Center for Biological Diversity v. Public Utilities Com. ( 2024 )


Menu:
  • Filed 1/16/24 (unmodified opn. attached; second modification)
    CERTIFIED FOR PUBLICATION
    THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA
    FIRST APPELLATE DISTRICT
    DIVISION THREE
    CENTER FOR BIOLOGICAL
    DIVERSITY, INC. et al.,
    Petitioners,
    v.                                                      A167721
    PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION,
    (Cal.P.U.C. Dec. No. 22-12-056)
    Respondent;
    PACIFIC GAS AND ELECTRIC                            ORDER MODIFYING OPINION
    COMPANY et al.,                                      AND DENYING REHEARING
    Real Parties in Interest.                   [NO CHANGE IN JUDGMENT]
    THE COURT:
    The published opinion, filed on December 20, 2023, and modified
    December 21, 2023, is ordered further modified as follows:
    The first two sentences of the second paragraph on page 18 are deleted
    and replaced with the following sentence:
    1
    Petitioners take issue with the Decision’s discussion of the extent to
    which the adoption of distributed energy shifts utility costs to nonowners.
    This modification effects no change in the judgment.
    The petition for rehearing and request for judicial notice are denied.
    Dated: __1/15/2024_______                  __Tucher, P. J.___________, P. J.
    2
    Shute, Mihaly & Weinberger, Ellison Folk and Aaron M. Stanton for
    Petitioners Protect our Communities Foundation and Environmental
    Working Group.
    Roger Lin, Anchun Jean Su and Howard Crystal for Petitioner Center for
    Biological Diversity, Inc.
    Law Offices of Richard K. Bauman and Richard K. Bauman for Albion Power
    Company, as Amicus Curiae on behalf of Petitioner Protect our Communities
    Foundation.
    Christine Jun Hammond and Edward Moldavsky for Respondent.
    Munger, Tolles & Olson, Henry Weissmann and Andra Lim for Real Parties
    in Interest Pacific Gas and Electric Company, San Diego Gas & Electric
    Company, and Southern California Edison Company.
    Pacific Gas and Electric Company Law Department and Ashley E. Merlo for
    Real Party in Interest Pacific Gas and Electric Company.
    San Diego Gas & Electric Company and E. Gregory Barnes for Real Party in
    Interest San Diego Gas & Electric Company.
    Southern California Edison Company and Rebecca Meiers-De Pastino for
    Real Party in Interest Southern California Edison Company.
    3
    Filed 12/21/23 (unmodified opn. attached)
    CERTIFIED FOR PUBLICATION
    THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA
    FIRST APPELLATE DISTRICT
    DIVISION THREE
    CENTER FOR BIOLOGICAL
    DIVERSITY, INC., et al.,
    Petitioners,
    v.                                             A167721
    PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION,
    (Cal.P.U.C. Dec. No. 22-12-056)
    Respondent;
    PACIFIC GAS AND ELECTRIC
    COMPANY et al.,
    Real Parties in Interest.
    ORDER MODIFYING OPINION
    [NO CHANGE IN JUDGMENT]
    THE COURT:
    The published opinion, filed on December 20, 2023, is ordered modified
    as follows:
    The signature page on page 32 is modified to add Presiding Justice
    Tucher’s signature under the words, “I CONCUR:”.
    This modification effects no change in the judgment.
    Dated: __December 21, 2023_                        ______TUCHER, P.J.__, P. J.
    1
    Shute, Mihaly & Weinberger, Ellison Folk and Aaron M. Stanton for
    Petitioners Protect our Communities Foundation and Environmental
    Working Group.
    Roger Lin, Anchun Jean Su and Howard Crystal for Petitioner Center for
    Biological Diversity, Inc.
    Law Offices of Richard K. Bauman and Richard K. Bauman for Albion Power
    Company, as Amicus Curiae on behalf of Petitioner Protect our Communities
    Foundation.
    Christine Jun Hammond and Edward Moldavsky for Respondent.
    Munger, Tolles & Olson, Henry Weissmann and Andra Lim for Real Parties
    in Interest Pacific Gas and Electric Company, San Diego Gas & Electric
    Company, and Southern California Edison Company.
    Pacific Gas and Electric Company Law Department and Ashley E. Merlo for
    Real Party in Interest Pacific Gas and Electric Company.
    San Diego Gas & Electric Company and E. Gregory Barnes for Real Party in
    Interest San Diego Gas & Electric Company.
    Southern California Edison Company and Rebecca Meiers-De Pastino for
    Real Party in Interest Southern California Edison Company.
    2
    Filed 12/20/23 (unmodified version)
    CERTIFIED FOR PUBLICATION
    IN THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA
    FIRST APPELLATE DISTRICT
    DIVISION THREE
    CENTER FOR BIOLOGICAL
    DIVERSITY, INC., et al.,
    Petitioners,
    v.                                             A167721
    PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION,
    (Cal.P.U.C. Dec. No. 22-12-056)
    Respondent;
    PACIFIC GAS AND ELECTRIC
    COMPANY et al.,
    Real Parties in Interest.
    For nearly 30 years, California has used a net energy metering (NEM)
    tariff to encourage public utility customers to install renewable energy
    systems (renewable systems). In practical effect, the tariff requires utilities
    to purchase excess electricity exported by renewable systems to the electrical
    grid at the price paid by a utility’s customers for electricity. Utilities have
    long been rankled by the tariff, contending it overcompensates owners of
    renewable systems for their exported energy and thereby raises the cost of
    electricity for customers without such systems.
    In 2013, the Legislature responded to these concerns by enacting Public
    Utilities Code section 2827.1 (undesignated statutory references are to this
    code), which requires the Public Utilities Commission (Commission) to adopt
    1
    a successor tariff to govern utility billing of customers with renewable
    systems. Among other objectives, section 2827.1 requires the successor tariff
    to promote the continued sustainable growth of renewable power generation
    while balancing costs and benefits to all customers. (Id., subds. (b)(1), (3),
    (4).) In 2022, the Commission adopted a successor tariff, which significantly
    reduces the price utilities pay for customer-generated power.
    Petitioners Center for Biological Diversity, Inc., Environmental
    Working Group, and The Protect our Communities Foundation (collectively,
    petitioners) filed a petition for writ review of the successor tariff, contending
    it fails to comply with various requirements of section 2827.1. Among other
    claims, petitioners argue it does not take account of the social benefits of
    customer-generated power, improperly favors the interests of utility
    customers who do not own renewable systems, fails to promote sustainable
    growth of renewable energy, and omits alternatives to promote the growth of
    renewable systems among customers in disadvantaged communities.
    In this writ matter, the scope of our review is “limited” (City and
    County of San Francisco v. Public Utilities Com. (1985) 
    39 Cal.3d 523
    , 530),
    and there’s a “strong presumption” in favor of the Commission decision’s
    validity. (Toward Utility Rate Normalization v. Public Utilities Com. (1978)
    
    22 Cal.3d 529
    , 537.) Applying the applicable deferential standard of review,
    we conclude the successor tariff adequately serves the various — albeit
    sometimes inconsistent — objectives of section 2827.1 and thus affirm.
