Alliance of Nonprofit Mailers v. Postal Regulatory Commission ( 2015 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued September 9, 2014               Decided June 5, 2015
    No. 14-1009
    ALLIANCE OF NONPROFIT MAILERS, ET AL.,
    PETITIONERS
    v.
    POSTAL REGULATORY COMMISSION,
    RESPONDENT
    AMERICAN FOREST & PAPER ASSOCIATION, ET AL.,
    INTERVENORS
    Consolidated with 14-1010
    On Petitions for Review of an Order
    of the Postal Regulatory Commission
    Paul D. Clement argued the cause for petitioner United
    States Postal Service. With him on the briefs were Jeffrey M.
    Harris, Barbara A. Smith, and David C. Belt, Attorney, U.S.
    Postal Service. Stephen T. Boardman, Attorney, entered an
    appearance.
    David M. Levy argued the cause for petitioner Mailer
    Petitioners and Supporting Intervenors. With him on the
    briefs were Matthew D. Field, John F. Cooney, David F.
    2
    Stover, William B. Baker, Matthew D. Field, Ian D. Volner,
    James E. Anderson, Tonda Rush, Donna Hanbery, William J.
    Olson, Jeremiah L. Morgan, John S. Miles, and Keith
    Kupferschmid.
    Daniel Tenny, Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice,
    argued the cause for respondent. With him on the brief were
    Stuart F. Delery, Assistant Attorney General, Michael S.
    Raab, Attorney, David A. Trissell, General Counsel, Postal
    Regulatory Commission, R. Brian Corcoran, Deputy General
    Counsel, Richard A. Oliver, Robert N. Sidman, and Anne J.
    Siarnacki, Attorneys.
    Before: BROWN, MILLETT and WILKINS, Circuit Judges.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge MILLETT.
    MILLETT, Circuit Judge: “Neither snow nor rain nor heat
    nor gloom of night stays these couriers from the swift
    completion of their appointed rounds.”1 But a bad economy
    might. Or so the Postal Service worried when the recent
    recession caused mail volumes—and thus Postal Service
    income—to plummet precipitously. Citing exigent economic
    circumstances, the Postal Service sought a 4.3% rate increase
    from the Postal Regulatory Commission.
    The Commission agreed that the recession that started in
    2008 was an “extraordinary or exceptional circumstance” that
    warranted some rate increase, but the Commission only
    permitted the Postal Service to recover $2.8 billion in lost
    revenue. The Commission reasoned that, by 2011, the Postal
    1
    United     States  Postal   Service,     Unofficial  Motto,
    https://about.usps.com/who-we-are/postal-history/mission-
    motto.pdf (Oct. 1999).
    3
    Service should have adjusted to a “new normal” business
    environment in which mail volumes appeared to be
    permanently lower than their pre-recession levels. The
    Commission also concluded that lost mail volumes could only
    be counted in the first year they occurred, even before the
    “new normal” arrived.
    The Postal Service says the Commission’s decision did
    not go far enough; mailer industry groups say the
    Commission went too far; and the Commission says it got the
    order just right. We hold that the Commission’s “new
    normal” determination is reasonable, but its rule that lost mail
    volumes should be counted only once makes no sense on this
    record. We therefore grant the Postal Service’s petition for
    review in part.        Finally, because the Commission’s
    econometric analysis was well within the wide bounds of
    agency expertise, we deny the separate petition for review
    filed by representatives of the mailing industry.
    I
    Statutory Framework
    Since the founding of the Republic, the Postal Service
    has been charged with “bind[ing] the Nation together through
    the personal, educational, literary, and business
    correspondence of the people.” 
    39 U.S.C. § 101
    (a). The
    Postal Service does so by providing “prompt, reliable, and
    efficient service to patrons in all areas and * * * all
    communities,” 
    id.,
     while charging “uniform [prices]
    throughout the United States, its territories, and possessions,”
    
    id.
     § 404(c).
