Jacobi Carbons AB v. United States , 365 F. Supp. 3d 1344 ( 2019 )


Menu:
  •                                      Slip Op. 19-28
    UNITED STATES COURT OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
    JACOBI CARBONS AB AND JACOBI
    CARBONS, INC.,
    Plaintiffs,
    and
    NINGXIA HUAHUI ACTIVATED
    CARBON CO., LTD., et al.,
    Plaintiff-Intervenors,
    Before: Mark A. Barnett, Judge
    v.                             Consol. Court No. 16-00185
    UNITED STATES,
    Defendant,
    and
    CALGON CARBON CORP. AND CABOT
    NORIT AM., INC,
    Defendant-Intervenors.
    OPINION AND ORDER
    [The U.S. Department of Commerce’s Second Remand Results are remanded with
    respect to the agency’s primary surrogate country selection and sustained with respect
    to the agency’s value-added tax adjustment.]
    Dated: March 5, 2019
    Daniel L. Porter and Tung A. Nguyen, Curtis, Mallet-Prevost, Colt & Mosle LLP, of
    Washington, DC, for Plaintiffs Jacobi Carbons AB and Jacobi Carbons, Inc.
    Gregory S. Menegaz, J. Kevin Horgan, and Alexandra H. Salzman, DeKieffer & Horgan,
    PLLC, of Washington, DC, for Plaintiff-Intervenors Carbon Activated Corporation,
    Ningxia Mineral and Chemical Ltd., Shanxi DMD Corporation, Shanxi Industry
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                           Page 2
    Technology Trading Co., Ltd., Shanxi Sincere Industrial Co., Ltd., Tianjin Channel
    Filters Co. Ltd., and Tianjin Maijin Industries Co., Ltd.
    Mollie L. Finnan, Trial Attorney, Commercial Litigation Branch, Civil Division, U.S.
    Department of Justice, of Washington, DC, for Defendant. With her on the brief were
    Joseph H. Hunt, Assistant Attorney General, Jeanne E. Davidson, Director, and Claudia
    Burke, Assistant Director. Of counsel on the brief was Emma T. Hunter, Attorney,
    Office of the Chief Counsel for Trade Enforcement and Compliance, U.S. Department of
    Commerce, of Washington, DC.
    R. Alan Luberda, John M. Herrmann, David A. Hartquist, Melissa M. Brewer, and
    Kathleen M. Cusack, Kelley Drye & Warren LLP, of Washington, DC, for Defendant-
    Intervenors Calgon Carbon Corporation and Cabot Norit Americas, Inc.
    Barnett, Judge: This matter is before the court following the U.S. Department of
    Commerce’s (“Commerce” or “the agency”) second redetermination upon remand in this
    case. See Final Results of Redetermination Pursuant to Court Remand (“2nd Remand
    Results”), ECF No. 124-1.
    Plaintiffs Jacobi Carbons AB and Jacobi Carbons, Inc. (together, “Jacobi”) and
    Plaintiff-Intervenors 1 (collectively, “Plaintiffs”) challenged several aspects of
    Commerce’s final results in the eighth administrative review of the antidumping duty
    1Plaintiff-Intervenors include Carbon Activated Corporation, Ningxia Mineral and
    Chemical Limited, Shanxi DMD Corporation, Shanxi Industry Technology Trading
    Co., Ltd., Shanxi Sincere Industrial Co., Ltd., Tianjin Channel Filters Co., Ltd., and
    Tianjin Maijin Industries Co., Ltd. (collectively, “CAC”); Ningxia Guanghua Cherishmet
    Activated Carbon Co., Ltd., Beijing Pacific Activated Carbon Products Co., Ltd., and
    Datong Municipal Yunguang Activated Carbon Co., Ltd (collectively, “Cherishmet”);
    Ningxia Huahui Activated Carbon Co., Ltd. (“Huahui”); and M.L. Ball Co., Ltd., and Jilin
    Bright Future Chemicals Company, Ltd. (together, “M.L. Ball”). The court consolidated
    cases filed by CAC, Cherishmet, and M.L. Ball under lead Court No. 16-00185, filed by
    Jacobi. See Order (Nov. 3, 2016), ECF No. 42. Those parties, along with Huahui, had
    also intervened in this action. See Order (Oct. 7, 2016), ECF No. 17; Order (Oct. 12,
    2016), ECF No. 22; Order (Oct. 20, 2016), ECF No. 36; Order (Oct. 20, 2016), ECF No.
    40.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 3
    order (“AD Order”) on certain activated carbon from the People’s Republic of China
    (“PRC” or “China”). See Certain Activated Carbon from the People’s Republic of China,
    81 Fed. Reg. 62,088 (Dep’t of Commerce Sept. 8, 2016) (final results of antidumping
    duty admin. review; 2014-2015) (“Final Results”), ECF No. 44-4, and accompanying
    Issues and Decision Mem., A-570-904 (Aug. 31, 2016) (“I&D Mem.”), ECF No. 44-5. 2
    Specifically, Plaintiffs challenged Commerce’s selection of Thailand as the primary
    surrogate country and Thai surrogate values for carbonized material, hydrochloric acid,
    coal tar, and financial ratios, and Commerce’s adjustment to Jacobi’s constructed export
    price to account for irrecoverable value-added tax (“VAT”). See, e.g., Confidential
    Consol. Pls. Jacobi Carbons AB and Jacobi Carbons, Inc.’s Mot. for J. Upon the Agency
    R. and Br. in Supp. of Mot. for J. on the Agency R., ECF No. 48; Consol. Pls. Carbon
    Activated Corporation, Ningxia Mineral and Chemical Limited, Shanxi DMD Corporation,
    Shanxi Industry Technology Trading Co., Ltd., Shanxi Sincere Industrial Co., Ltd.,
    Tianjin Channel Filters Co., Ltd., and Tianjin Maijin Industries Co., Ltd. Mem. in Supp. of
    Mot. for J. on the Agency R., ECF No. 53.
    2 The administrative record filed in connection with the Final Results is divided into a
    Public Administrative Record (“PR”), ECF No. 44-3, and a Confidential Administrative
    Record (“CR”), ECF No. 44-2. The administrative record associated with the 2nd
    Remand Results is contained in a Public Remand Record, ECF No. 125-3, and a
    Confidential Remand Record, ECF No. 125-2. Parties submitted joint appendices
    containing record documents cited in their remand briefs. See J.A. to Parties’
    Comments on Second Remand Redetermination (“PRJA”), ECF No. 133; Confidential
    Suppl. App. to Comments on Second Remand Redetermination (“CRJA”), ECF No. 135.
    These appendices supplement the documents previously provided. See Public J.A.
    (“PJA”), ECF No. 92; Confidential J.A. (“CJA”), ECF No. 91.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                        Page 4
    On June 20, 2017, the court granted Commerce’s request for a remand to clarify
    or reconsider its findings regarding economic comparability and Thailand’s status as a
    significant producer of comparable merchandise based on its export quantity. See
    Order (June 20, 2017), ECF No. 77. 3 On September 5, 2017, Commerce issued its first
    remand redetermination. See Final Results of Redetermination Pursuant to Court Order
    (Sept. 1, 2017) (“1st Remand Results”), ECF No. 78-1. Therein, Commerce further
    explained its methodology for determining which countries are at the same level of
    economic development as the PRC and relied on evidence of domestic production
    rather than exports to support its significant producer determination. 
    Id. at 3-21.
    On
    April 19, 2018, following briefing and oral argument on the Final Results as amended by
    the 1st Remand Results, the court sustained Commerce’s economic comparability
    determination while remanding the agency’s determination that Thailand is a significant
    producer of comparable merchandise, irrecoverable VAT adjustment, and surrogate
    value selections. See Jacobi Carbons AB v. United States (“Jacobi (AR8) I”), 42 CIT
    ___, 
    313 F. Supp. 3d 1344
    (2018). 4
    3 Commerce’s request was prompted by the court’s resolution of those issues in
    connection with the seventh administrative review of the AD Order on activated carbon.
