Moreover, with respect to the degree of impact
    on the CAISO system, the Commission found that unscheduled
    flow data for SMUD and Turlock distinguished these entities
    from neighboring balancing authority areas. See Rehearing
    Order ¶ 220. The Commission also responded to petitioners’
    objection that the former integration of SMUD and Turlock with
    the CAISO was irrelevant, pointing out that this “detailed
    knowledge” helped inform the CAISO’s understanding of
    challenges that might arise. Order ¶ 214. In sum, petitioners fail
    to show that the Commission did not examine the relevant data
    or articulate a rational connection between the facts found and
    the choice made, bearing in mind that the court’s review is
    highly deferential. See Alcoa, 
    564 F.3d at 1347
    .
    Petitioners persist, however, contending that the
    Commission failed to respond to comments raising the
    arbitrariness of “lumping” SMUD and Turlock together. This
    contention also fails. The Commission, citing evidence of two
    experts presented by the CAISO, explained that the high degree
    of integration between SMUD and Turlock justified the IBAA
    Proposal. See Order ¶ 210. On rehearing, the Commission
    pointed out that the CAISO had presented “compelling data that
    illustrates the significance of unscheduled flows between the
    SMUD and Turlock balancing authority areas and the CAISO-
    controlled grid.” Rehearing Order ¶ 220 (emphasis added). This
    data compared SMUD and Turlock with other neighboring
    balancing authority areas, and documented the amount and
    frequency of unscheduled flows over a 12-month period. The
    Commission found that “[t]he evidence demonstrates that SMUD
    22
    and Turlock both experienced large and, in many cases, frequent
    deviations between scheduled and actual power flows.” 
    Id.
     The
    Commission noted that SMUD did not address this long-term
    data and that the petitioners’ efforts to focus on individual
    factors and any one particular data set “miss the larger point of
    considering the totality of factors and unique characteristics of
    a potential IBAA.” Id.; see also id. ¶ 221. Finally, the
    Commission reasonably found that because Turlock is “uniquely
    situated within the CAISO’s balancing authority area with
    SMUD, making it possible for a schedule[d] [transfer] to be
    made from Turlock to the CAISO for power that is actually
    being sourced from within the SMUD balancing authority area
    or the Pacific Northwest, . . . it is important that the CAISO be
    better able to map such flows or reflect their source in its
    [locational marginal prices].” Id. ¶ 224.
    Petitioners’ remaining arguments fare no better. First,
    contrary to their suggestion, the Commission did not
    unreasonably reject evidence relating to flow rates. Rather, the
    Commission discussed in detail the parties’ respective positions
    regarding the accuracy of the data and the difference between
    frequency, magnitude, and peak flow data. See Order ¶¶ 37-39.
    On rehearing the Commission noted that “SMUD’s assertion
    that we ignored evidence it provided suggesting that flow
    reversals were ‘grossly exaggerated’ is incorrect.           The
    Commission considered all submitted evidence in the record in
    making determinations regarding the IBAA Proposal.”
    Rehearing Order ¶ 69. As the Commission points out, the fact
    that the CAISO’s experts and data were credited over petitioners’
    is no reason to grant the petition because the court,
    acknowledging the Commission’s expertise, “defers to the
    Commission’s resolution of factual disputes between expert
    witnesses.” Elec. Consumers Res. Council v. FERC, 
    407 F.3d 1232
    , 1236 (D.C. Cir. 2005).
    23
    Second, while petitioners correctly point out that future
    approval of other IBAAs does not justify undue discrimination
    against SMUD and Turlock, and that the availability of MEEAs
    — an agreement between the CAISO and an IBAA entity to
    share information — does not cure discrimination these
    considerations are of no aid to them here. The Commission
    identified no other entities suitable for IBAA treatment at the
    time of the challenged orders, and thus the Commission cannot
    be said to be treating similarly situated entities differently. See
    Sacramento Mun., 
    474 F.3d at 802
    . If, in the future, the
    petitioners or others provide information that another balancing
    authority area equals or surpasses SMUD and Turlock on the
    measures relied upon by the Commission and the CAISO, then
    the IBAA Proposal will allow the CAISO to treat the similarly
    situated balancing authority area as an IBAA. Further, the
    Commission did not reject petitioners’ discrimination challenges
    because MEEAs were available, but rather found the rates to be
    just, reasonable, and not unduly discriminatory even in the
    absence of MEEAs; it simply noted that the execution of MEEAs
    would “mitigate parties’ concerns.” Order ¶ 208.
    Third, petitioners incorrectly suggest that the Commission
    impermissibly relied on a “totality of circumstances” approach.
    Unlike in LeMoyne-Owen College v. NLRB, 
    357 F.3d 55
    , 61
    (D.C. Cir. 2004), on which petitioners rely, where the court
    overturned an agency decision that entirely ignored certain
    arguments made by the parties, here the Commission addressed
    the parties’ arguments, identifying six factors that supported its
    decision and explaining how the IBAA Proposal met those
    factors. See Order ¶¶ 193-216; Rehearing Order ¶¶ 197-226.
    Consequently the Commission’s reference to “multiple, non-
    exclusive factors,” Rehearing Order ¶ 218, is far from a “totality
    of the circumstances” approach that serves as “simply a cloak for
    agency whim — or worse.” LeMoyne-Owen, 
    357 F.3d at 61
    .
    Instead, as the CAISO suggests, it likely imparted that even if
    24
    petitioners could show that another entity satisfied one criterion
    for forming an IBAA, making the entity similarly situated to the
    SMUD-Turlock IBAA in one respect, this was insufficient to
    demonstrate discrimination because such entities, unlike the
    SMUD-Turlock IBAA, did not satisfy all six criteria.
    Fourth, the Commission did not, as petitioners note, directly
    address some of the evidence regarding parallel flows or explain
    why certain experts’ testimony was unpersuasive. But the
    overall explanation the Commission provided sufficed because
    it provided reasonable responses to petitioners’ objections that
    were neither summary nor dismissive. See NorAm, 
    148 F.3d at 1163-65
    . The Commission could have expanded its discussion
    of the evidence on undue discrimination, but a point-by-point
    rebuttal is not necessarily required. Cf. Lemoyne-Owen, 
    357 F.3d at 60-61
    . As the court explained in Transcontinental Gas
    Pipe Line Corp. v. FERC, 
    518 F.3d 916
    , 922 (D.C. Cir. 2008)
    (citation and internal quotation marks omitted), even when the
    Commission’s “explanation . . . left something to be desired, the
    decision as a whole and the rehearing decision clarify its
    analysis, and we will uphold a decision of less than ideal clarity
    if the agency’s path may reasonably be discerned.”
    D.
    Proxy Prices. The Commission accepted the IBAA Proposal
    to use default import and export proxy pricing points to model
    the IBAA. See Order ¶¶ 82-92; Rehearing Order ¶¶ 58-70.