    Since 1970, the Postal Service has been a government-
    owned corporation, which Congress expected to be largely
    self-sufficient financially. See Pub. L. No. 91-375, 
    84 Stat.
                                 4
    719 (1970). In the Postal Accountability and Enhancement
    Act of 2006 (“Accountability Act”), Pub. L. No. 109-435, 
    120 Stat. 3198
    , Congress created the Postal Regulatory
    Commission to oversee and administer a pricing regime for
    the Postal Service. 
    39 U.S.C. §§ 502
    (a), 3622(a). In addition,
    Congress imposed a price cap on Postal Service charges to
    “create predictability and stability in rates” while
    “maximiz[ing] incentives to reduce costs and increase
    efficiency,” 
    39 U.S.C. § 3622
    (b)(1) & (2). Postage rates for
    “market-dominant products”—that is, products over which
    the Postal Service enjoys either a statutory or practical
    monopoly (such as first-class mail and periodicals)—may rise
    only with the rate of inflation. See 
    id.
     § 3622(d)(1)(A).
    But hard times can call for hard measures. So Congress
    created a safety valve in the new pricing system that allows
    the Service to raise rates for market-dominant products above
    the inflation level if the Commission determines that an
    increase is warranted “due to either extraordinary or
    exceptional circumstances.” 
    39 U.S.C. § 3622
    (d)(1)(E). To
    permit such an exigent rate change, the Commission must
    find, after notice and public comment, that “such adjustment
    is reasonable and equitable and necessary to enable the Postal
    Service, under best practices of honest, efficient, and
    economical management, to maintain and continue the
    development of postal services of the kind and quality
    adapted to the needs of the United States.” 
    Id.
    II
    Procedural History
    Round One
    The Postal Service filed its first request for an exigent
    rate increase in 2010. The Postal Service claimed that the last
    5
    recession (which the Commission dubs the “Great
    Recession”) caused a “dramatic, rapid, and unprecedented
    decline in mail volume,” and sought to raise prices by more
    than five percent. See Exigent Request of the U.S. Postal
    Service, Postal Regulatory Commission Docket No. R2010–4,
    at 1 (July 6, 2010).
    The Commission denied that request. Although it agreed
    that “the recent recession, and the decline in mail volume
    experienced during the recession” counted as an
    “extraordinary or exceptional circumstance,” the Commission
    concluded that the Postal Service had not shown that it needed
    a rate increase “due to” the recession. Postal Regulatory
    Commission, Order Denying Request for Exigent Rate
    Adjustments, Order No. 547, Docket No. R2010–4, at 3 (Sept.
    30, 2010) (quoting 
    39 U.S.C. § 3622
    (d)(1)(E)). In particular,
    the Postal Service had failed “to quantify the impact of the
    recession on postal finances, address how the requested rate
    increases relate to the recession’s impact on postal volumes,
    or identify how the requested rates resolve the crisis at hand.”
    
    Id. at 4
    .
    The Postal Service petitioned for review. This court
    affirmed the Commission’s determination that “the plain
    meaning of [
    39 U.S.C. § 3622
    (d)(1)(E)] requires a causal
    relationship between the exigent circumstances and the
    proposed rate adjustments.” United States Postal Service v.
    Postal Regulatory Comm’n, 
    640 F.3d 1263
    , 1267 (D.C. Cir.
    2011). The court also held, however, that the phrase “due to”
    in the Accountability Act was ambiguous, since it “can mean
    ‘due in part to’ as well as ‘due only to.’” 
    Id. at 1268
    . The
    court accordingly remanded to the Commission “to fill the
    statutory gap by determining how closely the amount of the
    adjustments must match the amount of the revenue lost as a
    result of the exigent circumstances.” 
    Id.
    6
    Round Two
    On remand, the Commission issued Order 864, in which
    it interpreted “due to” to mean “that exigent rate adjustments
    are permitted only if, and to the extent that, they compensate
    for the net adverse financial impact of the exigent
    circumstances.”      Postal Regulatory Commission, Order
    Resolving Issues on Remand, Order No. 864, Docket No.