    See Def.’s Mot. for a Voluntary Remand, ECF No. 72; Jacobi Carbons AB v. United
    States (“Jacobi (AR7) I”), 41 CIT ___, 
    222 F. Supp. 3d 1159
    (2017). In that opinion, the
    court held that Commerce’s economic comparability determination lacked reasoned
    analysis and the agency had failed to persuade that total exports, absent evidence
    regarding the influence of those exports on world trade, was a permissible method of
    construing the term “significant producer.” Jacobi (AR7) 
    I, 222 F. Supp. 3d at 1176-82
    .
    4 Jacobi (AR8) I presents background information on this case, familiarity with which is
    presumed.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                            Page 5
    On October 24, 2018, Commerce filed the remand redetermination at issue here.
    See 2nd Remand Results. Therein, Commerce circled back to export quantity as its
    basis for finding that Thailand is a significant producer of comparable merchandise, see
    
    id. at 4-7;
    further explained its selection of Thai surrogate values for carbonized material
    and hydrochloric acid, see 
    id. at 8-15;
    revised its surrogate value selections for coal tar
    and financial ratios using data from South Africa and Romania, respectively, see 
    id. at 16-19,
    20-24; and reconsidered the basis for its VAT adjustment while continuing to
    adjust Jacobi’s constructed export price for VAT, see 
    id. at 26-37.
    Commerce’s
    redetermination reduced Jacobi’s weighted-average dumping margin from $1.756 per
    kilogram to $0.44 per kilogram. Compare 
    id. at 51,
    with Final Results, 81 Fed. Reg. at
    62,089. The reduction in Jacobi’s margin also reduced the weighted-average dumping
    margin assigned to the non-individually-examined respondents eligible for a separate
    rate from $1.357 per kilogram to $0.34 per kilogram. Compare 2nd Remand Results at
    52, with Final Results, 81 Fed. Reg. at 62,089.
    Jacobi and CAC filed comments opposing the 2nd Remand Results with respect
    to Thailand as a significant producer, the surrogate values selected for carbonized
    material and hydrochloric acid, and the VAT adjustment. See Pls.’ Comments on
    Commerce’s Second Remand Determination (“Jacobi’s Opp’n Cmts.”), ECF No. 127;
    Consol. Pls. Carbon Activated Corporation, Ningxia Mineral and Chemical Limited,
    Shanxi DMD Corporation, Shanxi Industry Technology Trading Co., Ltd., Shanxi
    Sincere Industrial Co., Ltd., Tianjin Channel Filters Co., Ltd., and Tianjin Maijin
    Industries Co., Ltd. Comments in Opp’n to Second Remand (“CAC’s Opp’n Cmts.”),
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 6
    ECF No. 126. No party challenged the 2nd Remand Results with respect to the
    surrogate values selected for coal tar or the financial ratios. Defendant United States
    (“the Government”) and Defendant–Intervenors Calgon Carbon Corp. and Cabot Norit
    Americas, Inc. (“Calgon”) filed comments in support of the 2nd Remand Results.
    See Def.’s Reply to Comments on the Second Remand Results (“Def.’s Reply Cmts.”),
    ECF No. 131; Def.–Ints.’ Comments in Supp. of U.S. Department of Commerce Second
    Remand Redetermination (“Def–Ints.’ Reply Cmts.”), ECF No. 132.
    For the following reasons, the court remands Commerce’s determination that
    Thailand is a significant producer of comparable merchandise and directs Commerce to
    reconsider its selection of a primary surrogate country. Because Commerce relied, in
    part, on its preference to use data from the primary surrogate country when making its
    surrogate value selections for carbonized material and hydrochloric acid, see 2nd
    Remand Results at 7, 15, the court also remands Commerce’s surrogate value
    selections. The court sustains Commerce’s VAT adjustment.
    JURISDICTION AND STANDARD OF REVIEW
    The court has jurisdiction pursuant to § 516A(a)(2)(B)(iii) of the Tariff Act of 1930,
    as amended, 19 U.S.C. § 1516a(a)(2)(B)(iii)(2012), 5 and 28 U.S.C. § 1581(c)(2012).
    The court will uphold an agency determination that is supported by substantial
    evidence and otherwise in accordance with law. 19 U.S.C. § 1516a(b)(1)(B)(i). The
    5 All citations to the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended, are to Title 19 of the U.S. Code,
    and all references to the United States Code are to the 2012 edition, unless otherwise
    stated.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                            Page 7
    court's review of Commerce's interpretation and implementation of a statutory scheme
    is guided by Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    (1984). See Apex Frozen Foods Private Ltd. v. United States, 
    862 F.3d 1322
    , 1329
    (Fed. Cir. 2017). First, the court must determine “whether Congress has directly spoken
    to the precise question at issue.” 
    Id. (quoting Chevron,
    467 U.S. at 842). If Congress's
    intent is clear, “that is the end of the matter,” and the court “must give effect to the
    unambiguously expressed intent of Congress.” 
    Id. (quoting Chevron,
    467 U.S. at 842-
    43). Only “if the statute is silent or ambiguous,” must the court determine whether the
    agency's action “is based on a permissible construction of the statute.” 
    Id. (quoting Chevron,
    467 U.S. at 843). Additionally, “[t]he results of a redetermination pursuant to
    court remand are also reviewed for compliance with the court’s remand order.”
    SolarWorld Ams., Inc. v. United States, 41 CIT ___, ___, 
    273 F. Supp. 3d 1314
    , 1317
    (2017) (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).
    DISCUSSION
    I.   Significant Producer of Comparable Merchandise
    A. Legal Framework
    An antidumping duty is “the amount by which the normal value exceeds the
    export price (or the constructed export price) for the merchandise.” 19 U.S.C. § 1673.
    When an antidumping duty proceeding involves a nonmarket economy country,
    Commerce determines normal value by valuing the factors of production 6 in a surrogate
    6The factors of production include but are not limited to: “(A) hours of labor required, (B)
    quantities of raw materials employed, (C) amounts of energy and other utilities
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                          Page 8
    country, see 
    id. § 1677b(c)(1),
    and those values are referred to as “surrogate values.”
    In selecting surrogate values, Commerce must use “the best available information” that
    is, “to the extent possible,” from a market economy country or countries that are
    economically comparable to the nonmarket economy country and are “significant
    producers of comparable merchandise.” 
    Id. § 1677b(c)(1),
    (4). Commerce generally
    values all factors of production in a single surrogate country. 7
    Commerce has adopted a four-step approach to selecting a primary surrogate
    country. Pursuant thereto:
    (1) the Office of Policy (“OP”) assembles a list of potential surrogate
    countries that are at a comparable level of economic development to the
    [non-market economy] country; (2) Commerce identifies countries from the
    list with producers of comparable merchandise; (3) Commerce determines
    whether any of the countries which produce comparable merchandise are
    significant producers of that comparable merchandise; and (4) if more
    than one country satisfies steps (1)–(3), Commerce will select the country
    with the best factors data.
    Jiaxing Brother Fastener Co., Ltd. v. United States, 
    822 F.3d 1289
    , 1293 (Fed. Cir.
    2016) (citation omitted); see also Import Admin., U.S. Dep't of Commerce, Non-Market
    Economy Surrogate Country Selection Process, Policy Bulletin 04.1 (2004), available at
    http://enforcement.trade.gov/policy/bull04–1.html (last visited Feb. 27, 2019) (“Policy
    Bulletin 04.1”).
    consumed, and (D) representative capital cost, including depreciation.” 19 U.S.C.
    § 1677b(c)(3).
    7 See 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(2) (excepting labor). But see Antidumping Methodologies
    in Proceedings Involving Non-Market Economies: Valuing the Factor of Production:
    Labor, 76 Fed. Reg. 36,092 (Dep’t Commerce June 21, 2011) (expressing a preference
    to value labor based on industry-specific labor rates from the primary surrogate
    country).