    BACKGROUND
    The supply of power generated by renewable systems is neither
    constant nor consistent. Residential solar power systems, for example,
    generate electricity only when the sun shines, and the amount of power they
    generate depends on the intensity of the sunlight. By contrast, the use of
    2
    electricity by a residence with a solar power system is independent of the
    supply of sunlight. Such systems often produce more electricity than needed
    by the residence during sunny days, and they produce no power after dark —
    notwithstanding the residents’ continuing need for electricity. Utilities
    remedy this imbalance. They supply supplemental electricity to customers
    with renewable systems when the systems do not generate sufficient power to
    meet the customers’ needs, and the power grid accepts and uses the excess
    electricity available when a renewable system produces more power than
    needed by the generating residence.
    The NEM tariff governs the way that owners of renewable systems are
    billed by their utility. The state’s first NEM tariff was created in response to
    the enactment of section 2827 in 1995. (Stats. 1995, ch. 369, § 1.) The
    purpose of the legislation was to clear regulatory hurdles to utilities’
    purchase of excess power generated by residential solar power systems and to
    create a regulatory structure for that purchase. (See Assem. Com. on
    Utilities and Commerce, Analysis of Sen. Bill No. 656 (1995–1996 Reg. Sess.)
    as amended June 7, 1995, at pp. 1–2 (Assem. Analysis).) The purchase of
    excess energy was expected to “encourage private investment in renewable
    energy resources” by helping to defray the then-substantial costs of solar
    power system installation.1 (§ 2827, subd. (a); Assem. Analysis, at pp. 1–2.)
    Under the original NEM tariff (NEM 1.0), residences with solar power
    systems were allowed to install an electricity meter that measured the
    1 Originally, the NEM tariff required by section 2827 applied only to
    solar power systems operated by a utility’s residential customers. (Former
    § 2827, subd. (b).) The tariff now applies to any “renewable electrical
    generation facility” with a total capacity of less than one megawatt operated
    by a utility customer, regardless of the way the power is generated or the
    nature of the customer. (§§ 2827, subd. (b)(4)(A); 2827.1, subd. (a).)
    3
    difference between the quantity of electricity supplied to the residence by the
    utility and the quantity of electricity supplied to the grid by the residence —
    thus the name, “net energy metering.” (Former § 2827, subds. (c), (d).) The
    residence was charged only for this difference, which represented the
    residence’s net use of electricity from the power grid. (Id., subd. (f)(2).) By
    offsetting exported power against imported power, NEM 1.0 functionally
    required utilities to purchase excess power generated by residential solar
    power systems at the price paid by their customers for electricity.
    Even prior to the enactment of section 2827, the proposed NEM tariff
    was criticized as “provid[ing] an electric ratepayer subsidy to purchasers of
    expensive residential photovoltaic systems.” (Assem. Analysis, at p. 3.) As
    characterized in a contemporary bill analysis, the NEM tariff’s opponents
    argued such an approach “assumes that [exported and imported power] have
    the same value, when they [do] not. A kwh [kilowatt-hour of electricity]
    delivered to a customer is a retail commodity while a kwh sold to the utility is
    a wholesale commodity and the prices for the two commodities are different.
    Instead of netting out kilowatt hours sold, opposition believes a more
    accurate system would net out the relative prices of the commodities that
    have been exchanged.” (Ibid.)
    The 2013 enactment of section 2827.1 required the Commission to
    adopt a successor tariff to replace NEM 1.0. (§ 2827.1, subd. (b); Stats. 2013,
    ch. 611, § 11.) The Commission characterized the general purpose of the
    legislation as granting it “the ability to ‘address current electricity rate
    inequities, protect low income energy users and maintain robust incentives
    for renewable energy investments.’ ” A bill analysis prepared by the Senate
    Rules Committee explained a more specific purpose, observing that “[a]s
    transmission and distribution costs are typically one-half to two-thirds of a
    4
    residential customer’s billing, full retail NEM offers a substantial subsidy to
    NEM customers with the costs being shifted to non-NEM customers. . . . The
    Legislature has in the past justified this subsidy as it stimulates the solar
    industry, helps the state reach its renewable energy goals, and provides other
    external benefits.” (Sen. Rules Com., Off. of Sen. Floor Analysis, 3d reading
    analysis of Assem. Bill No. 327 (2013–2014 Reg. Sess.) as amended Sept. 3,
    2013, pp. 6–7.)2 Under section 2827.1, however, “[t]he [Commission] would be
    required to ensure that the [successor tariff] is based on the electrical system
    costs and benefits received by nonparticipating customers and prevents a cost
    shift to non-NEM customers.” (3d reading analysis, at p. 4.)
    As an interim measure, the Commission adopted a revised tariff (NEM
    2.0) in 2016 that sought to address some of the concerns surrounding NEM
    1.0. NEM 2.0 continued to allow customers with renewable systems to offset
    excess electricity generated by their systems against electricity used, but
    these customers were charged a onetime interconnection fee and other
    periodic “non-bypassable” fees. It was anticipated NEM 2.0 would be subject
    2 Petitioners and real parties in interest Pacific Gas and Electric
    Company, San Diego Gas & Electric Company, and Southern California
    Edison Company have collectively filed three requests for judicial notice of
    various Commission decisions, legislative history materials, and other state
    agency documents. Finding such materials to be appropriate objects of
    judicial notice (Evid. Code, § 452, subd. (c)), we grant the requests. We grant
    judicial notice of exhibit 2 to the Commission’s request for judicial notice for
    the same reason.
    Given the extensive record of exhibits lodged by petitioners, we
    declined to require the Commission to file an administrative record but
    permitted the parties to request supplementation. We grant the
    Commission’s request to supplement the administrative record with exhibit 1
    to its request for judicial notice. Although petitioners contend this document
    is not relevant, it appears to be appropriate for inclusion in the record. In
    granting these various requests, we do not mean to suggest a view on the
    relevance for our decision of any of the documents.
    5
    to Commission review in or after 2019, when a more permanent replacement
    for NEM 1.0 would be adopted.
    In 2020, the Commission initiated a proceeding to “revisit” NEM 2.0. It
    ultimately adopted a successor tariff — which it calls a net billing tariff — in
    Decision Revising Net Energy Metering Tariff and Subtariffs (2022) Cal.
    P.U.C. Dec. No. D.22-12-056 (Decision). The “foundation” for the successor
    tariff was the Net-Energy Metering 2.0 Lookback Study, January 21, 2021
    (Lookback Study), an evaluation of NEM 2.0 by outside consultants Verdant
    Associates, LLC, which concluded “NEM 2.0 participants benefit from the
    structure, while ratepayers see increased rates.” (Lookback Study, at p. 1.)
    Drawing on the Lookback Study, the Commission found the NEM tariff
    “negatively impact[s]” utility customers who do not own renewable systems,
    particularly low-income customers, and is not cost-effective for the utilities’
    customers. (Decision at pp. 10, 39, 43, 207.) The Commission reasoned the
    tariff allows owners of renewable systems to avoid paying their proportionate
    share of the “infrastructure and other service costs” associated with electrical
    service because these costs are “embedded in” the rates charged for
    electricity.3 When owners of renewable systems reduce their purchase of
    electricity from the grid, they necessarily reduce their payment of these costs.
    (Id. at p. 208.) A portion of renewable system owners’ share of the utilities’
    fixed costs is thereby shifted to customers without renewable systems. The
    Commission found these shifted costs to be one of three drivers of high
    electricity rates, along with costs of transmission and distribution and
    wildfire mitigation. (Ibid.)
