Roy Allan Slurry Seal, Inc. v. Am. Asphalt S., Inc. , 2 Cal. 5th 505 ( 2017 )


Menu:
  • Filed 2/16/17
    IN THE SUPREME COURT OF CALIFORNIA
    ROY ALLAN SLURRY SEAL, INC., et al., )
    )
    Plaintiffs and Appellants, )
    )                            S225398
    v.                         )
    )                      Ct.App. 2/8 B255558
    AMERICAN ASPHALT SOUTH, INC.,         )
    )                      Riverside County
    Defendant and Respondent. )                   Super. Ct. No. RIC1308832
    ____________________________________)
    To prove the tort of intentional interference with prospective economic
    advantage, a plaintiff must establish “the existence of an economic relationship
    with some third party that contains the probability of future economic benefit to
    the plaintiff.” (Korea Supply Co. v. Lockheed Martin Corp. (2003) 
    29 Cal. 4th 1134
    , 1164 (Korea Supply).) Here we decide whether such a relationship exists
    between a bidder for a public works contract and the public entity soliciting bids.
    Plaintiffs alleged that they had submitted the second lowest bids on several
    contracts awarded to defendant, and that their bids would have been accepted but
    for defendant‟s wrongful conduct during the bidding process. A divided Court of
    Appeal panel found these allegations sufficient. We reverse. Public works
    contracts are a unique species of commercial dealings. In the contracts at issue
    here, the public entities retained broad discretion to reject all bids. The bids were
    sealed, and there were no postsubmission negotiations. In awarding the contracts,
    the public entities could give no preference to any bidder based on past dealings,
    1
    and were required to accept the lowest responsible bid. In these highly regulated
    circumstances, plaintiffs had “at most a hope for an economic relationship and a
    desire for future benefit.” (Blank v. Kirwan (1985) 
    39 Cal. 3d 311
    , 331 (Blank).)
    Accordingly, plaintiffs‟ allegations were insufficient; the demurrer was properly
    sustained.
    I. BACKGROUND
    Between 2009 and 2012 defendant American Asphalt South, Inc.
    (American) outbid the plaintiffs, Roy Allan Slurry Seal, Inc. (Allan) and Doug
    Martin Contracting, Inc. (Martin) on 23 public works contracts to apply a slurry
    seal coating on various roadways in Los Angeles, San Bernardino, Riverside,
    Orange, and San Diego Counties. The total value of the contracts exceeded $14
    million. In 2013, Allan and Martin jointly sued American in all five counties for
    intentional interference with prospective economic advantage (hereafter
    sometimes referred to as tortious interference).1 Only the Riverside tort action is
    at issue here.
    The Riverside complaint alleged that American won six public works
    contracts2 on which either Allan or Martin was the second lowest bidder.
    American‟s underbids ranged from $3,842 to $140,794. The complaint described
    the dates and amounts of American‟s bids, but did not include copies of the bids
    themselves. The actual bids appear nowhere in the appellate record.
    1      Plaintiffs also alleged predatory pricing under the Unfair Practices Act
    (Bus. & Prof. Code, §§ 17000, 17043) and sought an injunction against
    American‟s bidding practices under the unfair competition law (Bus. & Prof.
    Code, § 17200). The trial court sustained demurrers to those causes of action, and
    the Court of Appeal affirmed. Those holdings are not before us.
    2      The contracting entities included four cities and the County of Riverside.
    For simplicity, we refer to these contracts collectively as the Riverside contracts.
    2
    To support their theory of tortious interference, plaintiffs alleged as
    follows. Together, plaintiffs had 60 years of experience handling public works
    projects for slurry seal repair and maintenance. The cost of materials for these
    projects is essentially the same for all contractors. American engaged in wrongful,
    fraudulent, and illegal conduct by submitting deflated bids because it failed to pay
    prevailing wage and overtime compensation in connection with the named
    contracts, and with other public works contracts during the same period. Plaintiffs
    alleged they had both a relationship with the contracting public entities and a
    reasonable probability of future economic benefit, because they “were the
    respective second lowest bidder[s] and would have been awarded the contract[s]
    but for the fraudulent and/or illegal conduct of [American] . . . .” According to the
    complaint, “[American]‟s bid would have been rejected if [American]‟s conduct in
    failing to pay its employees properly was made known to the [public entity,]
    and/or [American] would not have been able to submit a lower bid . . . if
    [American] was properly paying all of its employees the prevailing wages . . . .”
    Plaintiffs alleged that the failure to secure the Riverside contracts resulted in
    estimated lost profits of $168,511 for Allan and $269,830 for Martin.