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                          Page 9
    Neither the statute nor Commerce’s regulations define “significant
    producer.” See 19 U.S.C. § 1677b; 19 C.F.R. § 351.408. However, in its Policy Bulletin
    04.1, Commerce described its practice for evaluating significant producer countries:
    [t]he extent to which a country is a significant producer should not be
    judged against the [subject non-market economy] country’s production
    level or the comparative production of the five or six countries [that are
    considered potential surrogate countries]. Instead, a judgement [sic]
    should be made consistent with the characteristics of world production of,
    and trade in, comparable merchandise (subject to the availability of data on
    these characteristics). Since these characteristics are specific to the
    merchandise in question, the standard for “significant producer” will vary
    from case to case. For example, if . . . there are ten large producers and a
    variety of small producers, “significant producer” could be interpreted to
    mean one of the top ten. If, in the example above, there is also a middle-
    size group of producers, then “significant producer” could be interpreted as
    one of the top ten or middle group. In another case, there may not be
    adequate data available from major producing countries. In such a case,
    “significant producer” could mean a country that is a net exporter, even
    though the selected surrogate country may not be one of the world's top
    producers.
    Policy Bulletin 04.1 at 3.
    Because the term is otherwise undefined and ambiguous, the court must assess
    whether Commerce’s interpretation of significant producer “is based on a permissible
    construction of the statute.” Apex Frozen 
    Foods, 862 F.3d at 1329
    (quoting 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 843
    ). To effectuate judicial review, Commerce must provide “a reasoned
    analysis or explanation for [its] decision” so the court may “determine whether a
    particular decision is arbitrary, capricious, or an abuse of discretion.” Thai I-Mei Frozen
    Foods Co., Ltd. v. United States, 
    616 F.3d 1300
    , 1304 (Fed. Cir. 2010) (citation
    omitted).
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 10
    B. Commerce’s Interpretation of “Significant Producer” in This Proceeding
    The 2nd Remand Results reflect Commerce’s third effort to justify its
    determination that Thailand is a significant producer of comparable merchandise.
    Therein, Commerce explained that it would “compar[e] data for comparable
    merchandise to establish whether any country that is at the same level of economic
    development as [the PRC] was: a) a significant net exporter; or b) a major exporter to
    the United States.” 2nd Remand Results at 5-6 & n.25 (citing Yantai Oriental Juice Co.
    v. United States, 
    27 CIT 477
    , 481 (2003)) (emphasis added). To that end, Commerce
    noted that the record contained Global Trade Atlas (“GTA”) import and export data for
    the potential surrogate countries as well as Malaysia and the Philippines, and 2014
    UNCOMTRADE data for 65 activated carbon exporting countries. 
    Id. at 6.
    The GTA
    data indicated that Malaysia and the Philippines were net exporters, but Thailand was
    not. 
    Id. Commerce did
    not, however, examine whether Thailand (or any of the potential
    surrogate countries) was “a major exporter to the United States,” its stated alternative
    metric for evaluating significant production. See 
    id. Rather, Commerce
    discussed
    Thailand’s total global exports. See 
    id. at 6-7.
    Commerce prefaced its discussion of export quantity by explaining that although
    “[t]he [c]ourt has suggested that significant production means production ‘having or
    likely to have influence or effect’ on world trade[,] . . . Commerce instead interprets
    ‘significant’ to mean a noticeably or measurably large amount.” 
    Id. at 6
    & n.31 (quoting
    Jacobi (AR8) 
    I, 313 F. Supp. 3d at 1358
    & n.26). According to the 2014
    UNCOMTRADE and GTA data sets, Thailand exported more than nine million kilograms
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                       Page 11
    (“kg”) of activated carbon worldwide. See 
    id. at 6
    & n.32 (citations omitted). Commerce
    characterized this amount as “noticeably or measurably large.” 
    Id. at 7.
    Commerce
    further characterized Thailand as “among the top global exporters of activated carbon”
    because it is the 14th largest global exporter of activated carbon according to the 2014
    UNCOMTRADE data, with 51 countries exporting less than Thailand, and 38 countries
    exporting less than one million kilograms. 8 
    Id. at 7,
    39. Thailand also was the largest
    exporter among the potential surrogate countries. 
    Id. at 7.
    Commerce relied on this
    evidence to conclude that Thailand is a significant producer of comparable
    merchandise. See 
    id. at 7,
    38, 39-40.
    C. Parties’ Contentions
    CAC contends that Commerce’s interpretation of significant as “noticeably or
    measurably large” is “unreasonably subjective.” CAC’s Opp’n Cmts. at 4. CAC also
    contends that the 2014 UNCOMTRADE data show that the top nine countries on the list
    may be considered “significant exporters” and, thereafter, the remaining countries,
    including Thailand, each account for less than two percent of total global exports. 
    Id. at 6
    -7. CAC further contends that Thailand’s status as a net importer undermines
    Commerce’s reliance on total exports. 
    Id. at 4-5.
    9
    8 The 2014 UNCOMTRADE data show that 40 countries exported less than one million
    kilograms of activated carbon, and 38 countries exported less than one million U.S.
    dollars’ worth. See Jacobi’s Comments on Economic Comparability (July 20, 2015)
    (“Jacobi’s EC Cmts.”), Attach. E, PR 82-83, PJA Tab 18, ECF No. 92-3 (2014
    UNCOMTRADE data). This minor error does not impact the court’s analysis.
    9 Jacobi did not comment on this issue.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 12
    The Government and Calgon contend that Commerce has permissibly
    interpreted an ambiguous statutory term and the 2014 UNCOMTRADE data provide
    substantial evidence that Thailand is a significant producer. Def.’s Reply Cmts. at 5-6;
    Def.-Ints.’ Reply Cmts. at 7-8.
    D. Commerce’s Determination is Remanded for Reconsideration
    Upon consideration of the agency’s second remand redetermination and the
    briefing to the court, Commerce’s finding that Thailand is a significant producer must be
    remanded. Commerce has effectively divorced the term “significant” from the term
    “production” and applied its interpretation of “significant” without the context and
    explanation necessary to ensure that its determination is not arbitrary. Although
    Commerce is within its discretion to define “significant” as “noticeably or measurably
    large,” see Juancheng Kangtai Chem. Co., Ltd. v. United States, Slip Op. 17-3, 
    2017 WL 218910
    , at *4 (CIT Jan. 19, 2017) (holding that Commerce’s corresponding
    interpretation of the term “significant” merited Chevron deference), Commerce has not
    supplied the court with a well-reasoned explanation supporting its consideration of total
    exports as a substitute for production. Overall, the agency has failed to interpret or
    apply the statutory criterion in its entirety and has not supported its determination that
    Thailand is a significant producer with substantial evidence.
    Commerce’s Policy Bulletin 04.1 does not discuss the use of total exports to
    identify significant producers. It indicates that, in the absence of production data, a
    “‘significant producer’ could mean a country that is a net exporter.” Policy Bulletin 04.1
    at 3 (emphasis added); cf. H.R. Rep. No. 100–576, at 590 (1988) (Conf. Rep.), reprinted
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 13
    in 1988 U.S.C.C.A.N. 1547, 1623 (“The term ‘significant producer’ includes any country
    that is a significant net exporter.”). 10 The use of net exports provides at least some
    assurance that a country’s exports do not consist entirely of transshipped imports.
    When a country imports more than it exports, that assurance is lacking. Here, Thailand
    imported 696,685 kg more activated carbon than it exported during the relevant period.
    See Pet’rs’ Comments on Surrogate Country Selection (Aug. 31, 2015), Attach. 4, PR
    155, PJA Tab 33, ECF No. 92-5 (Thailand’s import and export quantities). Commerce’s
    failure to address this aspect of the record undermines its reliance on total exports as a
    substitute for production. See Nippon Steel Corp. v. United States, 
    337 F.3d 1373
    ,
    1379 (Fed. Cir. 2003) (the court’s review must consider “the record as a whole,
    including evidence that supports as well as evidence that fairly detracts from the
    substantiality of the evidence”) (internal quotation marks and citation omitted). 11
    Commerce also failed to adequately explain its determination that Thailand’s total
    export quantity was significant. While Commerce appears to suggest that countries
    ranked among the top 15 exporters represent the “top global exporters,” see 2nd
    Remand Results at 7, 39, the lack of further explanation or any clear delineation
    10 While Commerce correctly notes that the legislative history’s reference to significant
    net exports does not preclude reliance on other metrics, 2nd Remand Results at 5,
    Commerce must still explain why its chosen metric represents a permissible
    construction of the term “significant producer.”
