Sorenson Communications, Inc. v. Federal Communications Commission , 765 F.3d 37 ( 2014 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued March 17, 2014            Decided September 2, 2014
    No. 13-1215
    SORENSON COMMUNICATIONS, INC.,
    PETITIONER
    v.
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION AND UNITED
    STATES OF AMERICA,
    RESPONDENTS
    On Petition for Review of an Order of
    the Federal Communications Commission
    Christopher J. Wright argued the cause for petitioner.
    With him on the briefs were John T. Nakahata and Mark D.
    Davis. Timothy J. Simeone entered an appearance.
    C. Grey Pash Jr., Counsel, Federal Communications
    Commission, argued the cause for respondents. With him on
    the brief were William J. Baer, Assistant Attorney General,
    U.S. Department of Justice; Robert B. Nicholson and Robert
    J. Wiggers, Attorneys; Jonathan B. Sallet, Acting General
    Counsel, Federal Communications Commission; and Richard
    K. Welch, Deputy Associate General Counsel. Jacob M.
    Lewis, Associate General Counsel, Federal Communications
    Commission, entered an appearance.
    2
    Roy T. Englert Jr. was on the brief for amicus curiae
    National Association of the Deaf in support of petitioner.
    Before: HENDERSON and MILLETT, Circuit Judges, and
    GINSBURG, Senior Circuit Judge.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    GINSBURG.
    GINSBURG, Senior Circuit Judge: When a hearing- or
    speech-impaired person wants to make a phone call, he can
    choose among several services that will assist him in doing
    so. One of these, video relay service (VRS), works much like
    a video call that any caller might make using a digital
    platform such as Skype or Apple FaceTime. The video call is
    placed to an American Sign Language interpreter, employed
    by the VRS provider, who then makes a standard voice call to
    the video caller’s hearing recipient. The interpreter signs with
    the caller via the visual connection and speaks with the
    recipient via the voice connection, translating messages back
    and forth.
    The petitioner, Sorenson Communications, Inc., has been
    the leading provider of VRS since the service began to gain
    popularity about ten years ago. Like all providers of VRS,
    Sorenson is paid by the minute at a rate set by the Federal
    Communications Commission and paid by the Commission
    from the Telecommunications Relay Services Fund. The per-
    minute rate is supposed to approximate the cost incurred to
    provide VRS, but in fact for much of the past decade the rate
    has generated revenues well in excess of that cost. In order
    more accurately to reflect cost until it could develop a new
    approach to reimbursement, therefore, the Commission
    lowered the per-minute rates first in its 2010 Rate Order and
    again in its 2013 Rate Order, the latter of which is the subject
    3
    of Sorenson’s petition for review. Having incurred costs
    under the pre-2010 rates that cannot be sustained under the
    new rates, Sorenson complains that the new rates are too low
    and, additionally, that the decremental rates it receives for
    minutes in excess of 500,000 and of 1,000,000 unreasonably
    favor its smaller, allegedly less efficient competitors.
    Sorenson challenges the 2013 Rate Order as arbitrary and
    capricious, in violation of the Administrative Procedure Act, 5
    U.S.C. § 706(2)(a), but its challenge is problematic for two
    principal reasons. First, it made nearly the same challenge to
    the 2010 Rate Order and lost in the Tenth Circuit. Second, in
    suggesting the Commission should be required to compensate
    providers for certain additional costs, Sorenson largely fails to
    demonstrate (or even to make a threshold showing) that the
    costs are necessary to the provision of VRS; it instead
    emphasizes that it did in fact incur those costs, discretionary
    though they may be. Because the 2013 Rate Order is not
    arbitrary and capricious for ignoring costs incurred
    unnecessarily, even when the consequence for the provider
    that incurred those costs might be ruinous, we find no fault
    with the new rates.
    In one respect, however, Sorenson has demonstrated that
    additional consideration by the Commission is necessary:
    Providing service under the more demanding speed-of-answer
    requirement that the agency adopted as part of the 2013 Rate
    Order likely entails additional labor costs, a prospect nowhere
    addressed in the Order. We therefore vacate the new speed-
    of-answer requirement and remand that portion of the Order
    to the Commission to decide whether that requirement of
    improved service justifies increasing the rate of compensation
    concomitantly.
    4
    As for the tiered rates, we hold the Commission
    adequately justified the 500,000- and 1,000,000-minute cut-
    offs. As the agency explained, it was pursuing two goals –
    setting rates to reflect economies of scale and transitioning the
    industry from rate regulation to competitive bidding. Because
    the task of balancing those goals is fairly within the discretion
    of the agency, we defer to its decision concerning the tiered-
    rate structure.
    I. Background
    Title IV of the Americans with Disabilities Act of 1990
    (ADA) requires the Commission to make available
    telecommunications relay services (TRS), of which VRS is
    one, so that individuals with hearing or speech disabilities
    may have telephone service that is “functionally equivalent”
    to the voice system used by hearing individuals. 47 U.S.C.
    § 225. VRS users receive the enhanced service free of charge
    and the Commission compensates providers from the TRS
    Fund, which is financed by a tax the agency levies on the
    revenues of interstate telecommunications services.
    § 225(d)(3)(B); 47 C.F.R. § 64.604(c)(5)(iii). The statute
    directs the Commission to set compensation rates and
    functional requirements for providers in order to
    (1) “ensure that [TRS is] available, to the extent possible
    and in the most efficient manner, to hearing-impaired
    and speech-impaired individuals,” § 225(b)(1);
    (2) “require that users of [TRS] pay rates no greater than
    the rates paid for functionally equivalent voice
    communication services with respect to such factors
    as the duration of the call, the time of day, and the
    distance from point of origination to point of
    termination,” § 225(d)(1)(D); and
    5
    (3) “not discourage or impair the development of
    improved technology.” § 225(d)(2).
