Beverage v. Apple, Inc. ( 2024 )


Menu:
  • Filed 4/25/24
    CERTIFIED FOR PUBLICATION
    IN THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA
    SIXTH APPELLATE DISTRICT
    MICHELLE BEVERAGE et al.,                           H050526
    (Santa Clara County
    Plaintiffs and Appellants,                 Super. Ct. No. 20CV370535)
    v.
    APPLE, INC.,
    Defendant and Respondent.
    I. INTRODUCTION
    This case requires us to explore the intersection of laws regulating antitrust
    activities and unfair competition. Plaintiffs Michelle Beverage and Joseph Mejia
    (Plaintiffs) appeal after the trial court sustained without leave to amend a demurrer
    brought by Defendant Apple, Inc. (Apple) to their class action complaint. They alleged
    that Apple’s restrictive contractual terms and its coercive conduct toward portable
    software developers who seek to do business on Apple’s App Store constituted unlawful
    and unfair practices that violated both the Cartwright Act (Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16700 et
    seq.) and the Unfair Competition Law (Id. § 17200 et seq. (UCL).). Applying the
    Colgate doctrine, U. S. v. Colgate & Co. (1919) 
    250 U.S. 300
     (Colgate) and the holding
    of Chavez v. Whirlpool Corporation (2001) 
    93 Cal.App.4th 363
     (Chavez), the trial court
    determined that Plaintiffs did not and could not state causes of action under either legal
    regime as a matter of law.
    On appeal, Plaintiffs challenge only one aspect of the trial court’s ruling. They
    argue the court erred by relying on Chavez to sustain the demurrer to their UCL cause of
    action alleging unfair practices by Apple toward one developer, Epic Games, Inc. (Epic),
    and its gaming application known as Fortnite. Plaintiffs claim that Chavez is inconsistent
    with the California Supreme Court’s decision in Cel-Tech Communications, Inc. v. Los
    Angeles Cellular Telephone Company (1999) 
    20 Cal.4th 163
     (Cel-Tech).
    As we will explain, we disagree that Chavez reflects a misapplication of Cel-Tech.
    Since the trial court properly relied on Chavez to sustain the demurrer without leave to
    amend, we affirm the judgment.
    II. FACTUAL AND PROCEDURAL BACKGROUND
    We summarize the facts underlying this action assuming, as we must, the truth of
    all properly pleaded allegations in Plaintiffs’ operative complaint. (Heckart v. A-1 Self
    Storage, Inc. (2018) 
    4 Cal.5th 749
    , 753.)
    A. Apple and the App Store
    Apple “designs, manufactures, markets, and sells to consumers” portable
    electronic devices that can connect to the internet via Wi-Fi or cellular data, such as
    iPhones and iPads (iOS devices). Apple released the first iPhone in 2007 and the iPad in
    2010. “Since then, Apple has sold billions of devices—setting a record for 1.5 billion
    active devices in 2020.” iOS devices have a market share of roughly 50 percent in the
    United States.
    iOS devices operate software programs called “apps” that are specifically designed
    to run on portable electronics. Apps are also operating system specific, such that they
    must be specifically configured to function on iOS devices. In 2008, Apple launched the
    App Store, which “makes apps and updates available for purchase, download, and
    update.” The App Store is the only legal means by which developers can market and sell
    their apps to users of iOS devices, and the only legal means for those users to purchase
    and download apps to their devices. On that point, Plaintiffs allege that “[c]onsumers are
    unable to legally load apps onto their iOS Devices in any other way—they are required to
    purchase and download applications on their iOS Devices through the App Store and
    make In-App Purchases through Apple’s payment system.” Additionally, “Apple has
    2
    complete control over the content found on the App Store—the approval or removal of
    applications or updates rests entirely with them.” The App Store features 1.96 million
    apps available for download, the vast majority of which are developed and programmed
    by third-party developers.
    Developers who wish to do business on the App Store must agree to a
    non-negotiable contract that requires them to use Apple’s in-app purchase system.
    Developers are also prohibited from “steering” users to alternative payment methods
    outside of the app. When it first launched the App Store, Apple collected 30 percent of
    the price paid for each app and the developer received the remaining 70 percent. A year
    later, Apple also began collecting 30 percent of all sales of digital goods and currency
    made within apps. Aside from a handful of developers who have negotiated with Apple
    to receive a larger percentage of purchases made on the App Store, “[d]evelopers and
    firms had no way to avoid or minimize Apple’s 30% cut for purchases of digital content.”
    B. Fortnite
    Epic created Fortnite, which is a social and gaming app “where dozens of
    participants, either individually or in teams, are dropped into a landscape” to engage in a
    “King of the Hill” style match where “the last one standing at the end wins.” Within
    Fortnite, users can pay for digital currency, known as V-Bucks, which can then be used to
    “buy” digital goods for use in the application, such as costumes or specialized dances for
    the playable characters. When users on iOS devices purchase V-Bucks or digital goods
    in Fortnite, “the transaction goes through Apple,” who takes a 30 percent cut of the user’s
    payment and sends the remaining 70 percent to Epic “as is the custom for in-app
    purchases on iOS devices.”
