Gold East Paper (Jiangsu) Co. v. United States , 121 F. Supp. 3d 1304 ( 2015 )


Menu:
  •                                           Slip Op. 15 - 131
    UNITED STATES COURT OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
    :
    GOLD EAST PAPER (JIANGSU) CO., LTD.,         :
    NINGBO ZHONGHUA PAPER CO., LTD.,             :
    and GLOBAL PAPER SOLUTIONS,                  :
    :
    Plaintiffs,   : Before: R. Kenton Musgrave, Senior Judge
    :
    and                       : Consol. Court No. 10-00371
    :
    BUREAU OF FAIR TRADE FOR IMPORTS             :
    & EXPORTS, MINISTRY OF COMMERCE,             :
    PEOPLE’S REPUBLIC OF CHINA,                  :
    :
    Plaintiff-Intervenor, :
    :
    v.                       :
    :
    UNITED STATES,                               :
    :
    Defendant, :
    :
    and                       :
    :
    APPLETON COATED LLC, NEWPAGE CORP., :
    S.D. WARREN COMPANY d/b/a SAPPI FINE :
    PAPER NORTH AMERICA, and UNITED              :
    STEEL, PAPER AND FORESTRY, RUBBER,           :
    MANUFACTURING, ENERGY, ALLIED                :
    INDUSTRIAL AND SERVICE WORKERS               :
    INTERNATIONAL UNION, AFL-CIO-CLC,            :
    :
    Defendant-Intervenors. :
    :
    OPINION
    [Sustaining third results of administrative redetermination on investigation of sales at less than fair
    value of certain coated paper from the People’s Republic of China.]
    Decided: November 23, 2015
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                               Page 2
    Daniel L. Porter, James P. Durling, and Claudia D. Hartleben, Curtis, Mallet-Prevost, Colt
    & Mosle LLP, of Washington DC, for the plaintiffs and plaintiff-intervenor.
    Alexander V. Sverdlov, Trial Attorney, Commercial Litigation Branch, Civil Division, U.S.
    Department of Justice, of Washington DC, for defendant. With him on the brief were Benjamin C.
    Mizer, Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General, Jeanne E. Davidson, Director, and Claudia
    Burke, Assistant Director. Of Counsel on the brief was Mykhaylo A. Gryzlov, Senior Attorney,
    Office of the Chief Counsel for Import Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce.
    Terence P. Stewart, William A. Fennell, and Stephanie M. Bell, Stewart and Stewart, of
    Washington, DC, and Gilbert B. Kaplan, Joseph W. Dorn, and Daniel L. Schneiderman, King &
    Spalding, LLP, of Washington DC, for the defendant-intervenors.
    Musgrave, Senior Judge: The defendant’s International Trade Administration, U.S.
    Department of Commerce (“Commerce”) has submitted its third Final Results of Redetermination
    Pursuant to Court Remand (“Redetermination” or “RR3”) on the antidumping duty investigation
    into Certain Coated Paper from the PRC.1 Familiarity with the case2 is presumed. To summarize,
    the investigation was remanded for (1) further insight into the use of market economy purchase
    (“MEP”) prices for certain inputs procured from the Kingdom of Thailand by or for the plaintiffs
    (herein “APP-China”), and (2) further explanation of the targeted dumping methodology utilized.
    1
    Certain Coated Paper Suitable for High-Quality Print Graphics Using Sheet-Fed Presses
    from the People’s Republic of China, 75 Fed. Reg. 59217 (Sept. 27, 2010), PDoc 360, as amended
    by Certain Coated Paper Suitable for High-Quality Print Graphics Using Sheet-Fed Presses from
    the People’s Republic of China: Amended Final Determination of Sales at Less than Fair Value and
    Antidumping Order, 75 Fed. Reg. 70203 (Nov. 17, 2010) (“Final Determination”), and
    accompanying issues and decision memorandum (“IDM”), PDoc 353. The period of investigation
    (“POI”) covers January 1, 2009 through June 30, 2009.
