Investment Co. Institute v. Commodity Futures Trading Commission , 720 F.3d 370 ( 2013 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued May 6, 2013                     Decided June 25, 2013
    No. 12-5413
    INVESTMENT COMPANY INSTITUTE AND CHAMBER OF
    COMMERCE OF THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
    APPELLANTS
    v.
    COMMODITY FUTURES TRADING COMMISSION,
    APPELLEE
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the District of Columbia
    (No. 1:12-cv-00612)
    Eugene Scalia argued the cause for appellants. On the
    briefs were Robin S. Conrad and Rachel Brand. Daniel T. Davis
    entered an appearance.
    Steven G. Bradbury and Susan Ferris Wyderko were on the
    brief for amici curiae Mutual Fund Directors Forum, et al. in
    support of appellants.
    Jonathan L. Marcus, Deputy General Counsel, U.S.
    Commodity Futures Trading Commission, argued the cause for
    appellee. With him on the brief were Dan M. Berkovitz, General
    Counsel, Robert A. Schwartz, Nancy R. Doyle, and Martin B.
    White, Assistant General Counsel, and Melissa Chiang, Counsel.
    2
    John M. Devaney, Martin E. Lybecker, Dennis M. Kelleher,
    and Stephen W. Hall were on the brief for amici curiae The
    National Futures Association, et al. in support of appellee.
    Before: GARLAND, Chief Judge, BROWN, Circuit Judge, and
    SENTELLE, Senior Circuit Judge.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    SENTELLE.
    SENTELLE, Senior Circuit Judge: The Investment Company
    Institute and the Chamber of Commerce of the United States
    brought this action against the Commodity Futures Trading
    Commission (CFTC), seeking a declaratory judgment that
    recently adopted regulations of the Commission regarding
    derivatives trading were unlawfully adopted and invalid, and
    seeking to vacate and set aside those regulations and to enjoin
    their enforcement. The district court granted summary judgment
    in favor of the Commission. Because we agree with the district
    court that the Commission did not act unlawfully in
    promulgating the regulations at issue, we affirm.
    I. BACKGROUND
    A. Regulatory History
    The Commodity Exchange Act (CEA), Title 7, United
    States Code, Chapter 1, establishes and defines the jurisdiction
    of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission. Under this
    Act, the Commission has regulatory jurisdiction over a wide
    variety of markets in futures and derivatives, that is, contracts
    deriving their value from underlying assets. See 
    7 U.S.C. § 2
    (a).
    In addition to establishing the regulatory authority of the
    Commission, the CEA also directly imposes certain duties on
    regulated entities. As relevant here, the Act requires that
    3
    Commodity Pool Operators (CPOs) register with CFTC and
    adhere to regulatory requirements related to such issues as
    investor disclosures, recordkeeping, and reporting. 7 U.S.C.
    §§ 6k, 6n; 
    17 C.F.R. §§ 4.20
    –4.27. The CEA defines CPOs as
    entities “engaged in a business that is of the nature of a
    commodity pool, investment trust, syndicate, or similar form of
    enterprise” that buy and sell securities “for the purpose of
    trading in commodity interests.” 7 U.S.C. § 1a(11)(A)(i). The
    CEA, however, empowers CFTC to exclude an entity from
    regulation as a CPO if CFTC determines that the exclusion “will
    effectuate the purposes of” the statute. Id. § 1a(11)(B).
    Since 1985, the Commission has exercised its authority to
    exclude “otherwise regulated” entities through § 4.5 of its
    regulations. See Commodity Pool Operators, 
    50 Fed. Reg. 15,868
     (Apr. 23, 1985) (codified at 
    17 C.F.R. § 4.5
    ). Under the
    version of § 4.5 that applied before amendments of 2003,
    otherwise regulated entities could claim exclusion by meeting
    certain regulatory conditions. These conditions included that the
    entity:
    (i) Will use commodity futures or commodity options
    contracts solely for bona fide hedging purposes . . . [;] (ii)
    Will not enter into commodity futures and commodity
    options contracts for which the aggregate initial margin and
    premiums exceed 5 percent of the fair market value of the
    entity’s assets . . . [;] (iii) Will not be, and has not been,
    marketing participations to the public as or in a commodity
    pool or otherwise as or in a vehicle for trading in the
    commodity futures or commodity options markets; [and,]
    (iv) Will disclose in writing to each prospective participant
    the purpose of and the limitations on the scope of the
    commodity futures and commodity options trading in which
    the entity intends to engage[.]