    Fortnite was released for iOS devices in April 2018 and, by July 2018, reached $1
    billion in revenue for in-app purchases of digital currency and goods. By May 2020,
    Fortnite had a cumulative total of 350 million users, and the mobile application reached
    $1 billion in revenue, with the vast majority coming from iOS devices and the App Store.
    3
    In August 2020, Epic contacted Apple about the company’s plans to launch a
    direct payment system via Fortnite on iOS devices where users could purchase digital
    currency and goods at a discounted price. Apple responded by removing Fortnite from
    the App Store, which prevented users from downloading or updating Fortnite. This led
    Epic to initiate legal action against Apple in federal court.1
    After Apple removed Fortnite from the App Store, it began promoting Fortnite’s
    biggest competitor on both the App Store and on Twitter. Apple also “threatened” to
    remove the apps of other companies who contracted with Epic from the App Store, and
    “considered punitive measures against Netflix when Netflix was considering the removal
    of in-app purchases.”
    C. The Pleadings and Demurrers
    Plaintiffs are two individuals who made purchases through the App Store in
    Fortnite for use on iOS devices. They initiated this action in September 2020 on behalf
    of themselves and a putative class of iOS device users who downloaded Fortnite onto
    their device and made purchases of digital goods or currency within the app using
    Apple’s purchase system.
    After the trial court sustained a demurrer to Plaintiffs’ first amended complaint,
    they filed a second amended complaint (SAC) in April 2022. Plaintiffs alleged that
    Apple’s restrictions on app distribution increased the prices developers charge iOS device
    users, and that Apple’s anti-steering restrictions “artificially increase” Apple’s power
    within the market for mobile gaming transactions.2
    1
    The federal lawsuit, which we will refer to as the “district court case” to avoid
    confusion with a related appellate proceeding in the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals, was
    filed in the United States District Court for the Northern District of California. (See Epic
    Games, Inc. v. Apple Inc. (N.D. Cal. 2021) 
    559 F. Supp. 3d 898
    .).
    2
    Although Plaintiffs alleged that Apple promulgated “monopolistic policies and
    practices,” they did not allege that Apple held a monopoly over the market for mobile
    gaming transactions. Rather, Plaintiffs alleged in the SAC that Google was Apple’s
    (continued)
    4
    Plaintiffs asserted three causes of action in the SAC. The first was under the
    Cartwright Act, which Plaintiffs alleged Apple violated by leveraging “its market power
    to make developers and consumers accept unreasonable and anticompetitive terms in
    order to access the iOS marketplace.” The second, for violation of the “unlawful” prong
    of the UCL, was based on the same conduct.
    In the third cause of action, Plaintiffs asserted that Apple violated the “unfair”
    prong of the UCL by “threatening an incipient violation of an antitrust law by preventing
    an informed choice among users of the iOS platform by limited information regarding
    pricing and purchase option[s].” Plaintiffs further alleged that Apple’s conduct “violates
    the policy and spirit of antitrust laws because anti-steering has the effect of preventing
    substitution among platforms for transactions.”
    Apple filed a demurrer to the SAC, which the trial court sustained without leave to
    amend. The court found that Plaintiffs did not state claims under the Cartwright Act or
    the “unlawful” prong of the UCL as a matter of law because they alleged only unilateral
    conduct by Apple that was immunized from antitrust liability by the Colgate doctrine.
    Analyzing the UCL cause of action under the “unfair” prong separately, the trial court
    determined it was barred by Chavez.
    Plaintiffs timely appealed.
    III.    DISCUSSION
    Plaintiffs contend that the trial court wrongly relied on Chavez and misapplied
    Cel-Tech to sustain Apple’s demurrer to their cause of action under the “unfair” prong of
    the UCL. The central premise of Plaintiffs’ argument is that Chavez was wrongly
    decided to the extent it held that a failed antitrust claim cannot be replead as an unfair
    business practice under the UCL. Our review of Cel-Tech, Chavez, and related antitrust
    principles shows otherwise.
    “main competitor” within the market. These “two companies combine to dominate the
    mobile operating system market” and the market for mobile gaming transactions.
    5
    A. Standard of Review
    “ ‘The purpose of a demurrer is to test the sufficiency of a complaint by raising
    questions of law.’ ” (Candelore v. Tinder, Inc. (2018) 
    19 Cal.App.5th 1138
    , 1143
    (Candelore).) “We review an order sustaining a demurrer de novo, exercising our
    independent judgment as to whether a cause of action has been stated as a matter of law.”
    (Thompson v. Ioane (2017) 
    11 Cal.App.5th 1180
    , 1190.) In doing so, “ ‘[w]e assume the
    truth of the properly pleaded factual allegations, [and] facts that reasonably can be
    inferred from those expressly pleaded.’ [Citation.] But we do not assume the truth of
    ‘contentions, deductions, or conclusions of law.’ [Citation.] We liberally construe the
    complaint ‘with a view to substantial justice between the parties,’ drawing ‘all reasonable
    inferences in favor of the asserted claims.’ ” (Liapes v. Facebook, Inc. (2023) 
    95 Cal.App.5th 910
    , 919.) “To survive a demurrer, the complaint need only allege facts
    sufficient to state a cause of action.” (C.A. v. William S. Hart Union High School Dist.