    2
    See Gold East Paper (Jiangsu) Co. v. United States, 37 CIT ___, 
    918 F. Supp. 2d 1317
    (2013) (“Gold East I”) (remanding), 38 CIT ___, 
    991 F. Supp. 2d 1357
    (2014) (“Gold East II”)
    (remanding), 39 CIT ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d 1289
    (2015) (“Gold East III”) (remanding).
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                     Page 3
    On remand, Commerce determined to disregard the MEP prices for the relevant inputs
    from Thailand because they had likely benefitted from subsidies and therefore were likely distorted.
    This changed the calculation of the normal value for APP-China but not the number of APP-China
    sales that were found to be targeted. See RR3 at10. Commerce also considered whether its current
    differential pricing methodology involving the Cohen’s d test was a more appropriate measure of
    whether the targeted sales were “pervasive” than the prior Nails test. 
    Id. at 8-11.
    After considering
    the question, Commerce determined that it was not; therefore it continued to rely on the Nails test
    in determining that APP-China’s targeted was not “pervasive.” 
    Id. However, due
    to the changes in
    APP-China’s calculated normal value occasioned by the foregoing, Commerce determined that it
    was appropriate to apply the average-to-transaction (“A-T”) comparison to APP-China’s targeted
    sales, and to apply the standard average-to-average (“A-A”) comparison to the remainder. 
    Id. at 9
    n.42. APP-China’s final dumping margin was 3.64 percent. 
    Id. APP-China contests
    Commerce’s decision to reject the Thai input prices, and the
    defendant-intervenors (“Appleton”) argue for remand of the targeted dumping issue, in particular
    the agency’s decision to rely on the Nails test instead of differential pricing analysis. These issues
    are addressed in turn.
    I
    APP-China argues that Commerce’s disregard of Thai prices for certain inputs
    represents an unexplained and unlawful reversal from the second remand determination. See
    generally APP-China Br. at 2 11. The court concludes otherwise.
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                      Page 4
    As previously noted, Commerce may disregard prices for inputs purchased from
    market-economy countries based on its prior findings that a country maintained broadly-available,
    non-industry-specific export subsidies, if there is no evidence that the subsidy had been terminated
    and the flow of benefits had ceased. See Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1297-98.
    Among other things, Commerce’s normal practice when analyzing whether claimed MEPs for inputs
    are useable is to provide parties with an opportunity to submit “evidence that the program has been
    terminated and flow of the residual benefits has ceased”. See 
    id., 39 CIT
    at ___ n.16, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1297 n.16 (quoting Commerce’s practice). Commerce in the second remand explained its
    practice but at the time believed that its use had been precluded by the law of the case. Gold East
    III, however, clarified that the practice was not inconsistent therewith and could be used. See 
    id., 39 CIT
    at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1297-98. Thus, during the third remand, Commerce applied its
    normal practice and analyzed the evidence that had been submitted during the second remand in
    accordance with its established standards. See RR3 at 6, 15.
    Commerce explained that the evidence indicated that the Thai Tax Certificates for
    Export program had previously been countervailed as a generally-available export subsidy. See RR3
    at 6, citing Certain Apparel From Thailand: Final Results of Countervailing Duty Administrative
    Review, 62 Fed. Reg. 63071 (Nov. 26, 1997) (“1997 Apparel Review”). Absent evidence that the
    program was terminated and the flow of benefits ceased, Commerce considers that the benefits under
    the program continue, and in this matter Commerce found that such evidence had not been
    provided.3 Based on the information of record, therefore, Commerce determined that there was
    3
    RR3 at 6 (“[d]espite the opportunities to provide such evidence in the original investigation
    (continued...)
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                     Page 5
    reason to believe or suspect that Thai prices were distorted by subsidies and that APP-China’s
    claimed MEPs therefor should be disregarded. RR3 at 6.
    APP-China argues that Commerce improperly changed its position from the second
    remand, or that it did not articulate the basis for a different conclusion when “the legal standard did
    not change and there is no new factual evidence.” APP-China Br. at 3. However, the legal standard
    itself did not change, Commerce’s understanding of it did after the prior decisions on the case were
    clarified in the latest remand opinion. Commerce detailed how this changed understanding led to
    a different result. See RR3 at 6, 15 (noting that “given . . . clarification that [Commerce’s] normal
    practice is not at odds with [prior judicial] decisions,” there was no reason “to depart from [the]
    normal practice here”).