    When the FCC first recognized VRS as a form of TRS
    eligible for reimbursement, see In re Telecomms. Relay Servs.
    & Speech-to-Speech Servs. for Individuals with Hearing &
    Speech Disabilities, Report & Order, 15 FCC Rcd. 5140,
    5152-54, ¶¶ 21-27 (2000), video calling was “a specialized,
    niche market requiring customized hardware and software, as
    well as frequently unavailable broadband Internet access
    service.” In re Structure & Practices of the Video Relay Serv.
    Program, Telecomms. Relay Servs. & Speech-to-Speech
    Servs. for Individuals with Hearing & Speech Disabilities,
    Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 26 FCC Rcd. 17367,
    17380, ¶ 19 (2011) [hereinafter 2011 Notice]. As video
    calling has proliferated generally, so has VRS; callers now
    use over 10 million minutes of the service per month. See
    Interstate TRS Fund Performance Status Report, Rolka Loube
    Saltzer Associates (TRS Fund Administrator) (June 2014),
    http://www.r-l-s-a.com/TRS/reports/2014-06TRSStatus.pdf
    (last visited August 25, 2014). Despite video calling having
    become “a mainstream, mass-market offering,” 2011 Notice
    at ¶ 19, the market for VRS is highly concentrated and has
    become only more so in recent years: Sorenson provides
    about 80% of the VRS minutes logged every month, and its
    two principal competitors each provide another five to ten
    percent.
    From the inception of VRS until 2007, the Commission
    annually set compensation rates based upon the average of all
    VRS providers’ projected costs, as reported to a fund
    Administrator appointed by the agency. See In re Telecomms.
    Relay Servs. & Speech-to-Speech Servs. for Individuals with
    Hearing & Speech Disabilities, Report & Order, 19 FCC Rcd.
    12475, 12487-90, ¶¶ 17-24 (2004) [hereinafter 2004 R&O].
    6
    During this period, the Commission developed a list of
    compensable costs that has consistently included, for
    example, directly attributable overhead, labor costs, executive
    compensation, and an 11.25% rate of return on investment.
    Telecomms. Relay Servs. & Speech–to–Speech Servs. for
    Individuals with Hearing & Speech Disabilities, Report &
    Order & Declaratory Ruling, 22 FCC Rcd. 20140, 20161,
    ¶ 49, 20168-70, ¶¶ 74-80 (2007) [hereinafter 2007 Order];
    2004 R&O, 19 FCC Rcd. at 12544-45, ¶¶ 181-82, 12566,
    ¶ 238.     The Commission also consistently refused to
    compensate providers for a mark-up on expenses, the costs of
    research and development for enhancements that exceed
    mandatory minimum requirements, i.e., the baseline technical
    and operational standards providers must meet, see 47 C.F.R.
    § 64.404(b), and the costs of providing videophones,
    software, and technical assistance to VRS users. 2007 Order,
    22 FCC Rcd. at 20161, ¶ 49, 20170, ¶ 82; 2004 R&O, 19 FCC
    Rcd. at 12543-44, ¶¶ 179-81, 12547-48, ¶¶ 189-90; see also
    In re Telecomms. Relay Servs. & Speech-to-Speech Servs. for
    Individuals with Hearing & Speech Disabilities, Mem. Op. &
    Order, 21 FCC Rcd. 8063, 8071-72, ¶¶ 17-19 (2006)
    [hereinafter 2006 MO&O] (denying request to add categories
    of compensable costs).
    In 2007, the Commission sought to align reimbursement
    with actual compensable costs more closely and so adopted a
    three-year rate plan that included, for the first time, a tiered-
    rate structure. 2007 Order, 22 FCC Rcd. at 20161, ¶ 48,
    20163, ¶ 53. In order to reflect economies of scale, providers
    were compensated at a lower per-minute rate for minutes in
    excess of 50,000 per month, and at a still lower rate for
    minutes in excess of 500,000 per month. 
    Id. at 20167,
    ¶ 67.
    In 2010, the Commission began a major effort to
    overhaul VRS compensation and cut back on waste and fraud.
    7
    It issued a Notice of Inquiry in which it set forth problems
    with per-minute compensation and posed open-ended
    questions about a better methodology. See In re Structure &
    Practices of the Video Relay Serv. Program, Notice of
    Inquiry, 25 FCC Rcd. 8597 (2010). Pending this overhaul,
    the Commission announced it would set interim rates based in
    part upon actual historical costs instead of relying exclusively
    upon the projected costs providers had been submitting. In re
    Telecomms. Relay Servs. & Speech-to Speech Servs. for
    Individuals with Hearing & Speech Disabilities, Order, 25
    FCC Rcd. 8689, 8692-93, ¶ 6 (2010) [hereinafter 2010 Rate
    Order].
    The TRS Fund Administrator recommended blending the
    projected and historical costs to ease the austerity of this new
    methodology, and the Commission ultimately departed
    upward even from that recommendation because it would
    have entailed a sudden and significant diminution in revenues
    for VRS providers. 
    Id. at 8695-96,
    ¶ 12. For the 2009-2010
    year, providers had received $6.70, $6.43, and $6.24 for
    minutes in the three tiers respectively; the Administrator’s
    proposal for 2010-2011 was $5.78, $6.03, and $3.90, and the
    adopted rates were an average of the two, viz., $6.24, $6.23,
    and $5.07. 