    (2012) 
    53 Cal.4th 861
    , 872.) “[B]ecause we are reviewing the trial court’s ruling and not
    its reasoning, we may affirm on any ground supported by the record regardless of
    whether the trial court relied upon it.” (Doe v. Roman Catholic Archbishop of Los
    Angeles (2016) 
    247 Cal.App.4th 953
    , 960.)
    “When a demurrer is sustained without leave to amend, ‘we decide whether there
    is a reasonable possibility that the defect can be cured by amendment: if it can be, the
    trial court has abused its discretion and we reverse; if not, there has been no abuse of
    discretion and we affirm.’ [Citation.] Plaintiff has the burden to show a reasonable
    possibility the complaint can be amended to state a cause of action.” (Hamilton v.
    Greenwich Investors XXVI, LLC (2011) 
    195 Cal.App.4th 1602
    , 1609.) “Where, however,
    amendment could not correct a deficiency in the complaint or where the action is barred
    as a matter of law, the demurrer is properly sustained without leave to amend.” (State of
    California Automobile Dismantlers Assn. v. Interinsurance Exchange (1986) 180
    
    6 Cal.App.3d 735
    , 742.) “The issue of leave to amend is always open on appeal, even if
    not raised by the plaintiff.” (City of Stockton v. Super. Ct. (2007) 
    42 Cal.4th 730
    , 746.)
    B. The UCL and Cel-Tech
    “The UCL prohibits, and provides civil remedies for, unfair competition, which it
    defines as ‘any unlawful, unfair or fraudulent business act or practice.’ [Citation.] Its
    purpose ‘is to protect both consumers and competitors by promoting fair competition in
    commercial markets for goods and services.’ ” (Kwikset v. Super. Ct. (2011) 
    51 Cal.4th 310
    , 320 (Kwikset).) The law is “broad” and “ ‘sweeping, embracing “ ‘anything that can
    properly be called a business practice and that at the same time is forbidden by law.’ ” ’ ”
    (Cel-Tech, supra, 20 Cal.4th at p. 180.)
    Functionally, “[t]he UCL operates as a three-pronged statute: ‘Each of these three
    adjectives [unlawful, unfair, or fraudulent] captures a “separate and distinct theory of
    liability.” ’ ” (Beaver v. Tarsadia Hotels (9th Cir. 2016) 
    816 F.3d 1170
    , 1177; accord
    Adhav v. Midway Rent A Car, Inc. (2019) 
    37 Cal.App.5th 954
    , 970 [since the UCL is
    written in the disjunctive, it establishes three varieties of unfair competition].) “By
    proscribing ‘any unlawful’ business practice, ‘section 17200 “borrows” violations of
    other laws and treats them as unlawful practices’ that the unfair competition law makes
    independently actionable.” (Cel-Tech, supra, 20 Cal.4th at p. 180; Candelore, 
    supra,
     19
    Cal.App.5th at p. 1155.) However, “[i]t is not necessary for a business practice to be
    ‘unlawful’ in order to be subject to an action under the unfair competition law.” (Smith v.
    State Farm Mutual Automobile Insurance Co. (2001) 
    93 Cal.App.4th 700
    , 718.) Under
    the UCL’s “unfair” prong, “a practice may be deemed unfair even if not specifically
    proscribed by some other law.” (Cel-Tech, supra, 20 Cal.4th at p. 180.) “ ‘ “In other
    words, a practice is prohibited as ‘unfair’ . . . even if not ‘unlawful’ and vice versa.” ’ ”
    (Ibid.) In creating this distinction, the Legislature recognized that “ ‘unfair or fraudulent
    business practices may run the gamut of human ingenuity and chicanery’ ” and sought to
    account for “ ‘the creative nature of the scheming mind.’ ” (Id. at p. 181.)
    7
    Although the UCL’s scope is broad, it is not unlimited. (Cel-Tech, supra, 20
    Cal.4th at p. 182.) “Courts may not simply impose their own notions of the day as to
    what is fair or unfair.” (Ibid.) To prevent that from occurring, the California Supreme
    Court has held that “[s]pecific legislation may limit the judiciary’s power to declare
    conduct unfair. If the Legislature has permitted certain conduct or considered a situation
    and concluded no action should lie, courts may not override that determination.” (Ibid.)
    Thus, “[w]hen specific legislation provides a ‘safe harbor,’ plaintiffs may not use the
    general unfair competition law to assault that harbor.” (Ibid.)