    APP-China contends that the presumption Commerce uses contravenes the Federal
    Circuit’s holding in AK Steel Corp. v. United States, 
    192 F.3d 1367
    (Fed. Cir. 1999). APP-China
    Br. at 3-4. In APP-China’s view, that case stands for the proposition that Commerce “must provide
    evidence to support a reasonable inference that the subsidy continues into the period of
    investigation.” 
    Id. (emphasis omitted).
    AK Steel considered what evidence was required to support
    finding that a countervailable subsidy actually existed for purposes of actually imposing a
    countervailing duty order. See generally AK 
    Steel, 192 F.3d at 1370
    . The Federal Circuit explained
    that when analyzing this issue in the context of a full-blown countervailing duty investigation, the
    3
    (...continued)
    and subsequently in response to Commerce’s reopening of the record in the second remand,
    APP-China has not provided any evidence that the tax coupon program has been terminated and the
    flow of benefits has ceased” ). By contrast, Commerce found that the petitioners had submitted
    information showing that recent changes to the Thai laws continued the subsidy program. See
    generally RR3 at 4; Gold East III39 CIT at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1295-96.
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                     Page 6
    fact that a subsidy existed at some point is insufficient; it must be found to have existed during the
    relevant period. AK 
    Steel, 192 F.3d at 1376
    . AK Steel is therefore inapposite, because the standard
    for finding the existence of a subsidy in the countervailing duty context necessary to support
    imposition of a countervailing duty is higher, and therefore different, from a “reason to believe or
    suspect” standard that permits disregard of prices Commerce reasonably believes or suspects are
    distorted.4 The prior remand order explicitly recognized that this standard can be satisfied when a
    subsidy program is shown to have existed in the past, and no evidence is presented showing that the
    program has been terminated and the flow of benefits has ceased. See Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___,
    
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1298-99. On remand, Commerce found that to be the case based on prior
    countervailing duty proceedings that found broadly available, non-industry-specific export subsidies
    in Thailand, and APP-China submitted no evidence showing that the program had been terminated.
    See RR3 at 6, 15. And substantial evidence of record supports that determination. See 
    id. APP-China’s argument
    that Commerce’s remand analysis does not satisfy the test set
    out in Fuyao II fails for the same reason. See APP-China Br. at 5-7. The decision in Gold East III
    4
    The court has previously observed that the “reason to believe or suspect” standard is “a
    relatively low threshold.” Zhejiang Mach. Imp. & Exp. Corp. v. United States, 
    31 CIT 159
    , 169, 
    473 F. Supp. 2d 1365
    , 1374 (2007) (internal quotes and citations omitted). It does not require that
    Commerce conduct a formal investigation or determine that the particular supplier or product at issue
    benefitted from a specific subsidy: “Congress did not intend to require Commerce to conduct formal
    investigations in situations like this, and did not intend Commerce to definitively determine whether
    prices actually are subsidized.” 
    Zhejiang, 31 CIT at 168
    , 473 F. Supp. 2d at 1374 (italics in
    original); see also China Nat’l Mach. Imp. & Exp. Corp. v. United States, 
    27 CIT 1553
    , 1557, 
    293 F. Supp. 2d 1334
    , 1338 (2003) (“[t]he ‘reason to believe or suspect’ standard articulated in the House
    Report by which Commerce’s actions must be evaluated establishes a lower threshold than what is
    required to support a firm conclusion”). All that is required is that Commerce have some evidence
    supporting its suspicion that subsidy programs may exist. See generally 
    Zhejiang, 31 CIT at 168
    -70,
    473 F. Supp. 2d at 1374-75.
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                      Page 7
    clarified that Fuyao II is just one way that Commerce may evaluate whether the evidence before it
    gives it a reason to believe or suspect that prices have been distorted, and is not the only “reasonable
    method.” Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1298-99; see also CS Wind Vietnam Co.
    v. United States, 38 CIT ___, ___, 
    971 F. Supp. 2d 1271
    , 1292 (2014) (making a similar
    observation). Commerce did not have to satisfy the particular test of Fuyao II as long as it
    “articulated with sufficient clarity” why it has “a valid belief or suspicion that input prices are
    distorted.” Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1299. Commerce has done so here.