    Id. at 8694,
    ¶ 8 tbl.1.
    Sorenson petitioned the U.S. Court of Appeals for the
    Tenth Circuit for review of the 2010 Rate Order, claiming it
    violated both the ADA and the APA. See Sorenson
    Commc’ns, Inc. v. FCC, 
    659 F.3d 1035
    (2011). There it
    challenged both the tiered-rate structure and the particular
    rates, but the Tenth Circuit upheld the 2010 Rate Order in
    both respects. 
    Id. at 1038.
    Continuing its overhaul effort, in 2011 the Commission
    issued a Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, in which it
    8
    called for comments on several proposals, including the
    institution of a per-user rate methodology and the elimination
    of the tiered-rate structure. 2011 Notice, 26 FCC Rcd. at
    17394, ¶ 53, 17396, ¶ 59, 17418, ¶ 141. Sorenson and the
    other providers responded with comments on these proposals
    and with suggestions of their own.
    In 2013 the Commission struck out in a new direction,
    announcing its intention to set compensation rates through
    competitive bidding among VRS providers. See In re
    Structure & Practices of the Video Relay Serv. Program,
    Telecomms. Relay Servs. & Speech-to-Speech Servs. for
    Individuals with Hearing & Speech Disabilities, Report &
    Order & Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 28 FCC
    Rcd. 8618, 8661, ¶ 107, 8706-07, ¶ 217 (2013) [hereinafter
    2013 Rate Order]. Because three years had elapsed since last
    setting VRS rates, however, the Commission also set a new
    “transitional rate plan” for 2013-2017 in order to bring per-
    minute rates still closer to historical compensable costs. 
    Id. at 8694,
    ¶ 188, 8702-04, ¶¶ 209, 212.
    The plan set the TRS Fund Administrator’s rate
    recommendation, which was based upon updated historical
    cost data, as the goal at the end of a “glide path.” 
    Id. at 8704,
    ¶ 212. The rates are to be adjusted downward every six
    months, starting at $5.98, $4.82, and $4.82 in 2013 and
    ending at $4.06, $4.06, and $3.49 in 2017. See 
    id. at 8705,
    ¶ 215 tbl.2. Additionally, the plan adopted a new tier
    structure in order better to reflect evidence of the minimum
    efficient scale for providing VRS. See 
    id. at 8698-702,
    ¶¶ 197-208. Tier II minutes now start at 500,000 and Tier III
    minutes start at 1,000,000. It also reduced the difference in
    the per-minute rates between tiers. 
    Id. at 8702,
    ¶ 208 tbl.1.
    9
    Sorenson petitioned this court for review of the 2013
    Rate Order. As in its Tenth Circuit case against the 2010 Rate
    Order, it challenges both the tiered-rate structure and the rates
    themselves.
    II. Analysis
    We address first the preclusive effect of the Tenth
    Circuit’s resolution of Sorenson’s challenges to the 2010 Rate
    Order. We then turn to the merits of Sorenson’s challenges
    unique to the 2013 Rate Order.
    A. Issue Preclusion
    The Commission asks us to dismiss Sorenson’s entire
    petition for review on the ground it is precluded by the Tenth
    Circuit’s decision denying the Company’s challenge to the
    2010 Rate Order, which raised the same issues with respect to
    the same ratemaking methodology as does the present
    petition. According to the Commission, it is immaterial that
    the present challenge is to a distinct rate order, whereas
    Sorenson argues the doctrine of issue preclusion is entirely
    inapplicable to the rates adopted in the 2013 Rate Order.
    The doctrine of issue preclusion bars “‘successive
    litigation of an issue of fact or law actually litigated and
    resolved in a valid court determination essential to the prior
    judgment,’ even if the issue recurs in the context of a different
    claim.” Taylor v. Sturgell, 
    553 U.S. 880
    , 892 (2008) (quoting
    New Hampshire v. Maine, 
    532 U.S. 742
    , 748-49 (2001)). As
    applied to a challenge to agency action, this court has
    consistently held a petitioner may not relitigate an agency’s
    “standards and procedures ... prior to each application”
    thereof. W. Coal Traffic League v. ICC, 
    735 F.2d 1408
    , 1410
    (1984); accord Nat'l Classification Comm. v. United States,
    10
    
    765 F.2d 164
    , 169-70 (1985). Therefore, in order to avoid
    issue preclusion, a petitioner bringing a successive challenge
    to the application of an established ratemaking methodology
    that the agency did not reconsider (or change) must show
    circumstances have changed in a way that required the agency
    to reconsider (or to change) it. Cf. Tesoro Alaska Petroleum
    Co. v. FERC, 
    234 F.3d 1286
    , 1290 (D.C. Cir. 2000) (in an
    adjudicatory proceeding, agency may preclude repeat
    argument that a rate is unreasonable unless the challenger
    presents “new evidence” or demonstrates “changed
    circumstances”); W. Coal Traffic 
    League, 735 F.2d at 1410
    (where rulemaking is “standard-setting, not standard-
    implementing, in character,” issue preclusion will not bar a
    challenge to an agency’s “renewed consideration” of an
    existing standard it ultimately decides to retain). This
    application of the doctrine is consistent with Commissioner v.
    Sunnen, 
    333 U.S. 591
    (1948), where the Supreme Court
    explained that a party could be collaterally estopped from
    relitigating the judicial determination of a tax issue it had
    raised and lost with respect to a prior tax year, but warned that
    “where the situation is vitally altered between the time of the
    first judgment and the second, the prior determination is not
    conclusive.” 