    In Cel-Tech, the California Supreme Court examined whether the defendant, a
    seller of cellular telephones and services, could invoke a “safe harbor” to prevent liability
    under the unfair prong of the UCL. (Cel-Tech, supra, 20 Cal.4th at p. 187.) The
    defendant was one of two federally licensed providers of cellular telephone service in the
    Los Angeles area and “formulated a strategy of selling cellular telephones below cost in
    order to increase the number of subscribers” to its service. (Id. at p. 169.) The plaintiffs
    sued the defendant over that practice, alleging that selling telephones below cost violated
    the Unfair Practices Act (UPA) (Bus. & Prof. Code, § 17000 et seq.)3 and constituted an
    unfair business practice under the UCL. (Cel-Tech at p. 187.) The California Supreme
    Court held that plaintiffs did not prove a violation of the UPA because the evidence did
    not show that the defendant acted with the necessary mental state. (Id. at p. 178.) At the
    same time, however, the court also determined that the UPA did not provide the
    defendant a “safe harbor” for the UCL cause of action since “nothing in [the UPA] makes
    all other below-cost sales lawful, including those that have the effect, although not the
    purpose, of destroying competition.” (Id. at pp. 174-175, 178, 187.) The court reasoned
    3
    Unlike the UCL, the UPA “prohibits specific ‘practices which the [L]egislature
    has determined constitute unfair trade practices,” such as “purposeful below-cost sales
    and loss leaders.” (Cel-Tech, supra, 20 Cal.4th at p. 179.) “The [UCL] is independent of
    the [UPA] and other laws.” (Ibid.)
    8
    that because the defendant was a “ ‘duopolist,’ employing an overall strategy that might
    not be available to its nonduopolist competitors,” the Legislature “undoubtedly did not
    consider below-cost sales in this context.” (Id. at p. 188.) The court also rejected the
    defendant’s argument that, because the UPA addressed below-cost sales but did not
    prohibit the defendant’s specific conduct, its practice could not be considered unfair.
    (Ibid.)
    C. The Cartwright Act and the Colgate Doctrine
    “The Cartwright Act was passed in 1907 as part of a wave of turn-of-the-century
    state and federal legislation intended to stem the power of monopolies and cartels.”
    (Clayworth v. Pfizer, Inc. (2010) 
    49 Cal.4th 758
    , 772.) But unlike its federal counterpart,
    the Sherman Act (
    15 U.S.C. §§ 1
    , 2),4 “single firm monopolization is not cognizable
    under the Cartwright Act.” (Asahi Kasei Pharma Corp. v. CoTherix, Inc. (2012) 
    204 Cal.App.4th 1
    , 8 (Asahi); Dimidowich v. Bell & Howell (9th Cir. 1986) 
    803 F.2d 1473
    ,
    1478 (Dimidowich) [“No California statute deals expressly with monopolization or
    attempted monopolization”].) Instead, “[t]he act ‘generally outlaws any combinations or
    agreements which restrain trade or competition or which fix or control prices’ [citation],
    and declares that, with certain exceptions, ‘every trust is unlawful, against public policy
    and void’ [citation].” (Pacific Gas & Electric Co. v. County of Stanislaus (1997) 
    16 Cal.4th 1143
    , 1147; accord Kolling v. Down Jones & Co. (1982) 
    137 Cal.App.3d 709
    ,
    717 (Kolling) [Cartwright Act codifies “the common law prohibition against restraint of
    trade”].) A violation of the Cartwright Act “requires ‘a combination of capital, skill or
    acts by two or more persons’ that seeks to achieve an anticompetitive end.” (Asahi,
    
    supra,
     204 Cal.App.4th at p. 8.) Accordingly, “a corporation cannot conspire with itself
    The two sections of the Sherman Act “focus on different problems. Section 1
    4
    deals with concerted activity, outlawing ‘combination[s] . . . in restraint of trade.’
    [Citation.] Section 2, on the other hand, concerns unilateral activity, punishing ‘every
    person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize . . . .’ [Citation.]” (Alaska
    Airlines, Inc. v. United Airlines, Inc. (9th Cir. 1991) 
    948 F.2d 536
    , 540-541.)
    9
    or its agents for purposes of the antitrust laws.” (Kolling at p. 720.) “Only separate
    entities pursuing separate economic interests can conspire within the proscription of the
    antitrust laws.” (Freeman v. San Diego Assn. of Realtors (1999) 
    77 Cal.App.4th 171
    ,
    189.)
    In order to state a claim under the Cartwright Act, a plaintiff must allege “ ‘the
    formation and operation of the conspiracy and the illegal acts done in furtherance of the
    conspiracy.’ ” (Marsh v. Anesthesia Services Medical Group, Inc. (2011) 
    200 Cal.App.4th 480
    , 493; Kolling, supra, 137 Cal.App.3d at p. 720 [“The Cartwright Act . . .
    requires an illegal ‘combination’ or ‘conspiracy’ to restrain trade”].) Conversely, a claim
    describing only a unilateral refusal to deal without alleging a corresponding illegal
    conspiracy or combination does not state an actionable antitrust claim. (Kolling, supra,
    137 Cal.App.3d at p. 720.) This premise, that “[a]bsent a legal provision to the contrary,
    a private party generally may choose to do or not do business with whomever it pleases”
    without violating antitrust laws (Drum v. San Fernando Valley Bar Assn. (2010) 
    182 Cal.App.4th 247
    , 254 (Drum)), is known as the Colgate doctrine, arising from the United
    States Supreme Court’s opinion of the same name. (Chavez, supra, 93 Cal.App.4th at
    p. 370.) In Colgate, “the Supreme Court recognized that, subject to antitrust laws such as
    the Sherman Act, there is a ‘long recognized right of [a] trader or manufacturer engaged
    in an entirely private business, freely to exercise his own independent discretion as to
    parties with whom he will deal.’ ” (People’s Choice Wireless, Inc. v. Verizon Wireless
    (2005) 
    131 Cal.App.4th 656
    , 663, fn. omitted; accord Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service
    Corp. (1984) 
    465 U.S. 752
    , 761 (Monsanto) [“A manufacturer of course generally has a
    right to deal, or refuse to deal, with whomever it likes, as long as it does so
    independently”]; Dimidowich, supra, 803 F.3d at p. 1478 [“A manufacturer may choose
    those with whom it wishes to deal and unilaterally may refuse to deal with a distributor or
    customer for business reasons without running afoul of the antitrust laws”].)
