Ixchel Pharma, LLC v. Biogen, Inc. ( 2020 )


Menu:
  •         IN THE SUPREME COURT OF
    CALIFORNIA
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC,
    Plaintiff and Appellant,
    v.
    BIOGEN, INC.,
    Defendant and Respondent.
    S256927
    Ninth Circuit
    18-15258
    Eastern District of California
    2:17-cv-00715-WBS-EFB
    August 3, 2020
    Justice Liu authored the opinion of the Court, in which Chief
    Justice Cantil-Sakauye and Justices Chin, Corrigan, Cuéllar,
    Kruger, and Groban concurred.
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    S256927
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    This case presents two questions about the bounds of
    legitimate business competition under California tort and
    antitrust law.    Plaintiff Ixchel Pharma, LLC (Ixchel), a
    biotechnology company, entered into an agreement with
    Forward Pharma (Forward) to jointly develop a drug for the
    treatment of a disorder called Friedreich’s ataxia. The drug
    development went according to plan until Forward decided to
    withdraw from the agreement, as was allowed by its terms.
    Pursuant to a settlement with another biotechnology company,
    defendant Biogen, Inc. (Biogen), Forward had agreed to
    terminate its contract with Ixchel.
    Ixchel sued Biogen in federal court for tortiously
    interfering with Ixchel’s contractual and prospective economic
    relationship with Forward and claimed that Biogen did so in
    violation of Business and Professions Code section 16600. On
    appeal, the United States Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit
    asked us to decide (1) whether Biogen’s interference in Ixchel’s
    at-will contract with Forward must be independently wrongful
    and (2) how Business and Professions Code section 16600
    applies to the settlement provision requiring Forward to
    terminate its agreement with Ixchel.
    We hold that tortious interference with at-will contracts
    requires independent wrongfulness and that a rule of reason
    1
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    applies to determine the validity of the settlement provision
    under Business and Professions Code section 16600.
    I.
    Because this case comes to us from the Ninth Circuit at
    the motion to dismiss stage, we assume the truth of the facts as
    alleged in Ixchel’s operative complaint. (Grisham v. Philip
    Morris U.S.A., Inc. (2007) 
    40 Cal. 4th 623
    , 629.) Ixchel is a
    biotechnology company that develops drugs to treat
    mitochondrial disease. Since 2012, it has been developing a
    drug containing the active ingredient dimethyl fumarate (DMF)
    to treat Friedreich’s ataxia, a neurodegenerative disorder
    affecting one in 50,000 Americans.
    Because Ixchel did not have the resources to develop the
    drug by itself, in 2016 it entered into a Collaboration Agreement
    with Forward, a biotechnology company that also develops
    drugs containing DMF for the treatment of neurological
    diseases. Under the terms of the Collaboration Agreement,
    Ixchel agreed to assign certain patent rights it possessed to
    Forward. In return, Forward agreed to work with Ixchel to
    develop a new drug containing DMF to treat Friedreich’s ataxia.
    Forward would investigate the feasibility of conducting clinical
    trials for the drug and, if feasible, would conduct those trials and
    pay for them. Ixchel would provide assistance with the clinical
    trials as necessary. If the clinical trials were successful,
    Forward agreed to manage and pay for the manufacturing and
    commercialization of the drug with the assistance of Ixchel.
    Ixchel was entitled to a percentage of royalties on sales of the
    drug and retained certain rights to engage in its own
    commercialization of the drug independent of Forward.
    2
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    The Collaboration Agreement authorized Forward to
    terminate the agreement “at any time” so long as it provided
    notice to Ixchel 60 days in advance. Ixchel was authorized to
    terminate the agreement if Forward informed Ixchel that it
    would not conduct clinical trials of the new drug or if it would
    not or did not timely submit a new drug application for the
    developed drug to the Food and Drug Administration. In
    October 2016, Forward informed Ixchel that it had confirmed
    the feasibility of conducting clinical trials and would proceed to
    conduct those trials. Thereafter, Ixchel and Forward began to
    develop a plan for a trial study.
    At the same time that Forward and Ixchel were working
    together, Forward was negotiating with Biogen, another
    biotechnology company, to settle a patent dispute related to the
    use of DMF for the treatment of multiple sclerosis. One of
    Biogen’s drugs, Tecfidera, is used to treat multiple sclerosis and
    contains DMF as an active ingredient. Ixchel alleges that
    because physicians can prescribe a drug containing DMF to
    treat conditions that the drug was not approved to treat, Ixchel’s
    drug development poses a competitive threat to Biogen’s
    Tecfidera drug.
    As a result of negotiations, Forward and Biogen entered
    into a settlement and license agreement (Forward-Biogen
    Agreement) in which Biogen agreed to pay Forward $1.25 billion
    in exchange for a license to certain Forward patents and other
    intellectual property. In addition, section 2.13 of the Forward-
    Biogen Agreement required Forward to “terminate any and all
    existing, and not enter into any new, Contracts or obligations to
    Ixchel Pharma LLC . . . and/or any other Person, to the extent
    related to the development [by Forward and its affiliate
    companies] of any pharmaceutical product having dimethyl
    3
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    fumarate as an [active ingredient] for the treatment of a human
    for any indication, including Friedreich’s ataxia.” Because
    Forward’s only business is the development of drugs containing
    DMF as an active ingredient to treat humans, Ixchel alleges that
    the Forward-Biogen Agreement effectively prohibited Forward
    from engaging in its entire business or a substantial part of it.
    Forward notified Ixchel that because it had entered into
    the Forward-Biogen Agreement, it would be terminating the
    Collaboration Agreement with Ixchel in 60 days. After Forward
    terminated the agreement, Ixchel lost its ability to develop its
    Friedreich’s ataxia treatment and has been unable to find
    another development partner to do so.
    Ixchel filed suit against Biogen in federal district court,
    asserting (1) violations of the federal and state antitrust laws
    (15 U.S.C. § 1; Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16700 et seq.), (2) tortious
    interference with contractual relations, (3) intentional and
    negligent interference with prospective economic advantage,
    and (4) violations of the unfair competition law (UCL) (Bus. &
    Prof. Code, § 17200 et seq.). (All undesignated references are to
    the Business and Professions Code.)
    The district court granted Biogen’s motion to dismiss with
    respect to each of Ixchel’s claims. (Ixchel Pharma, LLC v. Biogen
    Inc. (E.D.Cal., Sept. 12, 2017, No. 2:17-cv-00715-WBS-EFB)
    
    2017 WL 4012337
    .) It determined that Ixchel had failed to state
    a claim for interference with prospective economic advantage or
    interference with contractual relations because Ixchel did not
    plead that Biogen engaged in an independently wrongful act.
    (Id. at p. *5.) The district court acknowledged that tortious
    interference with contract claims do not generally require
    independent wrongfulness, but it held that because the contract
    4
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    at issue was one terminable at will, independent wrongfulness
    was required. (Id. at p. *4.) The district court also dismissed
    Ixchel’s federal and state antitrust claims for lack of antitrust
    standing. (Id. at p. *3.) Finally, because Ixchel’s other claims
    had been dismissed, the district court dismissed Ixchel’s UCL
    claim for failing to allege an actionable unlawful practice. (Id.
    at pp. *5–*6.)
    Ixchel then filed a second amended complaint, the
    operative complaint in this case, to allege that Biogen had
    committed the wrongful act of violating section 16600’s
    prohibition against restraints of trade. Ixchel claimed that by
    agreeing to section 2.13 of the Forward-Biogen Agreement,
    Biogen restrained Forward from engaging in lawful business
    with Ixchel and any other entity to develop neurological
    treatments containing DMF.
    The district court disagreed and again dismissed the
    complaint, this time on the grounds that the Forward-Biogen
    Agreement must be analyzed under the antitrust rule of reason
    and that section 16600 does not apply outside the employment
    context. (Ixchel Pharma, LLC v. Biogen Inc. (E.D.Cal., Jan. 25,
    2018, No. 2:17-cv-00715-WBS-EFB) 
    2018 WL 558781
    , p. *4.)
    Ixchel sought review of its tort and UCL claims. After oral
    argument, the Ninth Circuit certified two questions to this
    court: (1) “Does section 16600 of the California Business and
    Professions Code void a contract by which a business is
    restrained from engaging in a lawful trade or business with
    another business?” (2) “Is a plaintiff required to plead an
    independently wrongful act in order to state a claim for
    intentional interference with a contract that can be terminated
    by a party at any time, or does that requirement apply only to
    5
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    at-will employment contracts?” (Ixchel Pharma, LLC v. Biogen,
    Inc. (9th Cir. 2019) 
    930 F.3d 1031
    , 1033 (Ixchel).)
    We rephrase and reorder the questions as follows (see Cal.
    Rules of Court, rule 8.548(f)(5)): (1) Is a plaintiff required to
    plead an independently wrongful act in order to state a claim for
    tortious interference with a contract that is terminable at will?
    (2) What is the proper standard to determine whether section
    16600 voids a contract by which a business is restrained from
    engaging in a lawful trade or business with another business?