    Id. at 599-600.
    1. Compensable expenses
    Pursuant to these principles, we hold Sorenson’s
    challenge to the Commission’s list of compensable expenses
    is precluded. More specifically, Sorenson argues the rates
    should be calculated to reimburse its costs for providing users
    with video equipment, training users, porting phone numbers,
    and “raising and servicing [debt] capital.” With regard to all
    these expenses, however, Sorenson is merely attempting to
    relitigate an application of the standard it challenged in its
    petition for review of the 2010 Rate Order. See Sorenson,
    
    11 659 F.3d at 1046
    (“In [Sorenson’s] view, [the
    Administrator’s] proposed rates are badly flawed because
    they do not reflect Sorenson's actual costs of providing
    services”); 2013 Rate Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 8695-98,
    ¶¶ 191-96 (approving the same compensable costs as had the
    previous order and addressing questions raised about the
    categories in the 2011 Notice).
    The Tenth Circuit rejected Sorenson’s challenge to the
    Commission's current list of compensable costs, holding the
    agency had neither violated the ADA nor failed the arbitrary-
    and-capricious test of the 
    APA. 659 F.3d at 1043-45
    ; 
    id. at 1046-47.
    Sorenson points to no new evidence or changed
    circumstances suggesting the Commission was required to
    expand its list of compensable costs.
    Sorenson does argue two features of the 2013 Rate Order
    make the Commission’s application of the list of compensable
    costs different from its application in the 2010 Rate Order,
    thus suggesting the Tenth Circuit did not actually decide the
    issues Sorenson is raising now. First, the 2013 Rate Order
    includes a provision directing and funding a neutral third
    party to develop a “VRS access technology reference
    platform” that will operate as a software application and be
    “useable on commonly available off the shelf equipment and
    operating systems.” 2013 Rate Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 8644-
    45, ¶¶ 53-55. According to Sorenson, this provision suggests
    the Commission has a new interpretation of its statutory
    mandate that makes giving video equipment to users free of
    charge a necessary cost. But see 
    id. at 8696,
    ¶ 193 (reiterating
    the agency’s consistent position, see, e.g., 2006 MO&O, 21
    FCC Rcd. at 8071, ¶ 17, that providers may be compensated
    only for “the providers’ expenses in making the service
    available and not the customer’s costs of receiving the
    equipment”).
    12
    On the contrary, developing a common platform for off-
    the-shelf equipment and operating systems will make
    provider-funded video equipment even less relevant to the
    provision of VRS and will give users an experience more
    closely akin to that of hearing telecommunications customers,
    who buy their equipment off the shelf. See 2011 Notice, FCC
    Rcd. at 17380, ¶ 19 (“Indeed, currently available commercial
    video technology can provide closer functional equivalence,
    may be less costly, and is likely to improve at a faster pace
    than the custom devices supplied exclusively by VRS
    providers”). Therefore, the Tenth Circuit’s determination the
    statute does not require that “VRS users receive free
    equipment,” only that they “pay no higher rates for calls than
    others pay for traditional phone services,” is preclusive.
    
    Sorenson, 659 F.3d at 1044
    .
    Second, Sorenson points out that the 2013 Rate Order
    sets rates for four years (until 2017), whereas the 2010 Rate
    Order set rates for one year (although the Commission later
    renewed those rates for two more years, i.e., until 2013).
    Therefore, Sorenson argues, the Tenth Circuit could not have
    resolved any issue with regard to a four-year rate plan because
    the rates it reviewed were “interim” in nature and the Tenth
    Circuit upheld the rates on the premise that the Commission
    soon would revisit its ratemaking methodology.
    Sorenson’s focus upon the respective timeframes of the
    2010 and 2013 Rate Orders is misplaced. Because the agency
    is transitioning to a new ratemaking methodology, the 2013
    Rate Order is “interim” in the precise way the 2010 Rate
    Order was when the Tenth Circuit reviewed it. See 
    Sorenson, 659 F.3d at 1046
    n.6 (relying upon the Commission’s
    “intention that the new rates be temporary while it totally
    reevaluates VRS compensation”). Nor has anything of
    significance changed over the years between the two Orders;
    13
    both adopt per-minute rates based upon the same long-
    standing list of compensable costs. Therefore, Sorenson’s
    challenge to the compensable expenses is precluded by our
    sister circuit’s holding that “the categories of compensable
    costs in [the] proposed rates are the same categories that were
    compensable when the agency reimbursed on the basis of
    providers’ projected costs. …          Particularly given this
    consistent position on allowable costs, the Commission
    provided a sufficient explanation for declining to change the
    categories of allowed costs during the interim period.”
    
    Sorenson, 659 F.3d at 1046
    -47.
    2. Other issues
    Contrary to the Commission’s contention, none of
    Sorenson’s four other challenges to the 2013 Rate Order is
    precluded. First, Sorenson challenges the levels at which the
    Commission set rates of return on labor and on capital
    investments. Although these levels are the same in the 2013
    and 2010 Rate Orders, perusal of its briefs in the earlier case
    makes clear that Sorenson did not challenge those rates before
    the Tenth Circuit and so they have not been “actually litigated
    and resolved” by a court.