    3 In addition to the costs of servicing customers and maintaining the
    power grid, these costs include funding for various public policy programs,
    such as those subsidizing utility service to low-income customers.
    6
    In addition, the Commission was concerned NEM takes no account of
    the time of day and season when the owner of a solar power system imports
    electricity. Yet the cost of electricity varies significantly with the time of its
    use — peaking in late afternoon and early evening. By overriding these cost
    variations, NEM fails to incentivize more efficient use of power by owners of
    renewable systems. (Decision at pp. 217–218.) Further, the Commission
    concluded, by equating the prices of imported and exported electricity, NEM
    overcompensates owners of renewable systems for the electricity they
    generate, effectively paying such owners at a rate from 3.8 to 5.4 times
    greater than the benefit conferred on the grid by their exported power. (Id.
    at p. 216.)
    Based on these and other findings, the Commission adopted the net
    billing tariff. The most fundamental change from a NEM tariff is that
    charges for electricity under the successor tariff are no longer based on the
    difference between the quantity of electricity imported by a customer and the
    quantity exported. Instead, the meter of a residence owning a renewable
    system will separately measure the power imported from and exported to the
    grid. The value of the exported and imported energy is determined
    independently, and customers are billed for the difference between the value
    of the power imported and exported by the residence, rather than the
    difference in quantity. (Decision at p. 237.) Imported and exported power, in
    other words, are no longer treated as equivalent.
    Under the successor tariff, the price paid for exported power is
    determined by the “Avoided Cost Calculator” (calculator), an algorithm
    developed earlier by the Commission that aims “to determine the primary
    7
    benefits of distributed energy resources [i.e., customer-generated power].”4
    (Decision Adopting Changes to the Avoided Cost Calculator (2022) Cal. P.U.C.
    Dec. No. D.22-05-002, at p. 3; Decision at p. 237.) As explained by the
    Commission, the calculator “ ‘calculates seven types of avoided costs:
    generation capacity, energy, transmission and distribution capacity, ancillary
    services, Renewable Portfolio Standard, greenhouse gas emissions, and high
    global warming potential gases.’ . . . [¶] [These] costs . . . are the utilities’
    marginal costs of providing electric service to customers. Those costs can be
    avoided when the demand for energy decreases because of distributed energy
    resources, and are, thus, the benefits of using distributed energy resources.”
    (Decision at p. 59.) In other words, the calculator estimates the cost to the
    utilities of providing an additional increment of electrical power; this is the
    cost “avoided” when a customer’s renewable system supplies that increment.
    Under the successor tariff, this avoided cost is the price paid by the utilities
    for exported energy.
    The successor tariff determines charges for imported electricity under
    “[h]ighly differentiated time-of-use rates” specified in the Decision. (Decision
    at p. 239.) By imposing time-of-use rates, the successor tariff is intended to
    encourage renewable system owners to purchase batteries that permit excess
    energy generated during times of low power demand to be stored and
    subsequently used by the customer or exported to the grid during times of
    higher demand. The use of renewable system batteries is also incentivized by
    the calculator, which grants a higher price for energy exported during periods
    of peak demand. The successor tariff also includes a so-called “glide path,” a
    4 Customer-generated renewable energy is sometimes referred to as
    “distributed energy resources,” presumably because the generating systems
    are decentralized.
    8
    five-year transition period during which more generous terms are granted to
    the owners of renewable systems. (Id. at p. 237.)
    When fully implemented, these changes will cause a noticeable increase
    in the energy bills of utility customers who own renewable systems. Peak
    period electricity rates can be more than double the price during morning and
    nighttime hours, and the price paid for exported power determined by the
    calculator is typically less than one-third of the retail price. Despite these
    changes, the Commission concluded the purchaser of a residential solar
    power system will still see energy bill savings of $100 a month, which will
    repay the cost of system installation within nine years.
    Petitioners sought leave to challenge the Decision by filing a petition
    for a writ of review in this court. (§ 1756, subd. (a).) We granted the petition.
    Answers in support of the successor tariff were filed by the Commission and
    real parties in interest.
    DISCUSSION
    “[T]he PUC is not an ordinary administrative agency, but a
    constitutional body with broad legislative and judicial powers.” (Wise v.
    Pacific Gas & Electric Co. (1999) 
    77 Cal.App.4th 287
    , 300.) The scope of our
    review of its decision is “limited.” (City and County of San Francisco v.
    Public Utilities Com., supra, 39 Cal.3d at p. 530.) “There is a strong
    presumption favoring the validity of a Commission decision.” (Toward Utility
    Rate Normalization v. Public Utilities Com., supra, 22 Cal.3d at p. 537.)
    Under section 1757, judicial review of a Commission decision “shall
    not extend further than to determine, on the basis of the entire
    record . . . whether” the Commission “acted without, or in excess of, its
    powers or jurisdiction”; failed to proceed “in the manner required by law”;
    rendered a decision unsupported by the findings; made findings unsupported
    9
    by substantial evidence; rendered a decision that “was procured by fraud or
    was an abuse of discretion”; or issued an order or decision that violates the
    petitioner’s state or federal constitutional rights. (Id., subds. (a)(1)–(6).) “We
    do not conduct a trial de novo, nor weigh nor exercise independent judgment
    on the evidence. [Citations.] The Commission’s findings of fact ‘ “are not
    open to attack for insufficiency if they are supported by any reasonable
    construction of the evidence.” ’ ” (Southern California Gas Co. v. Public
    Utilities Com. (2023) 
    87 Cal.App.5th 324
    , 339 (SoCalGas).)
    When, as here, the Commission is charged with interpreting a
    provision of the Public Utilities Code, “[w]e give great weight to the
    Commission’s interpretation.” (SoCalGas, supra, 87 Cal.App.5th at p. 339.)
    We will disturb the Commission’s interpretation only if “ ‘it fails to bear a
    reasonable relation to statutory purposes and language.’ ” (Southern
    California Edison Co. v. Peevey (2003) 
    31 Cal.4th 781
    , 796.) “This judicial
    deference acknowledges a role for the Commission’s administrative expertise:
    ‘[W]e give presumptive value to a public agency’s interpretation of a statute
    within its administrative jurisdiction because the agency may have “special
    familiarity with satellite legal and regulatory issues,” leading to expertise
    expressed in its interpretation of the statute.’ ” (Pacific Gas & Electric Co. v.
    Public Utilities Com. (2015) 
    237 Cal.App.4th 812
    , 839.)
    Section 2827.1, the statute at issue here, requires the Commission to
    “develop a standard contract or tariff, which may include net energy
    metering,” for utility customers owning noncommercial renewable systems.
    (§§ 2827.1, subds. (a), (b); 2827, subd. (b)(4)(A).) The statute sets out seven
    requirements for the tariff. (§ 2827.1, subds. (b)(1)–(7).) As relevant here,
    the successor tariff “shall do all of the following” (id., subd. (b)): (1) ensure
    renewable system installation “continues to grow sustainably” (id.,
    10
    subd. (b)(1)); (2) include “specific alternatives designed for growth among
    residential customers in disadvantaged communities” (ibid); (3) be based on
    “the costs and benefits of the renewable electrical generation facility” (id.,
    subd. (b)(3)); and (4) equalize the “total benefits” and “total costs” of the tariff
    “to all customers and the electrical system” (id., subd. (b)(4)).
    I.