    The trial court sustained American‟s demurrer to the entire cause of action
    without leave to amend. On appeal, the appellate court majority reversed as to the
    tortious interference claim, concluding that plaintiffs‟ pleading was adequate:
    “Plaintiffs here alleged that as the second lowest bidders they would have been
    awarded the contracts but for American‟s interference. Implicit in this is the
    allegation that the various public entities were required to award the contract to the
    lowest responsible bidder and that plaintiffs satisfied all the requirements
    necessary to qualify for those contracts. Although plaintiffs here did not submit
    the lowest bids, that was alleged to be due solely to American‟s violation of its
    statutory obligation to pay its workers the prevailing wage. As in Korea Supply,
    3
    absent that alleged misconduct it was plaintiffs who in fact submitted the true and
    lawful lowest bids.” The majority concluded that, although a public entity retains
    discretion to reject all bids submitted in response to its solicitation, “an actionable
    economic expectancy arises once the public agency awards a contract to an
    unlawful bidder, thereby signaling that the contract would have gone to the second
    lowest qualifying bidder.”
    The dissent urged to the contrary that plaintiffs failed to allege the existence
    of an economic relationship with the soliciting public entities. The dissent
    reasoned that the tort was meant to guard against interference with existing
    relationships. “[I]n the context of public works contracts, it is not possible for
    such a relationship to exist between the bidder and the public entity soliciting bids
    because public contract law forbids it.” Moreover, “[i]t is antithetical to the
    principles of competitive bidding on public works projects that any bidder may
    expect probable future economic benefit . . . .” Because the award of a
    government contract is highly discretionary, “none of the bidders has a
    „probability‟ of future economic benefit from the contract on which it is bidding.”
    The dissent pointed out that timing is important. The relationship interfered with
    must be in existence when defendant‟s allegedly wrongful conduct took place. In
    the dissent‟s view, the majority went astray by relying on plaintiffs‟ subsequently
    discovered placement as the second-lowest bidder to posit a relationship that did
    not, and could not, have existed during the bidding process.
    II. DISCUSSION
    A demurrer is properly sustained when “[t]he pleading does not state facts
    sufficient to constitute a cause of action.” (Code Civ. Proc., § 430.10, subd. (e).)
    On appeal, a resulting judgment of dismissal is reviewed independently. (McCall
    v. PacifiCare of Cal., Inc. (2001) 
    25 Cal. 4th 412
    , 415.) “ „ “[W]e accept as true all
    the material allegations of the complaint” ‟ ” (Korea 
    Supply, supra
    , 29 Cal.4th at
    4
    p. 1141), but do not “assume the truth of contentions, deductions or conclusions of
    law” (Aubry v. Tri-City Hospital Dist. (1992) 
    2 Cal. 4th 962
    , 967).
    Intentional interference with prospective economic advantage has five
    elements: (1) the existence, between the plaintiff and some third party, of an
    economic relationship that contains the probability of future economic benefit to
    the plaintiff; (2) the defendant‟s knowledge of the relationship; (3) intentionally
    wrongful acts designed to disrupt the relationship; (4) actual disruption of the
    relationship; and (5) economic harm proximately caused by the defendant‟s action.
    (Korea 
    Supply, supra
    , 29 Cal.4th at pp. 1164-1165.)
    Here we focus on the first element, and consider a question of first
    impression. Can a disappointed bidder on a public works contract demonstrate the
    requisite economic relationship with the public entity? The first element
    (hereafter the economic relationship element) has two parts: (1) an existing
    economic relationship that (2) contains the probability of an economic benefit to
    the plaintiff.
    American argues that merely submitting a bid to a public entity does not
    create an existing relationship but rather the hope of one. It emphasizes that each
    bidder is considered a stranger to the public entity because the entity is prohibited
    from favoring bidders with whom it has had past dealings. Additionally, public
    entities have discretion to reject all of the bids submitted. Under these
    circumstances, American contends, there is no existing relationship with which to
    interfere and no reasonable probability that a benefit will be conferred by the
    awarding of a contract.
    Plaintiffs counter that their act of submitting what would have been the
    lowest responsible bid but for American‟s wrongful interference in the bidding
    process demonstrates the existence of an economic relationship with the
    probability of future economic benefit. They rely on two facts. First, the public
    5
    entities were required to award the contracts to the lowest responsible bidder.
    Second, in each instance the entities actually awarded a contract rather than
    rejecting all bids. Accordingly, plaintiffs contend, their expectation was not
    unduly speculative. Defendant has the better argument.
    Plaintiffs rely heavily on Korea 
    Supply, supra
    , 
    29 Cal. 4th 1134
    , but that
    case is distinguishable. There, the companies MacDonald Dettwiler and Lockheed
    Martin submitted bids to the Republic of Korea to provide military equipment.