    Sorenson’s other three challenges concern features
    unique to the 2013 Rate Order and therefore could not have
    been resolved in the Tenth Circuit case. Sorenson challenges
    the “end result” of the Order, Fed. Power Comm'n v. Hope
    Natural Gas Co., 
    320 U.S. 591
    , 603 (1944) (first adopting the
    “end result” criterion), claiming it will cause VRS providers
    to go out of business and hence will disrupt service to
    hearing- and speech-impaired individuals. This alleged
    problem clearly is unique to the 2013 Rate Order; the Tenth
    Circuit specifically said Sorenson, in its challenge to the 2010
    Rate Order, did “not contend that under the interim VRS rates
    14
    it, or any other provider, will be unable to serve any customer
    who requests 
    service.” 659 F.3d at 1043
    . Likewise, Sorenson
    is not precluded from arguing the rate is too low to cover
    providers’ costs of complying with the requirement that they
    answer 85% of calls within 30 seconds, measured daily,
    because that speed of answer was newly imposed by the 2013
    Rate Order. Cf. 
    id. (“Sorenson does
    not claim that it will be
    unable to satisfy the mandatory 80/120 speed-of-answer
    requirement under the interim rates”).
    Finally, Sorenson challenges the new tiered-rate structure
    in the 2013 Rate Order. The Tenth Circuit, although it upheld
    the tiered-rate structure in the 2010 Rate Order, 
    id. at 1048-
    50, could not have resolved Sorenson’s challenge to the
    tiered-rate structure in the 2013 Rate Order because the
    Commission adopted a new “configuration” for the tiers,
    raising the cut-offs and reducing the differences between tiers,
    as a step toward realization of its plan to institute competitive
    bidding among firms in the future. See 2013 Rate Order, 28
    FCC Rcd. at 8698-702, ¶¶ 197-208. Moreover, Sorenson
    argues the tiered rates are arbitrary and capricious in light of
    “new evidence” and a “changed circumstance,” respectively:
    The Commission maintained a tiered-rate structure even as it
    acknowledged new evidence about minimum efficient scale
    and concluded that tiered rates were inefficient.
    We turn next to address the merits of the four above-
    mentioned issues.
    B. Rate of Return
    Sorenson argues the Commission’s interim ratemaking
    methodology “virtually guarantees that providers will be
    unable to earn a reasonable rate of return” because it allows
    for an 11.25% rate of return on physical capital but no return
    15
    on labor, which is “the primary thing [providers] sell.”
    According to Sorenson, this limitation, which originated with
    monopoly telephone companies, is inappropriate and hence
    arbitrary and capricious as applied to the labor- rather than
    capital-intensive VRS industry. The reasonableness of the
    rates, it maintains, should be judged on the profit margin as a
    percentage of its total cost, which it shows is likely to be less
    than 2% under the agency’s interim methodology.
    1. Denial of a return on labor costs
    As the Commission has explained more than once, a
    provider of VRS is entitled to compensation only for the
    reasonable costs of providing VRS. 2013 Rate Order, 28
    FCC Rcd. at 8692, ¶ 181; see also 47 U.S.C. § 225(d)(3)(B)
    (the TRS Fund shall reimburse only the “costs caused by
    interstate telecommunications relay services”); In re
    Telecomms. Relay Servs. & Speech-to-Speech Servs. for
    Individuals with Hearing & Speech Disabilities, Report &
    Order, Order on Reconsideration, and Further Notice of
    Proposed Rulemaking, 19 FCC Rcd. 12475, 12543-44, ¶ 181
    (2004) [hereinafter 2004 Order] (reasonable costs are ‘‘those
    direct and indirect costs necessary to provide the service’’).
    Therefore, the Commission acts directly in accordance with
    its statutory mandate by setting rates to compensate providers
    for their actual labor costs. Wages are the costs of hiring
    labor, just as interest and dividends are the cost of hiring
    capital. A “return” on labor costs in addition to revenues
    sufficient to cover the wages themselves would in effect
    increase the Company’s compensation above what is
    necessary for the provision of VRS. See 2007 Order, 22 FCC
    Rcd. at 20161, ¶ 49 (“[T]he ‘reasonable’ costs of providing
    service for which providers are entitled to compensation do
    not include profit or a mark-up on expenses”). Therefore,
    Sorenson has not met its burden of showing the agency’s
    16
    decision to provide for recovery of labor costs as an expense
    was arbitrary or capricious. See generally 1 ALFRED E. KAHN,
    THE ECONOMICS OF REGULATION: PRINCIPLES AND
    INSTITUTIONS 26-54 (1970) (discussing the proper
    compensation for operating costs versus capital outlays).
    2. Sufficiency of the return on capital
    Sorenson next argues that it was arbitrary and capricious
    for the Commission to set the rate of return on capital at
    11.25%, which rate it borrowed 20 years ago from its
    regulation of monopoly telephone companies. Although there
    are, of course, many differences between the traditional
    telephone business and VRS, that alone is not cause to vacate
    the rate of return. “Even assuming [the agency] made
    missteps ... , the burden is on petitioners to demonstrate that
    [the agency’s] ultimate conclusions are unreasonable.” Nat’l
    Petrochemical & Refiners Ass’n v. EPA, 
    287 F.3d 1130
    , 1146
    (D.C. Cir. 2002).
    Sorenson advances two specific reasons for deeming the
    11.25% rate of return unreasonable: (1) when spread over all
    costs, the rate yields a gross profit margin of less than 2%,
    and (2) the rate is too low to attract necessary capital to the
    VRS business. The first argument has no merit whatsoever;
    the second is simply unproven.