    The questions are related; the alleged violation of section 16600
    is the independently wrongful act in Ixchel’s contractual
    interference claim.
    II.
    We first address Ixchel’s claim that Biogen tortiously
    interfered in Ixchel’s contract with Forward. Before this court,
    neither party contests that the Cooperation Agreement is a valid
    contract that Forward was entitled to terminate at will. Nor is
    it at issue whether Forward terminated the agreement
    according to its terms by giving Ixchel notice 60 days prior to
    termination. The only question before us is whether Ixchel must
    allege that Biogen committed an independently wrongful act in
    order to state a claim for tortious interference with contract in
    light of the fact that the Cooperation Agreement is an at-will
    contract.
    A.
    California has traditionally recognized two economic
    relations torts: interference with the performance of a contract
    (Imperial Ice Co. v. Rossier (1941) 
    18 Cal. 2d 33
    , 35 (Imperial
    Ice)) and interference with a prospective economic relationship
    (Buckaloo v. Johnson (1975) 
    14 Cal. 3d 815
    , 822 (Buckaloo)).
    6
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    “[B]oth of these torts protect the public interest in stable
    economic relationships . . . .” (Reeves v. Hanlon (2004) 
    33 Cal. 4th 1140
    , 1152 (Reeves).)
    The two torts are related but distinct.             Tortious
    interference with contractual relations requires “(1) the
    existence of a valid contract between the plaintiff and a third
    party; (2) the defendant’s knowledge of that contract; (3) the
    defendant’s intentional acts designed to induce a breach or
    disruption of the contractual relationship; (4) actual breach or
    disruption of the contractual relationship; and (5) resulting
    damage.” 
    (Reeves, supra
    , 33 Cal.4th at p. 1148; see Pacific Gas
    & Electric Co. v. Bear Stearns & Co. (1990) 
    50 Cal. 3d 1118
    , 1126
    (Pacific Gas).) It is generally not necessary that the defendant’s
    conduct be wrongful apart from the interference with the
    contract itself. (Quelimane Co. v. Stewart Title Guaranty Co.
    (1998) 
    19 Cal. 4th 26
    , 55 (Quelimane).) This general rule is
    subject to certain exceptions discussed below.
    Tortious interference with prospective economic
    advantage, on the other hand, does not depend on the existence
    of a legally binding contract. A plaintiff asserting this tort must
    show that the defendant knowingly interfered with an
    “ ‘ “economic relationship between the plaintiff and some third
    party, [which carries] the probability of future economic benefit
    to the plaintiff.” ’ ” (Korea Supply Co. v. Lockheed Martin Corp.
    (2003) 
    29 Cal. 4th 1134
    , 1153 (Korea Supply).)
    Before our decision in Della Penna v. Toyota Motor Sales,
    U.S.A., Inc. (1995) 
    11 Cal. 4th 376
    (Della Penna), we treated
    interference with contractual relations and interference with
    prospective economic advantage as two species of the same tort.
    (See 
    Buckaloo, supra
    , 14 Cal.3d at p. 823.) Each tort contained
    7
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    the same elements with the exception that interference with
    contractual relations required the existence of a binding
    contract. (Compare
    id. at p. 827
    [elements of interference with
    prospective economic advantage] with Pacific 
    Gas, supra
    , 50
    Cal.3d at p. 1126 [elements of interference with contractual
    relations].) The primary difference between the two torts was
    that the range of acceptable justifications — that is, affirmative
    defenses — was broader when a defendant interfered with an
    unconsummated prospective economic relationship. (Pacific
    Gas, at p. 1126; Environmental Planning & Information Council
    v. Superior Court (1984) 
    36 Cal. 3d 188
    , 194 (EPIC); Buckaloo, at
    p. 828.) “[A] competitor’s stake in advancing his own economic
    interest will not justify the intentional inducement of a contract
    breach [citation], whereas such interests will suffice where
    contractual relations are merely contemplated or potential.”
    (EPIC, at p. 194.)
    That changed in Della Penna, when we “dr[e]w and
    enforce[d] a sharpened distinction between claims for the
    tortious disruption of an existing contract and claims that a
    prospective contractual or economic relationship has been
    interfered with.” (Della 
    Penna, supra
    , 11 Cal.4th at p. 392.) We
    held that a plaintiff seeking to recover damages for interference
    with prospective economic advantage must plead as an element
    of the claim that the defendant’s conduct was “wrongful by some
    legal measure other than the fact of interference itself.” (Id. at
    p. 393.) We reasoned that “courts provide a damage remedy
    against third party conduct intended to disrupt an existing
    contract precisely because the exchange of promises resulting in
    such a formally cemented economic relationship is deemed
    worthy of protection from interference by a stranger to the
    agreement.     Economic relationships short of contractual,
    8
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    however, should stand on a different legal footing as far as the
    potential for tort liability is reckoned. Because ours is a culture
    firmly wedded to the social rewards of commercial contests, the
    law usually takes care to draw lines of legal liability in a way
    that maximizes areas of competition free of legal penalties.” (Id.
    at p. 392.) Concerned that the old rule led “to time consuming
    and expensive lawsuits . . . by a rival, based on conduct that was
    regarded by the commercial world as both commonplace and
    appropriate” (id. at p. 384), we found it important to afford
    “greater solicitude to those relationships that have ripened into
    agreements, while recognizing that relationships short of that
    subsist in a zone where the rewards and risks of competition are
    dominant” (id. at p. 392).            Imposing an independent
    wrongfulness requirement at the pleading stage thus struck a
    “balance between providing a remedy for predatory economic
    behavior and keeping legitimate business competition outside
    litigative bounds.” (Id. at p. 378.)
    Our decisions since Della Penna have reaffirmed the
    distinction between the two torts. (See 
    Quelimane, supra
    , 19
    Cal.4th at pp. 55–56; Korea 
    Supply, supra
    , 29 Cal.4th at
    p. 1158.) So, while intentionally interfering with an existing
    contract is generally “a wrong in and of itself” (Quelimane, at
    p. 56), intentionally interfering with prospective economic
    advantage requires pleading that the defendant committed an
    independently wrongful act (Korea Supply, at p. 1158). “[A]n act
    is independently wrongful if it is unlawful, that is, if it is
    proscribed by some constitutional, statutory, regulatory,
    common law, or other determinable legal standard.” (Id. at
    p. 1159.)
    9
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    B.
    With that framework in mind, we consider whether
    stating a claim for interference with an at-will contract requires
    pleading an independently wrongful act.           We have long
    recognized that interference with at-will contracts is actionable
    as an economic tort. (Pacific 
    Gas, supra
    , 50 Cal.3d at p. 1127
    [citing cases]; accord, Truax v. Raich (1915) 
    239 U.S. 33
    , 38
    [recognizing that the weight of authority considers a third
    party’s unjustified interference with an employment-at-will
    contract actionable].) “[T]he fact that a contract is ‘at the will of
    the parties, respectively does not make it one at the will of
    others . . . .’ ” (Speegle v. Board of Fire Underwriters of the
    Pacific (1946) 
    29 Cal. 2d 34
    , 39 (Speegle).)
    But we have not decided whether interference with an at-
    will contract more closely resembles interference with
    contractual relations or interference with prospective economic
    advantage. That is because the distinction was not important
    for the many decades when the two interference torts contained
    basically the same elements. Ixchel argues that we settled the
    question in Pacific 
    Gas, supra
    , 
    50 Cal. 3d 1118
    , a case decided
    five years before Della Penna distinguished the two torts.
    According to Ixchel, Pacific Gas set “the default rule that, for an
    intentional interference with contract claim, there is no
    requirement of an independently wrongful act, even where the
    alleged misconduct is inducing a party to terminate an at-will
    contract.” We disagree.
    In that case, the Pacific Gas and Electric Company sued
    Bear Stearns for interfering in the utility’s contract to purchase
    hydroelectric power from a water resource agency and for
    interfering with the utility’s prospective economic relations.
    10
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    (Pacific 
    Gas, supra
    , 50 Cal.3d at pp. 1123–1124.) The contract
    at issue allowed the water resource agency to terminate the
    agreement at the end of the year in which the agency retired all
    of its project bonds. Bear Stearns convinced the agency to seek
    a determination in state court that it could terminate the
    contract by retiring its project bonds early. (Ibid.) We held that
    merely inducing a contracting party to seek a judicial
    determination whether it can terminate a contract according to
    its terms is not sufficient to state a claim under either economic
    tort. (Id. at p. 1137.) We outlined the elements of a contract
    interference claim for the first time and did not require that the
    interference be independently wrongful. (Id. at p. 1126.)
    Separately, we explained that interference with an at-will
    contract has long been actionable. (Id. at p. 1127.)