    R2010–4R, at 25 (September 20, 2011). In demonstrating
    that causal linkage, the Commission elaborated, the Postal
    Service must “exclude non-exigent impacts, such as on-going
    electronic diversion of mail volumes.” 
    Id. at 42
    .
    Under that standard, the Postal Service must “[q]uantify
    the net adverse financial impact of the exigent circumstances”
    to justify an exigent rate increase. Order 864, at 25. The
    Postal Service need not achieve “absolute precision” in its
    calculations, but larger proposed increases require “more
    rigorous estimation techniques” and a “persuasive showing
    that the sums sought are the result of the exigent
    circumstances.” 
    Id. at 44
    . The Commission concluded that
    its standard was workable because the Postal Service, in the
    past, had “demonstrated an ability to develop and refine
    methodologies for measuring and projecting costs in a variety
    of Commission proceedings” by using “a volume forecasting
    methodology that enables it to distinguish and account for the
    impact of multiple factors that have affected First-Class Mail
    volumes.” 
    Id. at 50
    .
    No party challenged Order 864 when it came out, and all
    parties agree that it provides the framework for this case. See
    Brief for Petitioner United States Postal Service at 8, United
    States Postal Service v. Postal Regulatory Commission (No.
    14-1010); Brief for Petitioners Alliance of Nonprofit Mailers
    et al. at 37, Alliance of Nonprofit Mailers et al. v. United
    7
    States Postal Regulatory Commission (No. 14-1009); Brief
    for Respondent United States Postal Regulatory Commission
    at 13, United States Postal Service et al. v. United States
    Postal Regulatory Commission (Nos. 14-1009 & 14-1010).
    Round Three
    Two years later, the Postal Service renewed its request
    for a rate increase, seeking an open-ended 4.3% increase in
    rates. Renewed Exigent Request of the U.S. Postal Service,
    Postal Regulatory Commission Docket No. R2010–4R, at 2
    (Sept. 26, 2013). To demonstrate that the increased rate was
    “due to” the recession, the Postal Service provided an
    econometric analysis prepared by its designated expert,
    Thomas Thress. Thress used a methodology based on “a set
    of calculations which underlie all of the Postal Service’s
    demand equation analysis and volume forecasts.” Further
    Statement of Thomas E. Thress on Behalf of the United States
    Postal Service, Postal Regulatory Commission Docket No.
    R2010–4R, at 5 (Sept. 26, 2013).
    After receiving comments from interested parties,
    including industry groups and major mailers, the Commission
    granted the Postal Service’s requested rate increase in part.
    Postal Regulatory Commission, Order Granting Exigent Price
    Increase, Order No. 1926, Docket No. R2013–11 (December
    24, 2013) (Order 1926). The Commission reaffirmed that the
    recession qualified as an extraordinary or exceptional
    circumstance warranting a rate increase. 
    Id. at 44
    . But the
    Commission disagreed with the Postal Service about the
    amount of lost volume that the recession itself caused on a
    forward-looking basis. 
    Id.
     As a result, the Commission
    allowed the full 4.3% increase, but ordered that it could only
    last as long as necessary to yield $2.8 billion of additional
    profit—a period of less than two years. 
    Id. at 181
    .
    8
    As relevant here, the Commission’s decision rested on
    two distinct determinations. First, the Commission rejected
    the Postal Service’s view that the loss of mail volume could
    be attributed to the recession unless and until the volume
    returned to levels consistent with pre-recession trends. Order
    1926, at 85. Instead, the Commission decided that mail-
    volume loss could no longer be considered “due to” the
    exigencies of the recession once a “new normal” in
    operational levels was achieved. 