    As we explained in relation to labor costs, and as the
    Commission has been explaining since its 2004 Order, 19
    FCC Rcd. at 12543-44, ¶¶ 178-81, the agency is not required
    to compensate providers for anything more than the
    reasonable costs of providing VRS, which include the cost of
    hiring the necessary capital. A provider’s accounting profit
    margin as a percentage of its total costs is of no moment
    whatsoever.
    17
    In contrast, if Sorenson is correct that the 11.25% rate of
    return is too low to attract the capital necessary to operate a
    VRS business, then it should prevail in its quest for a higher
    rate. Cf. Jersey Cent. Power & Light Co. v. FERC, 
    810 F.2d 1168
    , 1178 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (en banc) (“[T]he reviewing
    court ‘must determine’ whether the Commission’s rate order
    may reasonably be expected to ‘maintain financial integrity’
    and ‘attract necessary capital.’” (quoting In re Permian Basin
    Area Rate Cases, 
    390 U.S. 747
    , 792 (1968))). Sorenson
    raised this issue before the agency by arguing VRS presents a
    “significantly different risk profile to the capital markets”
    than does a conventional telephone company. It pointed out
    the VRS industry is competitive rather than monopolistic, the
    firms are smaller, and the regulatory risk is greater because
    VRS providers receive nearly all their revenue not from a
    large number of customers but from a single source, viz., the
    TRS Fund.
    Although these differences do suggest a telephone
    company’s rate of return is not an obvious proxy for
    reimbursing a provider of VRS, we cannot conclude the
    Commission’s admittedly flawed* basis for selecting a rate
    leads to an arbitrary and capricious result because there is no
    evidence in the record to suggest Sorenson or any other
    provider actually has had trouble raising the necessary capital
    under the long-standing 11.25% rate regime. Because the
    Commission is required to raise the allowable rate of return
    only if presented with evidence the current rate is insufficient
    to attract capital, Sorenson did not carry its burden of proof
    *
    The Commission acknowledges the rate of return is based upon a
    flawed analogy; in its view, however, the rate is too high because
    capital is less expensive than it was 20 years ago. See FCC Br. 40
    (citing proceedings to lower the authorized rate of return as part of
    a comprehensive reform of the Universal Service Fund).
    18
    before the agency. Cf. 
    Tesoro, 234 F.3d at 1290
    (suggesting a
    ratemaking agency is required to revisit whether its existing
    ratemaking methodology is reasonable only when presented
    with new evidence or changed circumstances). Therefore, we
    defer to the Commission’s judgment that its long-standing
    11.25% rate of return provides an adequate, and thus
    reasonable, approach to setting per-minute rates while
    transitioning to a new methodology.
    C. End Result of the Rates
    Sorenson next challenges the 2013 Rate Order as
    arbitrary and capricious because the Commission did not
    respond to its evidence that the end result of the rates would
    be to “drive every provider out of business or into
    bankruptcy,” degrading service and violating the statutory
    mandate requiring service be made “available, to the extent
    possible,” 47 U.S.C. § 225(b)(1). Sorenson’s challenge to the
    end result of the rates is distinct from its challenge to the
    component parts of the agency’s ratemaking methodology,
    see Jersey 
    Cent., 810 F.2d at 1177
    (“In examining the end
    result of the rate order, ... a court cannot affirm simply
    because each of the component decisions of that order, taken
    in isolation, was permissible; it must be the case ‘that they do
    not     together    produce     arbitrary    or   unreasonable
    consequences’” (quoting and adding emphasis to Permian
    
    Basin, 390 U.S. at 800
    )); Sorenson, however, fails to establish
    the end result of this Rate Order is arbitrary or unreasonable.
    It is not unreasonable for the Commission to allow a provider
    to go bankrupt if that provider has incurred costs far in excess
    of what is necessary.
    Sorenson points out that comments before the agency by
    all the major providers indicated “no provider could offer
    service at the rates proposed by the Administrator,” but the
    19
    comments to which it refers are inapposite to Sorenson’s
    claim because they addressed the rates proposed by the
    Administrator,* not the higher rates and “glide path” actually
    adopted by the Commission. Perhaps that is why the other
    providers, which did not incur the same level of non-
    compensable costs, are not petitioning for review of the 2013
    Rate Order. In any event, the Commission explained why it
    would not cover all of a provider’s actual costs even if the
    result were to bankrupt the company. In the Order under
    review it reasoned that it would be “irresponsible and contrary
    to our mandate to ensure the efficient provision of TRS ... to
    simply reimburse VRS providers for all capital costs they
    have chosen to incur – such as high levels of debt – where
    there is no reason to believe that those costs are necessary to
    the provision of reimbursable services.” 2013 Rate Order, 28
    FCC Rcd. at 8697, ¶195. The agency was even more explicit
    about the prospect of bankruptcy in the Notice that preceded
    the Order:
    *
    See, e.g., Comments of CSDRVS, LLC, Docket Nos. 10-51 & 03-
    123, 2-3 (May 31, 2013) (J.A. 825-26) (discussing “The RLSA
    Rate Proposal”); Comments of Purple Commc’ns., Inc., Docket
    Nos. 10-51 & 03-123, 12 (Nov. 14, 2012) (J.A. 624) (discussing
    “TRS Fund Administrator’s Rate Proposal”); Comments of Convo
    Commc’ns., Inc., Docket Nos. 10-51 & 03-123, 5-6 (Nov. 14,
    2012) (J.A. 552-53) (discussing “The VRS Rates Proposed by
    RLSA”); Ex Parte Notice of CSDVRS, LLC, Docket Nos. 10-51 &
    30-123 (Oct. 25, 2012) (objecting to “compensation rates if they are
    at all similar to what Rolka Loube Saltzer Associates (“RLSA”) has
    proposed); Comments of Hancock, Jahn, Lee & Puckett, LLC d/b/a
    Communication Axcess Ability Group (CAAG), Docket Nos. 10-
    51 & 03-123, 5-7 (Nov. 15, 2012) (discussing “RLSA’s Rate
    Proposals”).