    10
    The Colgate doctrine is “firmly entrenched in antitrust jurisprudence.” (The
    Jeanery, Inc. v. James Jeans, Inc. (9th Cir. 1988) 
    849 F.2d 1148
    , 1154.) It reflects a
    limitation to the reach of antitrust liability, grounded in the concept that “a single firm’s
    conduct, absent the danger of monopolization, is not the object of intense antitrust
    scrutiny because to treat it with such scrutiny would heighten ‘the risk that the antitrust
    laws will dampen the competitive zeal of a single aggressive entrepreneur.’ ” (Id. at
    p. 1152.) “[C]oncerted action poses a substantially greater risk of anticompetitive harm
    than does independent behavior” because it “ ‘deprives the marketplace of the
    independent centers of decisionmaking that competition assumes and demands.’ ” (Id. at
    pp. 1152-1153.)
    “California courts have adopted the Colgate doctrine for purposes of applying the
    Cartwright Act.” (Chavez, supra, 93 Cal.App.4th at p. 370; see G.H.I.I. v. MTS, Inc.
    (1983) 
    147 Cal.App.3d 256
    , 267 [“It is well settled that the antitrust laws do not preclude
    a trader from unilaterally determining the parties with whom it will deal and the terms on
    which it will transact business]; Drum, 
    supra,
     182 Cal.App.4th at p. 254 [“ ‘right to
    refuse to deal remains sancrosanct’ ”].)
    D. Chavez
    In Chavez, a case decided after Cel-Tech, the court applied the Colgate doctrine to
    preclude a UCL cause of action. There, the consumer plaintiff alleged that the
    defendants, a home appliances manufacturer and retailer, had agreed to maintain
    minimum resale prices for products in violation of the Cartwright Act and the UCL.
    (Chavez, supra, 93 Cal.App.4th at p. 367.) The plaintiff alleged that the manufacturer
    announced a unilateral resale price policy and advised retailers it would monitor their
    compliance and terminate any retailers who failed to implement the minimum resale
    prices with no “ ‘second chances.’ ” (Ibid.) The plaintiff further contended that the
    retailer from whom he purchased an appliance either voluntarily agreed to implement the
    manufacturer’s policy or did so under coercion. (Ibid.) Reviewing these allegations, the
    11
    trial court sustained the defendants’ demurrer to the complaint without leave to amend,
    relying on the Colgate doctrine. (Id. at p. 368.)
    The Second District Court of Appeal affirmed, holding that the plaintiff failed to
    plead facts sufficient to establish a coerced agreement in violation of the Cartwright Act
    or the “unlawful” prong of the UCL. (Chavez, supra, 93 Cal.App.4th at p. 367.) Citing
    Colgate and Monsanto, the court reasoned that the plaintiff did not state a claim under the
    Cartwright Act because “a manufacturer’s announcement of a resale price policy and its
    refusal to deal with the dealers who do not comply coupled with the dealers’ voluntary
    acquiescence in the policy does not constitute an implied agreement or an unlawful
    combination as a matter of law.” (Id. at p. 372.) Although the plaintiff alleged that the
    manufacturer went beyond merely announcing a policy and refusing to deal by taking
    several steps to monitor retailers’ compliance, such as reviewing advertisements,
    collecting sales receipts, and sending in “mystery shoppers,” the court held that the
    manufacturer’s conduct was permitted by the Colgate doctrine. (Id. at p. 373.) To that
    end, the court explained that “measures to monitor compliance that do not interfere with
    the dealers’ freedom of choice are permissible,” because “[t]o hold otherwise would
    render the manufacturer’s announced policy ineffective and undermine rights protected
    by the Colgate doctrine.” (Ibid.) “In this manner, a manufacturer that announces a resale
    price policy and enforces the policy by monitoring the dealers’ compliance and refusing
    to deal with dealers who do not comply does not violate the Cartwright Act.” (Ibid.)
    The court also held that the plaintiff’s allegations did not state a claim under the
    UCL’s “unfair” prong. (Chavez, supra, 93 Cal.App.4th at p. 375.) Since “[t]he purpose
    of federal and state antitrust laws is to protect and promote competition for the benefits of
    consumers,” the court reasoned that “[i]f the same conduct is alleged to be both an
    antitrust violation and an ‘unfair’ business act or practice for the same reason—because it
    unreasonably restrains competition and harms consumers—the determination that the
    conduct is not an unreasonable restraint of trade necessarily implies that the conduct is
    12
    not ‘unfair’ toward consumers.” (Ibid.) In the Chavez court’s view, permitting a
    “separate inquiry” under the UCL “into essentially the same question” raised by the
    Cartwright Act claim “would only invite conflict and uncertainty and could lead to the
    enjoining of procompetitive conduct.” (Ibid.)