    Id.
     at 83–94. In the
    Commission’s view, that “new normal” was established once
    “all or most of” four conditions were met: “(1) the disruption
    to a sufficient number of relevant macroeconomic indicators
    demonstrate[d] a return to near historic positive trends; (2)
    application of the macroeconomic variables accurately
    project[ed] change, and the rate of change on Postal Service
    mail volume is positive; (3) the Postal Service regain[ed] its
    ability to predict or project mail volumes following an
    extraordinary or exceptional event; and (4) the Postal Service
    demonstrate[d] an ability to adjust operations to lower
    volumes.” 
    Id. at 86
    . The new normal, the Commission
    added, arrived at different times for different classes of mail,
    
    id.,
     ranging between the start of fiscal year 2010 and the start
    of fiscal year 2012, 
    id. at 94
    .
    Secondly, despite having just found that the Postal
    Service did not regain its ability to predict or project mail
    volumes or to adjust operations to lower volume levels until
    the “new normal” was achieved, Order 1926, at 86, the
    Commission announced that it would only count decreased
    mail volume one time, and that would be in the first year in
    which it was lost. Order 1926, at 96. The Commission said
    that it would disregard any enduring loss of mail volume after
    that one-year cycle because, in all “subsequent years, the
    Postal Service is aware of that loss” and should “adjust[] its
    expectations to continue without that mail piece.” 
    Id.
    9
    In rejecting the Postal Service’s request, the Commission
    also begged to differ with certain aspects of Thress’s
    econometric analysis.        Thress’s econometric technique,
    known as “backcasting,” “start[ed] with a specific
    outcome”—the decreased mail volume—“and then work[ed]
    backwards in an attempt to determine the causes of that
    outcome.” Order at 61-62 n.53.             In an econometric
    forecasting model like Thress’s, “postal mail volume is set as
    a function of multiple independent variables.” 
    Id. at 62
    .
    The bottom-line problem for the Postal Service, the
    Commission explained, was that some of Thress’s variables
    made more sense than others. In particular, Thress’s
    assumption that the recession alone could be blamed for lost
    mail volume year after year over-strained the “due to” test.
    Thress reached his result by using both “linear” and “non-
    linear” “intervention variables” in his models.                The
    intervention variables “refer to any change in the level or
    trend of mail volumes which starts at a particular time.”
    Order 1926, at 48 n.32.            Although the Commission
    acknowledged that intervention variables can be an
    appropriate part of an econometric model, “the usual practice
    is to include them only when it is clear what they represent.”
    
    Id. at 71
    . Thress, however, used variables that were “often
    ambiguous in the sense that there is no definitive way to
    identify the causes for the effects that these variables or trends
    capture.” 
    Id.
     Worse still, the Commission explained, was
    that while “the Great Recession is a cyclical event,” the
    “linear intervention trends that Thress attributes to the Great
    Recession continue in a negative direction forever.” 
    Id.
     at 82
    & n.71. Whatever changes in mail volumes those variables
    may have picked up, the Commission concluded, “[t]here is
    nothing [in the record] that suggests changes in long run
    trends or changes in the rate of electronic diversion are due to
    the Great Recession.” 
    Id. at 81
    .
    10
    By contrast, the Commission determined that most of
    Thress’s non-linear intervention variables passed muster
    because they “exhibit[ed] characteristics of cyclical variables
    and shift[ed] to a positive impact on mail volumes that
    coincides with the point in time that the macroeconomic
    variables used by the Postal Service in their corresponding
    demand equations begin to improve.” Order 1926, at 82–83.
    Unlike the linear intervention variables, in other words, the
    non-linear variables did not imply that the recession would
    continue costing the Postal Service volume for the rest of
    time. Instead, they fit the down-and-then-back-up pattern of
    the recession itself.
    Having backed out those aspects of the Postal Service’s
    analysis that it considered deficient, the Commission
    calculated that roughly $2.8 billion in losses could be
    attributed to the recession. Order 1926, at 106. The
    Commission then ruled that recouping that amount through a
    rate increase was “reasonable and equitable and necessary,”
    
    id. at 107, 147
    , because the “the Postal Service’s liquidity
    levels are so low that they pose an unreasonable risk to the
    Postal Service’s continued operation,” 
    id. at 122
    .