    Commerce first recognized that it had previously countervailed the Thai tax coupon
    program as an export subsidy and pointed to a determination in which it had done so. See RR3 at
    6, 18. Commerce described this program as one through which the Thai government “issue[d] tax
    certificates to exporters of record to rebate indirect taxes and import duties levied on inputs into
    exported products.” 
    Id. at 18
    n.77. Next, Commerce explained that, under its practice, once the
    agency has determined that a particular program is countervailable, there is a presumption that the
    subsidy continues to exist absent evidence that the program has been terminated or benefits have
    ceased. 
    Id. at 6-7;
    see Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1297. Commerce noted that
    APP-China has placed no information on the record to suggest that the program has been terminated
    or that benefits have ceased, and therefore this presumption has not been rebutted. RR3 at 6. Finally,
    Commerce explained that the existence and availability of the countervailable export subsidy makes
    it reasonable to assume that the export prices of Thai goods are distorted. 
    Id. at 6-7.
    Cf. China Nat’l
    Mach. Imp. & Exp. Corp. v. United States, 
    27 CIT 1553
    , 1558, 
    293 F. Supp. 2d 1334
    , 1339 (2003)
    (“Commerce’s actions are reasonable because a company like CMC’s suppliers may have benefitted
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                      Page 8
    from a generally available subsidy program given the competitive nature of the industry and by virtue
    of having engaged in foreign trade”). Commerce’s remand thus articulates the basis for finding Thai
    prices distorted: it explains that the evidence of prior broadly-available, non-industry-specific export
    subsidies gives rise to an inference that prices may remain distorted by such subsidies, and justifies
    disregarding those prices in the absence of contrary evidence. No more is required.
    Turning away from the legal standard, APP-China challenges how Commerce
    evaluated the evidence before it. But these challenges have no greater merit. For example, APP-
    China complains that Commerce improperly found the existence of generally-available subsidies
    based on only one piece of evidence -- the 1997 Apparel Review. APP-China Br. at 5. But that
    ignores that Commerce also observed that it repeatedly “countervailed the Tax Certificates for
    Export Program as an export subsidy, first in 1989 Iron Pipe Investigation,” as well as the 1997
    Apparel Review. RR3 at 18 (citations omitted). Each of these determinations was supported by a
    fully-developed administrative record showing that Thai exporters were, in fact, receiving subsidies.
    Contrary to APP-China’s assertions, the mere fact that time had passed since these
    determinations were made does not, in itself, demonstrate that the subsidy terminated and the flow
    of benefits has ceased. See APP-China Br. at 5. Rather, under Commerce’s normal practice
    (recognized in Gold East III as consistent with prior judicial decisions) APP-China was required to
    provide affirmative evidence to rebut the presumption that the program continues. The fact that the
    orders countervailing the tax coupon program had been revoked since 2000 does not constitute such
    information because, as previously stated, “[r]evocation is a discrete agency action, and the act
    thereof does not invalidate the prior administrative findings and conclusions upon which the issuance
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                    Page 9
    of the countervailing or antidumping duty order being revoked was validly predicated.” Gold East
    III, 39 CIT at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1297 (citing Canadian Wheat Bd. v. United States, 32 CIT ___,
    ___, 
    580 F. Supp. 2d 1350
    (2008), aff’d 
    641 F.2d 1344
    (Fed. Cir. 2011)). Indeed, revocation of a
    countervailing duty order may occur for any number reasons, e.g., a lack of interest by the domestic
    industry or no likelihood of continuation or recurrence of material injury. That an order is revoked
    therefore does not automatically mean that the export subsidy program was terminated and the flow
    of benefits ceased; APP-China was required to provide affirmative evidence that this happened,
    which it apparently did not. See APP-China Br. at 4 (conceding that “affirmative evidence of the
    record may not directly demonstrate that the subsidy program examined in 1997 (i.e., Tax
    Certificates for Exports programs) has been terminated.”).