    4
    Id. at 15,883. These conditions were amended slightly in 1993,
    when CFTC promulgated a rule removing the bona fide hedging
    requirement and excluding bona fide hedging from the trading
    threshold. Commodity Pool Operators, 
    58 Fed. Reg. 6,371
    ,
    6,372 (Jan. 28, 1993). Under these conditions, there was no
    automatic exclusion for registered investment companies, or
    “RICs,” regulated by the Securities and Exchange Commission
    pursuant to the Investment Company Act of 1940, 15 U.S.C.
    §§ 80a-1 to -64. Therefore, a commodity pool operator that was
    also a registered investment company was included within
    CFTC’s regulatory definition of CPOs unless it met all of the
    § 4.5 requirements for exclusion.
    In 2000, Congress enacted the Commodity Futures
    Modernization Act of 2000, Pub. L. No. 106-554, 
    114 Stat. 2763
    . That statute barred CFTC and SEC from regulating most
    “swaps,” a type of derivative involving the exchange of cash
    flows from financial instruments. See 
    7 U.S.C. § 2
    (d).
    Responsive to the statutory change, the Commission amended
    its requirements for exclusion to eliminate the five percent
    ceiling. See Additional Registration and Other Regulatory
    Relief for Commodity Pool Operators and Commodity Trading
    Advisors, 
    68 Fed. Reg. 47,221
    , 47,224 (Aug. 8, 2003). These
    2003 amendments “effectively excluded RICs from the CPO
    definition,” freeing registered investment companies from most
    CFTC CPO regulations. Investment Company Institute v. CFTC,
    
    891 F. Supp. 2d 162
    , 172 (D.D.C. 2013). CFTC viewed its 2003
    amendments as consistent with the deregulatory spirit of the
    2000 statute. See 68 Fed. Reg. at 47,223.
    In 2010, the Commission began shifting back to a more
    stringent regulatory framework. This shift came in the wake of
    the 2007–2008 financial crisis, which many attributed to poorly
    regulated derivatives markets, when Congress passed the Dodd-
    Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub.
    5
    L. No. 111-203, 
    124 Stat. 1376
     (2010) (codified as amended in
    scattered sections of the U.S. Code). As relevant here, Dodd-
    Frank repealed several statutory provisions that had excluded
    certain commodities transactions from CFTC oversight. 
    Id.
    §§ 723, 734. Dodd-Frank also gave CFTC regulatory authority
    over swaps, and amended the statutory definition of commodity
    pool operators to include entities that trade swaps. Id. §§ 721(a),
    722. Dodd-Frank, however, did not affect CFTC’s authority to
    set exclusion requirements for CPOs.
    B. Rulemaking Process
    After Congress passed Dodd-Frank, the National Futures
    Association (NFA), to which all CPOs must belong, filed a
    petition of rulemaking with CFTC requesting that CFTC amend
    § 4.5 to limit the scope of its exclusion for registered investment
    companies. See Petition of the National Futures Association, 
    75 Fed. Reg. 56,997
     (Sept. 17, 2010). In NFA’s view, mutual
    funds were using the relaxed § 4.5 standards to evade CFTC
    oversight of their derivative operations, reducing transparency
    and potentially harming the public because no other regulator
    had rules equivalent to CFTC’s. See Investment Company
    Institute, 891 F. Supp. 2d at 175–76. Therefore, NFA asked
    CFTC to restore the trading threshold and public marketing
    prohibition requirements to § 4.5 for any registered investment
    company seeking exclusion from CPO status. See 75 Fed. Reg.
    at 56,998. In essence, NFA sought a return to the pre-2003
    regulatory framework, but only for registered investment
    companies.