    III
    Analysis
    Both the Postal Service and an array of groups
    representing major mailers sought this court’s review of the
    Commission’s order. We review those challenges under the
    familiar rubric of the Administrative Procedure Act, 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2). See 
    39 U.S.C. § 3663
     (applying APA standards to
    review of Commission actions). Accordingly, we must
    uphold the Commission’s decision unless it is “arbitrary,
    capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in
    accordance with law.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A).
    11
    Applying that deferential standard of review, we uphold
    most of Order 1926 as neither arbitrary nor capricious, and as
    supported by substantial evidence. We reverse, however, the
    Commission’s determination that lost mail volume can only
    be counted for one year, as the rationale that the Postal
    Service should have been able to identify and adjust to that
    downturn immediately is at war with the Commission’s “new
    normal” holding, which openly endorsed a longer period of
    time for such adjustments.
    The “New Normal” Causation Determination
    The Commission concluded that, while the “Great
    Recession” constituted an exigent circumstance warranting
    some rate relief, the effects of the recession on the Postal
    Service would only be caused by, or “due to,” those
    “extraordinary or exceptional circumstances” within the
    specific meaning of 
    39 U.S.C. § 3622
    (d)(1)(E) until the Postal
    Service had an opportunity to adjust to the “new normal” in
    the mail economy. Order at 83–94. That “new normal”
    arrived and cut off the causal “due to” linkage between the
    exigency and its economic impact, the Commission ruled,
    once (1) macroeconomic indicators “demonstrate[d] a return
    to near historic positive trends”; (2) macroeconomic variables
    “accurately project[ed] change, and the rate of change on
    Postal Service mail volume [became] positive”; (3) the Postal
    Service “regain[ed] its ability to predict or project mail
    volumes”; and (4) the Postal Service “demonstrate[d] an
    ability to adjust operations to lower volumes.” 
    Id. at 86
    .
    Because the scope of the Accountability Act’s “due to”
    causation standard is ambiguous, Congress left it to the
    Commission to “determin[e] how closely the amount of the
    adjustments must match the amount of the revenue lost as a
    result of the exigent circumstances.” United States Postal
    12
    Service v. Postal Regulatory Comm’n, 
    640 F.3d 1263
    , 1268
    (D.C. Cir. 2011). The only question before us is whether the
    Commission’s use of the “new normal” to measure causal
    effect falls within the permissible bounds of reason. See
    Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council,
    
    467 U.S. 837
    , 843 (1984); United States Postal Service, 640
    F.3d at 1266. We hold that it does. Given the Accountability
    Act’s central focus on tightly restricting Postal Service rate
    increases and increasing efficiency, the Commission sensibly
    concluded that the statutory exception allowing higher rates
    when needed to respond to extraordinary financial
    circumstances should only continue as long as those
    circumstances, in fact, remained extra-ordinary.          The
    Commission’s “new normal” test is designed to capture
    precisely the time when the exigent character of a
    circumstance dissipates—when its effects lose their
    exceptional character—even though the effects in some
    literal, but-for causal sense linger. In other words, the
    Commission permissibly reasoned that just because some of
    the effects of exigent circumstances may continue for the
    foreseeable future, that does not mean that those
    circumstances remain “extraordinary” or “exceptional” for
    just as long.
    The Postal Service advances a number of objections to the
    “new normal” rule, none of which pass muster.
    First, the Postal Service protests that the “new normal”
    analysis would be better housed not in the Accountability
    Act’s requirement that the increased rate be “due to” exigent
    circumstances, 
    39 U.S.C. § 3622
    (d)(1)(E), but in the Act’s
    separate requirement that any rate imposed be “reasonable
    and equitable and necessary,” 
    id.
     The very language of the
    “new normal” test, the Postal Service argues, shows that the
    13
    recession continues to cause losses because, if there had been
    no recession, mail volumes would still be in the old normal.