    Petitioners first contend the successor tariff fails to satisfy the
    requirement of section 2827.1 that it balance various costs and benefits
    because the calculator fails to take account of all the benefits of renewable
    energy, particularly those conferred on society generally. In particular,
    petitioners contend the calculator fails to take account of (1) the value of
    resiliency, (2) avoided out-of-state methane leakage, (3) avoided land use
    impacts, and (4) certain avoided transmission costs. In addition, petitioners
    contend the Commission “improperly dismisse[d]” an alternative test for
    determining the benefits of distributed power, the “Societal Cost Test.”
    Section 2827.1, subdivision (b), contains several requirements. Two
    subdivisions, (b)(3) and (4), respectively require the Commission to consider
    “the costs and benefits of the renewable electrical generation facility” and to
    ensure “the total benefits of the [successor tariff] to all customers and the
    electrical system are approximately equal to the total costs.” (Ibid.)
    Petitioners argue the use of the definite article “the” in the phrase “the costs
    and benefits” in subdivision (b)(3) “means that the clause refers to all costs
    and benefits. . . . [¶] The failure to properly account for the costs and
    benefits of distributed generation . . . constitutes legal error requiring that
    the Decision be set aside.”
    Although petitioners characterize their argument as challenging the
    omission of various purported benefits of renewable energy, it is more
    11
    generally an attack on the Commission’s approach to valuing exported energy
    from renewable systems by means of the calculator. As previously explained,
    the Commission chose — through the calculator — to value exported energy
    by the marginal cost to utilities of providing power. This marginal cost, in
    turn, is measured by the various costs the utilities need not incur because of
    their use of exported energy. (Decision at p. 59.) Petitioners effectively argue
    section 2827.1 requires the Commission to take all of the benefits of
    renewable energy generation into account when valuing exported energy,
    rather than merely the economic costs avoided by the use of customer-
    generated power.
    We must give “great weight” to the Commission’s interpretation of
    provisions of the Public Utilities Code. (SoCalGas, supra, 87 Cal.App.5th
    at p. 339.) In light of the Commission’s expertise in energy regulation, we are
    permitted to overturn its interpretation of a statutory mandate only if the
    interpretation “ ‘fails to bear a reasonable relation to statutory purposes and
    language.’ ” (Southern California Edison Co. v. Peevey, 
    supra,
     31 Cal.4th
    at p. 796.) Further, “[t]here is a strong presumption favoring the validity of
    a Commission decision.” (Toward Utility Rate Normalization v. Public
    Utilities Com., supra, 22 Cal.3d at p. 537.) This uniquely deferential
    standard of review is accorded the Commission because of its status as “a
    constitutional body with broad legislative and judicial powers.” (Kerman
    Telephone Co. v. Public Utilities Com. (2023) 
    94 Cal.App.5th 920
    , 931.)
    We conclude the successor tariff adopted by the Commission bears a
    reasonable relation to the statutory purposes and language. Petitioners
    argue the statute requires the Commission to “properly account for the costs
    and benefits of distributed generation” in formulating the successor tariff.
    Notably, neither section 2827.1, subdivision (b)(3) nor subdivision (b)(4)
    12
    refers to the costs and benefits of “distributed generation.” Subdivision (b)(3)
    requires the Commission to base the successor tariff on “the costs and
    benefits of the renewable electrical generation facility.” The meaning of this
    subdivision is not wholly clear; its reference to the costs and benefits of
    “the . . . facility” appears to require the tariff to be based on the costs and
    benefits of renewable systems. In any event, the language certainly does not
    compel the Commission to consider the costs and benefits of renewable
    energy generally.
    Similarly, section 2827.1, subdivision (b)(4) requires the Commission to
    ensure “the total benefits of the standard contract or tariff to all customers
    and the electrical system are approximately equal to the total costs.” Again,
    there is no reference to the costs and benefits of distributed generation.
    Instead, the statute speaks of the costs and benefits of the “standard contract
    or tariff” — that is, the successor tariff — to “all customers.” In accord, the
    Commission strove to ensure the successor tariff is fair to both owners and
    nonowners of renewable systems. Although some of the benefits of renewable
    energy presumably factor into that calculus — and certainly did factor into
    the Commission’s formulation of the calculator — we find nothing in the
    statutory text that indisputably requires the Commission to take account of
    “all costs and benefits” of “distributed renewable generation.”
    The Commission’s decision to base the price of exported energy on the
    marginal cost of energy to the utilities serves this goal of equity between
    generating and nongenerating customers. Generating customers are
    compensated for the economic benefit they confer on the grid — and thereby
    on their fellow utility customers — by supplying excess energy. On the other
    side of the ledger, nongenerating utility customers are no longer required to
    subsidize generating customers by purchasing excess energy at a premium
    13
    above its economic value. As directed by the Legislature, the calculator
    compensates generators for the benefits they confer on “all customers and the
    electrical system” (§ 2827.1, subd. (b)) by supplying excess energy without
    burdening ratepayers with additional costs — such as compensating system
    owners for the purported benefits conferred on society at large, as advocated
    by petitioners.5
    The Commission presumably could have elected to adopt some version
    of petitioners’ approach by compensating customers who export energy to the
    grid for the social, as well as economic, benefits conferred by the distributed
    generation of power. Indeed, the Commission’s counsel conceded as much at
    oral argument. But of course, it’s a zero-sum game; such an approach
    necessarily would have lessened the extent to which the successor tariff
    reduced the cost shift targeted by section 2827.1. By requiring utilities to
    factor social benefits into the price paid for exported power, petitioners’
    approach would effectively require customers who do not own renewable
    systems to compensate owners of the systems for the value of these social
    benefits, as well as for the economic benefits conferred on the grid. It can be
    debated whether this approach would better satisfy the Legislature’s
    command to balance the equities among all customers, but we needn’t choose
    5 Petitioners rely primarily on Ctr. for Biological Diversity v. Nat’l
    Highway Traffic Safety Admin. (9th Cir. 2008) 
    538 F.3d 1172
    , which holds
    that, when an administrative agency is directed to evaluate the costs and
    benefits of a regulatory action, “it cannot put a thumb on the scale by
    undervaluing the benefits and overvaluing the costs” of the action. (Id. at
    p. 1198.) In that case, the administrative agency was found to have “assigned
    no value to the most significant benefit” of the regulatory action when
    making its cost-benefit analysis. (Id. at p. 1199.) As the statute did not
    compel the Commission to consider societal costs and benefits, we find this
    case inapposite.
    14
    a side. Plainly, the successor tariff adopted by the Commission bears a
    reasonable relation to statutory purposes and language.
    Accordingly, we find no error in the Commission’s decision to restrict
    the calculator to economic benefits conferred on the grid by exported power.
    Because two of the specific benefits cited by petitioners are manifestly
    social — the avoidance of methane leakage in other states that occurs when
    the utilities’ need for out-of-state natural gas is reduced by the export of
    excess power and the reduced use of land for utility infrastructure made
    possible by distributed generation — they need not be discussed further. Nor
    did the Commission err by selecting an approach that excluded the two other
    benefits cited by petitioners, nor by deciding not to use the Societal Cost Test.