    E. Analysis of this Case
    With these principles in mind, we now turn to the parties’ arguments. But first, we
    comment on the scope of this appeal. Since Plaintiffs’ challenge is limited only to the
    dismissal of their cause of action under the “unfair” prong of the UCL, they have
    abandoned any claim of error in the other aspects of the trial court’s ruling on Apple’s
    demurrer. (See Limon v. Circle K Stores, Inc. (2022) 
    84 Cal.App.5th 671
    , 687.)
    Applying well-settled appellate standards, we therefore presume the trial court correctly
    found that Plaintiffs’ causes of action under the Cartwright Act and the “unlawful” prong
    of the UCL were legally insufficient by application of the Colgate doctrine and we
    conduct our analysis with that presumption in mind. (See Denham v. Super. Ct. (1970) 
    2 Cal.3d 557
    , 564 [judgment of the trial court is presumed correct on appeal and error must
    be affirmatively shown]; Mejia v. City of Los Angeles (2007) 
    156 Cal.App.4th 151
    , 158
    [“We presume that the court properly applied the law and acted within its discretion
    unless the appellant affirmatively shows otherwise”].) The question that remains is
    whether Plaintiffs adequately alleged an “unfair” act or practice under the UCL
    considering the trial court’s ruling that Apple’s practices constituted permissible
    unilateral conduct. Under these circumstances, we hold that Plaintiffs did not state a
    claim as a matter of law.
    Looking at the SAC, there is no doubt that Plaintiffs’ UCL cause of action based
    on the “unfair” prong fell squarely within the rule announced in Chavez. Like their
    Cartwright Act cause of action, Plaintiffs alleged under the UCL that Apple’s practices
    toward Epic and other developers that dictated the terms of business on the App Store
    and imposed restrictions on contacting and steering the users of iOS devices to other app
    13
    storefronts threatened “an incipient violation of an antitrust law by preventing an
    informed choice among users of the iOS platform” and violated “the policy and spirit of
    antitrust laws because anti-steering has the effect of preventing substitution among
    platforms for transactions.” Thus, the same conduct was alleged in the SAC “to be both
    an antitrust violation and an ‘unfair’ business act or practice for the same reason—
    because it unreasonably restrains competition and harms consumers.” (Chavez, supra, 93
    Cal.App.4th at p. 375.) According to Chavez, once the trial court determined that the
    Colgate doctrine applied to these practices, this “necessarily implie[d] that the conduct
    [was] not ‘unfair’ toward consumers.” (Ibid.) Chavez, therefore, forecloses Plaintiffs’
    UCL claim.
    To resist that outcome, Plaintiffs argue that Chavez was wrongly decided and is
    “wholly inconsistent” with Cel-Tech. According to Plaintiffs, the implication from
    Chavez that a “safe harbor” can be found outside of explicit statutory language
    immunizing specific conduct cannot be reconciled with Cel-Tech, particularly with the
    court’s declaration that the “Legislature’s mere failure to prohibit an activity does not
    prevent a court from finding it unfair.” (Cel-Tech, supra, 20 Cal.4th at p. 184.) Stated
    differently in the context of this case, Plaintiffs theorize that because the Legislature has
    not enacted a statute or provision condoning conduct embraced by the Colgate doctrine
    as lawful, Cel-Tech establishes that such conduct may constitute a predicate “unfair”
    practice for a UCL cause of action even though it could not support an antitrust claim.
    Looking closely at Cel-Tech, however, we disagree that it countenances Plaintiffs’
    theory. As Apple points out, the court’s description of qualifying “safe harbors” in
    Cel-Tech was not limited solely to instances where explicit statutory language either
    authorizes conduct as lawful or imposes a litigation bar. Instead, the court explained that
    “safe harbors” can arise in two ways: “If the Legislature has permitted certain conduct or
    considered a situation and concluded no action should lie, courts may not override that
    determination.” (Cel-Tech, supra, 20 Cal.4th at p. 182, italics added; accord Zhang v.
    14
    Super. Ct. (2013) 
    57 Cal.4th 364
    , 379, fn. 8.) Building on that concept, the court
    emphasized the principle that a plaintiff may not “ ‘plead around’ an ‘absolute bar to
    relief’ simply ‘by recasting the cause of action as one for unfair competition.’ ”
    (Cel-Tech at p. 182.) This rule ensures that courts are not imposing “their own notions of
    the day as to what is fair or unfair” under the guise of the UCL, as the Cel-Tech court
    cautioned. (Ibid.) Indeed, “[a]lthough its reach is broad, the UCL ‘ “ ‘is not an
    all-purpose substitute for a tort or contract action.’ ” ’ ” (People v. Potter Handy, LLP
    (2023) 
    97 Cal.App.5th 938
    , 950.) In substance, that is exactly what Chavez held; a
    plaintiff cannot plead around the absolute bar imposed by the Colgate doctrine by
    resurrecting a failed antitrust claim as an unfair business practice under the UCL (Chavez,
    supra, 93 Cal.App.4th at p. 375), especially when, as here, the only other cause of action
    alleged in the SAC was a violation of the Cartwright Act. (Cf. Zhang, 
    supra,
     57 Cal.4th
    at p. 384 [UCL action may lie if defendant’s alleged conduct independently violates
    “obligations imposed by other statutes or the common law” even if “safe harbor” also
    applies].) To find otherwise would permit plaintiffs to use the UCL to “assault” the
    “ ‘absolute bar to relief’ ” established by the Colgate doctrine. (Cel-Tech, supra, 20
    Cal.4th at p. 182.) Viewed in that way, Chavez is entirely consistent with Cel-Tech.