    Critically, we acknowledged that “[m]any cases have
    treated claims of interference with voidable and terminable
    contracts as coming within the cause of action for interference
    with prospective advantage. [Citations.] . . . [I]t may be
    preferable not to distinguish the two as separate torts [citation]
    but we need not resolve that point here, in view of our conclusion
    that the activity complained of is not included within either
    tort.” (Pacific 
    Gas, supra
    , 50 Cal.3d at p. 1128, fn. 4.) Thus,
    contrary to Ixchel’s argument, Pacific Gas expressly reserved
    the question of whether interference with an at-will contract
    should be treated as a claim of interference with contractual
    relations or as a claim of interference with prospective economic
    advantage. Because the alleged misconduct in that case did not
    constitute interference with any economic relationship,
    contractual or otherwise, it was unnecessary to resolve the
    question.
    11
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    It was also unnecessary to resolve the question because,
    as explained, the elements of both torts were largely the same
    at that time. We had yet to differentiate the two torts in Della
    Penna by requiring an independent wrongfulness element for
    interference with prospective economic advantage. There was
    thus no occasion to address whether interference with an at-will
    contract required pleading an independently wrongful act since
    it was not then a requirement for either tort. (Cf. Bed, Bath &
    Beyond of La Jolla, Inc. v. La Jolla Village Square Venture
    Partners (1997) 
    52 Cal. App. 4th 867
    , 880, fn. 9 [cases decided
    before Della Penna are not relevant to determining whether
    interference with an unenforceable contract constitutes
    interference with contractual relations or interference with
    prospective economic advantage].) So, Pacific Gas did not
    answer the question now before us.
    Fourteen years later in 
    Reeves, supra
    , 
    33 Cal. 4th 1140
    , we
    resolved part of the question Pacific Gas left open. Reeves held
    that a plaintiff must plead independent wrongfulness to state a
    claim for interference with a specific category of at-will
    contracts: employment contracts. (Reeves, at p. 1145.) That
    holding was based on two rationales. First, California’s public
    policy favoring employment competition supported such a rule.
    We observed that “it has long been the public policy of our state
    that ‘[a] former employee has the right to engage in a
    competitive business for himself and to enter into competition
    with his former employer, even for the business of . . . his former
    employer, provided such competition is fairly and legally
    conducted.’ ” (Id. at p. 1149.) Our previous decisions indicated
    that “[w]here no unlawful methods are used, public policy
    generally supports a competitor’s right to offer more pay or
    better terms to another’s employee, so long as the employee is
    12
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    free to leave.” (Id. at p. 1151; see also
    id. at p. 1145
    [observing
    that the independent wrongfulness requirement “will promote
    the public policies supporting the right of at-will employees to
    pursue opportunities for economic betterment and the right of
    employers to compete for talented workers”].)
    Second, we reasoned that “the economic relationship
    between parties to contracts that are terminable at will is
    distinguishable from the relationship between parties to other
    legally binding contracts.” 
    (Reeves, supra
    , 33 Cal.4th at
    p. 1151.) We explained that interference with other legally
    binding contracts, such as contracts of a definite term, is tortious
    “ ‘because the exchange of promises resulting in such a formally
    cemented economic relationship is deemed worthy of protection
    from interference by a stranger to the agreement.’ ” (Ibid.,
    quoting Della 
    Penna, supra
    , 11 Cal.4th at p. 392.) But at-will
    contracts do not involve the same “cemented economic
    relationship[s]” as contracts of a definite term. (Della Penna, at
    p. 392.) Quoting the Restatement Second of Torts, we explained
    that “ ‘any interference with [an at-will contract] that induces
    its termination is primarily an interference with the future
    relation between the parties, and the plaintiff has no legal
    assurance of them. As for the future hopes he has no legal right
    but only an expectancy; and when the contract is terminated by
    the choice of [a contracting party] there is no breach of it. The
    competitor is therefore free, for his own competitive advantage,
    to obtain the future benefits for himself by causing the
    termination. Thus, he may offer better contract terms, as by
    offering an employee of the plaintiff more money to work for him
    or by offering a seller higher prices for goods, and he may make
    use of persuasion or other suitable means, all without liability.’ ”
    13
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    (Reeves, at pp. 1151–1152, first bracketed insertion added,
    quoting Rest.2d Torts, § 768, com. i.)
    Ixchel argues that we should limit Reeves to the
    employment context. It cites the employment-specific policy
    concerns animating Reeves as well as appellate decisions that
    have limited Reeves’s holding to suits involving a former
    employer suing a competitor for hiring away a former employee.
    (See Redfearn v. Trader Joe’s Co. (2018) 
    20 Cal. App. 5th 989
    ,
    1003; Popescu v. Apple Inc. (2016) 
    1 Cal. App. 5th 39
    , 62.) Biogen
    contends that the rationale in Reeves applies beyond the
    employment context to intentional interference with contract
    whenever a “defendant induces a new partner to terminate an
    at-will agreement.”
    It is true that our holding in Reeves relied partly on
    reasoning specific to the employment context. But the broader
    logic underlying that decision is persuasive with respect to other
    spheres of economic relations. The Restatement’s rationale on
    which Reeves relied is not limited to employment relationships.
    The Restatement explains: “One’s interest in a contract
    terminable at will is primarily an interest in future relations
    between the parties, and he has no legal assurance of them. For
    this reason, an interference with this interest is closely
    analogous to interference with prospective contractual
    relations. [Citation.] If the defendant was a competitor
    regarding the business involved in the contract, his interference
    with the contract may be not improper.” (Rest.2d Torts, § 766,
    com. g; accord
    , id., § 768, com.
    i.)
    A number of states have adopted this section of the
    Restatement to require proof of independent wrongfulness in a
    claim for interference with at-will contractual relations. (See
    14
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    Nostrame v. Santiago (2013) 
    213 N.J. 109
    , 121; Macklin v.
    Robert Logan Associates (1994) 
    334 Md. 287
    , 304; Duggin v.
    Adams (1987) 
    234 Va. 221
    , 226–227; Memorial Gardens, Inc. v.
    Olympian Sales & Management Consultants, Inc. (Colo. 1984)
    
    690 P.2d 207
    , 211; Guard-Life Corp. v. S. Parker Hardware Mfg.
    Corp. (1980) 
    50 N.Y.2d 183
    , 191.) We have often aligned the
    elements of both economic relations torts with the Restatement
    (see Korea 
    Supply, supra
    , 29 Cal.4th at p. 1156 [intentional
    interference with contract does not contain a specific intent
    requirement]; 
    Quelimane, supra
    , 19 Cal.4th at p. 56
    [interference with prospective economic advantage does not
    contain a specific intent requirement]; Della 
    Penna, supra
    , 11
    Cal.4th at p. 378 [interference with prospective economic
    advantage requires proof of a “ ‘wrongful act’ ”]), and we find the
    Restatement persuasive here as well.
    The purpose of the independent wrongfulness
    requirement in economic interference torts is to “balance
    between providing a remedy for predatory economic behavior
    and keeping legitimate business competition outside litigative
    bounds.” (Della 
    Penna, supra
    , 11 Cal.4th at p. 378; see
    
    Buckaloo, supra
    , 14 Cal.3d at p. 828; Imperial 
    Ice, supra
    , 18
    Cal.2d at p. 36.) Where economic relationships have solidified
    into binding future promises, the stability of the contractual
    relationship takes precedence over business competition. While
    “[o]urs is a competitive economy in which business entities vie
    for economic advantage” (Buckaloo, at p. 828), that competition
    must at some point result in entities making agreements and
    exchanging things of value. When parties enter a contract not
    terminable at will, they cement their bargained-for intentions in
    accordance with the terms of that contract into the future. The
    concreteness of this relationship means that contracting parties
    15
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    as well as other entities may structure their decisions, invest
    resources, and take risks in reliance on it. It is precisely this
    “exchange of promises resulting in such a formally cemented
    economic relationship [that courts have] deemed worthy of
    protection from interference by a stranger to the agreement.”
    (Della Penna, at p. 392.) “Intentionally inducing or causing a
    breach of an existing contract is therefore a wrong in and of
    itself.” (
    Quelimane, supra
    , 19 Cal.4th at pp. 55–56.)
    The same balance of interests does not apply to
    prospective economic relationships. Such relationships are only
    “probable” (Korea 
    Supply, supra
    , 29 Cal.4th at p. 1164), and
    harms resulting from a breach of such relationships are
    “speculative” (
    Quelimane, supra
    , 19 Cal.4th at p. 56). Neither
    party to such a relationship has a legal claim to continued
    relations with the other. Because the expectation of future
    relations is weaker and the interest in maintaining open
    competition is stronger, “the law usually takes care to draw lines
    of legal liability in a way that maximizes areas of competition
    free of legal penalties.” (Della 
    Penna, supra
    , 11 Cal.4th at
    p. 392.) In circumstances where parties have no legal assurance
    of future relations, “the rewards and risks of competition are
    dominant.” (Ibid.)