    11 Indeed, in the case upon which Commerce relied to support its consideration of
    significant net exports and major exports to the United States, the agency explained that
    India was not a significant producer because it did not fulfill either of those criteria and
    was a net importer of subject merchandise. See 
    Yantai, 27 CIT at 481
    ; 2nd Remand
    Results at 6 & n.25.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                        Page 14
    between countries ranked proximately above and below 15 leaves the court unable to
    discern the reasons for Commerce’s conclusion. See NMB Singapore Ltd. v. United
    States, 
    557 F.3d 1316
    , 1319 (Fed. Cir. 2009) (noting that although Commerce’s
    “explanations do not have to be perfect, the path of Commerce's decision must be
    reasonably discernable to a reviewing court”); Jacobi’s EC Cmts., Attach. E. 12
    Commerce’s seemingly arbitrary delineation contrasts with Policy Bulletin 04.1’s
    recognition of the contextual nature of the significant producer determination and
    corresponding examples that evaluate significance in terms of the particular
    characteristics of overall global trade in the subject merchandise. See Policy Bulletin
    04.1 at 3 (noting, “[f]or example, [that] if there are just three producers of comparable
    merchandise in the world, then arguably any commercially meaningful production is
    significant”).
    Commerce’s assertion that Thailand’s export quantity is “noticeably large” in
    comparison to countries exporting less than one million kilograms is also unavailing.
    See 2nd Remand Results at 39. While perhaps true, the import of this observation for
    12 CAC asserts that the line between significant and insignificant exports is more
    suitably drawn after Mozambique, ranked ninth with 35,035,750 kg of activated carbon
    exports, because the volume of exports decreases thereafter to roughly 15,000,000 kg,
    or from five to ten percent of global exports to one to two percent of global exports.
    CAC’s Opp’n Cmts. at 6. The Government and Calgon respond to CAC’s assertion by
    attempting to place Thailand within the “middle-sized group of producers” contemplated
    by Policy Bulletin 04.1. See Def.’s Reply Cmts. at 6; Def.-Ints.’ Reply Cmts. at 8; Policy
    Bulletin 04.1 at 3. Regardless of the degree of merit in the Government’s and Calgon’s
    approach to interpreting the available evidence, it departs from Commerce’s decision,
    and the court may not accept “post hoc rationalizations for agency action.” Burlington
    Truck Lines, Inc. v. United States, 
    371 U.S. 156
    , 168–69 (1962).
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                           Page 15
    purposes of Commerce’s significant producer determination is unclear. For example,
    Chile’s export quantity of 2,200 kg is “noticeably larger” than El Salvador’s 41 kg export
    quantity. See Jacobi’s EC Cmts., Attach. E. Chile, which is ranked 60th and accounts
    for roughly 0.00027 percent of total global production, would not be considered a
    significant producer on the basis of export quantity. See 
    id. Commerce’s reliance
    on
    particular rankings or isolated data points highlights the relevance of appropriate
    contextual analysis in order to determine whether descriptors such as “large” or
    “significant” reasonably apply.
    Lastly, Commerce’s reliance on Thailand’s status as “the largest exporter of
    activated carbon among the countries identified as being at the same level of economic
    development as China” lacks merit. See 2nd Remand Results at 7. As the Government
    points out, Commerce’s practice is not to evaluate “[t]he extent to which a country is a
    significant producer . . . against . . . the comparative production of the five or six
    countries on [Commerce’s] surrogate country list.” Def.’s Reply Cmts. at 6 (quoting
    Policy Bulletin 04.1 at 3). Commerce’s policy recognizes that a country’s level of
    economic development is irrelevant to whether that country’s production (or exports) of
    a given product may be considered “significant.” Nevertheless, while Commerce is not
    irrevocably committed to this statement of policy, its diametrically opposite approach in
    this case, absent any explanation, cannot be sustained. Accordingly, Thailand’s ranking
    among this group of countries is not substantial evidence that Thailand is a significant
    producer of comparable merchandise.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                       Page 16
    Commerce has now had three opportunities to justify its selection of Thailand as
    the primary surrogate country. Once again, Commerce has failed to provide a reasoned
    explanation or substantial evidence supporting its determination that Thailand is a
    significant producer of comparable merchandise. Commerce’s reliance on Thailand’s
    export quantity and various rankings among global exporters is untethered to its own
    statements of practice regarding the significant producer determination and appears
    arbitrary. While Commerce is not bound by its statements of practice, it must explain its
    departures therefrom and has seemed unable. Therefore, the court finds that the
    record does not support the selection of Thailand as a significant producer. On remand,
    Commerce must identify a surrogate country, whether from its list of countries at the
    same level of economic development as the PRC or another country at a comparable
    level of economic development not on the list, which meets the statutory criteria and is
    supported by substantial evidence. Because Commerce justified its selection of
    surrogate values for carbonized material and hydrochloric acid, in part, on the basis that
    they are derived from Thailand as the primary surrogate, Commerce must revisit these
    surrogate values on remand.
    II.   Value-Added Tax
    A. The Application of Section 1677a(c)(2)(B) to Nonmarket Economies
    When calculating export price and constructed export price, Commerce may
    deduct “the amount, if included in such price, of any export tax, duty, or other charge
    imposed by the exporting country on the exportation of the subject merchandise to the
    United States, other than an export tax, duty, or other charge described in section
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                        Page 17
    1677(6)(C) of this title.” 13 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(B). Such price adjustments must be
    “reasonably attributable to the subject merchandise.” 19 C.F.R. § 351.401(c).
    Prior to 2012, Commerce did not apply 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(B) in
    proceedings involving imports from nonmarket economy (“NME”) countries. Commerce
    reasoned that “pervasive government intervention in NMEs precluded proper valuation
    of taxes paid by NME respondents to NME governments.” Methodological Change for
    Implementation of Section 772(c)(2)(B) of the Tariff Act of 1930, as Amended, In Certain
    Non–Market Economy Antidumping Proceedings, 77 Fed. Reg. 36,481, 36,482 (Dep't
    Commerce June 19, 2012) (“Methodological Change”) (citing Pure Magnesium and
    Alloy Magnesium From the Russian Federation, 60 Fed. Reg. 16,440 (Dep’t Commerce
    Mar. 30, 1995) (notice of final determination of sales at less than fair value) (“Pure
    Magnesium from Russia”)). Commerce had taken the position that nonmarket economy
    countries are
    governed by a presumption of widespread intervention and influence in
    the economic activities of enterprises[ and a]n export tax charged for one
    purpose may be offset by government transfers provided for another
    purpose. . . . To make a deduction for export taxes imposed by a NME
    government would unreasonably isolate one part of the web of
    transactions between government and producer.
    
    Id. (citation omitted).
    Commerce’s declination to apply section 1677a(c)(2)(B) in NME
    proceedings accorded with its former practice of declining to countervail subsidies paid
    by a NME government to a NME producer. See 
    id. Commerce reasoned
    that
    13Section 1677(6)(C) concerns “export taxes, duties, or other charges levied on the
    export of merchandise to the United States specifically intended to offset the
    countervailable subsidy received” and is not relevant here.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                      Page 18
    “[a]ttempts to isolate individual government interventions in this setting—whether they
    be transfers from the government or from exporters to the government—make no
    sense.” 
    Id. (citation omitted).
    As the countries that Commerce considered to be nonmarket economies
    evolved, so did Commerce’s practices. In 2002, Commerce revoked Russia’s status as
    a NME country. See Silicon Metal From the Russian Federation, 68 Fed. Reg. 6,885,
    6,887 (Dep’t Commerce Feb. 11, 2003) (notice of final determination of sales at less
    than fair value) (citation omitted). In 2007, Commerce determined that China (and
    Vietnam), while still regarded as NME countries, had nevertheless become sufficiently
    dissimilar from the centrally-planned economies of the Soviet-era such that Commerce
    could determine whether those governments bestowed countervailable subsidies on
    certain companies or industries. See Methodological Change, 77 Fed. Reg. at 36,482;
    Issues and Decision Mem. for the Final Determination in the Countervailing Duty
    Investigation of Coated Free Sheet Paper from the People’s Republic of China, C-570-
    907 (Oct. 17, 2007) at Cmt. 1, available at https://enforcement.trade.govfrn/summary
    /prc/E7-21046-1.pdf (last visited Feb. 27, 2019). 14 In accordance with its determination
    that countervailable subsidies from China and Vietnam could be measured, Commerce
    14Commerce’s initial application of the countervailing duty laws to NME countries was
    challenged in court and held unlawful. See GPX Int’l Tire Corp. v. United States, 
    666 F.3d 732
    , 745 (Fed. Cir. 2011), reh’g granted, 
    678 F.3d 1308
    (Fed. Cir. 2012).