    The plaintiff, Korea Supply, was a broker who represented MacDonald Dettwiler
    during the bidding process. The contract was awarded to Lockheed Martin after
    its agent allegedly bribed Korean officials. (Id. at pp. 1141-1142.) Korea Supply
    dealt primarily with the intent element of the tort. However, it also held that the
    economic relationship element had been adequately pled. (Id. at p. 1164.) The
    plaintiff‟s agreement with MacDonald Dettwiler fixed its commission at 15
    percent of the contract price. The plaintiff would have been entitled to a $30
    million commission had MacDonald Dettwiler won the contract. The economic
    relationship allegedly interfered with was not a relationship between the broker
    and the Republic of Korea, the soliciting entity. Instead, the relationship was that
    between the broker and MacDonald Dettwiler. That relationship was an existing
    one that arose before the bidding process began. (Id. at pp. 1141, 1164.) Under
    the agreement, the broker had a reasonable expectation that it would receive its
    defined future economic benefit but for Lockheed‟s alleged interference. Thus,
    the business relationship and corresponding expectancy was sufficiently alleged.
    (Id. at p. 1164.)
    Plaintiffs argue that Korea Supply is quintessentially a case about losing
    bidders and that plaintiffs have an even stronger claim here because “Korea
    Supply Company was once removed from the bidding process and its stake in the
    matter was completely dependent upon the fortunes of MacDonald Dettwiler.”
    6
    Significantly, however, there is no indication that the bidding process between
    MacDonald Dettwiler and the Republic of Korea, upon which the broker‟s
    commission depended, was constrained in a manner similar to the statutory rules
    that govern California public works contracts. As explained below, the public
    works bidding process differs significantly from the commercial transactions that
    traditionally formed the basis for tort liability. Korea Supply does not stand for
    the proposition that a public contract bidder has an existing relationship with the
    entity soliciting the bid.
    Buckaloo v. Johnson (1975) 
    14 Cal. 3d 815
    (Buckaloo) is another case in
    which the economic relationship element was adequately pled.3 That case
    involved a tortious interference claim in the real estate brokerage context. A
    property owner posted an “ „open listing‟ ” soliciting local brokers to identify
    buyers for her property. (Buckaloo, at p. 820.) Plaintiff Buckaloo told a
    prospective buyer about the property and informed the seller that he was the
    “ „procuring cause‟ ” of that buyer. (Ibid.) The buyer ultimately purchased the
    property without Buckaloo‟s participation. (Id. at pp. 820-821.) When he
    requested his commission, the seller refused to pay. Buckaloo sued the seller, the
    buyer, and others involved in the transaction; a demurrer was sustained as to all
    defendants but the seller. (Id. at p. 821.)
    Buckaloo held the tort had been adequately pled even though the open
    listing was not a contract enforceable against the seller because of the statute of
    3       Buckaloo was disapproved in part in Della Penna v. Toyota Motor Sales,
    U.S.A., Inc. (1995) 
    11 Cal. 4th 376
    , 393, footnote 5 (Della Penna). The
    disapproved aspect of Buckaloo‟s holding involved the “wrongful” act element of
    the tort (Della Penna, at p. 393), which is not at issue here.
    7
    frauds.4 
    (Buckaloo, supra
    , 14 Cal.3d at pp. 821-822.) As Buckaloo explained,
    “the mere fact that a prospective economic relationship has not attained the dignity
    of a legally enforceable agreement does not permit third parties to interfere with
    performance.” (Id. at p. 827.) The plaintiff had pled a “prospective contractual
    relationship” because the seller posted an open listing offering to pay brokers a
    commission. Plaintiff reasonably understood this action to constitute an invitation
    to find a buyer. (Id. at p. 828.) The plaintiff alleged he had “completed the
    unilateral, albeit unenforceable, contract” with the seller by providing the
    necessary buyer. (Id. at p. 829.) The seller‟s posting of an open listing and the
    offer of a commission, on which Buckaloo relied in procuring a buyer, was
    sufficient to demonstrate an existing economic relationship between Buckaloo and
    the seller. The complaint further alleged tortious interference: the buyer knew of
    the seller‟s promise to pay, and intentionally interfered with the prospective
    commission by approaching the seller directly and inducing her to sell the property
    while intentionally excluding Buckaloo‟s participation. (Ibid.)5
    4       Civil Code section 1624, subdivision (a)(4) (formerly subd. 5) requires a
    writing subscribed by the party to be charged for “[a]n agreement authorizing or
    employing an agent, broker, or any other person to purchase or sell real estate, . . .
    or to procure, introduce, or find a purchaser or seller of real estate . . . for
    compensation or a commission.”
    5       Citing Buckaloo, the Court of Appeal in Settimo Associates v. Environ
    Systems, Inc. (1993) 
    14 Cal. App. 4th 842
    (Settimo) described the economic
    relationship element as requiring “the existence of a prospective business
    relationship containing the probability of future economic rewards for plaintiff.”