    In any event, we find sufficient indication from the text and history of the
    Cartwright Act that the Legislature has determined that “no action should lie” for
    unilateral refusals to deal that are permissible under the Colgate doctrine. (Cel-Tech,
    supra, 20 Cal.4th at p. 182.) Since its enactment over 100 years ago, the Cartwright Act
    has by its own terms prohibited only anticompetitive conduct by two or more entities in
    conspiracy or in combination. (See State of California ex rel. Van de Kamp v. Texaco,
    Inc. (1988) 
    46 Cal.3d 1147
    , 1161 (Texaco), superseded by statute on another ground as
    stated in Stop Youth Addiction, Inc. v. Lucky Stores, Inc. (1998) 
    17 Cal.4th 553
    , 570.)
    Although other states’ antitrust acts in existence at the time of its adoption had broader
    application, the California Legislature chose to model the Cartwright Act after a “more
    15
    narrowly worded” Texas act that defined a “trust” as a “ ‘combination of capital, skills or
    acts . . .’ for various improper purposes.” (Texaco at pp. 1154-1155, italics omitted.)
    As we have mentioned, the Colgate doctrine “has been a basic part of antitrust law
    concepts since it was first announced in 1919” by the United States Supreme Court.
    (United States v. Parke, Davis & Co. (1960) 
    362 U.S. 29
    , 49 (dis. opn. of Harlan, J.).)
    Rather than retreat from the doctrine over time, the high court continues to recognize its
    viability. (See, e.g., Monsanto, 
    supra,
     465 U.S. at p. 760; Leegin Creative Leather
    Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. (2007) 
    551 U.S. 877
    , 901 [observing that Supreme Court
    decisions have accommodated the Colgate doctrine].) The Colgate doctrine was first
    recognized by California courts in 1979. (See R.E. Spriggs Co. v. Adolph Coors Co.
    (1979) 
    94 Cal.App.3d 419
    , 424-425, fn. 1.) Although the Legislature has amended the
    Cartwright Act at least twice since 1979 (Stats. 1983, ch. 1069, § 1; Stats 1987, ch. 865,
    § 2), not to mention numerous times since 1919 (Texaco, supra, 46 Cal.3d at
    pp. 1162-1163), it has not undermined the applicability or effect of the Colgate doctrine.
    Nor did the Legislature act in response to Chavez. Because “[w]e generally presume the
    Legislature is aware of appellate court decisions” (Therolf v. Super. Ct. (2022) 
    80 Cal.App.5th 308
    , 335), its inaction on this subject for at least the past 45 years is
    significant. (See Texaco, supra, 46 Cal.3d at p. 1162.)
    Moreover, Chavez does not stand alone. Its holding has been adopted and applied
    by other California Courts of Appeal. (See Belton v. Comcast Cable Holdings, LLC
    (2007) 
    151 Cal.App.4th 1224
    , 1240; SC Manufactured Homes, Inc. v Liebert (2008) 
    162 Cal.App.4th 68
    , 93; Drum, 
    supra,
     182 Cal.App.4th at p. 254.) Additionally, the Ninth
    Circuit Court of Appeals recognized in Epic Games, Inc. v. Apple, Inc. (9th Cir. 2023) 
    67 F.4th 946
     (Epic Games), that a “categorical legal bar”—as opposed to express statutory
    language— can also operate as a “safe harbor” against UCL liability in the area of
    antitrust. There, the court acknowledged the distinction outlined in Cel-Tech that “there
    is a ‘difference between (1) not making an activity unlawful, and (2) making that activity
    16
    lawful.’ ” (Epic Games, supra, 67 F.4th at p. 1001.) But it continued its discussion of
    “safe harbors” by explaining that “in every instance where a court found the Sherman Act
    to preclude a UCL action, a categorical antitrust rule formed the basis of the decision.”
    (Ibid.) By way of example, the court cited its decision in City of San Jose v. Office of the
    Commissioner of Baseball (9th Cir. 2015) 
    776 F.3d 686
    , in which it “held that the
    judge-made baseball exemption—that ‘the business of providing public baseball games
    for profit . . . [is] not within the scope of the federal antitrust laws’—precluded a UCL
    action.” (Epic Games, supra, 67 F.4th at p. 1001.) While the baseball exemption applies
    to a particular industry not at issue here, the exemption is nonetheless indistinguishable
    from the Colgate doctrine since it operates as a categorical rule exempting certain
    business conduct from the reach of the antitrust laws.