    20
    If ... some providers are not able to manage their
    businesses, gain scale, or support their existing capital
    structures during a transition period, they will likely have
    to change their current business plans. ... We ... will not
    act to preserve any particular competitor. We do not
    believe that any provider has an inherent entitlement to
    receive compensation from the Fund, and so do not
    regard as the goal the protection of VRS providers who
    are high cost and/or uncompetitive.
    2011 Notice, 26 FCC Rcd. at 17399, ¶ 66.
    Sorenson’s costs were particularly high for two reasons.
    First, it was saddled with the debt it had incurred to finance a
    leveraged buyout. (A private equity firm, having acquired the
    Company, then caused it to incur substantial debt in order to
    fund a dividend to its new owner.) See In re Telecomms.
    Relay Servs. & Speech-to-Speech Servs. for Individuals with
    Hearing & Speech Disabilities, Order Denying Stay Motion,
    25 FCC Rcd. 9115, 9121, ¶ 21 (2010). In addition, Sorenson
    purchased and then gave users videophones free of charge in
    order to encourage their use of its service, but the cost of that
    equipment was not and never had been deemed compensable
    by the Commission. See 
    id. at 9120,
    ¶ 16. The reasons for
    Sorenson’s financial hardship, therefore, are precisely the
    reasons the Commission had rightly warned were insufficient
    justification for raising rates. Moreover, Sorenson is wrong
    to equate bankruptcy with an inability to provide reasonable
    service; the Commission did not have before it any evidence
    that Sorenson’s service would be degraded if its debt
    obligations were reduced or restructured as equity in a
    bankruptcy proceeding. Nor does Sorenson give us any
    reason to believe insolvency would cause a provider to exit
    the market so long as the reasonable costs of continuing to
    21
    provide service, including an appropriate return on equity and
    wages sufficient to attract labor, remain fully recoverable.
    D. Speed-of-Answer Requirement
    Sorenson’s penultimate challenge is to the new speed-of-
    answer requirement, with which it claims it cannot comply at
    the per-minute rates set by the Order. In response to the
    Commission’s call for comments about whether to tighten this
    requirement, see 2011 Notice, 26 FCC Rcd. at 17405, ¶ 87
    (“[S]hould the speed of answer requirements set forth in [47
    C.F.R. §] 64.604(b)(2) be modified?”), Sorenson explained
    that a faster speed of answer meant a higher cost of service.
    Reply Comments of Sorenson, Commc’ns., Inc., Docket Nos.
    10-51 & 03-123, 49 (Mar. 30, 2012) (J.A. 410) (“speed-of-
    answer is directly affected by compensation levels”).
    Because the Commission did not specify the metric it was
    considering, however, Sorenson did not have occasion to state
    whether or by how much its labor cost would increase if it
    were required to answer 85% of all calls within 30 seconds,
    measured daily (as the Commission went on to require) rather
    than 80% of all calls within 120 seconds, measured monthly
    (as it had been required to and was doing).
    The Commission adopted this more demanding speed-of-
    answer requirement based in part upon the explicit premise
    that it would not increase labor costs over the historical costs
    upon which the rates in the 2013 Rate Order are based,
    contrary to the general relationship suggested by Sorenson
    and without citing any evidence to dispel that suggestion. See
    2013 Rate Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 8671-72, ¶¶ 137 & 139
    (“[T]his action will set a new standard for VRS provider
    performance without additional cost to providers or the TRS
    Fund”). Even if the Commission was correct in saying “[t]he
    record indicates that VRS providers already achieve a speed
    22
    of answer of 30 seconds for the majority of VRS calls,” 
    id. at 8671,
    ¶ 137 – an assertion for which we have found no
    support – that says nothing about the cost of achieving the 30-
    second speed of answer 85% of the time, measured daily.
    Indeed, counsel for the Commission conceded at oral
    argument that, to the extent it adopted the new standard on the
    premise that providers were already meeting that standard
    measured daily, the agency was mistaken. Oral Arg. R.
    29:40-30:05.
    The Commission argues this challenge to the speed-of-
    answer requirement is not ripe for judicial review because
    Sorenson “never presented [it] to the Commission.” We have
    held, however, an issue is ripe for review pursuant to section
    405(a) of the Communications Act of 1934, 47 U.S.C.
    § 405(a), if the Commission had an “opportunity to pass”
    upon the question of fact or law raised in the petition; the
    party need not have raised the precise argument before the
    agency. See Time Warner Entm’t Co. v. FCC, 
    144 F.3d 75
    ,
    79 (D.C. Cir. 1998). Because the Commission had before it
    comments that suggested costs would go up under an
    enhanced metric for speed of answer, and because it reached
    the opposite conclusion on that very issue, the Commission
    had and indeed took the opportunity to pass upon the
    question. Therefore, Sorenson’s challenge is ripe for judicial
    review.