    Petitioners first contend the Commission erred in failing to give
    renewable system owners credit for the “benefits of increased resiliency—that
    is, the ability to maintain power during a blackout or other grid disruption—
    and reliability conferred by distributed renewable generation.” The
    Commission considered and rejected the suggestion that the calculator, in
    valuing excess power, should take account of the purported increased
    resilience of the energy grid afforded by renewable energy. The Commission
    explained proponents had not provided “convincing evidence” the benefits
    of resiliency accrued to the grid, rather than to the owners of renewable
    systems. This is a finding of fact we must accept if supported “ ‘ “by
    any reasonable construction of the evidence.” ’ ” (SoCalGas, supra,
    87 Cal.App.5th at p. 339.) We find no reason to question the Commission’s
    conclusion. Although petitioners claim the benefits of resiliency accrue “not
    just to individual participants,” the only examples they cite are the type of
    owner benefits to which the Commission referred: the ability of a renewable
    system owner to generate power during a heat wave, system owners’
    15
    avoidance of food spoilage due to loss of refrigeration, and the ability of
    households with a renewable system to participate in educational activities
    during a power outage. Because these benefits are not conferred on utilities
    or the electrical system from the export of excess energy, but instead are
    benefits realized by generating customers from their installation of a
    renewable system, there was no statutory basis compelling their
    incorporation into the calculator.
    Petitioners also contend the calculator fails to take full account of the
    transmission costs avoided because of exported energy. For the three major
    public utilities, the calculator projects a total expenditure of over $481
    million for transmission costs during the period 2021–2025. A Commission
    report in the record, however, states that a regulatory category called
    “transmission revenue requirements” for the three utilities exceeded $4
    billion in 2021. Characterizing the latter figure as “actual transmission
    spending,” petitioners argue the real avoided transmission costs must be
    much greater than accounted for in the calculator. The calculator does not,
    however, include all “actual transmission spending.” Rather, it includes only
    transmission spending that is avoided — that is, rendered unnecessary — by
    the export of electricity by owners of renewable systems. Petitioners make no
    attempt to demonstrate that the transmission revenue requirements listed in
    the report represent avoided costs. Moreover, an examination of the
    Commission report makes clear that the category sweeps much broader than
    avoided transmission costs, including, for example, “wildfire mitigation work,
    including enhanced inspections and vegetation management efforts.” These
    are the type of ordinary overhead costs that are unaffected by the export of
    energy from renewable systems. Given the uncertain relationship between
    transmission revenue requirements and avoided transmission costs,
    16
    petitioners’ argument fails to convince that the calculator’s estimate of
    avoided transmission costs is not supported by substantial evidence.
    Petitioners also quibble with the Commission’s accounting for avoided
    transmission costs in the calculator, citing various items of evidence in the
    record to argue transmission costs avoided by use of exported energy are
    greater than the value assigned in the calculator. Having reviewed the
    arguments, we are not persuaded the Commission’s chosen value is not
    supported by substantial evidence.
    Finally, petitioners contend the Commission erred in failing to adopt
    the Societal Cost Test — an evaluative tool under development by
    Commission — as a measure of the benefits of renewable energy use. The
    Commission rejected a request to use the test in connection with the
    successor tariff as “premature because the evaluation to determine the final
    details of the test has not been completed.” (Decision at p. 66.) Contrary to
    petitioners’ claim, there was nothing “improper[]” in the Commission’s refusal
    to use a test that was not fully developed. (Of course, the Commission might
    revisit the issue if and when it deems the Societal Cost Test fully developed.)
    To the extent petitioners are arguing more generally that the Commission
    erred in basing the successor tariff on the costs and benefits of renewable
    power to generators and ratepayers, rather than the costs and benefits to
    society at large, we find the Commission’s approach to bear a reasonable
    relation to its statutory mandate. Our standard of review allows for no
    further inquiry.6
    6 This argument is followed in petitioners’ brief by an extended
    criticism of the Commission’s use of the calculator in this context. The
    discussion, which mentions neither our standard of review nor the statutory
    language, appears to be premised on the assumption that we can reverse or
    17
    II.
    Petitioners next contend the Decision fails to properly account for the
    costs of renewable energy because it treats reduced energy usage by owners
    of renewable systems as a cost rather than a benefit. The argument arises in
    the context of the successor tariff’s attempt to address the long-standing
    criticism that the NEM tariff permits owners of renewable systems to shift a
    disproportionate share of the fixed costs of energy supply to customers who
    lack such systems. The shift occurs because the utilities’ fixed costs are
    recovered through the rates charged for energy use. Every utility customer
    pays a portion of the fixed costs through their monthly bill, with the amount
    of the payment proportional to the amount of energy the customer uses. To
    the extent self-generated power reduces owners’ use of energy from the grid,
    these customers necessarily reduce their payment of the utilities’ fixed costs;
    the utilities’ remaining customers must collectively pay the portion avoided
    by renewable system owners. The NEM tariff magnifies this effect by
    permitting renewable system owners to offset their exported energy against
    imported energy, thereby further reducing their purchase of energy. As
    noted, the Legislature anticipated in enacting section 2827.1 that the
    successor tariff would mitigate this shift, and the statute’s instruction in
    subdivision (b)(4) to equalize costs and benefits of the successor tariff to all
    customers effectuates that intent.
    Petitioners do not dispute this cost-shifting effect of a NEM tariff.
    Rather, they take issue with a more general discussion in the Decision of the
    extent to which the adoption of distributed energy shifts utility costs to
    nonowners. Petitioners contend the Commission should have treated the
    modify the Decision merely because we find another approach to be
    preferable. We cannot.
    18
    reduction in energy purchases as a benefit of renewable energy — rather
    than a cost — because reduced demand for utility-generated energy
    represents a social good. They point out that customers’ efforts to reduce
    energy consumption through conservation are not treated as a cost, even
    though these reductions similarly result in reduced purchases of energy from
    the grid, thereby shifting costs to those who do not conserve.
    Petitioners’ arguments about the proper treatment of reduced energy
    use are legally immaterial because they are not pertinent to the successor
    tariff. Contrary to petitioners’ claim, the successor tariff does not charge, or
    otherwise penalize, renewable system owners when they reduce their use of
    imported electricity by substituting self-generated power. Owners are billed
    only for the energy they actually import, regardless of the degree to which
    they reduce their use of imported energy by generating power. In this way,
    the successor tariff makes no attempt to address any shift of costs that
    results solely from the reduction in renewable system owners’ use of imported
    energy. Rather, it remedies only the cost shift that occurs when the NEM
    tariff permits renewable system owners to avoid paying for imported energy
    by offsetting exported energy against it. Because this approach is consistent
    with the statutory language and clearly serves the statutory purpose of
    equalizing the successor tariff’s costs and benefits to all customers, it
    provides no basis for challenging the Decision.
    With this understanding of the role of cost shift in the successor tariff,
    it is clear petitioners’ argument regarding energy conservation misses the
    point. It is true, as petitioners contend, that customers who do not own
    renewable systems are not penalized when they reduce their purchases of
    energy through conservation. But owners of renewable systems are not
    penalized when they reduce their purchases of energy either — whether
    19
    those reductions result from conservation or energy generation. There is no
    inconsistency in the tariff’s treatment of reduced energy consumption by
    owners and nonowners.
    Petitioners also argue the utilities’ charges for electricity imported by
    owners of renewable systems should be based on the actual cost of serving
    such customers, rather than on ordinary service rates. Although this was
    presumably a viable option for the Commission to consider, it was by no
    means required by the statutory language. The Commission rejected the
    suggestion as inconsistent with prior precedent. Because the Commission’s
    chosen approach represents a proper application of the statutory language,
    our standard of review does not permit the type of regulatory second-guessing
    petitioners advocate.