    Consistent with Chavez, we conclude—taking into account the Cartwright Act’s
    prohibition only on coordinated conduct, the Colgate doctrine’s longstanding and
    prominent role in federal and state antitrust jurisprudence, and the Legislature’s
    nonintervention against that backdrop—that the Colgate doctrine provides Apple with a
    “safe harbor” against Plaintiffs’ UCL claim under the “unfair” prong. Although we
    disagree with Plaintiffs that Chavez is irreconcilable with Cel-Tech, this result
    harmonizes the two.
    In their appellate briefing, Plaintiffs argue that the trial court conflated the
    “unlawful” and “unfair” prongs of the UCL by sustaining Apple’s demurrer. They imply
    that affirming the trial court in this instance would have the effect of collapsing the two
    prongs into one in a manner contrary to Cel-Tech, such that “[t]here could be no instance
    where the defendant’s conduct was ‘lawful’ (in the sense that it did not violate any
    prohibitory statute) but was still ‘unfair.’ ” However, we do not perceive that danger
    because our decision is a narrow one. We do not broadly hold that a “safe harbor”
    precluding a UCL claim can necessarily arise from legislative inaction in connection with
    other statutory schemes or in contexts outside of the Colgate doctrine’s application to
    17
    antitrust claims based on unilateral refusals to deal. We also acknowledge, as did the
    Chavez court, that an “unfair” business act or practice need not violate an antitrust law to
    be actionable under the UCL. (Chavez, supra, 93 Cal.App.4th at p. 375.) Instead, our
    decision is limited to situations typified by this case, where the same conduct found
    immune from antitrust liability by the Colgate doctrine is also alleged to violate the
    “unfair” prong of the UCL. Because both antitrust laws and the UCL are designed to
    protect and promote competition for the benefit of consumers (Kwikset, supra, 51 Cal.4th
    at p. 320; Chavez, supra, 93 Cal.App.4th at p. 375), logic dictates that there can be no
    harm to consumers under the UCL based on the same unilateral practices that have been
    historically accepted as procompetitive and categorically shielded from antitrust liability
    by the Colgate doctrine. (See Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
    Trinko, LLP (2004) 
    540 U.S. 398
    , 407-408 (Verizon Communications).)5 This remains
    true whether the “unlawful” and “unfair” prongs are considered jointly or separately.6
    5
    In Verizon Communications, the United States Supreme Court explained why the
    Colgate doctrine protects unilateral conduct as procompetitive: “Firms may acquire
    monopoly power by establishing an infrastructure that renders them uniquely suited to
    serve their customers. Compelling such firms to share the source of their advantage is in
    some tension with the underlying purpose of antitrust law, since it may lessen the
    incentive for the monopolist, the rival, or both to invest in those economically beneficial
    facilities. Enforced sharing also requires antitrust courts to act as central planners,
    identifying the proper price, quantity, and other terms of dealing—a role for which they
    are illsuited. Moreover, compelling negotiation between competitors may facilitate the
    supreme evil of antitrust: collusion.” (Verizon Communications, 
    supra,
     
    540 U.S. 398
    ,
    407-408.)
    6
    Plaintiffs also argue we should depart from Chavez and instead follow Epic
    Games and the order filed after trial in the underlying district court case. We have
    reviewed these decisions but decline to do so. Although we recognize that the “decisions
    of . . . the lower federal courts may be instructive to the extent we find their analysis
    persuasive, they are neither binding nor controlling on matters of state law.” (T.H. v.
    Novartis Pharmaceuticals Corporation (2017) 
    4 Cal.5th 145
    , 175.) The Ninth Circuit and
    the district court mentioned Chavez only in passing, and neither court engaged a rigorous
    analysis of the Colgate doctrine and its effect on UCL claims. We therefore do not find
    these decisions persuasive on the precise issue presented by this appeal.
    18
    Turning back to the SAC, we find that the trial court correctly sustained Apple’s
    demurrer because Plaintiffs did not state a cause of action against Apple for violation of
    the “unfair” prong of the UCL. Since Plaintiffs do not argue in their opening brief on
    appeal that the trial court abused its discretion in denying leave to amend under these
    circumstances, we therefore affirm the judgment.
    IV. DISPOSITION
    The judgment is affirmed. Apple may recover its costs on appeal. (Cal. Rules of
    Court, rule 8.278(a)(1), (2)
    19
    ____________________________
    ADAMS, J.
    WE CONCUR:
    _____________________________________
    GREENWOOD, P. J.
    _____________________________________
    BAMATTRE-MANOUKIAN, J.
    Beverage et al. v. Apple, Inc.
    H050526
    
    Judge of the Santa Clara County Superior Court, assigned by the Chief Justice pursuant
    to article VI, section 6 of the California Constitution.
    Trial Court:                              Santa Clara County
    Superior Court No.: 20CV370535
    Trial Judge:                              The Honorable Sunil Kulkarni
    Attorneys for Plaintiffs and Appellants   Kurt Kessler
    Michelle Beverage & Joseph Mejia:         William Audet
    Ling Kuang
    Myron Moskovitz
    Attorneys for Defendant and Respondent    Julian Kleinbrodt
    Apple, Inc.:                              Ethan Dettmer
    Anna Mathieson
    Beverage et al. v. Apple, Inc.
    H050526
    

Document Info

Docket Number: H050526

Filed Date: 4/25/2024

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 5/15/2024