    On February 11, 2011, CFTC proposed new regulations that
    would amend § 4.5 “to reinstate the pre-2003 operating criteria”
    for all registered investment companies. Commodity Pool
    Operators and Commodity Trading Advisors: Amendments to
    Compliance Obligations, 
    76 Fed. Reg. 7,976
    , 7,984 (Feb. 11,
    6
    2011). One notable difference from the 2003 framework is that
    because of Dodd-Frank’s extension of CFTC authority to swaps,
    the regulations proposed that swaps be included in the trading
    thresholds. See 
    id. at 7,989
    . The proposed regulations also
    required certified regular reports from CPOs, a requirement that
    would be contained in a new § 4.27. See id. at 7,978. CFTC
    provided four explanations for these proposed regulations: First,
    the regulations would align CFTC’s regulatory framework “with
    the stated purposes of the Dodd-Frank Act.” Id. Second, they
    would “encourage more congruent and consistent regulation of
    similarly situated entities among Federal financial regulatory
    agencies.” Id. Third, they would “improve accountability and
    increase transparency of the activities of CPOs” and commodity
    pools. Id. Fourth, they would make it easier to collect data for
    the Financial Stability Oversight Council (“FSOC”), a new body
    created by Dodd-Frank charged with “identify[ing] risks to the
    financial stability of the United States.” Id.; Dodd-Frank Act
    § 112 (codified at 
    12 U.S.C. § 5322
    ).
    After the public comment period expired, CFTC
    promulgated a Final Rule amending § 4.5 and adding § 4.27
    largely as proposed. See Commodity Pool Operators and
    Commodity Trading Advisors: Compliance Obligations, 
    77 Fed. Reg. 11,252
     (Feb. 24, 2012), as corrected due to Fed. Reg. errors
    in its original publication, 
    77 Fed. Reg. 17,328
     (Mar. 26, 2012);
    see also 
    17 C.F.R. §§ 4.5
    , 4.27. The primary difference between
    the proposed rule and the Final Rule is that, to be eligible for
    exclusion, a RIC’s non-bona fide hedging trading must be less
    than or equal to five percent of the liquidation value of the
    entity’s portfolio, or the aggregate net notional value of such
    trading must be less than or equal to “100 percent of the
    liquidation value of the pool’s portfolio.” 77 Fed. Reg. at
    11,283. As the appellants do not directly challenge the
    aggregate net notional value threshold, we decline to define it
    further and fill the Federal Reporter with irrelevant financial
    7
    lingo.
    In its Final Rule, CFTC justified its decision to return to the
    pre-2003 regulatory framework on the basis of “changed
    circumstances [that] warrant revisions to these rules.” Id. at
    11,275. According to CFTC, the 2003 “system of exemptions
    was appropriate because [registered investment companies]
    engaged in relatively little derivatives trading.” Id. Since the
    2003 amendments, however, such companies have engaged in
    “increased derivatives trading activities” and “now offer[]
    services substantially identical to those of registered entities
    [that] are not subject to the same regulatory oversight.” Id.
    Given this changed circumstance, and Dodd-Frank’s “more
    robust mandate to manage systemic risk and to ensure safe
    trading practices by entities involved in the derivatives
    markets,” CFTC considered it necessary to narrow the
    exclusions from its derivatives regulation. Id. Following this
    rule change, RICs that do not satisfy the exclusion requirements
    must register with CFTC per § 4.5.
    In adopting the heightened disclosure requirements, CFTC
    explained that “there currently is no source of reliable
    information regarding the general use of derivatives by
    registered investment companies.” Id. Such information would
    be useful to CFTC and FSOC in performing their statutory
    mandates of regulating commodities trading and identifying
    systemic financial risks. See id. at 11,281.
    Several commenters called the Commission’s attention to
    possible inconsistencies with or redundancies to SEC
    compliance requirements. In response to those commenters, and
    concurrently with the issuance of the Final Rule, CFTC issued
    a notice of proposed rulemaking to harmonize CFTC and SEC’s
    compliance requirements. See Harmonization of Compliance
    Obligations for Registered Investment Companies Required To
    8
    Register as Commodity Pool Operators, 
    77 Fed. Reg. 11,345
    (Feb. 24, 2012). In this notice, CFTC stated that it may change
    certain disclosure requirements to harmonize them with SEC
    requirements but, importantly, it does not plan to change the
    new reporting requirements promulgated in the Final Rule and
    contained in 
    17 C.F.R. § 4.27
    . See id.; see also Investment
    Company Institute, 891 F. Supp. 2d at 183. The § 4.27 reporting
    requirements, however, are suspended for registered investment
    companies until CFTC and SEC promulgate a Final Rule on
    harmonization. See id. at 183–84.