    III.
    Petitioners contend the Decision’s “focus on addressing the purported
    cost shift” improperly placed the interests of customers who do not own
    renewable systems over “cost-effectiveness to the electrical system as a
    whole.” According to petitioners, section 2827.1, subdivision (b)(4), which
    requires the Commission to “[e]nsure that the total benefits of the [successor
    tariff] to all customers and the electrical system are approximately equal to
    the total costs,” requires the successor tariff to be premised on “cost-
    effectiveness for the system as a whole, not effects on one ratepayer group.”
    We find no error in the Commission’s interpretation of its statutory
    mandate. Contrary to petitioners’ characterization, the Commission’s
    decision to reduce the subsidy provided to renewable system owners did not
    constitute an improper focus on one ratepayer group. The statute directs the
    Commission to ensure the costs and benefits of the successor tariff to all
    customers and the electrical system are approximately equal. The
    20
    implication of that language, honored by the Commission in formulating the
    successor tariff, is to ensure the successor tariff does not grant unwarranted
    benefits or impose unwarranted costs on any particular group of ratepayers.
    In evaluating the successor tariff’s satisfaction of that requirement, it is
    important to remember the successor tariff was formulated in the shadow of
    the NEM tariff, which is generally recognized as granting an economically
    unwarranted subsidy to owners of renewable systems by shifting a
    disproportionate share of the utilities’ fixed costs to nonowners. The
    successor tariff’s reduction of the benefits to system owners — decried by
    petitioners as a focus on the interests of nonowners — was inevitable because
    the statutory command to equalize the costs and benefits of the successor
    tariff required reducing the subsidy granted to renewable system owners by
    NEM 1.0 and NEM 2.0. Even if this is characterized as a “focus” on the
    interests of nonowners, it was not improper. It occurred only because the
    NEM tariffs favored renewable system owners.
    In short, although one of the primary differences between NEM 2.0 and
    the successor tariff was a mitigation of the cost shift imposed by a NEM
    tariff, that does not mean the Commission placed the interests of nonowners
    over those of system owners or the entire electrical system. On the contrary,
    the “primary test” (Decision at p. 65) used by the Commission to evaluate the
    cost-effectiveness of existing and proposed tariffs, the “Total Resource Cost”
    (TRC) test, considered the costs to the system as a whole. (Decision at
    pp. 62–63 [“the TRC test has the ability to indicate whether a demand side
    program is cost-effective to the grid relative to other resource options”].) The
    Commission simply concluded accomplishing the directive of section 2827.1,
    subdivision (b)(4) to equalize costs and benefits both to all customers and to
    the electrical system required reducing the costs disproportionately shifted to
    21
    nonowners by the NEM tariff. This was a reasonable and proper
    interpretation of the statute.
    IV.
    Petitioners argue the Decision fails to satisfy the directive of section
    2827.1, subdivision (b)(1), that the successor tariff “ensure[] that customer-
    sited renewable distributed generation continues to grow sustainably.”
    Petitioners point out the successor tariff “is specifically designed to decrease
    bill savings and increase payback periods” for renewable systems, thereby
    making the systems less financially attractive. Petitioners also note similar
    efforts to reduce the financial advantages of renewable systems in other
    states have led to a substantial decline in the rate of installation of renewable
    systems.
    There are two answers to petitioners’ contention. First, the directive of
    subdivision (b)(1) is one of several requirements imposed on the successor
    tariff by section 2827.1. The Commission is directed by the statute to “do all
    of the following” (§ 2827.1, subd. (b)), leaving the Commission to decide how
    best to accomplish the seven aims articulated by the Legislature. To the
    extent those objectives are in tension, it was left to the Commission to decide
    how to satisfy the conflicting demands. As the Commission observed, “[i]t is
    the Commission’s responsibility to balance the multiple and, sometimes,
    conflicting requirements of the statute.” (Decision at p. 108.) In adopting the
    successor tariff, the Commission affirmed it intended to “balance the multiple
    requirements of the Public Utilities Code and the needs of the electric grid,
    the environment, participating ratepayers, as well as all other ratepayers.”
    (Id. at p. 2.)
    At the time section 2827.1 was enacted, the NEM tariff had long been
    recognized to confer a financial benefit on owners of renewable systems and
    22
    impose a disproportionate burden on nonowners. Remedying this inequity
    necessarily required the Commission to adopt a successor tariff making the
    installation of renewable systems less financially attractive to utility
    customers.7 Subdivision (b)(1) cannot be interpreted, as petitioners insist, to
    require the successor tariff to preserve the financial benefit conferred on
    system owners by a NEM tariff. When it directed the Commission to devise a
    successor tariff equalizing the treatment of owners and nonowners, the
    Legislature was aware the successor tariff would make renewable systems
    less remunerative. Necessarily, the Commission’s task was not to preserve
    existing advantages for owners of the NEM tariff, but to reduce those
    advantages without halting the adoption of renewable systems. The mere
    fact that the successor tariff reduces the financial advantages of renewable
    system installation does not alone place it in violation of section 2827.1.
    Petitioners argue the Commission was not empowered to balance the
    demands of the statute’s potentially conflicting requirements because the
    Legislature directed the Commission to “do all of the following.” (§ 2827.1,
    subd. (b).) The Legislature, of course, could direct the Commission to have its
    cake and eat it too; regrettably, the Commission has no such power. The
    statute’s instruction to do all of the following must be understood as
    requiring the Commission to take into consideration all of the listed
    objectives in formulating the successor tariff. To the extent those objectives
    are in tension, it was for the Commission to decide how best to balance the
    7 Petitioners argue it was not necessary for the Commission to remedy
    the inequities inherent in a NEM tariff to equalize the costs and benefits
    because the Commission could have considered the “full” — i.e., social —
    benefits of renewable systems. Whatever the merits of this argument, the
    Commission was not obligated to adopt this approach.
    23
    demands. We are not persuaded the Commission’s decision in this respect
    constituted an abuse of its discretion.
    Second, petitioners’ argument is based on a misreading of the language
    of section 2827.1, subdivision (b)(1). Petitioners assert “continue” means “ ‘to
    maintain without interruption a condition, course, or action’ ” and argue,
    based on this definition, “the Legislature directed that any successor tariff
    may not materially reduce the continued uptake of” renewable systems.
    Subdivision (b)(1), however, requires continued “growth” of renewable
    energy — that is, continued installation of new renewable systems. It does
    not require continued growth at the same pace. That the rate of adoption of
    renewable systems will slow under the successor tariff does not mean
    adoption will cease. Rather, it will simply grow more slowly than it would
    have under a NEM tariff.
    As noted, we assume the Legislature understood its instruction to
    reduce the inequity of the NEM tariff would result in a successor tariff less
    advantageous to renewable system owners. Thus, section 2827.1, subdivision
    (b)(1) was presumably intended to ensure the successor tariff is not so
    financially disadvantageous as to make installation of such systems
    uneconomic. The successor tariff satisfies that requirement. After its
    implementation, customers who install a renewable system will recover their
    investment within nine years; after that time, owners will see an energy cost
    savings for the remaining life of the system. That financial incentive,
    combined with the environmental benefits of renewable energy, presumably
    will ensure the continued growth of renewable energy, as required by
    subdivision (b)(1).