    Imports into the CAISO, i.e., sales from the IBAA entities to the
    CAISO, are given a locational marginal price as if they
    originated at the Captain Jack substation in Oregon; exports from
    the CAISO, i.e., sales from the CAISO to the IBAA entities, are
    given a locational marginal price at a hypothetical “SMUD hub,”
    a composite point representing the average location of exports.
    See Order ¶ 64. As an alternative to these default locational
    marginal prices, the IBAA Proposal provided for MEEAs.
    25
    The Commission found this model and the underlying
    assumptions of the IBAA Proposal to be reasonable “given the
    available information on interchange transactions,” Order ¶ 82,
    and “the absence of additional information . . . verifying an
    interchange transaction’s source or sink,” id. ¶ 83. It noted that
    the CAISO “has appropriately chosen to make an assumption
    that imports are likely to flow through Captain Jack and exports
    are likely to flow through the SMUD hub.” Id. ¶ 82. It further
    agreed that the CAISO’s experience from which it “anticipates
    that its proposal is needed to address unscheduled flows and
    effectively manage congestion,” as applied here, reasonably
    supported the use of default proxy prices. Id. The Commission
    noted as well that IBAA entities could avoid the proxy price by
    providing confidential proprietary information on actual power
    sources through MEEAs. See id. ¶ 83.
    In rejecting comments that the IBAA Proposal’s use of the
    Captain Jack default proxy prices was unreasonable because it
    erroneously assumed Captain Jack to be the import source, the
    Commission explained that the CAISO “does not assert that all
    interchange transactions are sourced at Captain Jack,” but
    “[r]ather, in the absence of additional information, it asserts that
    Pacific Northwest resources are likely to support interchange
    transactions since they are generally less expensive.” Order ¶ 83.
    The Commission cited record evidence, submitted by the
    CAISO, demonstrating that “[t]ransactions that source from the
    Pacific Northwest (i.e. near Captain Jack) have very little flow
    through Tracy” and therefore “[m]odeling these transactions as
    if they source at Tracy will result in an inaccurate model of
    congestion, since the transaction’s actual flows will not match
    the scheduled flows.” Id. ¶ 83 n.67. Finally, the Commission
    explained that “[w]hile a default pricing and modeling
    mechanism may not reflect the actual sourcing location of an
    interchange transaction, as the parties contend, it does reflect a
    conservative proxy that allows the CAISO to better manage
    26
    congestion on its system and will reduce incentives for artificial
    scheduling.” Order ¶ 83; see also id. ¶ 90.
    Petitioners challenge as arbitrary and capricious the
    Commission’s determination that the default proxy prices for the
    IBAA were just and reasonable. They offer four grounds, none
    of which ultimately is persuasive. First, petitioners challenge the
    reasonableness of the assumption that IBAA entities use
    inexpensive Pacific Northwest power to schedule imports into
    the CAISO, but do not challenge the use of the proxy system
    itself. Their principal objection is that the Commission failed to
    address uncontradicted evidence demonstrating the IBAA
    entities use power from the Pacific Northwest to serve their own
    loads, rather than re-selling that power to the CAISO.
    Petitioners’ complaint about the different assumptions that
    underlie the default prices charged for imports and for exports is
    misdirected; the Commission did not mistakenly treat those
    assumptions as established facts. Rather, as the Commission
    explained, the default prices were based on flow data used to
    accomplish the CAISO’s purpose of eliminating arbitrage
    opportunities. See Order ¶ 83. The use of proxy pricing, as the
    CAISO explains in its brief, focused not on the intended ultimate
    use of energy purchased by the IBAA entities but on the power
    flow, and the CAISO studies showed that 15% or less of energy
    passing through Captain Jack flowed through Tracy and “[m]ost
    of the remainder, 66% of the power flows, entered the ISO
    system through the Pacific AC Intertie.” Intervenor CAISO Br.
    25.
    The Commission adopted this analysis in rejecting
    petitioners’ evidence and contrary views. See Order ¶¶ 90-92.
    The Commission concluded that absent more detailed
    information from IBAA entities about generation sources,
    imports into the CAISO are likely to flow through the Captain
    27
    Jack substation, supported by resources from the Pacific
    Northwest. The CAISO flow studies support this finding.
    Moreover, the Commission noted, petitioners may avoid default
    prices by providing accurate information to the CAISO, either
    through MEEAs or otherwise.
    Second, petitioners object that the Commission’s failure to
    remedy duplicative congestion charges is irreconcilable with its
    recognition that default IBAA prices account for parallel flows.
    The Commission ordered the CAISO to prevent double-charging
    for losses flowing over the COTP, one of the three California-
    Oregon Intertie lines, and explained why there is no comparable
    congestion duplication to be eliminated:
    [T]he congestion will not arise due to capacity
    limitations on the California-Oregon Intertie. Rather,
    the congestion will arise due to the capacity limitations
    of other elements of the CAISO-controlled grid which,
    under normal operations, will be the limiting factors for
    scheduling interchange transactions that also use the
    California-Oregon Intertie. Said another way, any
    congestion that is reflected in [locational marginal
    prices] applicable to interchange transactions that use
    the California-Oregon Intertie will be attributable to
    binding constraints, not on the intertie, but on the other
    elements of the CAISO-controlled grid.
    Order ¶ 105; see also Rehearing Order ¶ 82. Petitioners maintain
    that the Commission failed to address record evidence
    demonstrating that their congestion charges will increase under
    the IBAA Proposal, creating an “overcollection.” But such
    evidence does not undermine the Commission’s point that the
    CAISO charges are not for congestion on the California-Oregon
    Intertie. The Commission, noting evidence submitted by the
    CAISO, explained that the charges are for congestion on the
    28
    CAISO’s own underlying 230 kilovolt line and “other elements
    of the CAISO-controlled grid,” not for congestion on the
    California-Oregon Intertie. See Order ¶ 105 & n.97 (citing IBAA
    Proposal Ex. ISO-1, at 88-89). Thus, a customer transacting in
    the CAISO market will pay one charge for using the California-
    Oregon Intertie and another charge for any congestion created on
    the CAISO-controlled grid.
    Third, petitioners object that the Commission’s approval of
    the default price for imports was inconsistent with its finding that
    such a rate design “may, in limited circumstances, create an
    artificially low price” for energy. Order ¶ 120. Quoting Federal
    Power Comm’n v. Texaco Inc., 
    417 U.S. 380
    , 399 (1974),
    petitioners maintain the FPA “does not permit even a ‘little
    unlawfulness’” with respect to rates. Pet’rs Br. 56. But Texaco
    concerned a total exemption for small producers from regulation
    under the Natural Gas Act, 
    15 U.S.C. §§ 717
     et seq., see Texaco,
    