    (Id. at p. 845, italics added.) Plaintiffs attribute significance to Settimo‟s use of the
    word “prospective.” However, the court did not address the first element of the
    tort. It held that the plaintiff had failed to state a cause of action because the
    winning bidder‟s lack of a general contracting license to perform some of the work
    called for by the contracts “does not amount to actionable unlawful interference
    with contracts.” (Id. at p. 846.) Settimo offers no guidance regarding the
    economic relationship element.
    8
    By contrast, a cause of action for tortious interference has been found
    lacking when either the economic relationship with a third party is too attenuated
    or the probability of economic benefit too speculative. In 
    Blank, supra
    , 
    39 Cal. 3d 311
    , the plaintiff alleged that the defendant had interfered with his application for
    a city license to operate a poker club. Blank held the plaintiff‟s pleading failed to
    satisfy the economic relationship element. “First, „[t]he relationship between
    [plaintiff] and the City cannot be characterized as an economic relationship. It
    was [plaintiff‟s] relationship to a class of as yet unknown [patrons] which was the
    prospective business relationship.‟ [Citation.]” (Id. at p. 330.) “Second, even if
    the relationship between the plaintiff and the city could be so characterized, it
    would make little difference. The tort has traditionally protected the expectancies
    involved in ordinary commercial dealings—not the „expectancies,‟ whatever they
    may be, involved in the governmental licensing process.” (Ibid.) Third, the city
    council‟s discretion to grant or deny a poker club license application was “so
    broad as to negate the existence of the requisite „expectancy‟ as a matter of law.
    Thus, „no facts are alleged . . . showing that the plaintiff had any reasonable
    expectation of economic advantage which would otherwise have accrued to
    him . . . .‟ [Citation.]” (Ibid.)
    Youst v. Longo (1987) 
    43 Cal. 3d 64
    (Youst), held that the outcome of a
    sporting contest involving harness horseracing was too speculative to support a
    tortious interference claim. (Id. at p. 74.) The plaintiff alleged that the defendant
    had driven his horse into the path of the plaintiff‟s horse during a race and had
    struck plaintiff‟s horse with a whip, causing it to break stride and finish in sixth
    place. The plaintiff sought damages based on the purse for first, second, or third
    place, with the ultimate placement to be determined by the jury, along with
    punitive damages. (Id. at p. 68.) The trial court sustained defendant‟s demurrer
    without leave to amend. Youst affirmed, observing: “the true source of the
    9
    modern law on interference with prospective relations is the principle that tort
    liability exists for interference with existing contractual relations. [Citation.] „For
    the most part the “expectancies” thus protected have been those of future
    contractual relations . . . . In such cases there is a background of business
    experience on the basis of which it is possible to estimate with some fair amount of
    success both the value of what has been lost and the likelihood that the plaintiff
    would have received it if the defendant had not interfered.‟ ” (Id. at p. 75, quoting
    Prosser & Keeton, Torts (5th ed. 1984) § 130, p. 1006, italics added by Youst.) By
    contrast, the tort “traditionally has not protected speculative expectancies such as
    the particular outcome of a contest.” (Youst, at pp. 74-75.) The defendant‟s
    demurrer was therefore properly sustained because “[d]etermining the probable
    expectancy of winning a sporting contest but for the defendant‟s interference
    seems impossible in most if not all cases, including the instant case.” (Id. at p. 75,
    italics omitted.)
    In Westside Center Associates v. Safeway Stores 23, Inc. (1996) 
    42 Cal. App. 4th 507
    (Westside Center), the Court of Appeal interpreted our holdings
    in Youst and Blank to require proof that the defendant had disrupted a particular
    relationship with a known third party. There, the plaintiff purchased a shopping
    center containing several small stores. An “anchor” building in the center was
    separately owned and leased to Safeway. Safeway vacated the premises, but
    executed an option to renew its lease for five years. Business at the rest of the
    center suffered while the anchor premises stood vacant, and the plaintiff ultimately
    sold its property interest at a claimed loss of more than $2 million. (Id. at pp. 510-
    515.) The plaintiff sued Safeway for tortious interference with prospective
    economic advantage, alleging that Safeway interfered, not with a particular sale,
    but with the relationship between plaintiff and the class of all potential buyers for
    the property, thereby reducing its market value. (Id. at p. 523.) The Court of
    10
    Appeal upheld the trial court‟s dismissal of the claim.6 It reasoned that an
    “ „interference with the market‟ ” or “ „lost opportunity‟ ” claim (Westside Center,
    at p. 527) was unduly speculative: “It assumes what normally must be proved,
    i.e., that it is reasonably probable the plaintiff would have received the expected
    benefit had it not been for the defendant‟s interference.” (Id. at p. 523.)