    24
    V.
    Petitioners next contend the successor tariff fails to “include specific
    alternatives designed for growth among residential customers in
    disadvantaged communities,” as required by section 2827.1, subdivision
    (b)(1). Not so.
    The Commission designed the successor tariff to satisfy this
    requirement in two ways. First, the Lookback Study concluded low-income
    customers were less likely to install renewable systems not only because of
    the upfront cost of such systems, but also because such customers also
    received lower bill savings, contributing to a longer payback period. To
    mitigate this disincentive, low-income and other disadvantaged customers
    are eligible under the successor tariff to receive a higher rate of compensation
    for energy exported to the grid, a benefit designed to ensure they can pay
    back the upfront costs of a system within nine years. (Decision at pp. 175–
    176, 238.) Second, the successor tariff eliminates a discount applied by NEM
    2.0 to the compensation paid for exported energy to customers participating
    in two programs — California Alternate Rates for Energy and Family
    Electric Rate Assistance — providing discounted energy rates to low-income
    customers. (Id. at p. 176.)
    In addition to these provisions of the successor tariff, the Commission
    had earlier adopted a series of three programs to make renewable systems
    more accessible to low-income customers. (See Alternate Decision Adopting
    Alternatives to Promote Solar Distributed Generation in Disadvantaged
    Communities (2018) Cal. P.U.C. Dec. No. D.18-06-027, at pp. 2–4.) The
    Disadvantaged Communities–Single-family Solar Homes program, for
    example, subsidizes the purchase of renewable systems by low-income
    homeowners. (Id. at pp. 2–3, 27–30.) The other two programs provide low-
    25
    income customers with access to renewable energy and bill discounts.
    (Id. at pp. 3–4.) The Commission expressly adopted these programs, which
    will be funded through utility revenues, to satisfy the statutory requirement.
    (Id. at pp. 6, 30–31, A-1.)
    Petitioners fault the Commission’s efforts to stimulate adoption of
    renewable systems in disadvantaged communities because (1) the
    Commission failed to adopt a proposed “Equity Fund,” (2) the Commission’s
    calculation of the higher rate for exported energy was based on an
    underestimate of the cost of solar installation for low-income households, and
    (3) the Commission improperly deferred consideration of the benefits of
    renewable systems that particularly accrue to low-income customers. Before
    addressing these arguments, we note the Commission’s compliance with
    section 2827.1, subdivision (b)(1) must be measured by what it did rather
    than by what it chose not to do. The fact that, as petitioners argue, these
    efforts might be imperfect does not demonstrate the Commission failed to
    comply with the Legislature’s direction. As noted, the Commission modified
    the tariff applicable to low-income customers to increase the compensation for
    exported energy, thereby making renewable systems more financially
    attractive. Further, it adopted three programs that directly subsidize the
    cost of solar installation or provide access to renewable energy for such
    customers. All of these constitute “specific alternatives designed for growth
    among residential customers in disadvantaged communities.” Petitioners fail
    to demonstrate (or even try to demonstrate) the benefits provided by these
    efforts are illusory or so inadequate as to disqualify their consideration. On
    the contrary, we conclude these efforts bear a reasonable relation to statutory
    purposes and language and satisfy the requirements of section 2827.1,
    subdivision (b)(1).
    26
    Petitioners contend these earlier-adopted programs cannot be
    considered because the requirements of section 2827.1 apply only to the
    successor tariff. Necessarily, however, the successor tariff itself can be of
    limited use in meeting the goal of subdivision (b)(1) to stimulate “growth [of
    renewable energy adoption] among residential customers in disadvantaged
    communities.” Any benefits of the successor tariff accrue only after a system
    is installed; the tariff cannot directly overcome the primary barrier to the
    growth sought by the statute — the initial cost of solar system installation.
    Given this limitation, we find the Commission’s conclusion that subdivision
    (b)(1) can be satisfied in part by programs subsidizing system installation
    and promoting renewable energy use among low-income customers to bear a
    reasonable relation to the statutory purposes and language because these
    programs provide access to the successor tariff for low-income customers.
    Again, we find petitioners’ arguments about the inadequacy of the
    Commission’s efforts to make renewable system adoption more affordable to
    be largely beside the point. Petitioners first argue the Commission should
    have created an “Equity Fund,” which would use a billing surcharge imposed
    through the successor tariff to assist low-income customers in acquiring
    renewable systems. The Commission decided against such a fund because
    the Legislature enacted, shortly before issuance of the Decision, Assembly
    Bill No. 209, which created a state program to provide incentives for the
    installation of solar generation and storage systems. (§ 379.10, subds. (a), (b);
    Decision at pp. 178–179.) At the time, 70 percent of the funds appropriated
    for this program were earmarked for low-income residents; an amendment of
    section 379.10 enacted after issuance of the Decision now appears to require
    all of the funds in the new program to be so allocated. (Former § 379.10,
    subd. (a); Stats. 2023, ch. 52, § 6.) Although petitioners fault the
    27
    Commission’s rationale in deciding against the equity fund, they cite no
    statutory authority requiring its adoption. Further, of course, the programs
    adopted separately by the Commission serve the same purpose as the
    suggested equity fund. Because, as noted, the Commission’s efforts to satisfy
    section 2827.1, subdivision (b)(1) are sufficient, it did not err in electing not to
    implement an equity fund.
    Second, petitioners contend the augmented rate for exported energy
    applicable to disadvantaged customers will not promote their adoption of
    renewable systems because the Commission did not accurately estimate the
    cost of solar installation. As a result, they argue, the additional payments
    will not pay back the cost of installation within the intended nine years.
    Even if this criticism was well founded, the augmented rate was only one of
    the methods by which the Commission sought to satisfy section 2827.1,
    subdivision (b)(1). Its incentives for solar growth must be considered together
    with those other methods. Further, the augmented rate, even if insufficient
    to recoup installation costs within nine years, will still provide an incentive
    for system installation. Finally, the Commission expressly considered
    petitioners’ argument and rejected it, concluding the higher cost figure was
    derived from a materially different program. (Decision at pp. 83–84.) This
    factual finding is supported by substantial evidence.
    Third, petitioners contend the Commission improperly deferred
    consideration of promoting the installation of solar systems serving entire
    communities. Assuming, as petitioners argue, that “[w]ell-designed
    community solar and storage programs could realize considerable grid and
    ratepayer benefits,” that alone did not mandate their adoption. Section
    2827.1, subdivision (b)(1) does not require the Commission to adopt any
    particular “specific alternatives” to ensure growth of renewable energy in
    28
    disadvantaged communities, and the steps it has taken are adequate to meet
    its statutory obligation. The Commission’s explanation that consideration of
    community solar is “premature” because such programs are the subject of
    other ongoing Commission proceedings fully justifies their omission.
    (Decision at p. 188.)
    VI.
    Petitioners finally argue the modifications of the NEM tariff for
    nonresidential customers effected in the successor tariff are “based on
    erroneous and unsupported findings.” We disagree.
    The Lookback Study found, based on the TRC test, that the NEM 2.0
    tariff was cost-effective for nonresidential customers.8 The tariff’s average
    TRC score was 1.25, where a score of 1.00 represents no net cost or benefit.