    417 U.S. at 383
    , whereas the Commission’s approval of the
    IBAA Proposal is based on its consistency with the FPA’s
    Section 205 requirement that rates be “just and reasonable,” 16
    U.S.C. § 824d(a). That a proxy price will deviate from the
    market price in limited circumstances does not mean it is
    necessarily unjust and unreasonable. As the Supreme Court
    cautioned in Texaco, 
    417 U.S. at 397
    , in some circumstances “the
    prevailing price in the marketplace cannot be the final measure of
    ‘just and reasonable’ rates mandated by the [Natural Gas] Act.”
    See also 
    id. at 397-99
    . If, as petitioners suggest, the proxy price
    could never deviate from the market price without becoming
    unlawful, then proxy pricing would be unlawful as a matter of
    law unless it was in fact the market price at all times. The court
    has recognized that proxy prices can be just and reasonable, if
    supported by record evidence. See, e.g., Oxy USA, Inc. v. FERC,
    
    64 F.3d 679
    , 695 (D.C. Cir. 1995). Petitioners cite no authority
    to the contrary.
    29
    Finally, the Commission gave a reasoned explanation for
    rejecting petitioners’ suggestion that the Captain Jack price could
    lead to substantially reduced imports creating instability on the
    CAISO-controlled grid. Essentially, the Commission concluded
    that the proxy prices generate benefits to all entities using the
    CAISO-controlled grid because SMUD and Turlock cannot cause
    inaccurate market prices and infeasible scheduling. In the
    Commission’s view, the use of locational marginal pricing would
    strengthen the market by accurately reflecting market demand
    across the power grid and facilitating energy transactions. As the
    Commission stated, the IBAA Proposal “is unlikely to
    substantially decrease imports to the CAISO.” Order ¶ 111.
    Market supply and demand would prevent a decrease in imports
    large enough to affect system stability, and while “trading
    opportunities may be lost” when the Captain Jack locational
    marginal price falls below the cost of generating power locally,
    Order ¶ 108 (citation and quotation marks omitted), petitioners
    offered no evidence that this would occur all or even a large part
    of the time. On rehearing the Commission noted that “[n]o
    evidence has been provided to support the legitimacy of the claim
    that the IBAA Proposal could undermine resource adequacy
    programs or harm reliability in the region.” Rehearing Order ¶
    99. Further, the Commission observed, “the IBAA proposal does
    not change the resource adequacy program” and thus will not
    “lead to reliability or resource adequacy problems for the
    CAISO.” Order ¶ 112. The Commission’s response to
    petitioners’ concern was reasonable and supported by record
    evidence submitted by the CAISO.
    Accordingly, we deny the petitions for review.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 09-1213