    However, Congress subsequently amended the statute to confirm that Commerce was
    authorized to apply the countervailing duty laws to nonmarket economy countries. See
    Application of Countervailing Duty Provisions to NonMarket Economy Countries, Pub. L.
    No. 112–99, 126 Stat. 265 (2012); 19 U.S.C. §§ 1671(f), 1677f–1(f).
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 19
    reconsidered whether taxes, duties and other charges paid by NME producers to those
    NME governments could likewise be identified and measured. See Methodological
    Change, 77 Fed. Reg. at 36,482.
    In 2012, Commerce concluded that it could now identify and measure certain
    taxes paid by Chinese producers to the Chinese government and announced that,
    henceforth, it would consider whether the PRC “has imposed an export tax, duty, or
    other charge upon export of the subject merchandise during the period of investigation
    or the period of review,” including, for example, “an export tax or VAT that is not fully
    refunded upon exportation.” 
    Id. at 36,482
    (internal quotation marks omitted). Thus,
    when the PRC does so, and “the respondent was not exempted, [Commerce] will
    reduce the respondent's export price and constructed export price accordingly, by the
    amount of the tax, duty or charge paid, but not rebated.” 
    Id. at 36,483.
    When “the
    export tax, VAT, duty, or other charge” is “a fixed percentage of the price,” Commerce
    announced that it would “adjust the export price or constructed export price downward
    by the same percentage.” 
    Id. “[B]ecause these
    are taxes affirmatively imposed by the
    Chinese . . . government[],” Commerce “presume[s] that they are also collected.” 
    Id. B. Commerce’s
    Application of the Statute to Chinese VAT
    Pursuant to the Methodological Change, for the Final Results, Commerce
    reduced Jacobi’s constructed export price by an amount it described as “irrecoverable
    VAT.” I&D Mem. at 7. According to Commerce, irrecoverable VAT constituted an
    “export tax, duty, or other charge” pursuant to section 1677a(c)(2)(B) because it
    represented the amount of VAT Jacobi paid on inputs and raw materials used in the
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                       Page 20
    production of activated carbon (“input VAT”) that was nonrefundable when those inputs
    and raw materials were consumed in the production of exported subject merchandise.
    
    Id. at 7-8.
    15 Commerce calculated irrecoverable VAT by multiplying the free on board
    (“FOB”) value of the subject merchandise by the difference between the standard VAT
    rate (here, 17 percent) and the applicable VAT rebate rate (here, zero). 
    Id. at 8.
    When
    Jacobi’s entered values were less than an “estimated customs value,” which Commerce
    defined as “ex-factory net U.S. price plus foreign movement expenses,” Commerce
    applied the irrecoverable VAT rate to the estimated customs value as a proxy for the
    FOB China port value. 
    Id. at 9-10.
    In Jacobi (AR8) I, the court remanded the VAT adjustment for reconsideration in
    accordance with its resolution of this issue in the seventh administrative review. 
    16 313 F. Supp. 3d at 1373
    . In that proceeding, the court found that section 1677a(c)(2)(B)
    was ambiguous. See Jacobi (AR7) 
    I, 222 F. Supp. 3d at 1186
    –87. Because the statute
    is ambiguous, pursuant to Chevron prong two, Commerce could reasonably determine
    that an input VAT that becomes nonrefundable when the finished product is exported
    15 Commerce explained that
    [i]n a typical VAT system, companies do not incur VAT expense for
    exports. Instead, they receive on export a full rebate of the VAT they pay
    on purchases of inputs used in the production of exports (“input VAT”),
    and, in the case of domestic sales, the company can credit [input VAT] . . .
    against the VAT they collect from customers [“output VAT”].
    I&D Mem. at 7. In the PRC, however, “some portion of the input VAT that a company
    pays on purchases of inputs used in the production of exports is not refunded.” 
    Id. 16 The
    Government had acknowledged that there were no material differences in
    Commerce’s VAT calculations in the seventh and eighth administrative reviews. See
    Jacobi (AR8) 
    I, 313 F. Supp. 3d at 1373
    .
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 21
    constitutes, at the very least, an “other charge” that is “imposed by the exporting country
    on the exportation of the subject merchandise” because it remains recoverable (as a
    credit or offset against output VAT) until the product is exported. 
    Id. The court
    further
    found that Commerce’s determination that certain of Jacobi’s entered values were
    unreliable was supported by substantial evidence and thus affirmed its use of estimated
    customs values. 
    Id. at 1190–92.
    The court, however, remanded Commerce’s VAT
    calculation because the agency’s application of the irrecoverable VAT rate to the price
    of the finished good potentially overstated an adjustment intended to account for
    unrefunded input VAT. 
    Id. at 1192-94.
    In its first redetermination in the seventh administrative review, Commerce
    continued to characterize its adjustment as accounting for irrecoverable VAT (i.e.,
    unrefunded input VAT). See Jacobi Carbons AB v. United States (“Jacobi (AR7) II”), 42
    CIT ___, 
    313 F. Supp. 3d 1308
    , 1341 (2018). As the basis for its adjustment, however,
    Commerce pointed to the 17 percent output VAT rate applicable to Jacobi’s foreign and
    domestic sales and found that it was, thus, included in Jacobi’s U.S. price. See 
    id. The court
    again remanded the adjustment, this time because Commerce’s revised
    explanation introduced an inconsistency between the calculation methodology (based
    on output VAT) and the theory underlying the adjustment (unrefunded input VAT). 
    Id. at 1341-44.
    Pointing to the record on remand, the court further instructed:
    [t]o the extent that Commerce continues to justify the adjustment as
    accounting for irrecoverable VAT defined as unrefunded input VAT,
    Commerce must address record evidence demonstrating that Jacobi, in
    fact, recovers the input VAT it incurs by the offset it takes before remitting
    the output VAT it collects. . . .
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                       Page 22
    On the other hand, if Commerce asserts that the adjustment is based on
    an export tax due to Jacobi’s collection of output VAT, Commerce must (a)
    address the record evidence regarding Jacobi's offset for input VAT paid
    on inputs taken against the output VAT collected, and (b) explain why the
    VAT adjustment is properly made on the basis of an estimated customs
    value instead of the FOB value on which the PRC assesses it.
    
    Id. at 1342-43
    (internal citations omitted).
    In addition to reconsidering its VAT adjustment in accordance with Jacobi (AR7) I
    and Jacobi (AR7) II, in a subsequent order, the court instructed Commerce to include in
    its redetermination consideration of Aristocraft of Am., LLC v. United States, 42 CIT
    ___, 
    331 F. Supp. 3d 1372
    , 1379 (2018), in which that court posed several questions for
    Commerce to address on remand regarding the evidentiary basis for the adjustment.
    See Order (Aug. 22, 2018), ECF No. 120. Commerce’s explanation for the VAT
    adjustment as discussed in Aristocraft differed significantly from the explanation offered
    in this proceeding.
    In its second remand redetermination in this action, Commerce changed the
    basis for its VAT adjustment from irrecoverable VAT (i.e. unrefunded input VAT) to the
    17 percent output VAT imposed on foreign and domestic activated carbon sales. 2nd
    Remand Results at 30-31. Commerce supported its revised explanation by way of
    reference to a more recent iteration of Chinese VAT law, the relevance of which it had
    not previously considered. 
    Id. at 27-28
    & n.133 (citing Notice of the Ministry of Finance
    and the State Administration of Taxation on VAT and Consumption Tax Policies for
    Exported Goods and Labor Services (“2012 VAT Notice”)); see also Jacobi’s Second
    Suppl. Sec. C Questionnaire Resp. (Nov. 25, 2015), Ex. C-6, PR 266, PRJA Tab 3 (the
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                        Page 23
    2012 VAT Notice). Commerce’s revised explanation recognizes that Chinese VAT law
    treats products differently depending on their eligibility for an export VAT refund. See
    
    id. at 26-30.