    Emphasizing the requirement of an existing relationship, the court held that the
    tort “protects the expectation that the relationship eventually will yield the desired
    benefit, not necessarily the more speculative expectation that a potentially
    beneficial relationship will eventually arise.” (Id. at p. 524.) The court concluded
    that the plaintiff‟s theory “fails to provide any factual basis upon which to
    determine whether the plaintiff was likely to have actually received the expected
    benefit. Without an existing relationship with an identifiable buyer, [plaintiff]‟s
    expectation of a future sale was „at most a hope for an economic relationship and a
    desire for future benefit.‟ ” (Id. at p. 527, quoting 
    Blank, supra
    , 39 Cal.3d at p.
    331.)
    These authorities counsel against recognizing an “economic relationship”
    containing the “probability of future economic benefit” (Korea 
    Supply, supra
    , 29
    Cal.4th at p. 1164), solely because plaintiffs submitted a bid in response to a
    public entity‟s solicitation. First, as the dissent below observed, there could be no
    existing relationship between plaintiffs and the public entities soliciting bids
    “because public contract law forbids it.” The various public entities named in the
    Riverside County action were required by statute to award these contracts to the
    lowest responsible bidder. (See Pub. Contract Code, §§ 20162 [city contracts],
    6      The dismissal occurred, not on demurrer, but instead after questions of law
    and stipulated facts were presented to the trial court in pretrial proceedings.
    (Westside 
    Center, supra
    , 42 Cal.App.4th at p. 510.)
    11
    20128 [county contracts], 10122 [state contracts].) The purpose of this
    requirement is to “ „guard against favoritism, improvidence, extravagance, fraud
    and corruption . . . .‟ ” (Domar Electric, Inc. v. City of Los Angeles (1994) 
    9 Cal. 4th 161
    , 173 (Domar Electric); accord, Pub. Contract Code, § 100.) Under the
    law, each bidder must be treated as a stranger to the entity. Thus, unlike Korea
    Supply, where the plaintiff had an ongoing agency relationship with the losing
    bidder, no past or ongoing dealings could affect the award of these public
    contracts. The entities were required to award the contract to the lowest
    responsible bidder, or not at all.
    Second, plaintiffs “ha[ve] pleaded and can plead no protectible
    „expectancy.‟ ” (
    Blank, supra
    , 39 Cal.3d at p. 331.) A public entity‟s solicitation
    for bids is merely a request for offers from interested parties. It encourages
    multiple parties to compete for the contract. (Domar 
    Electric, supra
    , 9 Cal.4th at
    p. 173; Konica Business Machines U.S.A., Inc. v. Regents of the University of
    California (1988) 
    206 Cal. App. 3d 449
    , 456.) Here, the bidding was sealed, and
    no negotiations took place. (See Pub. Contract Code, §§ 20170 [city contracts],
    20129, subd. (a) [county contracts], 10167 [state contracts].) Ultimately, the
    public entities had broad discretion to reject all bids. (Universal By-Products, Inc.
    v. City of Modesto (1974) 
    43 Cal. App. 3d 145
    , 152; Pub. Contract Code, §§ 20166
    [city contracts], 20150.9 [county contracts], 10185 [state contracts].) Just as the
    city‟s discretion to grant or deny a poker club license defeated the plaintiff‟s
    expectancy in Blank, here too, plaintiffs had “at most a hope for an economic
    relationship and a desire for future benefit.” (
    Blank, supra
    , 39 Cal.3d at p. 331.)
    In reaching a contrary conclusion, the Court of Appeal majority reasoned
    that “an actionable economic expectancy arises once the public agency awards a
    contract to an unlawful bidder, thereby signaling that the contract would have
    gone to the second lowest qualifying bidder.” (Italics added.) The court found
    12
    “implicit” in plaintiffs‟ allegations “that plaintiffs satisfied all the requirements
    necessary to qualify for those contracts.” It further concluded that, “[a]lthough
    plaintiffs here did not submit the lowest bids, that was alleged to be due solely to
    American‟s violation of its statutory obligation to pay its workers the prevailing
    wage.” It observed that “[w]hether a plaintiff was in fact the second lowest bidder
    and would have been awarded a contract had the winning bidder complied with
    the prevailing wage law is a factual issue susceptible to standard civil discovery
    practices and is amenable to proof at trial.”
    The majority‟s analysis puts the cart before the horse. The case law
    recognizes that “the interference tort applies to interference with existing
    noncontractual relations which hold the promise of future economic advantage.”