    C. Procedural History
    The Investment Company Institute and the Chamber of
    Commerce filed suit in the district court against CFTC, alleging
    that CFTC violated APA and CEA requirements in
    promulgating the amendments to § 4.5 and § 4.27. Investment
    Company Institute, 891 F. Supp. 2d at 184. The business
    associations moved for summary judgment, and CFTC cross-
    moved for summary judgment and moved to dismiss in part. Id.
    at 167. The district court granted CFTC’s motion to dismiss in
    part, ruling that the associations’ challenge to certain
    compliance obligations (other than those arising under § 4.27)
    was unripe because the Final Rule states that those obligations
    are subject to change during the harmonization process. Id. at
    205. The associations do not appeal that dismissal. The
    associations do, however, appeal the district court’s grant of
    summary judgment in favor of CFTC with regard to the other
    issues raised in the associations’ complaint.
    II. DISCUSSION
    Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 56(a) provides that
    summary judgment is appropriate “if the movant shows that
    there is no genuine dispute as to any material fact and the
    9
    movant is entitled to judgment as a matter of law.” Our review
    of a district court’s grant of summary judgment is de novo.
    Calhoun v. Johnson, 
    632 F.3d 1259
    , 1261 (D.C. Cir. 2011).
    There being no genuine dispute as to any material fact, the only
    question before us is whether CFTC is entitled to judgment as a
    matter of law. See Sherley v. Sebelius, 
    689 F.3d 776
    , 780 (D.C.
    Cir. 2012). Under the APA, we must “hold unlawful and set
    aside agency action, findings, and conclusions found to be . . .
    arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in
    accordance with law.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2). “Although the ‘scope
    of review under the “arbitrary and capricious” standard is
    narrow and a court is not to substitute its judgment for that of
    the agency,’ we must nonetheless be sure [CFTC] has
    ‘examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a satisfactory
    explanation for its action including a rational connection
    between the facts found and the choice made.’” Chamber of
    Commerce v. SEC, 
    412 F.3d 133
    , 140 (D.C. Cir. 2005) (quoting
    Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co.,
    
    463 U.S. 29
    , 43 (1983)).
    Appellants contend that CFTC violated the APA in its
    rulemaking by: (1) failing to address its own 2003 rationales for
    broadening CPO exemptions; (2) failing to comply with the
    Commodity Exchange Act and offering an inadequate
    evaluation of the rule’s costs and benefits; (3) including swaps
    in the trading threshold, restricting its definition of bona fide
    hedging, and failing to justify the five percent threshold; and, (4)
    failing to provide an adequate opportunity for notice and
    comment. We address each contention in turn.
    A. Change in Agency Position
    The appellants first contend that CFTC failed to explain
    why it changed from its more generous exemption requirements
    that had existed since 2003 to the more stringent requirements
    10
    contained in the Final Rule. Though it is true that the Final Rule
    stated that investment companies are increasing their
    participation in derivatives markets, the 2003 rule was explicitly
    designed to promote liquidity in the commodities markets by
    making it easier for registered investment companies to
    participate in derivatives markets. CFTC, according to the
    appellants, completely failed to address the liquidity issue, and
    therefore its change in position was arbitrary and capricious.
    We disagree. An agency changing course “need not
    demonstrate to a court’s satisfaction that the reasons for the new
    policy are better than the reasons for the old one; it suffices that
    the new policy is permissible under the statute, that there are
    good reasons for it, and that the agency believes it to be better.”
    FCC v. Fox Television Stations, Inc., 
    556 U.S. 502
    , 515 (2009).
    Appellants do not argue that the new rule is impermissible under
    CFTC’s statutory framework. Instead, appellants argue that
    CFTC had an obligation to address the rule’s impact on
    liquidity. But the APA imposes no heightened obligation on
    agencies to explain “why the original reasons for adopting the
    displaced rule or policy are no longer dispositive.” 
    Id. at 514
    (internal quotation marks and citation omitted). So long as
    CFTC provided a reasoned explanation for its regulation, and
    the reviewing court can “reasonably . . . discern[]” the agency’s
    path, we must uphold the regulation, even if the agency’s
    decision has “less than ideal clarity.” Bowman Transp., Inc. v.
    Arkansas-Best Freight Sys., Inc., 
    419 U.S. 281
    , 286 (1974).