    The “due to” provision in the statute is not as woodenly
    literal as the Postal Service suggests. To be sure, “due to”
    looks at causation, and, in at least some sense, “the
    consequences of an act go forward to eternity, and the causes
    of an event go back to the dawn of human events, and
    beyond.” CSX Transportation, Inc. v. McBride, 
    131 S. Ct. 2630
    , 2642 (2011) (quoting W. Keeton, D. Dobbs, R. Keeton,
    & D. Owen, Prosser and Keeton on Law of Torts § 41, p. 264
    (5th ed. 1984)). Thus perhaps in some Palsgrafian sense, the
    effects of the recession may well continue to ripple for as long
    as the Postal Service’s proposed unending rate increase.2
    But the Commission acted well within its discretion in
    concluding that the “due to” test is concerned with
    determining the extent of the impact of an extraordinary or
    exceptional past event. The “reasonable and equitable and
    necessary” test, by contrast, applies only after exigent
    causation for a loss has been established and turns on the
    Postal Service’s current need to get back on its feet in the
    wake of the now-defined exigency. More specifically, the
    “reasonable and equitable and necessary” test looks to present
    conditions to determine what the Postal Service requires “to
    maintain and continue the development of postal services of
    the kind and quality adapted to the needs of the United
    States,” 
    39 U.S.C. § 3662
    (d)(1)(E), given the realities of the
    post-exigency marketplace. And that inquiry focuses not on
    causation, but recovery. The Commission thus appropriately
    addressed those separate requirements in separate parts of its
    Order.
    2
    See Palsgraf v. Long Island R. Co., 
    248 N.Y. 339
    , 340 (N.Y.
    1928).
    14
    Second, the Postal Service contends that the Commission
    provided insufficient notice of its “new normal” test. That
    argument fails too. The Postal Service itself was the first to
    introduce the concept before the Commission, see Postal
    Regulatory Commission, Responses of U.S. Postal Service to
    Questions 1–9 of Presiding Officer’s Information Request No.
    1, Docket No. R2013-11 (Oct. 23, 2013), Question 6, and its
    own expert even suggested a rough start date of 2010 for the
    “new normal,” see Transcript of Proceedings Before the
    Postal Regulatory Commission, Docket No. R2013–11 (Nov.
    19, 2013) (Hearing Transcript), at 119 (Thress: “And so to
    some extent I think it’s fair to call maybe 2010 through 2013
    the new normal for standard mail.”).
    In addition, the concept was discussed extensively before
    the Commission.        See generally Public Representative
    Comments; Postal Service Reply Comments, Docket No.
    R2013–11. Thus, although no commenter suggested the
    precise details of the test that emerged in Order 1926, the
    Postal Service had ample notice that such a test could emerge
    logically from the Commission’s proceedings.
    Third, contrary to the Postal Service’s argument, the
    Commission acted well within its discretion in starting the
    date of the new normal separately for each class of mail,
    rather than smaller sub-classes. In his testimony, the Postal
    Service’s expert, Thress, himself suggested that the new
    normal arrived at different times for different classes of mail,
    and offered only a fleeting reference to further extending that
    calculus to different sub-classes. See Hearing Transcript at
    117–119. In any event, the “new normal” test turns largely on
    factors that cut across different classes of mail, such as the
    state of the macro-economy and the accuracy of the Postal
    Service’s forecasts.
    15
    Finally, the Postal Service complains that, in calculating
    the amount of net losses that the Service incurred even under
    the “new normal” rule, the Commission was wrong to
    discount the linear intervention variables in Thress’s models.
    Those variables, the Postal Service insists, captured volume
    losses caused by the recession. But to prove that claim, the
    Postal Service can point only to timing. That is, because
    intervention variables do not model specific changes in the
    real world, the best the Service can argue is that its variable
    started at the right time to pick up recession-based losses.