    (Westside 
    Center, supra
    , 42 Cal.App.4th at p. 524, citing 
    Blank, supra
    , 
    39 Cal. 3d 311
    and 
    Youst, supra
    , 
    43 Cal. 3d 64
    .) The tort‟s requirements “presuppose the
    relationship existed at the time of the defendant‟s allegedly tortious acts lest
    liability be imposed for actually and intentionally disrupting a relationship which
    has yet to arise.” (Westside Center, at p. 526, italics added.) As the dissent
    observed, “the plaintiff‟s „expectancy‟ must necessarily precede the interfering
    conduct.” (See, e.g., Sole Energy Co. v. Petrominerals Corp. (2005) 
    128 Cal. App. 4th 212
    , 243.) Here, when American allegedly submitted illegally
    deflated bids, plaintiffs were only one of several bidders on these public works
    contracts. No one knew if plaintiffs would be the lowest bidder, and the public
    entities had not yet decided whether or not to award the contracts. Plaintiffs
    cannot rely on the outcome of later events to prove that American interfered with
    an existing economic relationship.
    The majority‟s probable benefit analysis is also speculative. The tort of
    intentional interference with prospective economic advantage “traditionally has
    not protected speculative expectancies” (
    Youst, supra
    , 43 Cal.3d at pp. 74-75),
    13
    usually because “ „there is no sufficient degree of certainty that the plaintiff ever
    would have received the anticipated benefits‟ ” (id. at p. 74, quoting Prosser &
    Keeton, Torts, supra, § 130, p. 1006, italics added by Youst.) Accordingly, “[w]e
    have been cautious in defining the interference torts, to avoid promoting
    speculative claims.” (Pacific Gas & Electric Co. v. Bear Sterns & Co. (1990) 
    50 Cal. 3d 1118
    , 1136-1137.) 
    Buckaloo, supra
    , 
    14 Cal. 3d 815
    , stated that the tort lies
    “ „when a contract would, with certainty, have been consummated but for the
    conduct of the tortfeasor . . . .‟ ” (Id. at p. 823, fn. 6, quoting Builders
    Corporation of America v. U.S. (N.D.Cal. 1957) 
    148 F. Supp. 482
    , 484, fn. 1.)
    Youst stated a slightly lower threshold: California authority “requir[es] at least the
    reasonable probability of an expectancy to establish a cause of action for
    interference with prospective economic advantage . . . .” (Youst, at pp. 71-72;
    accord, Korea 
    Supply, supra
    , 29 Cal.4th at p. 1164 [plaintiff must “demonstrate an
    economic relationship with a probable future economic benefit”].) Youst
    emphasized that this requirement “is especially appropriate to evaluate a lost
    economic expectancy where the facts involve a competitive contest of one kind or
    another. To require less of a showing would open the proverbial floodgates to a
    surge of litigation based on alleged missed opportunities to win various types of
    contests, despite the speculative outcome of many of them.” (Youst, at p. 74.)
    We have previously noted, in a different context, the inherently speculative
    nature of public works bidding. (Kajima/Ray Wilson v. Los Angeles County
    Metropolitan Transportation Authority (2000) 
    23 Cal. 4th 305
    , 315-316 (Kajima).)
    In denying recovery against a government entity for lost profits under a
    promissory estoppel theory, Kajima stated: “Because the [public entity] was
    authorized to reject all bids, [the plaintiff] did not know at [the time its bid was
    submitted] whether the contract would even be awarded. Nor, because of the
    secrecy of the bidding process, did [the plaintiff] know whether it was indeed the
    14
    lowest responsible bidder. Therefore, given these uncertainties which are inherent
    in competitive bidding, bid preparation costs, not lost profits, were the only costs
    reasonably incurred.” (Ibid.)
    Plaintiffs‟ allegations of tortious interference likewise hinge on a high
    degree of uncertainty. Contrary to the majority‟s reasoning below, the award of
    contracts to American does not “signal[] that the contract would have gone to the
    second lowest qualifying bidder.” As amicus curiae League of California Cities
    observes, even if a public entity accepts the lowest bid, it retains discretion to
    reject all remaining bids if the contract is not consummated with the low bidder.
    (See Pub. Contract Code, § 20174 [“[t]he city council may, on refusal or failure of
    the successful bidder to execute the contract, award it to the next lowest
    responsible bidder” (italics added)].) Notably, in at least two of the contracts at
    issue here, American underbid plaintiffs by over $100,000. The public entities‟
    discretion to reject remaining bids would necessarily take into account the
    difference between the bid amounts of the lowest and second lowest bidders.
    Additionally, to be awarded the contracts, plaintiffs were required to meet
    the criteria for responsible bidders and responsive bids. (Pub. Contract Code, §
    1103 [defining responsible bidder]; MCM Construction, Inc. v. City and County of
    San Francisco (1998) 
    66 Cal. App. 4th 359
    , 368 (MCM Construction) [defining
    responsive bid].) Determining whether a certain bidder is “responsible” generally
    entails an evaluation of the bidder‟s trustworthiness, quality, fitness, capacity, and
    experience to satisfactorily perform the contract in question. (Pub. Contract Code,
    § 1103; City of Inglewood-L.A. County Civic Center Auth. v. Superior Court
    (1972) 
    7 Cal. 3d 861
    , 867.) It “is a complex matter dependent, often, on
    information received outside the bidding process and requiring, in many cases, an
    application of subtle judgment.” (Taylor Bus Service, Inc. v. San Diego Bd. of
    Education (1987) 
    195 Cal. App. 3d 1331
    , 1341-1342.) Given “the complex and
    15
    external nature of a determination of nonresponsibility” (id. at p. 1342), it is
    speculative for plaintiffs to allege, as a basis for the economic relationship, that
    they “were the respective second lowest bidder and would have been awarded the
    contract” if not for American‟s illegal conduct.