    Pursuant to that law, companies that produce exported goods that are ineligible
    for an export VAT rebate do not incur a reduction in the input VAT amount credited
    against the output VAT. See 2nd Remand Results at 29-30. Export sales of such
    goods are treated as domestic sales and are, thus, subject to the collection of output
    VAT. See 
    id. at 29-30
    & n.136 (citation omitted); 2012 VAT Notice, Art. 7.2(1)). In
    contrast, companies that produce exported goods that are eligible for a VAT rebate
    incur “a reduction in or offset to the input VAT that can be credited against output VAT”
    when the company calculates its net VAT payable amount. 2nd Remand Results at 27;
    see also 2012 VAT Notice, Art. 5.1(1). Export sales of such products are not subject to
    output VAT; instead, these companies incur a reduction in the input VAT amount they
    may credit against the output VAT collected solely on domestic sales. See 2nd
    Remand Results at 29. That reduction in the input VAT credit represents “irrecoverable
    VAT.” See 
    id. at 28-29.
    In accordance with the foregoing description of Chinese VAT law, Commerce
    explained that activated carbon is one of the products that is ineligible for an export
    rebate. Consequently, Commerce found that producers of activated carbon do not incur
    a reduction in the amount of input VAT creditable against output VAT. 
    Id. at 30;
    see
    also 2012 VAT Notice, Art. 7.1(1). Instead, export sales of activated carbon are treated
    in the same manner as domestic sales and are subject to the collection of output VAT.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                        Page 24
    2nd Remand Results at 30 & n.141 (citations omitted). Commerce concluded that it
    previously erred in adjusting Jacobi’s constructed export price by an amount purportedly
    representing irrecoverable VAT. 
    Id. at 30-31.
    Commerce nevertheless retained the
    downward adjustment to Jacobi’s U.S. price to account for the 17 percent output VAT,
    which the agency concluded represented an “export tax, duty, or other charge imposed
    by the exporting country on the exportation of the subject merchandise to the United
    States” pursuant to section 1677a(c)(2)(B). 
    Id. at 31.
    Commerce explained that
    deducting output VAT from Jacobi’s constructed export price ensured the calculation of
    a tax-neutral dumping margin because normal value in a nonmarket economy
    proceeding is based on the factors of production, which are VAT-exclusive. 
    Id. at 30
    &
    n.139.
    Commerce further noted that certain questions raised by the Aristocraft court
    concerning the calculation of irrecoverable VAT were now irrelevant to Commerce’s
    adjustment in this case. 
    Id. at 31-32.
    Additionally, in response to the court’s instruction
    that any assessment based on output VAT should include consideration of record
    evidence regarding Jacobi’s ability to offset the output VAT with input VAT, see Jacobi
    (AR7) 
    II, 313 F. Supp. 3d at 1343
    , the agency explained that “Commerce’s adjustment
    is not intended to account for the total amount of net VAT creditable,” 2nd Remand
    Results at 34. Rather, pursuant to the Methodological Change, “when the ‘export tax,
    VAT, duty, or other charge [is] a fixed percentage,’ Commerce ‘will adjust the export
    price or constructed export price downward by the same percentage.’” 
    Id. at 35
    (citing
    Methodological Change, 77 Fed. Reg. at 36,483).
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                       Page 25
    Commerce calculated the VAT adjustment pursuant to the following formula set
    forth in Chinese law:
    output VAT = FOB * exchange rate / (1 + legal VAT rate) * legal VAT rate.
    
    Id. at 36
    & n.164 (citing Jacobi’s Sec. C Questionnaire Resp. (Aug. 14, 2015) (“Jacobi’s
    § CQR”), Ex. SC-18, CR 56, CRJA Tab 6; 2012 VAT Notice). Commerce reconsidered
    its prior reliance on estimated customs values to calculate the adjustment and instead
    used Jacobi’s entered values because those “are the FOB China port values used in the
    Chinese tax authorities’ output VAT calculations.” 
    Id. at 36
    & n.165 (citation omitted).
    Commerce thus adjusted Jacobi’s U.S. price downwards by the output VAT amount
    calculated using the above formula and Jacobi’s entered values. 
    Id. at 36
    .
    Commerce further explained that because Jacobi’s sales of subject merchandise
    are subject to output VAT, Jacobi’s U.S. price “necessarily include[s]” output VAT. 
    Id. at 35
    . In response to Jacobi’s argument that Commerce had not shown its sales price to
    include output VAT because the invoice on the record of the remand proceeding does
    not reflect the collection of output VAT, Commerce pointed to Jacobi’s questionnaire
    response explaining that its sales to foreign and domestic buyers are subject to 17
    percent output VAT and Jacobi’s calculation of its net VAT payable that includes
    amounts representing the collection of output VAT for each POR month. 
    Id. at 49
    &
    nn.207-08 (citations omitted).
    C. Commerce’s Authority to Deduct Output VAT from U.S. Price
    Jacobi contends that “Commerce’s revised reasoning still fails to satisfy the
    statutory requirement for an adjustment” pursuant to section 1677a(c)(2)(B). Jacobi’s
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                          Page 26
    Opp’n Cmts. at 13. Jacobi does not, however, develop any particular argument that
    output VAT does not fulfill the statutory criteria of an “export tax, duty, or other charge
    imposed by the exporting country on the exportation of the subject merchandise to the
    United States.” Nevertheless, the court recognizes that since it issued Jacobi AR7 I,
    two opinions from the court have called into question Commerce’s legal authority to
    adjust export price or constructed export price to account for VAT (whether
    irrecoverable or not) pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(B). See Qingdao Qihang Tyre
    Co., Ltd. v. United States, 42 CIT ___, ___, 
    308 F. Supp. 3d 1329
    , 1338-47 (2018);
    China Mfrs. Alliance, LLC v. United States, Slip Op. 19-7, 
    2019 WL 221237
    , at *4-8 (CIT
    Jan. 16, 2019). The court does not find those opinions persuasive and declines to
    follow them.
    In Qingdao and China Manufacturers, the court, upon reviewing the statute in its
    current form and as enacted prior to the adoption of the Uruguay Round Agreements
    Act (“URAA”), 17 concluded, pursuant to Chevron prong one, that section 1677a(c)(2)(B)
    is unambiguous and does not permit Commerce to adjust export price or constructed
    export price for VAT imposed on export sales indirectly through an input VAT that
    becomes irrecoverable or, by extension, directly through an output VAT. 
    Qingdao, 308 F. Supp. 3d at 1338-42
    , 1346; China Mfrs., 
    2019 WL 221237
    , at *4-8. The court
    characterized VAT as a domestic tax that is distinct from an export tax imposed on the
    17On December 8, 1994, Congress enacted the URAA, including section 1677a in its
    current form. See Uruguay Round Agreements Act, Pub. L. No. 103–465, § 223, 108
    Stat. 4809, 4876 (1994).
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                          Page 27
    exportation of finished goods. See 
    Qingdao, 308 F. Supp. 3d at 1339
    , 1341, 1345;
    China Mfrs., 
    2019 WL 221237
    , at *6. The court reasoned that an “export tax, duty, or
    other charge” is “limited to one that is ‘imposed by the exporting country on the
    exportation of the subject merchandise to the United States,’” 
    Qingdao, 308 F. Supp. 3d at 1343
    (quoting 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(B)) and is, thus, “by definition” not included “in
    the home-market price,” id.; see also China Mfrs., 
    2019 WL 221237
    , at *4.
    Previously, when considering Commerce’s irrecoverable VAT theory for the
    adjustment, this court held that “the catchall phrase ‘other charge’ captures any financial
    obligation provided it is ‘imposed by the exporting country on the exportation of the
    subject merchandise,’ regardless of whether the imposing country explicitly labels the
    charge as one pertaining to exports.” Jacobi (AR 7) 
    I, 222 F. Supp. 3d at 1186
    -87
    (emphasis added). In other words, the court considered “other charge” inherently
    ambiguous and Commerce reasonably interpreted the phrase to encompass
    irrecoverable VAT.