Filed Date: 12/10/2010

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 12/21/2014

Authorities (25)

bonneville-power-administration-city-of-tacoma-port-of-seattle-coral , 422 F.3d 908 ( 2005 )

Federal Power Commission v. Sierra Pacific Power Co. , 76 S. Ct. 368 ( 1956 )

SW Elec Coop Inc v. FERC , 347 F.3d 975 ( 2003 )

Arkansas Electric Energy Consumers v. Federal Energy ... , 290 F.3d 362 ( 2002 )

Southern California Edison Co. v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 502 F.3d 176 ( 2007 )

Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, ... , 104 S. Ct. 2778 ( 1984 )

Consolidated Gas Transmission Corporation v. Federal Energy ... , 771 F.2d 1536 ( 1985 )

MI Pub Power Agcy v. FERC , 405 F.3d 8 ( 2005 )

NRG Power Marketing, LLC v. Maine Public Utilities ... , 130 S. Ct. 693 ( 2010 )

Alcoa Inc. v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission , 564 F.3d 1342 ( 2009 )

NorAm Gas Transmission Co. v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 148 F.3d 1158 ( 1998 )

Elec Consum Resrc v. FERC , 407 F.3d 1232 ( 2005 )

Transmission Agency v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission , 495 F.3d 663 ( 2007 )

United Gas Pipe Line Co. v. Mobile Gas Service Corp. , 76 S. Ct. 373 ( 1956 )

Iberdrola Renewables, Inc. v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 597 F.3d 1299 ( 2010 )

Sacramento Muni Util v. FERC , 474 F.3d 797 ( 2007 )

Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corporation v. FEDERAL ... , 518 F.3d 916 ( 2008 )

National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners v. ... , 475 F.3d 1277 ( 2007 )

Lemoyne-Owen College v. National Labor Relations Board , 357 F.3d 55 ( 2004 )

electricity-consumers-resource-council-v-federal-energy-regulatory , 747 F.2d 1511 ( 1984 )

View All Authorities »