    Like parties to a prospective economic relationship,
    parties to at-will contracts have no legal assurance of future
    economic relations.      (See Beckwith v. Dahl (2012) 
    205 Cal. App. 4th 1039
    , 1053 [at-will contracts provide “only an
    expectation of future contractual relations”].) An at-will
    contract may be terminated, by its terms, at the prerogative of
    a single party, whether it is because that party found a better
    offer from a competitor, because the party decided not to
    continue doing business, or for some other reason. And the other
    16
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    party has no legal claim to the continuation of the relationship.
    The contracting parties presumably bargained for these terms,
    aware of the risk that the relationship may be terminated at any
    time. At-will contractual relations are thus not cemented in the
    way that a contract not terminable at will is. The interest in
    protecting the contract from interference more closely resembles
    the interest in protecting prospective economic relationships
    than the interest in protecting a contractual relationship that,
    by its terms, is expected to continue on pain of breach.
    Indeed, sometimes the only difference between an at-will
    contract and a prospective economic relationship is the formality
    of how a contractual relationship is structured. For example, a
    buyer who regularly renews a one-time contract to purchase
    goods has a prospective economic relationship with the vendor
    with respect to future purchases of those goods. (See Shida v.
    Japan Food Corp. (1967) 
    251 Cal. App. 2d 864
    , 866 [interference
    with yearly renewal of contract treated as interference with
    prospective economic advantage].) But that same buyer would
    have an at-will contractual relationship if it entered into a single
    contract with the vendor to provide those goods at regular
    intervals terminable at the buyer’s will. In both, the vendor has
    no legal assurance of the buyer’s continued purchases.
    We recognize that in an at-will contract, the parties’
    expectations are of continuity unless one party terminates the
    contract, whereas the expectations of a continued relationship
    are more speculative where no contract exists. But from the
    perspective of third parties, there is no legal basis in either case
    to expect the continuity of the relationship or to make decisions
    in reliance on the relationship. We are not convinced that any
    difference in expectations between the parties requires a
    different pleading standard between interference with
    17
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    prospective economic advantage and interference with at-will
    contractual relations.
    Finally, allowing interference with at-will contract claims
    without requiring independent wrongfulness risks chilling
    legitimate business competition. An actionable claim for
    interference with contractual relations does not require that the
    defendant have the specific intent to interfere with a contract.
    A plaintiff states a claim so long as it alleges that the defendant
    knew interference was “ ‘certain or substantially certain to occur
    as a result of [defendant’s] action.’ ” (
    Quelimane, supra
    , 19
    Cal.4th at p. 56.) Without an independent wrongfulness
    requirement, a competitor’s good faith offer that causes a
    business to withdraw from an at-will contract could trigger
    liability or at least subject the competitor to costly litigation. In
    fact, even if a business in an at-will contract solicits offers on its
    own initiative, a third party that submits an offer could face
    liability if it knew that acceptance of the offer would cause the
    soliciting business to withdraw from its existing contract.
    Allowing disappointed competitors to state claims for
    interference with at-will contracts without alleging
    independently wrongful conduct may expose routine and
    legitimate business competition to litigation.
    We therefore hold that to state a claim for interference
    with an at-will contract by a third party, the plaintiff must
    allege that the defendant engaged in an independently wrongful
    act. We disapprove Redfearn v. Trader Joe’s 
    Co., supra
    , 
    20 Cal. App. 5th 989
    and Popescu v. Apple 
    Inc., supra
    , 
    1 Cal. App. 5th 39
    to the extent they are inconsistent with this opinion.
    18
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    III.
    Ixchel alleges that the wrongful act Biogen committed was
    including section 2.13 in the Forward-Biogen Agreement in
    violation of Business and Professions Code section 16600.
    Section 2.13 of the Forward-Biogen Agreement required
    Forward to terminate its Collaboration Agreement with Ixchel
    and barred Forward from engaging in business with any other
    entity to develop neurological treatments containing DMF.
    Ixchel claims that this contractual provision is an unlawful
    restraint of trade in violation of section 16600, which provides:
    “Except as provided in this chapter, every contract by which
    anyone is restrained from engaging in a lawful profession, trade,
    or business of any kind is to that extent void.”
    The Ninth Circuit certified the following question to us:
    “Does section 16600 of the California Business and Professions
    Code void a contract by which a business is restrained from
    engaging in a lawful trade or business with another business?”
    
    (Ixchel, supra
    , 930 F.3d at p. 1033.) That question appears to
    ask this court to decide whether section 16600 applies to
    contracts in the business context. The Ninth Circuit suggested
    that “the California Supreme Court . . . [has not] considered
    whether section 16600 extends beyond the employment setting
    entirely to contractual restraints on business operations.”
    (Ixchel, at p. 1036.)
    Ixchel asks us to decide that question only. But the
    primary dispute between Ixchel and Biogen in the Ninth Circuit
    was not whether section 16600 applies to business contracts. At
    oral argument in the Ninth Circuit, Biogen acknowledged that
    it does. Instead, the dispute was whether contractual restraints
    on business operations or commercial dealings are subject to a
    19
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    reasonableness standard under section 16600. Moreover, the
    proper standard governing alleged restraints of trade under
    section 16600 presents an important question of California law,
    potentially affecting all contracts in California that in some way
    restrain a contracting party from engaging in a profession,
    trade, or business.
    To provide the Ninth Circuit sufficient guidance to resolve
    the contentions of the parties and to answer an important
    question of California law, we address not only whether section
    16600 applies to contracts in the business context (the parties
    agree that it does) but also the proper standard — in particular,
    whether a rule of reason applies — to evaluate whether
    restraints on trade in business contracts are void under section
    16600. (See Cal. Rules of Court, rule 8.548(f)(5); Verdugo v.
    Target Corp. (2014) 
    59 Cal. 4th 312
    , 317, fn. 1 [restating certified
    question “to conform to the facts at issue in the underlying
    action”].)
    Ixchel argues that deciding this question is premature
    because the case is at the pleading stage and the parties have
    not had the opportunity to discover facts that would show
    whether section 2.13 of the Forward-Biogen Agreement was
    unreasonable. But in deciding whether section 16600 includes
    a reasonableness requirement in the context of business
    contracts, we are deciding a pure question of law. The question
    at this stage is whether Ixchel must plead and prove
    unreasonableness, not whether it has actually done so. Whether
    the   parties    have     put   forth    facts   demonstrating
    unreasonableness is immaterial to the antecedent question of
    whether a reasonableness requirement applies here.
    20
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    A.
    As an initial matter, we agree with the parties that section
    16600 applies to business contracts. The chapter of the Business
    and Professions Code containing section 16600 excepts from
    section 16600’s coverage certain noncompetition agreements
    upon the sale of goodwill or of ownership interest in a business
    (§ 16601) and upon the dissolution or dissociation from a
    partnership (§ 16602) or limited liability corporation
    (§ 16602.5). If section 16600 did not apply to business contracts,
    these exceptions would be unnecessary. Indeed, California
    courts have frequently analyzed whether contracts involving
    business dealings are void under section 16600. (See, e.g.,
    Centeno v. Roseville Community Hospital (1979) 
    107 Cal. App. 3d 62
    , 68 (Centeno); Dayton Time Lock Service, Inc. v. Silent
    Watchman Corp. (1975) 
    52 Cal. App. 3d 1
    , 6 (Dayton Time Lock);
    Great Western Distillery Products v. John A. Wathen Distillery
    Co. (1937) 
    10 Cal. 2d 442
    , 445–446 (Great Western Distillery)
    [applying Civ. Code, former § 1673, the predecessor statute to
    Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16600]; Getz Bros. & Co. v. Federal Salt Co.
    (1905) 
    147 Cal. 115
    , 118–119 (Getz Brothers) [same].)
    The parties do not contend that any of the exceptions to
    section 16600 apply here. Instead, they disagree on the
    applicable standard to examine the validity of section 2.13 of the
    Forward-Biogen Agreement under section 16600.                Biogen
    argues that the rule of reason used to analyze antitrust
    violations under the Cartwright Act (§ 16700 et seq.) should also
    govern restraints on business dealings under section 16600.
    That inquiry asks “whether an agreement harms competition
    more than it helps” by considering “ ‘the facts peculiar to the
    business in which the restraint is applied, the nature of the
    restraint and its effects, and the history of the restraint and the
    21
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    reasons for its adoption.’ ” (In re Cipro Cases I & II (2015) 
    61 Cal. 4th 116
    , 146 (Cipro).) Ixchel counters that section 16600 is
    not subject to a reasonableness standard; it urges the court to
    extend Edwards v. Arthur Andersen LLP (2008) 
    44 Cal. 4th 937
    (Edwards) and hold that any contract in restraint of trade is per
    se void.
    The language of section 16600 is broad on its face: “Except
    as provided in this chapter, every contract by which anyone is
    restrained from engaging in a lawful profession, trade, or
    business of any kind is to that extent void.” Read in isolation,
    the text suggests that any part of an agreement restraining a
    party from engaging in a trade, profession, or business is per se
    invalid unless certain exceptions apply. But in reading statutes,
    we consider the text in the context of “the statutory framework
    as a whole in order to determine its scope and purpose.”