    In a different procedural posture, that argument might
    gain traction. But not here. The Postal Service bore the
    burden of showing its net losses from the recession. And
    substantial    evidence     supported     the    Commission’s
    determination that the Postal Service had not proved that its
    linear intervention variables reliably captured only the effects
    of the recession. Most glaringly, Thress’s models had no
    separate variable to account for loss of mail volume to the
    Internet. So if people shifted to email at a faster pace during
    the recession than before, that effect would have been swept
    up wholesale in the linear intervention variables as
    attributable to the recession, rather than as, perhaps, the
    simple progress of inevitable change.
    The “Count Once” Rule
    In enforcing a “count once” limitation for lost mail, the
    Commission refused to recognize the cost to the Postal
    Service of lost mail volume beyond the year in which it first
    disappeared. Order 1926, at 96. For example, a worker laid
    off during the recession might cancel her cable subscription,
    and no longer pay her monthly bill by mail. The Commission
    would count that change as a loss of no more than twelve
    pieces of mail; the Postal Service would count it as lost
    16
    volume for as long as the recession stands between that
    worker and her cable subscription. If it takes her four years to
    find a new job and resubscribe, the Postal Service would
    count forty-eight lost pieces of mail.
    Order 1926 offered two rationales for its “count once”
    rule: First, the Commission worried that counting mail as lost
    any year beyond the first “makes it impossible for the
    Commission to fulfill its statutory mandate to calculate the
    total amount lost due to the exigent circumstance.” Order
    1926, at 95. Second, “once a piece of mail is lost in a given
    year due to the Great Recession, in subsequent years, the
    Postal Service is aware of that loss and adjusts it expectations
    to continue without that mail piece.” 
    Id. at 96
    .
    Neither of those rationales makes sense juxtaposed against
    the Commission’s immediately preceding explanation that the
    “new normal”—not the arbitrariness of turning a calendar—
    defines when the Postal Service “regain[ed] its ability to
    predict or project mail volumes” or to “adjust to the lower
    volumes.” Order 1926, at 86.
    The “new normal” rule also demonstrates that it is entirely
    possible—not “impossible” at all, Order 1926, at 95—to
    identify a stopping point for the recession’s exigent impact on
    lost mail volume. The Commission, in fact, did just that in
    adopting its “new normal” rule. Specifically, to pinpoint
    when the Postal Service regained the ability to accurately
    predict mail volumes, the Commission credited Thress’s
    testimony that “when we made a forecast in 2008 and 2009,
    there were terrible, terrible forecasts. * * * Now, 2011, ’12,
    ’13, we’re back to a world similar to where we were before in
    terms of we have a better handle on our forecast.” Order
    1926, at 93. To determine the Service’s ability to adjust to
    lost volume, the Commission then considered macroeconomic
    17
    variables: “[a] good measure of the Postal Service’s ability to
    adjust to changing circumstances is Total Factor
    Productivity,” a variable that suggested that the Service
    regained its ability to adjust in 2010—more than one year
    after the start of the recession. 
    Id. at 94
    . There is no reason
    that the same considerations, rather than a mechanical tally of
    the time passed since the recession, could not guide the
    Commission’s determination of when to stop counting lost
    mail volume.
    In sum, the “new normal” rule was well reasoned and
    grounded in the evidence before the Commission.           It
    comfortably passes deferential APA review; the “count once”
    rule’s controversion of the new normal rule’s premises does
    not and must be vacated.3
    The Mailers’ Petition For Review
    Twenty organizations that engage in extensive mailing as
    part of their business model (“Mailers”) separately sought
    review of the Commission’s decision, arguing that no rate
    increase at all should have been allowed. We disagree.
    The Mailers open their attack by arguing that the
    Commission inverted the burden of proof when it accepted
    some of Thress’s conclusions after rejecting his model. But
    that is not what the Commission did. The Commission did
    not throw out the entire Thress model as invalid and
    3
    At oral argument, counsel for the Postal Service argued that the
    “new normal” analysis in the Order is also inconsistent with the
    Commission’s analysis of whether the rate increase was
    “necessary.” See Oral Argument Transcript 19. That argument was
    not raised in the Postal Service’s briefs, and is not properly before
    this court. The Commission, of course, is free to consider that
    argument on remand.