    For these reasons, the public works bidding process differs from the types
    of commercial transactions that traditionally have formed the basis for tort
    liability. In ordinary commercial transactions, “ „there is a background of business
    experience on the basis of which it is possible to estimate with some fair amount of
    success both the value of what has been lost and the likelihood that the plaintiff
    would have received it if the defendant had not interfered.‟ ” (
    Youst, supra
    , 43
    Cal.3d at p. 75, quoting Prosser & Keeton, Torts, supra, § 130, at p. 1006, italics
    added by Youst.) By contrast, in these public works contracts, the bidding was
    sealed, there were no negotiations, all qualified contractors were on equal footing
    regardless of past contractual dealings, the public entities were required to
    determine the bidder‟s responsibility, and they retained discretion to reject all bids.
    These circumstances counsel against extending a tortious interference claim to the
    bid process for these public works contracts.
    Additionally, we must consider whether expanding tort liability in the area
    of public works contracts “would ultimately create social benefits exceeding those
    created by existing remedies for such conduct, and outweighing any costs and
    burdens it would impose.” (Cedars-Sinai Medical Center v. Superior Court
    (1998) 
    18 Cal. 4th 1
    , 8.) Courts must act prudently when fashioning damages
    remedies “in an area of law governed by an extensive statutory scheme.” 
    (Kajima, supra
    , 23 Cal.4th at p. 317.) In California, public contract bidding is largely
    governed by statute. (Id. at p. 313.) As noted, the public entity is required to
    determine whether a bidder is responsible and the bid is responsive. (Pub.
    Contract Code, § 1103; MCM 
    Construction, supra
    , 66 Cal.App.4th at p. 368.)
    16
    Competing bidders may challenge the award of a contract to an irresponsible
    bidder by a writ of mandate for injunctive relief. (Kajima, at p. 313, fn. 1; DeSilva
    Gates Construction, LP v. Department of Transportation (2015) 
    242 Cal. App. 4th 1409
    , 1421; Monterey Mechanical Co. v. Sacramento Regional County Sanitation
    Dist. (1996) 
    44 Cal. App. 4th 1391
    , 1414; Code Civ. Proc., § 1085.)
    Plaintiffs argue that their lawsuits will protect employees on public works
    projects by uncovering and deterring wage law violations. The argument fails for
    two reasons. First, the area is already extensively regulated. (See Lab. Code, §§
    1726, 1727, 1741, 1773.2, 1775, 1776.) Prevailing wages are required by statute
    to be paid on all public works contracts. (Lab. Code, § 1771; Alameda County
    Joint Apprenticeship & Training Committee v. Roadway Electrical Works Inc.
    (2010) 
    186 Cal. App. 4th 185
    , 190.) Several statutory mechanisms exist to enforce
    that duty. A public entity may withhold payments to a contractor who violates the
    prevailing wage laws. (Lab. Code, §§ 1726, subds. (a), (b), 1727.) The Division
    of Labor Standards Enforcement may recover wages, interest, and damages on
    behalf of employees through an administrative hearing process and a civil action.
    (Lab. Code, §§ 1741, 1775; Lusardi Construction Co. v. Aubry (1992) 
    1 Cal. 4th 976
    , 986.) The affected employees also possess private rights of action arising
    from statute and contract. (Road Sprinkler Fitters Local Union No. 669 v. G & G
    Fire Sprinklers, Inc. (2002) 
    102 Cal. App. 4th 765
    , 774 & fn. 13.) Notably, none of
    these statutory schemes contemplates damage awards to a disappointed public
    works bidder who alleges the winning bid was based on prevailing wage
    violations.7
    7      In 1991 the Legislature enacted Public Contract Code sections 19102 and
    20104.70. Those sections authorize the second lowest public contract bidder and
    others to sue a successful bidder for damages upon proof that the contract was
    (footnote continued on next page)
    17
    Second, the competitive bidding laws were enacted for the benefit of the
    public, “ „ “not for the benefit or enrichment of bidders, and should be so
    construed and administered as to accomplish such purpose fairly and reasonably
    with sole reference to the public interest.” ‟ ” 
    (Kajima, supra
    , 23 Cal.4th at
    pp. 316-317.) “The duties created by the wage-and-hour statutes run solely from
    employer to employee.” (Castillo v. Toll Bros., Inc. (2011) 
    197 Cal. App. 4th 1172
    ,
    1210.) They “do not create any action for civil damages in a competing bidder.”