    (Coalition of Concerned Communities, Inc. v. City of Los Angeles
    (2004) 
    34 Cal. 4th 733
    , 737.) And we must consider the statute
    in light of precedent construing it. (See Coker v. JPMorgan
    Chase Bank, N.A. (2016) 
    62 Cal. 4th 667
    , 676.)
    In context, section 16600 is best read not to render void
    per se all contractual restraints on business dealings, but rather
    to subject such restraints to a rule of reason. Section 16600 was
    initially enacted in 1872 as section 1673 of the Civil Code using
    substantively identical language. (Civ. Code, former § 1673,
    repealed by Stats. 1941, ch. 526, § 2, p. 1847 and enacted as
    Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16600 by Stats. 1941, ch. 526, § 1, p. 1834.)
    Our decisions interpreting Civil Code former section 1673 thus
    inform the interpretation of section 16600. (See People v.
    Bonnetta (2009) 
    46 Cal. 4th 143
    , 151 [“[W]hen a statute has been
    construed by the courts and the Legislature thereafter reenacts
    the statute without changing the interpreted language, a
    22
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    presumption is raised that the Legislature was aware of and has
    acquiesced in that construction.”].) And Civil Code former
    section 1673 was enacted against the backdrop of well-
    established common law prohibitions against restraints of
    trade. (See Vulcan Powder Co. v. Hercules Powder Co. (1892) 
    96 Cal. 510
    , 513 (Vulcan Powder).) As explained below, this court
    has interpreted section 16600 and its Civil Code predecessor on
    numerous occasions, and we have declined to categorically
    invalidate all agreements limiting the freedom to engage in
    trade. Over time, our case law has generally invalidated
    agreements not to compete upon the termination of employment
    or upon the sale of interest in a business without inquiring into
    their reasonableness, while invalidating other contractual
    restraints on businesses operations and commercial dealings
    only if such restraints were unreasonable.
    We must also consider section 16600’s “language in its
    ‘broader statutory context’ and, where possible, harmonize that
    language with related provisions by interpreting them in a
    consistent fashion.” (ZB, N.A. v. Superior Court (2019) 
    8 Cal. 5th 175
    , 189 (ZB).) Section 16600 sits alongside another antitrust
    statute, the Cartwright Act (§ 16700 et seq.), which we have
    construed to permit reasonable restraints of trade. 
    (Cipro, supra
    , 61 Cal.4th at p. 137.) This statutory context further
    supports the conclusion that a rule of reason applies to
    contractual restraints on business operations and commercial
    dealings under section 16600.
    B.
    We turn first to the statute’s history and our precedent.
    “Under the common law, . . . contractual restraints on the
    practice of a profession, business, or trade, were considered
    23
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    valid, as long as they were reasonably imposed.” 
    (Edwards, supra
    , 44 Cal.4th at p. 945; accord, Wright v. Ryder (1868) 
    36 Cal. 342
    , 357 (Wright).) As noted, the Legislature in 1872
    adopted Civil Code former section 1673, which provided: “Every
    contract by which any one is restrained from exercising a lawful
    profession, trade, or business of any kind, otherwise than is
    provided by the next two sections, is to that extent void.” The
    next two sections excepted certain contractual restraints upon
    the sale of goodwill in a business (Civ. Code, former § 1674) or
    upon dissolution of a partnership (Civ. Code, former § 1675).
    The Code Commissioners’ note stated that Civil Code
    former section 1673 was enacted in response to certain “modern
    decisions” that allowed contractual restraints to a “dangerous
    extent.” (Code commrs., note foll. 1 Ann. Civ. Code, § 1673 (1st
    ed. 1872, Haymond & Burch, commrs.-annotators) p. 502
    (Commissioners’ Note).) Specifically, it disapproved of two cases
    upholding agreements not to compete in the operation of boats.
    (Id. at pp. 502–503, citing Dunlop v. Gregory (1851) 
    10 N.Y. 241
    ,
    California Steam Nav. Co. v. Wright (1856) 
    6 Cal. 258
    .) But the
    Commissioners’ Note did not go so far as to say that Civil Code
    former section 1673 categorically replaced the common law
    standard of reasonableness with a per se rule. In fact, the note
    stated that the statute’s limitation on contractual restraints was
    consistent with two decisions adopting the common law
    reasonableness standard. (Commissioners’ Note, at p. 503,
    citing 
    Wright, supra
    , 
    36 Cal. 342
    , More v. Bonnet (1870) 
    40 Cal. 251
    (More).) And one of those decisions expressly upheld a
    noncompetition agreement “because the limits [were] not
    unreasonable.” (More, at p. 254.) Thus, the Commissioners’
    Note suggests that Civil Code former section 1673, in
    prohibiting agreements that restrained trade to a “dangerous
    24
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    extent,” was not intended to invalidate all restraints on trade.
    (Commissioners’ Note, at p. 502; see People v. Chun (2009) 
    45 Cal. 4th 1172
    , 1187 [Commissioners’ notes are “entitled to
    substantial weight”].)
    Nor did this court’s decisions interpreting Civil Code
    former section 1673 adopt a per se rule invalidating all contracts
    that limit business dealings. Our cases initially offered little
    clarity on the appropriate standard to evaluate agreements
    restraining trade. In our first reasoned opinion interpreting the
    statute, we invalidated an agreement between manufacturers of
    dynamite to fix prices and limit output. (Vulcan 
    Powder, supra
    ,
    96 Cal. at pp. 514–515.) We noted that the common law rule of
    reason “led to much perplexing legislation” and had been
    replaced by Civil Code former section 1673, but we did not
    explain what standard the new statute imposed. (Vulcan
    Powder, at p. 513.) We simply said that the agreement at issue
    was “clearly in restraint of trade and against public policy; and
    this conclusion is too obvious to need argument, authorities, or
    elucidation.” (Id. at p. 515.) Our reasoning did not explain
    whether we found the agreement per se invalid or invalid by
    some other standard. (See also Schwalm v. Holmes (1875) 
    49 Cal. 665
    , 669 [holding that exclusive sales contract was “not
    illegal, as being in restraint of trade” in two-sentence disposition
    without further analysis].)
    Over time, however, two discernible categories of holdings
    emerged in our case law: Agreements not to compete after the
    termination of employment or the sale of interest in a business
    were invalid without regard to their reasonableness. And
    agreements limiting commercial dealings and business
    operations were generally invalid if they were unreasonable.
    25
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    As to agreements not to compete after termination of
    employment or the sale of interest in a business, an early case
    was Merchants’ Ad-Sign Co. v. Sterling (1899) 
    124 Cal. 429
    (Merchants’ Ad-Sign), which invalidated an agreement not to
    compete as part of the sale of stock in an advertising company.
    (Id. at p. 434.) Our reasoning in that case rested on the plain
    language of the statute, and we did not examine whether the
    restraint was reasonable. We emphasized that “[t]he language
    of the code is unmistakable” and rejected the applicability of
    cases adopting a more “liberal construction” of the statute.
    (Ibid.) Because the noncompetition agreement prevented one
    party from engaging in the business of bill posting after he sold
    his interest in the advertising business to the other party, it
    violated the plain language of Civil Code former section 1673
    and was therefore void. (Merchants Ad-Sign, at p. 434.)
    Likewise, in Chamberlain v. Augustine (1916) 
    172 Cal. 285
    (Chamberlain), we invalidated an agreement imposing a
    financial penalty for competition, which was included as part of
    the sale of stock in a foundry company. (Id. at p. 288.) The
    $5,000 penalty was a sufficient deterrent to competition to
    constitute a restraint of trade under Civil Code former section
    1673. Pointing to “the very language of [former] section 1673,”
    we determined that “[t]he statute makes no exception in favor
    of contracts only in partial restraint of trade.” (Chamberlain, at
    pp. 288, 289; accord, Gregory v. Spieker (1895) 
    110 Cal. 150
    , 154
    [agreement not to compete in a particular county as part of the
    sale of a liquor business “transgressed the statute”].)
    It is true that these decisions spoke in broad terms,
    suggesting that restraints on trade in all contexts were void per
    se. (See Merchants’ 
    Ad-Sign, supra
    , 124 Cal. at p. 434 [“[t]he
    language of the code is unmistakable”]; 
    Chamberlain, supra
    ,
    26
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    172 Cal. at pp. 288–289 [“the very language of [former] section
    1673 . . . makes no exception in favor of contracts only in partial
    restraint of trade”].) But “[i]t is axiomatic that an unnecessarily
    broad holding is ‘informed and limited by the fact[s]’ of the case in
    which it is articulated.” (Covenant Care, Inc. v. Superior Court
    (2004) 
    32 Cal. 4th 771
    , 790, fn. 11; see People v. Mendoza (2000) 
    23 Cal. 4th 896
    , 915 [“ ‘we must view with caution seemingly
    categorical directives not essential to earlier decisions’ ”].) The
    contracts at issue in these cases involved agreements not to
    compete upon terminating employment or selling a business,
    and we understand their holdings to be informed and limited by
    the factual context presented.