    CFTC’s regulation clears this low bar. CFTC explicitly
    acknowledged that it was changing its position from its 2003
    rulemaking. The Final Rule detailed the changed circumstances
    that prompted CFTC to amend the rule, including increased
    derivatives trading by investment companies (an issue inherently
    tied to liquidity) and a perceived lack of market transparency
    that could lead to a buildup of systemic risk. See 
    77 Fed. Reg. 11
    at 11,275, 11,277. It is clear that the Commission, in adopting
    the changes and the rule, was attempting to respond to those
    changed circumstances by adding registration and reporting
    requirements. As is clear from our discussion of the regulatory
    and statutory history above, the Commission’s requirements
    followed a congressional shift evidenced in the Dodd-Frank
    Act—legislation expressly relied upon by the Commission. See
    
    id. at 11,252
    . Such reasoned decisionmaking is an acceptable
    way to change CFTC’s past rules, cf. Fox, 
    556 U.S. at 517
    , the
    appellants’ policy disagreements with CFTC notwithstanding.
    The law requires no more.
    B. Cost-Benefit Analysis
    Appellants next contend that CFTC failed to adequately
    consider the costs and benefits of the rule. The Commodity
    Exchange Act requires that CFTC “consider the costs and
    benefits” of its actions and “evaluate[]” those costs and benefits
    “in light of” five factors: “(A) considerations of protection of
    market participants and the public; (B) considerations of the
    efficiency, competitiveness, and financial integrity of futures
    markets; (C) considerations of price discovery; (D)
    considerations of sound risk management practices; and (E)
    other public interest considerations.” 
    7 U.S.C. § 19
    (a)(2). As
    a reviewing court, “[o]ur role is to determine whether the
    [agency] decision was based on a consideration of the relevant
    factors and whether there has been a clear error of judgment.”
    Center for Auto Safety v. Peck, 
    751 F.2d 1336
    , 1342 (D.C. Cir.
    1985) (internal quotation marks omitted) (quoting State Farm,
    
    463 U.S. at 43
    ).
    First, appellants argue that CFTC ignored existing SEC
    regulations that could provide the necessary information about
    investment companies’ activities in derivatives markets.
    Appellants point to two recent cases in which we vacated SEC
    12
    regulations because SEC had failed to address existing
    regulatory requirements to determine whether sufficient
    protections were already present. See Business Roundtable v.
    SEC, 
    647 F.3d 1144
    , 1154 (D.C. Cir. 2011); American Equity
    Inv. Life Ins. Co. v. SEC, 
    613 F.3d 166
    , 179 (D.C. Cir. 2010).
    According to the appellants, CFTC similarly failed to consider
    whether existing regulations made its proposed regulation
    unnecessary.
    We are unconvinced. In its Final Rule, CFTC explicitly
    discussed SEC’s oversight in the derivatives markets: “In its
    recent concept release regarding the use of derivatives by
    registered investment companies, the SEC noted that although
    its staff had addressed issues related to derivatives on a case-by-
    case basis, it had not developed a ‘comprehensive and
    systematic approach to derivatives related issues.’” 77 Fed.
    Reg. at 11,255 (quoting Use of Derivatives by Investment
    Companies Under the Investment Company Act of 1940, 
    76 Fed. Reg. 55,237
    , 55,239 (Sept. 7, 2011)). CFTC surveyed the
    existing regulatory landscape and concluded that it “is in the
    best position to oversee entities engaged in more than a limited
    amount of non-hedging derivatives trading.” Id.; see also 
    id. at 11,278
    . CFTC found that its registration and reporting
    requirements could fill gaps in current regulations, explaining
    that only it has the authority “to take punitive and/or remedial
    action against registered entities for violations of the CEA or of
    the Commission’s regulations.” 
    Id. at 11,254
    . It explained how
    the new § 4.27 forms would collect information from entities
    registered under § 4.5 that would not otherwise be collected by
    SEC. See id. at 11,275. Further, CFTC issued a harmonization
    proposal to ensure that its rules do not duplicate or contradict
    SEC regulations. See 
    77 Fed. Reg. 11,345
    .