    
    (Settimo, supra
    , 14 Cal.App.4th at p. 846.)
    Expanding tort liability to cover wrongful interference with the public
    contracts bid process would provide little additional benefit in light of the
    extensive statutory scheme. Conversely, an expansion has potentially significant
    public policy disadvantages. (See 
    Youst, supra
    , 43 Cal.3d at pp. 77-78.) The
    possibility of significant monetary gain may encourage frivolous litigation by
    second lowest bidders “ „for effort they did not make and risks they did not
    take.‟ ” 
    (Kajima, supra
    , 23 Cal.4th at p. 317, quoting City of Atlanta v. J.A. Jones
    Const. Co. (Ga. 1990) 
    398 S.E.2d 369
    , 371.) That litigation, in turn, may deter
    responsible bidders from participating in the process, thus undermining the
    Legislature‟s goal of “stimulating competition in a manner conducive to sound
    fiscal practices.” (Pub. Contract Code, § 100, subd. (c).) Such a result would
    directly contravene the principles underlying the tort of intentional interference
    (footnote continued from previous page)
    obtained through violations of the laws concerning workers‟ compensation and
    unemployment insurance. The statutes require criminal convictions as a
    prerequisite to the civil suit. (Pub. Contract Code, §§ 19102, subd. (a)(1),
    20104.70, subd. (a)(1).) Prevailing wage violations are not mentioned in the
    statutes. (See also Lab. Code, § 1750.)
    18
    with prospective economic advantage: carefully drawing “lines of legal liability in
    a way that maximizes areas of competition free of legal penalties.” (Della 
    Penna, supra
    , 11 Cal.4th at p. 392.) Additionally, although the public entities cannot be
    sued for lost profits (see 
    Kajima, supra
    , 23 Cal.4th at pp. 315-316), they would
    likely be called upon as witnesses and subjected to potentially voluminous
    document requests under the Public Records Act. Such litigation would risk
    draining government resources, and potentially interfere with the public‟s interest
    in having contracts awarded and performed promptly. “[I]t is incumbent on this
    court to consider the broad-ranging social consequences of the chosen remedy,”
    including whether “[a]llowing recovery of lost profits whenever a contract is
    wrongfully denied „could drain the public fisc . . . .‟ ” (Kajima, at pp. 317-318.)
    The costs of recognizing a tort remedy in this context are simply too high.
    III. DISPOSITION
    We reverse the judgment of the Court of Appeal, and remand with
    directions that the original order sustaining the demurrer be reinstated.
    CORRIGAN, J.
    WE CONCUR:
    CANTIL-SAKAUYE, C. J.
    WERDEGAR, J.
    CHIN, J.
    LIU, J.
    CUÉLLAR, J.
    KRUGER, J.
    19
    See next page for addresses and telephone numbers for counsel who argued in Supreme Court.
    Name of Opinion Roy Allan Slurry Seal, Inc. v. American Asphalt South, Inc.
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Unpublished Opinion
    Original Appeal
    Original Proceeding
    Review Granted XXX 
    234 Cal. App. 4th 748
    Rehearing Granted
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Opinion No. S225398
    Date Filed: February 16, 2017
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Court: Superior
    County: Riverside
    Judge: Richard J. Oberholzer*
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Counsel:
    Doyle & Schafer, Doyle Schafer McMahon, Daniel W. Doyle and David Klehm for Plaintiffs and
    Appellants.
    Altshuler Berzon, Scott A. Kronland and Stacey M. Leyton for State Building and Construction Trades
    Council of California, AFL-CIO as Amicus Curiae on behalf of Plaintiffs and Appellants.
    Atkinson, Andelson, Loya, Ruud & Romo, Scott K. Dauscher, Paul G. Szumiak and Jennifer D. Cantrell
    for Defendant and Respondent.
    Jarvis, Fay, Doporto & Gibson, Claire M. Gibson and Christine L. Crowl for League of California Cities as
    Amicus Curiae.
    *Retired judge of the Kern Superior Court, assigned by the Chief Justice pursuant to article VI, section 6 of
    the California Constitution.
    Counsel who argued in Supreme Court (not intended for publication with opinion):
    David Klehm
    Doyle Schafer McMahon
    100 Spectrum Center Drive, Suite 520
    Irvine, CA 92618
    (949) 727-7077
    Stacey M. Leyton
    Altshuler Berzon
    177 Post Street, Suite 300
    San Francisco, CA 94108
    (415) 421-7151
    Paul G. Szumiak
    Atkinson, Andelson, Loya, Ruud & Romo
    12800 Center Court Drive South, Suite 300
    Cerritos, CA 90703-9364
    (562) 653-3200