    By contrast, we did not interpret Civil Code former section
    1673 so literally with regard to contractual restraints on
    business operations and commercial dealings. We generally
    declared agreements in this context valid if the restraints they
    imposed were reasonable. In Grogan v. Chaffee (1909) 
    156 Cal. 611
    (Grogan), we upheld a contract between a manufacturer and
    purchaser of olive oil requiring the purchaser to resell the
    product at a certain price. We interpreted Civil Code former
    section 1673 to contain a reasonableness requirement: “It is not
    every limitation on absolute freedom of dealing that is
    prohibited. . . . ‘The question is whether, under the particular
    circumstances of the case, and the nature of the particular
    contract involved in it, the contract is, or is not,
    unreasonable.’ . . . [I]t must be taken to be settled that the
    sections of the Civil Code, [former] sections 1673, 1674, 1675,
    relating to contracts in restraint of trade are to be construed in
    the light of these principles.” (Grogan, at p. 615.) The
    agreement, we concluded, was a reasonable restraint because its
    purpose was not to create a monopoly but to “secur[e] the
    27
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    legitimate benefits of the reputation which [the manufacturer’s]
    product may have attained.” (Id. at p. 614.)
    Similarly, in Associated Oil Co. v. Myers (1933) 
    217 Cal. 297
    (Associated Oil), we upheld a contract between the lessor of
    an automobile service station and a lessee of the station, which
    included an agreement that the lessor would only sell the
    lessee’s petroleum products.        Citing the reasonableness
    standard in Grogan, we concluded that the lessee “had the right
    to decline to sell any but its own product upon the leased
    property. We can see nothing unreasonable in requiring the
    [lessor] to do the same thing. The public interest is not involved
    and competition is not stifled. In no way does the agreement
    attempt to limit production or fix the price of the commodity
    involved.” (Associated Oil, at p. 306.)
    Some of our cases invalidating contractual restraints in
    the business context did not expressly apply a reasonableness
    standard. (See Morey v. Paladini (1922) 
    187 Cal. 727
    (Morey);
    Pacific Wharf & Storage Co. v. Standard Am. Dredging Co.
    (1920) 
    184 Cal. 21
    (Pacific Wharf); Getz 
    Brothers, supra
    , 
    147 Cal. 115
    ; Vulcan 
    Powder, supra
    , 
    96 Cal. 510
    .) But these decisions
    did not invalidate contractual provisions merely because they
    restrained trade in some way. Instead, we examined the
    purpose of the contracts at issue, much as we would do in a
    reasonableness inquiry, and we found the contracts to be invalid
    when their purpose was to restrain trade by creating a
    monopoly, restricting supply, or fixing prices. (See 
    Cipro, supra
    ,
    61 Cal.4th at p. 146 [recounting that the rule of reason asks
    “ ‘whether the challenged conduct promotes or suppresses
    competition’ ”].)
    28
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    In Morey, for example, we invalidated an agreement
    requiring a vendor to sell lobsters exclusively to a purchaser in
    a certain geographic area. 
    (Morey, supra
    , 187 Cal. at pp. 732,
    736.) We emphasized that the overall purpose of the agreement
    was to “secure to [the purchaser], so far as possible, a monopoly
    of the lobster business in the selected territory.” (Id. at p. 738;
    see
    id. at p. 736
    [contract had “the purpose of putting it into the
    power of the [purchaser] to control the lobster market”];
    id. at p. 737
    [contract “intended to effect a virtual monopoly of the
    lobster trade”].) Our reasoning was more concerned with the
    potential monopoly effect of the agreement than with whether
    its terms limited trade per se.
    Our other decisions in the business context followed
    similar logic. (See Endicott v. Rosenthal (1932) 
    216 Cal. 721
    ,
    725 (Endicott) [invalidating an agreement between clothes
    dyeing businesses to form an association that set industry-wide
    prices and prevented its members from soliciting each other’s
    customers because “the two main purposes for which this
    association was formed were to increase prices and eliminate
    competition”]; Getz 
    Brothers, supra
    , 147 Cal. at p. 119
    [invalidating a contract by two companies to exclusively buy and
    sell salt from each other and to discourage salt shipments by
    third parties because it had a “direct and primary purpose” to
    restrain trade]; Santa Clara Val. M. & L. Co. v. Hayes (1888) 
    76 Cal. 387
    , 392 [invalidating exclusive dealing agreement with an
    “object and view to suppress the supply and enhance the price
    of lumber in four counties of the state”]; but see Pacific 
    Wharf, supra
    , 184 Cal. at p. 23 [invalidating agreement forbidding
    seller of harbor dredge to compete in the dredging business
    because “[t]he language of [Civil Code former section 1673] is
    clear and unambiguous”].)
    29
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    Our last decision to interpret Civil Code former section
    1673 in the context of business dealings made clear that a rule
    of reason applies in this context. In Great Western 
    Distillery, supra
    , 
    10 Cal. 2d 442
    , we upheld a contract in which a buyer
    agreed to purchase whiskey exclusively from a distillery in
    exchange for being the sole merchant of that whiskey in
    California. We summarized the law as follows: “ ‘Statutes are
    interpreted in the light of reason and common sense, and it may
    be stated as a general rule that courts will not hold to be in
    restraint of trade a contract between individuals, the main
    purpose and effect of which are to promote and increase business
    in the line affected, merely because its operations might possibly
    in some theoretical way incidentally and indirectly restrict trade
    in such line.’ ” (Id. at p. 446.) Reviewing the cases upholding
    and invalidating contractual agreements, we explained that this
    general rule was consistent with each of them. (Id. at pp. 447–
    449, citing Associated 
    Oil, supra
    , 217 Cal. at p. 304, 
    Grogan, supra
    , 156 Cal. at p. 615, 
    Morey, supra
    , 
    187 Cal. 727
    , 
    Endicott, supra
    , 
    216 Cal. 721
    .) Applying this rule to the agreement at
    issue, we upheld the agreement because it “disclose[d] merely
    an intent to provide for the promotion of the business of the
    defendant” and had the effect of “develop[ing] a market for the
    sale of the commodity within the limited territory.” (Great
    Western Distillery, at pp. 449, 450.)
    Thus, like previous decisions evaluating business
    contracts, Great Western Distillery rejected a literal reading of
    Civil Code former section 1673 in favor of a rule of
    reasonableness: Contracts with the purpose and effect of
    promoting trade and competition are valid even if their terms
    incidentally restrain commercial freedom in some way. After
    Great Western Distillery, the “trend of authorities [was] to
    30
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    construe such statutes as [former] section 1673 of the Civil Code,
    and contracts between individuals intended to promote rather
    than to restrict a particular business, ‘[i]n the light of reason
    and common sense’ so as to uphold reasonable limited
    restrictions.” (Keating v. Preston (1940) 
    42 Cal. App. 2d 110
    , 123,
    quoting Great Western 
    Distillery, supra
    , 10 Cal.2d at p. 446.)
    To summarize, our decisions interpreting Civil Code
    former section 1673, the predecessor to Business and
    Professions Code section 16600, gradually evolved to evaluate
    contractual restraints on business operations and commercial
    dealings based on a reasonableness standard. In this respect,
    Civil Code former section 1673 did not depart from the common
    law rule. (See 
    Centeno, supra
    , 107 Cal.App.3d at p. 68
    [observing in a case involving an exclusive medical services
    contract that “[s]ection 16600 is basically a codification of the
    common law relating to contracts in restraint of trade”].) But
    we often interpreted the statute more strictly when it came to
    agreements not to compete after the termination of employment
    or the sale of interest in a business. Thus, instead of adopting a
    per se rule that all contractual limitations on the freedom to
    engage in commercial dealings are invalid, our precedent
    interpreting Civil Code former section 1673 was more nuanced.
    In 1941, the Legislature repealed Civil Code former
    section 1673 and reenacted it as Business and Professions Code
    section 16600 using substantively identical language.
    (Stats. 1941, ch. 526, § 1, p. 1834.) In doing so, the Legislature
    is presumed to have incorporated this court’s construction of
    Civil Code former section 1673 into section 16600. (People v.
    
    Bonnetta, supra
    , 46 Cal.4th at p. 151.) Since then, this court has
    had occasion to construe section 16600 only in relation to
    contracts restraining competition after the termination of
    31
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    employment or the sale of interest in a business. (See 
    Edwards, supra
    , 44 Cal.4th at p. 950 [termination of employment];
    Swenson v. File (1970) 
    3 Cal. 3d 389
    , 395 (Swenson) [termination
    of partnership]; Muggill v. Reuben H. Donnelley Corp. (1965) 
    62 Cal. 2d 239
    , 242–243 (Muggill) [termination of employment];
    Martinez v. Martinez (1953) 
    41 Cal. 2d 704
    , 706 (Martinez) [sale
    of business].) These cases have followed our earlier decisions by
    strictly construing the prohibition on restraint of trade in such
    contexts.