    18
    unreliable across the board, but then cherry-pick portions to
    rehabilitate. The Commission instead examined each distinct
    part of the model on its own merits, accepting some parts and
    rejecting others. Nothing in the law or the record foreclosed
    the Commission from determining that Thress got it partly
    right.
    Next, the Mailers launch a barrage of highly technical
    objections to the Commission’s econometric methodology.
    Armed with a bevy of home-baked charts and graphs derived
    from the Commission’s work-papers, the Mailers argue that
    the Commission confused correlation with causation. Not so.
    The Commission found causation—it found that the recession
    did actually cause some exigent loss in mail volume, albeit
    less than the Postal Service had counted. See Order 1926, at
    106. That the Mailers view the same evidence differently is
    beside the point. The only question before us is whether the
    Commission’s view of the data as evidencing causation was
    supported by substantial evidence, keeping in mind that we
    are “particularly reluctant to interfere with [an] agency’s
    reasoned judgments” about technical questions within its area
    of expertise. NRG Power Marketing, LLC v. FERC, 
    718 F.3d 947
    , 953 (D.C. Cir. 2013) (internal citation and quotation
    marks omitted).
    The Mailers’ objection to the Commission’s reliance on
    Thress’s treatment of some variables’ “trend” and “cyclical”
    components suffers the same fate.         The Commission
    reasonably explained that the “trend” and “cyclical” labels
    were “somewhat misleading since both components typically
    respond to the business cycle when using macroeconomic
    variables.”   Order 1926, at 71.       So the Commission
    considered the trend components of some variables, and the
    cyclical components of others, 
    id. at 73
    , and in doing so
    credited Thress’s analysis of his employment variable, over
    19
    the Mailers’ objection that the “trend” component accounted
    for the majority of that variable’s effect on mail volumes.
    That judgment falls solidly within the Commission’s
    wheelhouse.
    The Mailers’ rely on Tex Tin Corp. v. EPA, 
    992 F.2d 353
    (D.C. Cir. 1993), to argue that the Commission confused
    correlation with causation. That reliance is misplaced. In Tex
    Tin, the agency error was to find causation in the face of an
    obvious and substantial alternative cause of the phenomenon
    at issue. 
    Id. at 356
    . The Mailers point to nothing similar in
    this record, and given the complex causal determination to be
    made in this case, we see no fatal error in the Commission’s
    analysis of the close fit between macroeconomic measures
    and the non-linear intervention variables.
    In light of the Mailers’ arguments, it bears emphasizing
    that this court is not a rubber stamp for agency actions, but
    neither are we a peer review board for an academic journal of
    econometrics. See City of Los Angeles v. Unites States Dep’t
    of Transportation, 
    165 F.3d 972
    , 977 (D.C. Cir. 1999). We
    are, instead, “a panel of generalist judges obliged to defer to a
    reasonable judgment by an agency acting pursuant to
    congressionally delegated authority.” 
    Id.
     The Commission’s
    analysis of the econometric evidence was reasonable; we need
    decide no more.
    Last and certainly least, the Mailers complain that the
    Commission did not properly respond to their rather
    sensational claim that no recovery for pre-2012 losses was
    necessary because the Postal Service managed to muddle
    through without discontinuing operations. But nothing in the
    statute forecloses the Commission’s eminently sensible
    determination that the “extraordinary or exceptional”
    20
    circumstances provision can apply to exigencies that fall short
    of a death knell.
    IV
    Conclusion
    We grant the Postal Service’s petition for review in part,
    vacate the “count once” portion of the Commission’s order,
    and otherwise deny the petition. We also deny the Mailers’
    petition for review. The case is remanded for proceedings
    consistent with this opinion.
    So ordered.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 14-1009, 14-1010

Judges: Brown, Millett, Wilkins

Filed Date: 6/5/2015

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/19/2024