    Turning to the substance of that challenge, we need
    hardly do more than note that the Commission is, by its own
    interpretation of the ADA, required to reimburse providers for
    all costs necessarily incurred to meet the mandatory minimum
    standards established by the agency, see 2004 Order, 19 FCC
    Rcd. at 12543-44, ¶ 181, of which speed-of-answer is one, see
    47 C.F.R. § 64.604(b)(2)(iii). By adopting the new speed-of-
    answer metric without evidence of the cost to comply with it,
    23
    the Commission acted arbitrarily and capriciously. See
    Permian 
    Basin, 390 U.S. at 792
    (“[E]ach of the order’s
    essential elements [must be] supported by substantial
    evidence”). Moreover, because the only evidence before the
    Commission was Sorenson’s submission indicating costs go
    up when standards of service go up, the new metric fails the
    “requirement of reasoned decisionmaking.” Allentown Mack
    Sales & Serv., Inc. v. NLRB, 
    522 U.S. 359
    , 374 (1998);
    accord Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n v. State Farm Mut. Auto
    Ins. Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 43 (1983) (a decision is arbitrary and
    capricious if the agency “offered an explanation for its
    decision that runs counter to the evidence before the agency”).
    Sorenson asks us to remedy this error by vacating the
    new rates in the 2013 Rate Order. We think it more
    appropriate for two reasons instead to vacate the new speed-
    of-answer requirement. First, it is the less disruptive course,
    more precisely tailored to the problem with the Order. Cf.
    Owner-Operator Indep. Drivers Ass’n v. Fed. Motor Carrier
    Safety Admin., 
    494 F.3d 188
    , 212 (D.C. Cir. 2007) (vacating
    only the offending parts of a rule despite petitioner’s request
    for vacatur of the whole). Second, we think the Commission,
    in expressing its understanding that it could adopt the new
    requirement without adding to costs, implied that its priority
    was to keep rates down, not to force the quality of service up;
    i.e., it wanted what it thought was a free lunch, leaving us in
    doubt whether it wanted the lunch if it was not free. On
    remand, the Commission is free, of course, to renew its
    consideration of the tradeoff: It may adhere to the status quo
    ante, reinstate the requirement we vacate today, or impose a
    different standard, as long as it bases its decision upon
    evidence of the required labor costs and adjusts the rates in
    the 2013 Rate Order to reflect any increase over the historical
    costs upon which they were based.
    24
    E. Tiered-Rate Structure
    Finally, Sorenson contends the tiered-rate structure is
    arbitrary and capricious for two distinct reasons. First, it
    argues, having tiered rates is inherently contrary to the
    Commission’s stated position that they are inefficient and
    should be eliminated. 2013 Rate Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at
    8698, ¶ 198 (the TRS Fund should not “support indefinitely
    VRS operations that are substantially less efficient”); see also
    2011 Notice, 26 FCC Rcd. at 17418, ¶ 141 (the “tiered rate
    structure supports an unnecessarily inefficient market
    structure, and apparently provides insufficient incentive for
    VRS providers to achieve minimal efficient scale”). As we
    see it, however, the decision to retain the tiers while
    transitioning to a competitive-bidding scheme is not
    inconsistent with the Commission’s stated position. The
    agency made clear in the 2013 Rate Order that it still plans to
    eliminate the per-minute rate methodology and that its
    critique of tiered rates guided its planning for the interim.
    2013 Rate Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at 8702, ¶ 205. It raised the
    cut-offs between the tiers immediately and will reduce over
    time the gap between the highest and lowest tiered rates,
    which adjustments increase the incentive to achieve minimum
    efficient scale, consistent with the concerns it expressed in the
    2011 Notice. See 
    id. at 8698,
    ¶ 198.
    Second, Sorenson challenges the specific cut-off levels
    demarcating the new tiers, arguing they are not optimal for
    achieving the Commission’s stated goal of supporting smaller
    providers until they grow to an efficient scale and are able to
    compete effectively. At its core, this objection is no more
    than a quibble over the precise cut-off that would be most
    efficient in the short term, and is certainly not significant
    enough to impugn the agency’s transitional methodology,
    which is explicitly aimed at achieving efficiency in the long
    25
    run. See 
    id. at 8699,
    ¶ 200 (“We conclude that it is worth
    tolerating some degree of additional inefficiency in the short
    term, in order to maximize the opportunity for successful
    participation of multiple efficient providers in the future, in
    the more competition-friendly environment that we expect to
    result from our structural reforms”). As we have noted before
    with regard to ratemaking, “[t]he relevant question is whether
    the agency’s numbers are within a zone of reasonableness, not
    whether its numbers are precisely right.” WorldCom, Inc. v.
    FCC, 
    238 F.3d 449
    , 462 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (quotation marks
    omitted). Because the Commission relied upon evidence in
    the record that supports its conclusions about minimum
    efficient scale, see, e.g., 2013 Rate Order, 28 FCC Rcd. at
    8699-700, ¶¶ 202-03, we are satisfied the cut-offs are within
    the zone of reasonableness and we defer to the agency’s
    judgment about how best to achieve a smooth transition to
    competitive bidding.
    III. Conclusion
    For the foregoing reasons, we vacate only the new speed-
    of-answer requirement prescribed in ¶¶ 135-39 of the 2013
    Rate Order. 28 FCC Rcd. at 8671-72. We remand that
    portion of the Order to the Commission to consider whether
    an enhanced speed-of-answer requirement will increase
    providers’ costs and, if so, whether having faster service is
    worth the concomitant increase in rates. Pending further
    action by the Commission, this decision will have the effect
    of reinstating the requirement that 80% of VRS calls be
    answered within 120 seconds, measured on a monthly basis.
    See 
    id. at 8671,
    ¶ 135.
    So ordered.