    In Muggill, we invalidated a noncompetition agreement
    between a retiree and his former employer when the former
    employer ceased pension payments after the employee went to
    work for a competitor. 
    (Muggill, supra
    , 62 Cal.2d at p. 240.) We
    said that the “settled interpretation” of section 16600 created an
    unambiguous rule: “This section invalidates provisions in
    employment contracts prohibiting an employee from working for
    a competitor after completion of his employment . . . .” (Muggill,
    at pp. 243, 242). Comparing the facts to those in Chamberlain,
    a pre-reenactment decision involving the sale of business stock
    by a former employee, we stated that “[s]imilarly, in this case,
    the provision forfeiting plaintiff’s pension rights if he works for
    a competitor restrains him from engaging in a lawful business
    and is therefore void.” (Id. at p. 243.)
    Even when we have upheld portions of noncompetition
    agreements under statutory exceptions to section 16600, we
    have recognized that any portion of the agreement restraining
    competition not within an exception is per se invalid. For
    example, we said in Swenson that a noncompetition agreement
    between a former partner of an accounting firm and his firm
    would fall outside the section 16602 exception and thus be
    invalid “[o]n its face” if “it forb[ade him] from serving former
    32
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    partnership clients without regard to territorial limits.”
    
    (Swenson, supra
    , 3 Cal.3d at p. 395; see § 16602, subd. (a) [“Any
    partner may, upon [dissolution or disassociation from the
    partnership], agree that he or she will not carry on a similar
    business within a specified geographic area where the
    partnership business has been transacted, so long as any other
    member of the partnership . . . carries on a like business
    therein.”]; see also 
    Martinez, supra
    , 41 Cal.2d at p. 706 [trial
    court “properly limited the duration of the covenant [not to
    compete] by providing that it should continue so long as plaintiff
    . . . should carry on a like business in San Diego County, that
    being the period permitted by sections 16600 and 16601 of the
    Business and Professions Code”].)
    Our most recent section 16600 decision broke no new
    ground in holding that a noncompetition agreement between a
    tax manager and his employer was per se invalid. 
    (Edwards, supra
    , 44 Cal.4th at p. 955.) The plaintiff in Edwards signed an
    agreement with his employer Arthur Andersen, which
    prohibited him from working for or soliciting certain clients of
    the firm for limited periods following his termination of
    employment. (Id. at p. 942.) When HSBC acquired Arthur
    Andersen, it offered to employ Edwards on the condition that he
    sign a “ ‘Termination of Non-compete Agreement,’ ” which would
    effect a general release of claims against Arthur Andersen and,
    in turn, induce Arthur Andersen to release Edwards from the
    noncompetition agreement he had previously signed. (Id. at
    p. 943.) When Edwards refused to sign the termination of
    noncompete agreement, Arthur Andersen fired him, and HSBC
    withdrew its offer to employ him. (Ibid.) Edwards sued Arthur
    Andersen for interference with prospective economic advantage,
    claiming that the interference was wrongful because the
    33
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    underlying noncompetition agreement he signed was invalid
    under section 16600. (Edwards, at p. 944.)
    We agreed, holding that “an employer cannot by contract
    restrain a former employee from engaging in his or her
    profession, trade, or business unless the agreement falls within
    one of the exceptions to the rule.” 
    (Edwards, supra
    , 44 Cal.4th
    at pp. 946–947.) We said that section 16600 and its predecessor
    statute had rejected the common law “ ‘rule of reasonableness’ ”
    for a “legislative policy in favor of open competition and
    employee mobility.” (Edwards, at pp. 945, 946.) Stressing the
    statute’s plain meaning, we rejected the argument that section
    16600 only voids restraints that entirely prohibit an employee
    from engaging in a profession and not less restrictive limitations
    that are reasonable. (Edwards, at pp. 946–947.) Similarly, we
    rejected the Ninth Circuit’s “narrow restraint” construction of
    section 16600, which excepted agreements limiting only a
    narrow part of a party’s business, trade, or profession.
    (Edwards, at pp. 948–950.)
    Ixchel argues that Edwards conclusively held that section
    16600 invalidates all restraints on trade for all contracts, no
    matter how reasonable. It relies on our conclusion that
    “[s]ection 16600 is unambiguous, and if the Legislature intended
    the statute to apply only to restraints that were unreasonable
    or overbroad, it could have included language to that effect.”
    
    (Edwards, supra
    , 44 Cal.4th at p. 950.) But Ixchel reads too
    much into Edwards. “It is axiomatic that language in a judicial
    opinion is to be understood in accordance with the facts and
    issues before the court.” (Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Workers’ Comp.
    Appeals Bd. (1999) 
    19 Cal. 4th 1182
    , 1195.) The plaintiff in
    Edwards sought to invalidate a noncompetition clause in his
    employment agreement, and we “limited our review” to whether
    34
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    “Business and Professions Code section 16600 prohibit[s]
    employee noncompetition agreements . . . .” (Edwards, at
    p. 941, fn. omitted.) We held that “section 16600 prohibits
    employee noncompetition agreements unless the agreement
    falls within a statutory exception . . . .” (Id. at p. 942.) The
    question of whether noncompetition agreements outside the
    employment context are per se invalid was not presented in
    Edwards.
    Moreover, the rationale in Edwards focused on policy
    considerations specific to employment mobility and competition:
    “The law protects Californians and ensures ‘that every citizen
    shall retain the right to pursue any lawful employment and
    enterprise of their choice.’ [Citation.] It protects ‘the important
    legal right of persons to engage in businesses and occupations of
    their choosing.’ ” 
    (Edwards, supra
    , 44 Cal.4th at p. 946; see
    ibid. [the statute “evinces
    a settled legislative policy in favor of open
    competition and employee mobility”].) And we cited cases
    exclusively from the employment context in our reasoning. (Id.
    at pp. 945–948, citing Bosley Medical Group v. Abramson (1984)
    
    161 Cal. App. 3d 284
    , D’sa v. Playhut, Inc. (2000) 
    85 Cal. App. 4th 927
    , 
    Muggill, supra
    , 
    62 Cal. 2d 239
    , 
    Chamberlain, supra
    , 
    172 Cal. 285
    , Armendariz v. Foundation Health Psychcare Services,
    Inc. (2000) 
    24 Cal. 4th 83
    , South Bay Radiology Medical
    Associates v. Asher (1990) 
    220 Cal. App. 3d 1074
    , and Vacco
    Industries, Inc. v. Van Den Berg (1992) 
    5 Cal. App. 4th 34
    .)
    Finally, the holding and language in Edwards simply
    confirmed our long line of decisions interpreting section 16600
    strictly in the context of noncompetition agreements following
    the termination of employment or the sale of interest in a
    business. Nothing about Edwards indicates a departure from
    that precedent to also invalidate reasonable contractual
    35
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    limitations on business operations and commercial dealings.
    Nor did Edwards address our substantial body of law permitting
    such reasonable limitations.
    In sum, a survey of our precedent construing section 16600
    and its predecessor statute reveals that we have long applied a
    reasonableness standard to contractual restraints on business
    operations and commercial dealings. We do not disturb the
    holding in Edwards and other decisions strictly interpreting
    section 16600 to invalidate noncompetition agreements
    following the termination of employment or sale of interest in a
    business. But those cases do not call into doubt the applicability
    of a reasonableness standard to contractual restraints on
    business operations and commercial dealings.
    C.
    We also consider section 16600 in its broader statutory
    context and seek to harmonize its language with related
    provisions. 
    (ZB, supra
    , 8 Cal.5th at p. 189.) Section 16600
    appears alongside the Cartwright Act (§ 16700 et seq.), which
    also employs broadly worded language to prohibit agreements
    in restraint of trade. Section 16722 provides: “Any contract or
    agreement in violation of this chapter is absolutely void and is
    not enforceable at law or in equity.” And section 16726 provides:
    “Except as provided in this chapter, every trust is unlawful,
    against public policy and void.” But we have not interpreted
    these provisions in a sweeping fashion. “Though the Cartwright
    Act is written in absolute terms, in practice not every agreement
    within the four corners of its prohibitions has been deemed
    illegal.” 
    (Cipro, supra
    , 61 Cal.4th at p. 136.) The provisions of
    the Cartwright Act “draw upon the common law prohibition
    against restraints of trade.” (Cipro, at p. 136; accord, Speegle,
    36
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, 
    J. supra
    , 29 Cal.2d at p. 44.) Accordingly, this court has taken
    direction from the common law in establishing a reasonableness
    standard for determining whether an agreement violates the
    Cartwright Act. (Cipro, at pp. 137, 146.) That standard asks
    whether an agreement “ ‘promotes or suppresses competition’ ”
    by considering the “ ‘circumstances, details, and logic of a
    restraint.’ ” (Id. at pp. 146, 147.)