    Upon Commerce’s further consideration of the record and recognition that, with
    regard to activated carbon, China simply imposes an output VAT on domestic and
    export sales, the issue is now whether Commerce may apply the statute, 19 U.S.C.
    § 1677a(c)(2)(B), to a VAT that is equally applicable to domestic and export sales. This
    court determines that section 1677a(c)(2)(B)’s reference to “export tax[es], dut[ies], or
    other charge[s] imposed by the exporting country on the exportation of the subject
    merchandise” is ambiguous as to whether the statute applies to such assessments
    imposed solely upon export sales or assessments imposed upon sales at the time of
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                        Page 28
    export, regardless of whether the assessment is also applied to domestic sales. But cf.
    
    Qingdao, 308 F. Supp. 3d at 1343
    ; China Mfrs., 
    2019 WL 221237
    , at *4.
    The notion that the imposition of a tax, duty or other charge that is generally
    applicable to both domestic and export sales does not alone preclude it from providing
    the basis for an adjustment pursuant to section 1677a(c)(2)(B) finds support in the U.S.
    Supreme Court’s Export Clause jurisprudence. The Export Clause provides: “No Tax or
    Duty shall be laid on Articles exported from any State.” U.S. Const., Art. 1, § 9, cl. 5. In
    United States v. International Business Machines Corp. (“IBM”), the Court held that the
    Export Clause bars the imposition of a generally applicable federal tax on goods in
    export transit, even if the tax is nondiscriminatory and equally applicable to non-export
    transactions. 
    517 U.S. 843
    , 845, 863 (1996); see also United States v. U.S. Shoe
    Corp., 
    523 U.S. 360
    , 363, 370 (1998) (holding that a harbor maintenance tax collected
    from exporters, importers, and domestic shippers and imposed at the time of loading for
    exports and unloading for other shipments violated the Export Clause as applied to
    exports). While the context in which those cases arose is arguably distinct,
    notwithstanding any such distinctions, IBM and U.S. Shoe support the proposition that a
    statutory reference to an export tax, duty, or other charge imposed upon exportation
    may include such a tax, duty or other charge also imposed on domestic sales.
    The court now turns to consideration of whether Commerce’s interpretation of
    section 1677a(c)(2)(B) was reasonable when applied to China’s output VAT in this case.
    Here, Commerce interpreted section 1677a(c)(2)(B) to permit a reduction to EP/CEP in
    order to achieve a tax neutral comparison between EP/CEP and normal value, see 2nd
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                        Page 29
    Remand Results at 30 & n.139, and such an interpretation, as discussed more fully
    below, was reasonable.
    As an initial matter, it is important to bear in mind that here, normal value is not
    based on home-market (i.e., domestic) sales prices, but is based on the respondent’s
    factors of production and corresponding surrogate values, which are determined on a
    tax-exclusive basis. 18 In such a case, the principle that dumping margin calculations
    should be tax-neutral supports Commerce’s adjustment. 19
    The Federal Circuit recognized more than two decades ago:
    Buried in the language of statute and case law, and obscured by the fog of
    litigation, is a simple policy issue: whether Congress, in the Tariff Act of
    1930 (the Act), precluded Commerce from determining dumping margins
    in a tax-neutral fashion.
    Federal Mogul Corp. v. United States, 
    63 F.3d 1572
    , 1577 (Fed. Cir. 1995). The
    question, then, is whether Congress, when it did not substantively alter section 1677a in
    18 In a proceeding involving a market economy country, a comparable tax-neutral
    comparison would be achieved by reducing the normal value for “taxes imposed directly
    upon the foreign like product . . . which have been rebated, or which have not been
    collected, on the subject merchandise, but only to the extent that such taxes are added
    to or included in the price of the foreign like product.” 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(a)(6)(B)(iii).
    19 Indeed, the Qingdao court recognized that Congress intended for Commerce to
    deduct export taxes from U.S. price in order to “achieve a tax-neutral comparison [with]
    normal value” in a market economy proceeding precisely because an export tax is not
    included in the home-market or comparison market price used to calculate normal
    
    value. 308 F. Supp. 3d at 1342-43
    . So too here, output VAT is not included in the
    surrogate values used to calculate normal value and, thus, notwithstanding the facts
    that output VAT is assessed on domestic sales of activated carbon and this is a
    nonmarket economy proceeding, the same principle of tax neutrality supports
    Commerce’s deduction of output VAT from U.S. price.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                          Page 30
    the URAA, 20 intended to prohibit Commerce from using that provision to achieve tax
    neutrality in nonmarket economy cases? This court can find no such intention.
    First, the pre-URAA version of the statute clearly permitted Commerce to make
    tax-neutral dumping calculations. Whether it was through adjustments to foreign market
    value or purchase price/exporter’s sales price, Federal Mogul confirms that “one thing is
    clear[:] . . . in administering the Act, [Commerce] over the years has pursued a policy of
    attempting to make the tax adjustment called for by the Act 
    tax-neutral.” 63 F.3d at 1580
    (further holding that nothing in the pre-URAA version of section 1677a precluded
    Commerce from achieving tax-neutrality in its administration of the provision requiring
    an upward adjustment to U.S. price to account for taxes included in the home market
    sales price and rebated or exempted in the context of exports sales). 21 Commerce’s
    policy accords with the principle that differences in sales prices due to differential tax
    treatment between the home market and export market “does not constitute unfair
    pricing behavior” but, rather, “is a difference created by forces outside the control of the
    20 The Statement of Administrative Action accompanying the URAA explained that
    although Congress gave new labels to “purchase price” and “exporter’s sale price,” now
    “export price” and “constructed export price,” respectively, the adjustments to those
    prices pursuant to section 1677a were unchanged. See 
    Qingdao, 308 F. Supp. 3d at 1339
    -40 (citing Uruguay Round Agreements Act, Statement of Administrative Action ,
    H.R. Doc. No. 103–316, vol. 1, at 822–23 (1994), reprinted in 1994 U.S.C.C.A.N. 4040,
    4163) (“SAA”)). Congress likewise renamed “foreign market value” to “normal value.”
    SAA at 820, 1994 U.S.C.C.A.N. at 4161. The SAA is the authoritative interpretation of
    the statute. 19 U.S.C. § 3512(d); RHP Bearings Ltd. v. United States, 
    288 F.3d 1334
    ,
    1345 n.7 (Fed. Cir. 2002).
    21 At least as early as 1991, Commerce adjusted export price to enable a tax-neutral
    comparison to foreign market value. See U.S. Dep’t Commerce, Int’l Trade Admin.,
    Import Admin., Antidumping Manual Chapter 7, pp. 8-10 (1991). As noted, the URAA
    did not affect any substantive change to these adjustments. See supra, note 20.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                      Page 31
    competitor, and does not involve the idea behind the antidumping act,” which is to
    prevent unfair competition from dumping. 
    Id. at 1575
    (citation omitted).
    Second, the suggestion that Congress, by providing for adjustments to normal
    value or EP/CEP, is legislating adjustments to increase or decrease the margin of
    dumping is unsupported. But cf., e.g., 
    Qingdao, 308 F. Supp. 3d at 1341
    , 1343
    (discussing congressional intent to impact the dumping margin through certain
    adjustments). To the contrary, Congress, when it enacted the URAA, intended to
    ensure that Commerce could continue to make the adjustments to normal value and
    EP/CEP necessary in order to place both prices, to the extent possible, on the same
    basis, permitting a “fair, ‘apples-to-apples’ comparison.” Maverick Tube Corp. v. United
    States, 
    861 F.3d 1269
    , 1274 (Fed. Cir. 2017) (quoting Torrington Co. v. United States,
    
    68 F.3d 1347
    , 1352 (Fed. Cir. 1995)); see also SAA at 827, 1994 U.S.C.C.A.N. at 4166
    (noting that a new statutory provision regarding deductions from normal value to
    account for indirect taxes represents a change from the pre-URAA statute that
    accounted for indirect taxes through an upward adjustment to export price, which
    change “is intended to ensure that dumping margins will be tax-neutral”). Typically,
    these adjustments lead to ex-factory prices, packed in the same manner, and on the
    same tax basis. See SAA at 827.