    APP-China’s suggestion that the information petitioners submitted during the
    investigation may pertain to a different subsidy program than the one found to be countervailable in
    the 1997 Apparel Review is not relevant for the same reason. See APP-China’s Br. at 8. Simply put,
    Commerce is not required to provide affirmative evidence that the subsidy found in the 1997 Apparel
    Review remains unchanged in all respects to infer that prices may continue to be distorted -- rather,
    APP-China must provide affirmative evidence that the program was terminated and the flow of
    benefits has ceased. Commerce expressly declined to decide on remand whether the evidence
    submitted by petitioners “provide[d] an additional basis for the reason to believe or suspect” that
    prices may have been distorted, explaining that such a finding is not necessary. See RR3 at 16.
    APP-China’s critiques of that evidence are therefore unavailing. See APP-China Br. at 8-9.
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                 Page 10
    As an alternative argument, APP-China speculates that the information submitted by
    petitioners may nevertheless show that the subsidy program was somehow modified to no longer
    providing a subsidy. See APP-China Br. at 10. However, APP-China did not persuade Commerce
    that any subsequent modifications to the law under which the program was originally established
    have led to termination of the program and cause the flow of the benefits to cease, and Commerce
    found no reason to assume that they did.5 Commerce considered that the evidence provided by
    petitioners was “even more remote,” Def’s Resp. at 10, because it did not relate to the program
    directly but rather to amendments to the law under which the program was originally established,
    but APP-China did not offer any analysis of the alleged changes or how they may affect the program,
    nor did it explain how these unspecified amendments could reasonably alleviate the reason to believe
    or suspect that exports from Thailand may have been subsidized. APP-China simply stated that some
    unspecified changes took place and, thus, Commerce should assume the program terminated. This
    type of speculation is not enough to displace Commerce’s reasoning.
    APP-China also argues that the tax program is a fact-specific export subsidy, not a
    broadly-available one, and therefore cannot be considered to benefit APP-China’s suppliers.
    APP-China Br. at 6. Pointing to Commerce’s 2001 countervailing duty investigation into hot-rolled
    carbon steel products from Thailand, APP-China argues that Commerce’s findings suggest that the
    program was designed “to rebate indirect taxes and import duties on inputs used to produce exports”
    and that the program provided a benefit only when it exceeded a certain allowable amount. 
    Id. 5 Commerce
    explains that countries that provide countervailable subsidies to their industries
    may modify their program from time to time, but that many modifications are of a technical nature
    and do not lead to the termination of a program. Def’s Resp. at 10.
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                    Page 11
    (internal quotes omittes), citing Affirmative Countervailing Duty Determination: Certain Hot-Rolled
    Carbon Steel Flat Products From Thailand, 66 Fed. Reg. 50410 (Oct. 3, 2001) (“2001 Hot-Rolled
    Carbon Steel Flat Products”). APP-China contends that Commerce was required to find that
    APP-China’s suppliers satisfied both conditions before disregarding the prices APP-China paid. 
    Id. Commerce’s response
    is that such findings are only required if it needed to establish
    for certain the particular amount of a subsidy that actually existed, whereas the statutory requirement
    that it have a “reason to believe or suspect” that prices may be subsidized requires no such showing.
    Commerce also notes that in the 1997 Apparel Review, it found that the Tax Certificates for Export
    program is an export subsidy, which can benefit companies in a number of different ways. Def’s
    Resp. at 11, referencing Certain Apparel From Thailand: Preliminary Results of Countervailing
    Duty Administrative Review, 62 FR 46475, 46477 (Sep. 3, 1997), unchanged in 1997 Apparel
    Review, and Wheatland Tube Corp. v. United States, 
    17 CIT 1230
    , 1231, 
    841 F. Supp. 1222
    , 1224
    (1993) (explaining that “tax certificates rebate indirect taxes and duties on both physically
    incorporated inputs, and non-physically incorporated inputs (e.g. fuel, office equipment and
    services)” and “remission of indirect taxes and duties on the non-physically incorporated inputs is
    countervailable”).6 Commerce further argues that the fact that one company in an unrelated industry
    in the 2001 Hot-Rolled Carbon Steel Flat Products investigation was found to have not taken
    advantage of the subsidy program does not mean that the subsidy was not broadly available or that
    there is no reason to believe or suspect that APP-China’s producers could have taken advantage of
    the subsidy, and again, for that matter, APP-China had an opportunity to submit affirmative evidence
    6
    Commerce also notes that APP-China does not contend that its suppliers do not use
    non-physically incorporated items (such as fuel, office equipment or services).