    Similarly, Civil Code former section 1673 was enacted
    against the backdrop of a common law standard prohibiting
    unreasonable restraints of trade. Our interpretation of that
    statute and section 16600 did not depart from the common law
    reasonableness standard for contractual restraints on business
    operations and commercial dealings. Section 16600 should
    therefore be read in accordance with the Cartwright Act to
    incorporate the same rule of reason in such cases. Indeed, we
    have occasionally relied on antitrust decisions when
    interpreting Civil Code former section 1673 (see Great Western
    
    Distillery, supra
    , 10 Cal.2d at pp. 448–449, citing United States
    v. American Tobacco Co. (1911) 
    221 U.S. 106
    , 179), and Courts
    of Appeal have evaluated section 16600 and antitrust claims
    together under a reasonableness standard (see Dayton Time
    
    Lock, supra
    , 52 Cal.App.3d at p. 6; Lafortune v. Ebie (1972) 
    26 Cal. App. 3d 72
    , 74–75).
    Amicus curiae Beckman Coulter, Inc. argues that Cianci
    v. Superior Court (1985) 
    40 Cal. 3d 903
    (Cianci) rejected the use
    of the Cartwright Act as an aid to construing section 16600.
    Cianci held that the Cartwright Act applied to the medical
    profession. In doing so, we overturned a previous decision that
    reasoned that because section 16600 includes the word
    “profession” in its scope, the absence of the same word in the
    Cartwright Act implied that it was not intended to apply to
    37
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    professions. (Cianci, at pp. 921–922, citing Willis v. Santa Ana
    etc. Hospital Assn. (1962) 
    58 Cal. 2d 806
    , 809.) We concluded
    that because section 16600 and the Cartwright Act were enacted
    separately and only later consolidated in the Business and
    Professions Code, “ ‘a finding of legislative intent to exclude the
    professions from the Cartwright Act, based upon nothing more
    than language differences between the two code sections,
    exceeds the limits of plausible inference.’ ” (Cianci, at p. 922.)
    But Cianci’s focus on a specific textual difference between the
    two statutes does not cast doubt on the broader point here: The
    similarities between the two statutes stretch beyond their
    language. They share a statutory purpose and doctrinal
    heritage in common law prohibitions on restraints of trade.
    They should therefore be interpreted together.
    D.
    Finally, we are mindful of the consequences of strictly
    interpreting the language of section 16600 to invalidate all
    contracts that limit the freedom to engage in commercial
    dealing. “Every agreement concerning trade . . . restrains.”
    (Chicago Board of Trade v. United States (1918) 
    246 U.S. 231
    ,
    238.) In certain circumstances, contractual limitations on the
    freedom to engage in commercial dealings can promote
    competition. Businesses engaged in commerce routinely employ
    legitimate partnership and exclusive dealing arrangements,
    which limit the parties’ freedom to engage in commerce with
    third parties. Such arrangements can help businesses leverage
    complementary capabilities, ensure stability in supply or
    demand, and protect their research, development, and
    marketing efforts from being exploited by contractual partners.
    38
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    These arrangements can have procompetitive effects since
    they “enable long-term planning on the basis of known costs,”
    “give protection against price fluctuations, and — of particular
    advantage to a newcomer to the field to whom it is important to
    know what capital expenditures are justified — offer the
    possibility of a predictable market.” (Standard Oil Co. of
    California v. United States (1949) 
    337 U.S. 293
    , 306–307; see
    also Sterling Merchandising, Inc. v. Nestle, S.A. (1st Cir. 2011)
    
    656 F.3d 112
    , 123 [“exclusive dealing agreements ‘can achieve
    legitimate economic benefits (reduced cost, stable long-term
    supply, predictable prices)’ ”].) Exclusive dealing arrangements
    also “may provide an incentive for the marketing of new
    products and a guarantee of quality-control distribution.”
    (Dayton Time 
    Lock, supra
    , 52 Cal.App.3d at p. 6; accord,
    Fisherman’s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court of San
    Francisco (2003) 
    114 Cal. App. 4th 309
    , 335.) For example,
    exclusive dealing arrangements are “often a part of a franchise
    agreement or a distributorship contract.” (UAS Management,
    Inc. v. Mater Misericordiae Hospital (2008) 
    169 Cal. App. 4th 357
    ,
    365.) In exchange for the right to sell the franchisor’s products,
    franchisees often agree to purchase from a particular supplier
    or operate in a particular geographic area. (See, e.g., Dayton
    Time Lock, at pp. 4–5 [describing franchise agreement].) We
    decline to construe section 16600 to call such arrangements into
    question simply because they restrain trade in some way.
    Ixchel and amicus curiae Beckman Coulter, Inc. argue
    that these dire consequences are exaggerated because section
    16600 only voids agreements that restrain a party from
    “engaging in a lawful . . . business” and not all contractual
    restraints on business activity do so. (Italics added.) But they
    do not explain where the line is to be drawn. Many forms of
    39
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    exclusive dealing restrain parties from “engaging in a lawful . . .
    business.” (§ 16600.) Franchise agreements often prohibit the
    franchisee from selling a third party’s products; requirements
    and output contracts restrain buyers and sellers respectively
    from doing business with third parties. In Great Western
    Distillery, we upheld a contract in which a business agreed to
    purchase whiskey exclusively from another whiskey distillery in
    exchange for being the sole merchant of that whiskey in
    California. (Great Western 
    Distillery, supra
    , 10 Cal.2d at
    pp. 445–446.)    Under the agreement, the purchaser was
    restrained from engaging in the business of buying whiskey
    from a third party, and the whiskey distiller was restrained
    from doing any business with other potential whiskey buyers.
    Our opinion applied a reasonableness standard in determining
    whether the agreement ran afoul of Civil Code former section
    1673. (Great Western Distillery, at pp. 445–446.) Similarly
    here, the Forward-Biogen Agreement restrained Forward from
    engaging in business with Ixchel or another third party to
    develop drugs containing the active ingredient DMF. Ixchel
    fails to meaningfully differentiate Great Western Distillery from
    this case with respect to the applicability of a reasonableness
    standard.
    CONCLUSION
    We hold that tortious interference with at-will contracts
    requires independent wrongfulness. Because Ixchel alleges that
    Biogen interfered with its at-will contract, it must allege that
    Biogen did so through wrongful means.
    We also hold that a rule of reason applies to determine the
    validity of a contractual provision by which a business is
    restrained from engaging in a lawful trade or business with
    40
    IXCHEL PHARMA, LLC v. BIOGEN, INC.
    Opinion of the Court by Liu, J.
    another business.      Section 2.13 of the Biogen-Forward
    Agreement is such a restraint because it prevents Forward from
    collaborating with Ixchel or any other partner in the
    development of treatments containing the active ingredient
    DMF. Its validity under section 16600 must therefore be
    evaluated based on a rule of reason. We express no view on the
    validity of the agreement at issue.
    LIU, J.
    We Concur:
    CANTIL-SAKAUYE, C. J.
    CHIN, J.
    CORRIGAN, J.
    CUÉLLAR, J.
    KRUGER, J.
    GROBAN, J.
    41
    See next page for addresses and telephone numbers for counsel who argued in Supreme Court.
    Name of Opinion Ixchel Pharma, LLC v. Biogen, Inc.
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Unpublished Opinion
    Original Appeal
    Original Proceeding XXX on request pursuant to rule 8.548, Cal. Rules of Court
    Review Granted
    Rehearing Granted
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Opinion No. S256927
    Date Filed: August 3, 2020
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Court:
    County:
    Judge:
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Counsel:
    Banys, Christopher D. Banys and Richard C. Lin for Plaintiff and Appellant.
    California Appellate Law Group, Anna-Rose Mathieson, Greg Wolff; Behmer & Blackford, Timothy S.
    Blackford; Williams & Connolly, John E. Schmidtlein and Carl R. Metz for Beckman Coulter, Inc., as
    Amicus Curiae on behalf of Plaintiff and Appellant.
    Ropes & Gray, Mark S. Popofsky, Rocky Chiu-Feng Tsai; Greines, Martin, Stein & Richland and Laurie J.
    Hepler for Defendant and Respondent.
    Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher, Thomas G. Hungar, Rachel S. Brass, Caeli A. Higney; LevatoLaw and Ronald
    C. Cohen for California Chamber of Commerce and California Business Roundtable as Amici Curiae on
    behalf of Defendant and Respondent.
    Lowenstein & Weatherwax and Kenneth J. Weatherwax for Amici Scholars as Amici Curiae.
    Horvitz & Levy, Robert H. Wright, Jeremy B. Rosen; Charis Lex and Sean P. Gates for Quidel Corporation
    as Amicus Curiae.
    Counsel who argued in Supreme Court (not intended for publication with opinion):
    Christopher D. Banys
    Banys, P.C.
    567 Marsh Street
    San Luis Obispo, CA 93401
    (650) 308-8505
    Carl R. Metz
    Williams & Connolly LLP
    725 Twelfth Street, N.W.
    Washington, D.C. 20005
    (202) 434-5000
    Laurie J. Hepler
    Greines, Martin, Stein & Richland LLP
    50 California Street, Suite 1500
    San Francisco, CA 94111
    (415) 315-1774