    These explanations suffice to justify the marginal benefit
    of CFTC regulation of registered investment companies in the
    13
    derivatives markets, and distinguish this case from Business
    Roundtable and American Equity. In Business Roundtable, we
    vacated an SEC rule because SEC had “failed adequately to
    address whether the regulatory requirements of the [Investment
    Company Act] reduce the need for, and hence the benefit to be
    had from” additional regulations. 647 F.3d at 1154. In
    American Equity, we determined that SEC acted in an arbitrary
    and capricious manner because it completely failed to “assess
    the baseline level of price transparency and information
    disclosure under state law.” 613 F.3d at 178. In fact, SEC had
    stated that it considered state regulatory regimes “not relevant.”
    Id. As the district court rightly held, these cases are “plainly
    distinguishable” from the present case. Investment Company
    Institute, 891 F. Supp. 2d at 219. As the district court noted,
    unlike the SEC in the other two cases, “CFTC did consider
    whether RICs were otherwise regulated, and concluded that
    CFTC regulation was necessary” despite the existing SEC
    regime. Id. at 217. Moreover, CFTC issued a notice of
    proposed rulemaking for a harmonization, the entire purpose of
    which was to synchronize SEC and CFTC regulations, further
    distinguishing this case from American Equity and Business
    Roundtable.
    Appellants next argue that CFTC, by engaging in a multi-
    step rulemaking with some regulations becoming final now and
    other regulations becoming final only after harmonization with
    SEC regulations, made it impossible to determine the costs and
    benefits of its rule. The thrust of the appellants’ argument is that
    CFTC counted benefits that may not materialize and depend on
    the harmonization rule while ignoring costs that may result from
    that rule.
    We again reject the appellants’ argument. In its Final Rule,
    CFTC explicitly listed and analyzed the five statutory factors
    that it must take into account when “consider[ing]” and
    14
    “evalulat[ing]” the costs and benefits of a rule. 
    7 U.S.C. § 19
    (a);
    see 77 Fed. Reg. at 11,275–83. It had no obligation to consider
    hypothetical costs that may never arise. The statute only
    requires the Commission to address costs and benefits “[b]efore
    promulgating a regulation.” 
    7 U.S.C. § 19
    (a)(1). CFTC stated
    that it had not finalized several disclosure requirements (not
    including the requirements in § 4.27) and would not do so until
    after harmonization. See 
    77 Fed. Reg. 11,345
    . We see at least
    two good reasons that CFTC need not count costs from these
    potential disclosure requirements. First, the statute does not
    mandate it, and second, it would be quite literally impossible to
    calculate the costs of an unknown regulation. And as the
    Supreme Court has emphasized, “[n]othing prohibits federal
    agencies from moving in an incremental manner.” Fox, 
    556 U.S. at 522
    . CFTC counsel correctly stated at oral argument that
    CFTC must consider and evaluate the costs and benefits of its
    harmonization rulemaking during that rulemaking, and the
    appellants can challenge that rule when it is finalized. See Oral
    Arg. Recording at 33:30–34:30. As the district court opined,
    “The time for any challenge to any new compliance obligations
    is when the final harmonization rule has been released and the
    nature of those obligations is clear.” Investment Company
    Institute, 891 F. Supp. 2d at 205.
    The appellants also assert that the agency improperly
    counted hypothetical benefits, but this assertion is incorrect. It
    was appropriate for CFTC to count the benefits flowing from its
    registration and disclosure requirements in § 4.5 and § 4.27, as
    the specifics of those requirements are finalized and not subject
    to the harmonization rule.1 The appellants further complain that
    1
    Unlike the cost posited by the appellants as unconsidered, the
    benefits upon which the Commission relies are not hypothetical. The
    Commission’s analysis relies upon the benefits as being established in
    the ungarnished application of § 4.5 and § 4.27, not in the
    15
    CFTC failed to put a precise number on the benefit of data
    collection in preventing future financial crises. But the law does
    not require agencies to measure the immeasurable. CFTC’s
    discussion of unquantifiable benefits fulfills its statutory
    obligation to consider and evaluate potential costs and benefits.
    See Fox, 
    556 U.S. at 519
     (holding that agencies are not required
    to “adduce empirical data that” cannot be obtained). Where
    Congress has required “rigorous, quantitative economic
    analysis,” it has made that requirement clear in the agency’s
    statute, but it imposed no such requirement here. American
    Financial Services Ass’n v. FTC, 
    767 F.2d 957
    , 986 (D.C. Cir.