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                    Page 12
    showing that its suppliers were not eligible for this subsidy program but apparently did not do so.
    See 
    id. at 11-12.
    In the absence of such evidence, it was not unreasonable for Commerce to presume
    the continued existence of a broadly-available, non-industry-specific program that may have
    distorted APP-China’s suppliers’ prices, and in the final analysis, APP-China does not point to any
    affirmative evidence showing that the subsidy program was terminated and the flow of benefits had
    ceased. Instead, APP-China essentially asks the court to infer as much based on its own weighing
    of the evidence on the record, which the court cannot do. The question is not whether the court
    agrees with Commerce’s conclusion or whether it would have reached the same result as Commerce
    if the matter were here de novo, the question is rather whether the agency’s decision is reasonable
    and supported by the record as a whole. See Nippon Steel Corp. v. United States, 
    458 F.3d 1345
    ,
    1352 (Fed. Cir. 2006) (citing Mitsubishi Heavy Indus., Ltd. v. United States, 
    275 F.3d 1056
    , 1060
    (Fed. Cir. 2001)). Commerce’s determination satisfies that standard; accordingly, it will be sustained.
    II
    For its part, Appleton continues to argue that Commerce should have employed the
    Cohen’s d test in its targeted dumping analysis. According to Appleton, Commerce’s current
    Cohen’s d test is the best way to determine whether the respondent’s targeted dumping was
    “pervasive” and therefore appropriate to determining whether the remedy normally applied to
    targeted sales should be used on all sales made by respondents. However, Appleton’s comments do
    not show that Commerce’s decision to use the Nails test was unreasonable.
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                  Page 13
    The question of whether a respondent’s targeting is pervasive derives from
    Commerce’s earlier regulation which has since been withdrawn. See 19 C.F.R. §351.414(c)(1)
    (2004). That regulation provided that Commerce would “normally” account for a respondent’s
    targeting by applying the average-to-transaction (A-T) comparison only to targeted sales, and apply
    the standard -- and statutorily preferred -- average-to-average (A-A) comparison to the remainder.
    Id.; see also 19 U.S.C. §§ 1677f-1(d)(1)(A) (defining A-A as the preferred methodology);
    1677f-1(d)(1)(B)(ii) (permitting the use of the average-to-transaction methodology only if Commerce
    explained why one of the default approaches could not account for the observed pattern of price
    differences).
    The regulation provided that applying the A-T comparison to all of a respondent’s
    sales would be appropriate if the respondent’s targeting was “pervasive” or impossible to segregate.
    See Antidumping Duties; Countervailing Duties, 61 Fed. Reg. 7308, 7350 (Feb. 27, 1996);
    Antidumping Duties; Countervailing Duties, 62 Fed. Reg. 27296, 27375 (May 19, 1997) (Preamble).
    Because Gold East I found the attempt to withdraw that regulation in 2008 ineffective, the regulation
    continued to apply to the proceeding at bar. See generally Gold East I, 37 CIT ___, ___, 918 F.
    Supp. 2d 1317, 1327-28 (2013) (directing Commerce to apply the regulation in this case). Thus, the
    orders of remand requested Commerce to consider the best way to measure “pervasiveness”, for
    example through Commerce’s prior targeted dumping analysis known as the Nails test, or through
    its new, recently developed, differential pricing methodology including the Cohen’s d analysis. See
    Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1305-06.
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                     Page 14
    Considering the question, Commerce determined that the Nails test was a more
    appropriate way to measure pervasiveness under the old regulation because Commerce’s current
    differential pricing methodology was developed after the withdrawal of the regulation that
    established the pervasiveness requirement and was not designed to evaluate the regulation’s criteria.
    RR3 at 10. In Commerce’s words, the differential pricing “analysis was not designed to evaluate,
    and does not address” the requirements of “the withdrawn targeted dumping regulation.” 
    Id. Accordingly, Commerce
    continued to rely on the Nails test. 