    Third, as discussed above, there is no indication that before 2012, Commerce (or
    Congress) considered section 1677a to be inapplicable in NME cases. See
    Methodological Change, 77 Fed. Reg. at 36,482; Pure Magnesium from Russia, 60 Fed.
    Reg. at 16,448 (noting that, in NME cases, “pecuniary aspects of internal transactions
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 32
    are considered meaningless and thus ignored”). Rather, Commerce considered itself
    unable to apply the provision in NME cases because “pervasive government
    intervention . . . precluded proper valuation of taxes paid by NME respondents to NME
    governments.” Methodological Change, 77 Fed. Reg. at 36,482. Thus, while it may be
    the case that, all other things being equal, a dumping margin calculated before
    Commerce’s policy shift would be lower than a margin calculated inclusive of an
    adjustment pursuant to section 1677a(c)(2)(B), there is nothing to indicate that the latter
    is not in accordance with law. Instead, the latter margin calculation simply includes an
    additional data point that Commerce was unable to include in the former.
    Finally, returning to the “policy issue” identified in Federal Mogul, adjusting
    EP/CEP for VAT imposed on export sales allows Commerce to calculate a tax-neutral
    dumping margin when normal value is calculated exclusive of VAT. In this case, as
    discussed in more detail below, the constructed export price reported by Jacobi includes
    17 percent output VAT imposed by the Chinese government, whereas the normal value,
    to which it is to be compared, is determined using surrogate values that are tax-
    exclusive. See 2nd Remand Results at 30 & n.139. To interpret section 1677a(c)(2)(B)
    as unambiguously barring Commerce from adjusting EP/CEP for these taxes when
    comparing those prices to a tax-exclusive normal value would be to require that it
    understate the margin of dumping. The court finds no support for such a requirement in
    the language of the statute. Thus, Commerce’s conclusion that China’s output VAT is
    an “export tax, duty, or other charge imposed by the exporting country on the
    exportation of the subject merchandise” is a permissible interpretation of section
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                       Page 33
    1677a(c)(2)(B), 2nd Remand Results at 31, and the court now turns to Jacobi’s
    arguments that the adjustment is unsupported by substantial evidence.
    D. Commerce’s Adjustment is Supported by Substantial Evidence
    Jacobi argues that Commerce’s determination that 17 percent output VAT is
    included in Jacobi’s constructed exported price lacks substantial evidence. See
    Jacobi’s Opp’n Cmts. at 13-14, 16. According to Jacobi, the existence of a “legal
    requirement” to collect output VAT on its U.S. sales is not evidence that it includes 17
    percent output VAT in sales prices to the United States. 
    Id. at 16.
    Jacobi points to its
    sales documentation submitted on the record and notes the lack of any reference to
    output VAT. See 
    id. at 13-14
    (citing Jacobi’s Sec. A Questionnaire Resp. (July 15,
    2015) (“Jacobi’s § AQR”), Ex. A-17, CR 27, 30, CRJA Tab 5). Jacobi further contends
    that Commerce has ignored the court’s instruction to address evidence that Jacobi
    offsets paid input VAT against the output VAT due. 
    Id. at 14.
    Jacobi also contends that
    Aristocraft remains relevant and Commerce erred in failing to address the opinion. 
    Id. at 15-16.
    The Government contends that Jacobi’s reporting of its output VAT collection
    obligations represents substantial evidence that output VAT was included in its U.S.
    prices and Jacobi’s sales documentation does not detract from the substantiality of that
    evidence. Def.’s Reply Cmts. at 16-17. The Government further contends that
    Commerce properly discounted the relevance of Jacobi’s ability to offset input VAT from
    output VAT and its calculation of a net VAT payable amount because Commerce’s
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                         Page 34
    margin calculations are intended to account for the amount of VAT included in U.S.
    price, not Jacobi’s net VAT burden. 
    Id. at 17-18.
    Calgon contends that because “the cost of output VAT falls on the buyer of the
    good, not on the [seller],” Def.-Ints.’ Reply Cmts. at 14 (quoting 2nd Remand Results at
    27), it is “necessarily included in Jacobi’s price,” 
    id. Calgon further
    contends that
    Commerce adequately addressed the court’s questions regarding the relationship
    between input VAT and output VAT and the relevance of the Aristocraft opinion in light
    of activated carbon’s treatment under Chinese VAT law. 
    Id. at 15-16.
    22
    The court sustains Commerce’s VAT adjustment. The absence of a line item for
    output VAT on Jacobi’s sales documents is not dispositive and the record supports
    Commerce’s determination that Jacobi’s export prices include output VAT. See
    Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. United States, 
    750 F.2d 927
    , 933 (Fed. Cir. 1984) (the
    possibility of drawing two inconsistent conclusions from the evidence does not preclude
    the agency’s finding from being supported by substantial evidence) (citing Consolo v.
    Fed. Mar. Comm’n, 
    383 U.S. 607
    , 619–20 (1966)).
    Here, Jacobi concedes that its U.S. sales were subject to the collection of 17
    percent output VAT pursuant to the 2012 VAT Notice. See Jacobi’s Opp’n Cmts. at 16;
    2012 VAT Notice, Art. 7.2(1). Jacobi suggests, however, that it calculates the net VAT
    payable amount as if it collected output VAT on U.S. sales, but that it does not actually
    collect output VAT on those sales. See Jacobi’s Opp’n Cmts. at 16. In making this
    22   CAC did not comment on this issue.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                          Page 35
    claim, Jacobi points to no affirmative evidence demonstrating that the FOB China port
    value reflected in its sales documents is output VAT-exclusive. See Jacobi’s § AQR,
    Ex. A-17 at ECF p. 94. The record reasonably supports Commerce’s conclusion that
    Jacobi’s U.S. prices included output VAT—regardless of whether Jacobi itemized that
    charge in its sales documents.
    Moreover, contrary to Jacobi’s arguments, see Jacobi’s Opp’n Cmts. at 14-15,
    Commerce did not impermissibly base its adjustment on the contemporaneous Chinese
    law while ignoring evidence of Jacobi’s net VAT payment. The statute directs
    Commerce to make adjustments based on certain amounts included in U.S. price, not
    amounts remitted to the subject nonmarket economy government. 23 See 19 U.S.C.
    § 1677a(c)(2)(B).
    In sum, Commerce’s redetermination on this issue complies with the court’s
    remand instructions set forth in Jacobi (AR8) I and the agency’s deduction of output
    VAT from Jacobi’s constructed export price is lawful and supported by substantial
    evidence.
    CONCLUSION AND ORDER
    In accordance with the foregoing, it is hereby
    ORDERED that Commerce’s 2nd Remand Results are remanded for Commerce
    to reconsider its surrogate country selection as well as the surrogate values for
    23The court also notes that Jacobi’s argument that it “only pays the Chinese
    government the ‘net’ VAT amount,” Jacobi’s Opp’n Cmts. at 14, is inaccurate. While the
    net VAT payment may represent Jacobi’s direct VAT payment to the Chinese
    government, Jacobi is simply reducing the output VAT it collected by the input VAT it
    has already paid to the Chinese government, albeit indirectly via its purchases of inputs.
    Consol. Court No. 16-00185                                                       Page 36
    carbonized material and hydrochloric acid, as set forth in Discussion Section I above; it
    is further
    ORDERED that Commerce’s 2nd Remand Results are sustained with respect to
    the agency’s VAT adjustment, as set forth in Discussion Section II above; it is further
    ORDERED that, in the event Commerce amends the antidumping margin
    assigned to Jacobi, Commerce reconsider the separate rate assigned to non-mandatory
    respondents; it is further
    ORDERED that Commerce shall file its second remand results on or before
    June 3, 2019; it is further
    ORDERED that the deadlines provided in USCIT Rule 56.2(h) shall govern
    thereafter; and it is further
    ORDERED that any opposition or supportive comments must not exceed 6,000
    words.
    /s/   Mark A. Barnett
    Mark A. Barnett, Judge
    Dated: March 5, 2019
    New York, New York