    1985); cf., e.g., 
    2 U.S.C. § 1532
    (a) (requiring the agency to
    “prepare a written statement containing . . . a qualitative and
    quantitative assessment of the anticipated costs and benefits”
    that includes, among other things, “estimates by the agency of
    the [rule’s] effect on the national economy”).
    Finally, the appellants argue that CFTC failed to consider
    the relevant costs and benefits of its rule because it had not yet
    adopted a definition of swaps and it did not obtain some market
    data suggested by commenters. But Dodd-Frank includes a
    detailed definition of “swap,” see 7 U.S.C. § 1a(47). Further,
    CFTC stated in a previous proposed rulemaking that “extensive
    further definition of the term[] by rule is not necessary.” Joint
    Proposed Rule, Further Definition of “Swap,” 
    76 Fed. Reg. 29,818
    , 29,821 (May 23, 2011) (internal quotation marks
    omitted). Given that the Commission explained the lack of need
    for significant additions to the definition in Dodd-Frank, it was
    not arbitrary or capricious for it to view any costs resulting from
    the lack of a CFTC regulation defining “swap” as minimal. In
    harmonization rule. Of course if it should materialize that the
    harmonization in some fashion destroys those benefits, appellants
    would then be free to raise the resulting imbalance of costs and
    benefits in a challenge to the harmonization rule.
    16
    any event, in light of a final rule defining “swap” in essentially
    the same way as Dodd-Frank, see Further Definition of “Swap,”
    
    77 Fed. Reg. 48,208
     (Aug. 13, 2012), the appellants can show no
    “prejudicial error.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    .
    The appellants also fail to show that CFTC’s refusal to
    gather additional market data as suggested by commenters was
    arbitrary or capricious. CFTC acknowledged that its data was
    limited in some respects, see 77 Fed. Reg. at 11,278, but that is
    true in practically any regulatory endeavor. CFTC adequately
    considered the costs and benefits of the rule given this
    uncertainty, explaining that the commenters provided no data
    that “would warrant deviation” from the proposed rule, given the
    rule’s “costs and benefits.” Id. CFTC went on to explain that
    “[t]hese data limitations are one reason why the Commission is
    pursuing additional data collection initiatives under these final
    rules.” Id. at 11,278 n.229. In essence, the appellants are
    challenging the very method for obtaining the data they want on
    the ground that CFTC has not yet obtained the data they want.
    But neither the APA nor the CEA imposes such a catch-22 on
    CFTC. We hold that CFTC’s consideration and evaluation of
    the rule’s costs and benefits was not arbitrary or capricious.
    C. The Rule’s Particulars
    The appellants challenge three particular aspects of the
    Final Rule. The first is CFTC’s decision to include swap
    transactions in the registration threshold, which has the effect of
    requiring more investment companies to register pursuant to
    § 4.5. The appellants claim that this decision was arbitrary and
    capricious because Dodd-Frank implemented a separate
    reporting framework with regard to swaps. Appellants contend
    that one of CFTC’s responses to this claim, that participation in
    swaps would trigger the registration requirement even if CFTC
    17
    based its threshold only on futures and options, is irrational and
    obviously incorrect.
    Though we agree that this particular response offers “less
    than ideal clarity,” CFTC gave sufficient other explanations for
    including swap trades in the § 4.5 trading threshold that we can
    “reasonably . . . discern[]” its rationale. Bowman, 419 U.S. at
    286. The Final Rule explained that “[t]he Dodd-Frank Act
    amended the statutory definition of the terms ‘commodity pool
    operator’ and ‘commodity pool’ to include those entities that
    trade swaps,” evidencing that swaps were a central concern of
    the statute. 77 Fed. Reg. at 11,258. The rule further explained
    that CFTC would use information obtained “from CPOs
    transacting in swaps” to “help to bring transparency to the swaps
    markets, as well as to the interaction of swaps and futures
    markets, protecting the participants in both markets from
    potentially negative behavior.” Id. at 11,283. Given these
    goals, it was not arbitrary or capricious to include swaps in the
    § 4.5 trading threshold.
    The second aspect of the rule challenged by the appellants
    is its definition of bona fide hedging transactions, a definition
    that the appellants claim is too narrow and should encompass
    risk management strategies in financial markets. This argument
    amounts to nothing more than another policy disagreement with
    CFTC, so we must reject it. CFTC adequately explained that it
    was rejecting the broader “risk management” definition because
    “bona fide hedging transactions are unlikely to present the same
    level of market risk [as risk management transactions] as they
    are offset by exposure in the physical markets.” Id. at 11,256.