    Id. Using that
    test, Commerce
    concluded that “the percentage of targeted sales in this case is not large enough to demonstrate that
    the targeted dumping is so pervasive or widespread as to justify” applying the A-T comparison to
    all of APP-China’s sales. Commerce therefore applied the A-T test only to the targeted sales.
    Commerce points out that Appleton does not dispute that there is no basis to apply
    the A-T comparison more broadly if the Nails test is used to measure “pervasiveness” -- that is, they
    do not dispute that, under the Nails test, APP-China’s targeted sales are neither pervasive nor
    impossible to segregate. See generally Appleton Br. at 3-11. Nor do they appear to dispute that the
    differential pricing analysis was not developed until after the old regulation was withdrawn, and
    therefore was not designed to satisfy its criteria. See 
    id. Instead, Appleton
    claims that the Nails test
    was also not designed to determine pervasiveness because it was first applied after the old regulation
    was withdrawn -- and therefore should not be preferred over the Cohen’s d test. Def-Ints’ Br. at 8.
    However, Commerce contends it adopted the Nails test before it withdrew the old regulation -- and
    first applied it while that regulation was still in effect.         Def’s Resp. at 14, referencing
    Mid-Continental Nails Corp. v. United States, 
    34 CIT 512
    , 523, 
    712 F. Supp. 2d 1370
    , 1380 (2010)
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                   Page 15
    (“[r][evocation is not an admission by Commerce that the [Nails] test is unlawful”). Commerce, in
    other words, contends that the test was designed while “pervasiveness” was still a criterion that had
    to be measured, and in fact measured that criterion.7
    Appleton also argues that the Cohen’s d test should be used to answer the
    “pervasiveness” question because it is a valid statistical tool that represents a refinement over the
    Nails test. Def-Ints’ Br. at 7. Responding, Commerce contends the argument fails for two reasons.
    Commerce first contends Appleton’s argument conflates different concepts, in that
    the differential pricing analysis is a refinement of determining whether sales satisfy the statutory
    criteria of forming a pattern of prices that differ significantly among consumers regions or time
    periods, not a refinement for determining whether targeted sales are pervasive. Commerce states that
    the reason for this is that the differential pricing analysis was developed at a time when Commerce
    understood the pervasiveness requirement to no longer apply, and that unlike the Nails test the
    differential pricing analysis “does not even measure the extent of targeted dumping per se -- rather,
    it measures all sales, those above and below normal value that exhibit a pattern of significant price
    differences” -- and using differential pricing analysis to measure “pervasiveness” of targeted (and
    dumped) sales “would therefore be extending the test far beyond its intended usage.” Def’s Resp.
    at 15, referencing RR3 at 21-22.
    7
    Commerce also contends Gold East III “explicitly disagreed with Petitioners’ claim that
    ‘pervasiveness’ is a new criteria that the Nails test did not examine.” Def’s Resp. at 15, referencing
    Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 
    61 F. Supp. 3d
    at 1304.
    Consol. Court No. 10-00371                                                                     Page 16
    The above explanation seems contrived.8 However, that is not fatal, because
    Commerce’s other point is still valid, to wit, that Appleton’s argument is essentially asking the court
    to substitute its judgment for that of the agency regarding which methodology is best suited to
    measuring regulatory criteria, and in the absence of demonstrated unreasonableness of the agency’s
    chosen methodology, it would be inappropriate for a court to substitute judgment for that of
    Commerce on resolving the problem. See, e.g., Chang Chun Petrochemical Co. v. United States,
    37 CIT ___, ___, 
    953 F. Supp. 2d 1300
    , 1306 (2013) (declining to direct Commerce to use a targeted
    dumping methodology established in 2008 in a 2004 case).
    Conclusion
    Because the methodology that Commerce employed in its remand redetermination
    was reasonable, the results will be sustained and judgment entered accordingly.
    /s/ R. Kenton Musgrave
    R. Kenton Musgrave, Senior Judge
    Dated: November 23, 2015
    New York, New York
    8
    For example, it must be the case, of course, that differential pricing does in fact “measure,”
    or at least indicate, the “extent” of targeted dumping in a sense, for if it does not do so then it runs
    the risk of being arbitrary and capricious.