    Yet the Commission declined to adopt this conclusion because the NEM tariff
    for nonresidential customers performed poorly on the “Ratepayer Impact
    Measure” (RIM) test, earning an average score of .57, suggesting costs
    predominated over benefits. That test “is useful for examining whether
    disproportionate impacts occur on non-participants” (Decision at p. 50), a
    measure of cost-effectiveness particularly pertinent to the requirement of
    section 2827.1, subdivision (b)(4) that the successor tariff should balance
    costs and benefits for all customers. Citing its conclusion that “the use of
    retail rates as a foundation for compensating customers for exporting
    electricity to the grid [has] no connection to the actual costs of the exports or
    the benefits the exported electricity provide to customers and the grid,” the
    Commission elected to use the calculator to determine the price paid to
    nonresidential customers for exported energy, just as it did for residential
    8 The TRC test measures cost-effectiveness of a program for the entire
    electrical grid. (Decision at p. 62.)
    29
    customers. (Decision at pp. 107–108.) In effect, the Commission applied the
    successor tariff to both residential and nonresidential customers, although
    nonresidential customers were not afforded the benefit of the phase-in
    granted to residential customers. (Id. at p. 238.)
    Petitioners fault the Commission’s conclusion that NEM 2.0 is not cost-
    effective for nonresidential customers. Petitioners note the Commission
    designated the TRC test as the primary test to determine the cost-
    effectiveness of the successor tariff for the electrical system. Accordingly,
    they argue, the Commission committed “legal error” when it “determined the
    NEM tariff for [nonresidential] sectors is not cost-effective based on its RIM
    test scores alone.”
    By treating cost-effectiveness as a single concept, petitioners distort the
    nature of the Decision. As petitioners argue, the TRC test is a measure of the
    cost-effectiveness of the tariff for the electrical system. Section 2827.1,
    subdivision (b)(4), however, does not require the successor tariff to be cost-
    effective only for the electrical system. Instead, it requires the Commission
    to ensure the costs and benefits of the successor tariff “to all customers and
    the electrical system” are approximately equal. As the Commission found,
    the RIM test is a better measure of cost-effectiveness for all customers
    because it measures the impact of a policy on nonparticipants. The
    Commission was therefore faced with test results suggesting that, while the
    nonresidential NEM 2.0 tariff conferred a fairly small net benefit on the
    electrical system, it failed, to a substantial degree, to equalize the costs and
    benefits among customers. As discussed above, it was for the Commission to
    balance the various legislative objectives expressed in section 2827.1. We
    find no abuse of discretion, and certainly no legal error, in the Commission’s
    30
    decision to strike a balance in favor of rectifying a substantial inequity
    among its customers.9
    VII.
    In section 2827.1, the Legislature specified several general objectives
    for a successor to the NEM tariff, leaving the Commission — in the exercise
    of its institutional expertise — to strike an appropriate balance among the
    many important — but sometimes conflicting — public policy interests. In
    reviewing the Decision, we may neither second-guess the Commission’s
    balancing of those interests nor substitute our own view of the optimal policy
    outcome. To the contrary, in recognition of the Commission’s unusual
    standing as a constitutional body, our review is limited to ensuring that the
    successor tariff bears a reasonable relation to the statute’s purpose and
    language and that the Commission did not otherwise err under section 1757.
    For the reasons discussed above, this deferential standard of review leaves no
    basis for faulting the Commission’s work. In reaching this conclusion, we
    mean to express no views about the Commission’s resolution of the policy
    issues implicated, except that the Decision is properly sensitive to — and
    consistent with — the objectives established by the Legislature.
    DISPOSITION
    The decision of the Commission is affirmed. The Commission and real
    parties in interest shall recover their costs in this proceeding.
    9 Petitioners also argue nonresidential customers were required under
    the NEM 2.0 tariff to pay higher utility bills than the cost for the utilities to
    provide them service. The intended legal significance of this argument is
    unclear. Section 2827.1 directed the Commission to devise a successor tariff
    balancing costs and benefits among all customers, but it did not require the
    Commission to ensure no customers were charged more by the utilities than
    the cost to serve them.
    31
    _________________________
    Rodríguez, J.
    I CONCUR:
    _________________________
    Petrou, J.
    A167721
    32
    TUCHER, P. J., Concurring.
    With the following additional observations, I concur in the court’s
    opinion.
    The Legislature established, as the first requirement for the successor
    tariff, that it “ensure[] that customer-sited renewable distributed generation
    continues to grow sustainably.” (Pub. Util. Code, § 2827.1, subd. (b)(1), italics
    added.) If petitioners’ worst fears are realized, and the successor tariff
    devastates solar adoption rates instead of fostering sustainable growth, the
    Commission will have to course correct when it revisits its work. The
    Legislature intended for the Commission to “revise the . . . tariff as
    appropriate to achieve [statutory] objectives” (§ 2827.1, subd. (b)), and the
    Commission has already committed to studying the performance of the
    successor tariff after its first three years.
    When the Commission undertakes this study, it may choose to look
    closely at its Societal Cost Test or at some other measure that fully accounts
    for the environmental detriments of conventional electricity generation. In
    adopting the successor tariff, the Commission determined it was “premature”
    to apply the Societal Cost Test, as the test was still under development. But
    when complete, that test may turn out to be a more refined and appropriate
    measure of the total benefits of customer-sited generation than the avoided
    cost calculator that the successor tariff currently incorporates. Section
    2827.1 allows for a tariff that captures the noneconomic benefits of renewable
    electricity. The Commission understands this, as evidenced by its actions in
    adopting and defending NEM 2.0 and its counsel’s response to questions at
    oral argument. And once a tariff is able to capture the full spectrum of costs
    avoided with renewable energy, it would seem optimal that it do so.
    1
    But the issue before the court today is, as the majority notes, not
    whether the Commission has chosen the best possible tariff. Rather, we are
    asked simply to decide whether the Commission has chosen a course that
    complies with the law and is reasonably supported by the evidence. (See maj.
    opn. ante, at pp. 9–10.) Given the limited scope of our review, I agree that
    the decision of the Commission must be affirmed.
    _________________________
    Tucher, P. J.
    2
    Shute, Mihaly & Weinberger, Ellison Folk and Aaron M. Stanton for
    Petitioners Protect our Communities Foundation and Environmental
    Working Group.
    Roger Lin, Anchun Jean Su and Howard Crystal for Petitioner Center for
    Biological Diversity, Inc.
    Law Offices of Richard K. Bauman and Richard K. Bauman for Albion Power
    Company, as Amicus Curiae on behalf of Petitioner Protect our Communities
    Foundation.
    Christine Jun Hammond and Edward Moldavsky for Respondent.
    Munger, Tolles & Olson, Henry Weissmann and Andra Lim for Real Parties
    in Interest Pacific Gas and Electric Company, San Diego Gas & Electric
    Company, and Southern California Edison Company.
    Pacific Gas and Electric Company Law Department and Ashley E. Merlo for
    Real Party in Interest Pacific Gas and Electric Company.
    San Diego Gas & Electric Company and E. Gregory Barnes for Real Party in
    Interest San Diego Gas & Electric Company.
    Southern California Edison Company and Rebecca Meiers-De Pastino for
    Real Party in Interest Southern California Edison Company.
    3
    

Document Info

Docket Number: A167721N

Filed Date: 1/16/2024

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/16/2024