    It also found that the risk management definition would be
    difficult to “properly limit” and make its exclusion “onerous to
    enforce.” Id. Given the deference appropriate to such expert
    determinations, we reject the appellants’ challenge to this aspect
    of the rule. See Rural Cellular Ass’n v. FCC, 
    588 F.3d 1095
    ,
    18
    1105 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (“The ‘arbitrary and capricious’ standard
    is particularly deferential in matters implicating predictive
    judgments . . . .”).
    We further reject the appellants’ contention that this aspect
    of the rule must be vacated because the bona fide hedging
    definition was cross-referenced to another rule that was recently
    vacated. See Int’l Swaps & Derivatives Ass’n v. CFTC, 
    887 F. Supp. 2d 259
     (D.D.C. 2012). The decision vacating the cross-
    referenced rule had nothing to do with the bona fide exception
    in this rule, and the fact that the definition here was cross-
    referenced instead of reproduced does not make it automatically
    invalid.
    The third and final particular aspect of the rule challenged
    by the appellants is the five percent registration threshold for
    § 4.5, which the appellants argue is too low. Our cases explain
    the appropriate deference given to these types of agency
    determinations:
    It is true that an agency may not pluck a number out of thin
    air when it promulgates rules in which percentage terms
    play a critical role. When a line has to be drawn, however,
    [CFTC] is authorized to make a rational legislative-type
    judgment. If the figure selected by the agency reflects its
    informed discretion, and is neither patently unreasonable
    nor a dictate of unbridled whim, then the agency’s decision
    adequately satisfies the standard of review.
    WJG Telephone Co. v. FCC, 
    675 F.2d 386
    , 388–89 (D.C. Cir.
    1982) (internal quotation marks and citations omitted). CFTC
    offered a reasoned explanation for its choice of five percent,
    finding that “trading exceeding five percent of the liquidation
    value of a portfolio evidences a significant exposure to the
    derivatives markets.” 77 Fed. Reg. at 11,278. According to the
    19
    Final Rule, the five percent threshold is appropriate because “it
    is possible for a commodity pool to have a portfolio that is
    sizeable enough that even if just five percent of the pool’s
    portfolio were committed to margin for futures, the pool’s
    portfolio could be so significant that the commodity pool would
    constitute a major participant in the futures market.” Id. at
    11,262 (quoting 76 Fed. Reg. at 7,985). We defer to CFTC’s
    judgment and hold that adopting the five percent threshold was
    neither arbitrary nor capricious.
    D. Notice and Comment
    Finally, appellants contend that CFTC failed to provide
    adequate opportunity for notice and comment both because the
    proposal’s cost-benefit discussion did not set out the basis for
    the Final Rule’s analysis and because CFTC did not give
    commenters notice of the seven-factor marketing test. We
    disagree. The APA requires “reference to the legal authority
    under which the rule is proposed” and “either the terms or
    substance of the proposed rule or a description of the subjects
    and issues involved.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 553
    (b). The proposed rule
    included a separate section entitled “Cost-Benefit Analysis” that
    gave adequate notice of CFTC’s approach to the cost-benefit
    analysis by setting forth the factors that CFTC would consider
    and summarizing expected costs and benefits. See 76 Fed. Reg.
    at 7,988.
    As for the seven-factor marketing test, no notice and
    comment was required. The APA’s notice-and-comment
    provision does not apply to “general statements of policy,” 
    5 U.S.C. § 553
    (b)(3)(A), and the seven factors were included in
    the rule only as guidance. See 77 Fed. Reg. at 11,258–59. The
    rule explicitly states that CFTC “will determine whether a
    violation of the marketing restriction exists on a case by case
    basis through an examination of the relevant facts.” Id. at
    20
    11,259. Even if these factors were not included as a mere
    statement of policy, the appellants do not even attempt to show
    that any prejudice resulted from this failure to provide notice, as
    they must to succeed on such a claim. See 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    ;
    American Coke & Coal Chemicals Institute v. EPA, 
    452 F.3d 930
    , 939 (D.C. Cir. 2006).
    III. CONCLUSION
    For the foregoing reasons, the decision of the district court
    is
    Affirmed.